Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/productiontheore00fish2 ieaH working paper department of economics THE PRODUCTION-THEORETIC MEASUREMENT OF INPUT PRICE AND QUANTITY INDICES Franklin M. Fisher No. 575 April 1991 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 THE PRODUCTION-THEORETIC MEASUREMENT OF INPUT PRICE AND QUANTITY INDICES Franklin M. Fisher No. 575 April 1991 JUL 1 8 ^ TBB-BB0DHCIIDBrTBBDBBTIC-asaSHB£[3BSI-0E IHEBT-BBICB-aMD-QUaHTIKf-IUDICSS Franklin M. Fisher ^ Massachusetts Institute of Technology Paper prepared for Conference in Honor of Zvi * Jerusalem, May 1991. forthcoming tually) Griliches, This paper adapts material from my (even- with Karl Shell book on the production- theoretic approach to price and quantity measurement. la_lD£loguc£iQD has long been understood that conventional It cost the living such as the consumer price of approximations to a measures index but are "true" index based on consumer theory. It is well accepted that measurement of prices and quantities less production are or ought to be focussed on approximating indices oased on production theory. gregates for production, properties. Indeed, of in "true" in calculating ag- concentration has oeen on arithmetical In a real sense, and practice has dominated. practice has come before theory, Yet the question of what it is chat we are trying to measure is of oovious importance. In the form considered here, in Fisher and Shell (1972) . that question was firsz raised Snell and I considered the case of the measurement of output and, especially, output prices when the production frontier oauer system (P?F) (1972) is descrioed by of a closed economy. the production possibility Following that, John Muell- pointed oun that an isomorphic theory can oe for the case of input deflation and proceeded to do so, built deriving many interesting results. Unfortunately, not however, Kuellbauer's isomorphic theory does economy characterization of its That is oecause the closed- seem of great direct interest. PPF oy fixed factor supplies has as a parallel the characterization of output as vector. fixed a Tnis means that the index numoer question oeing asked has to with the relative input usage required to produce a fixed output vector under two different regimes. narrow treatment. a (Ti\e production Since firms and systems usually do not face fixed demand vectors, do this seems too single- exception is the case of the output competitive firm.) Fortunately, low widening taat treatment does enaoie us to fol- up on Muellbauer's insight that input deflation and measure- ment requires case, production-theoretic treatment. a conditions that demand the given are not represented oy out by deflation a tiiis at quantities vector of fixed output a as firm can oe to assumption. treatment does not end the matter, however, for input and measurement is seldom done at the individual competitive firm. sold takes input deflation and usage proolem ought tnus analyzed using Such competitive firm vector of fixed output prices at which the a Tne sell. a In the simplest v7hile tne same level the of treatment of outputs fixed prices will serve for the case of a small fully open economy trading outputs on world markets at fixed prices, will not cover the case of a large economy or of industry fating downward sloping demand curves. a firm it or As it turns out, such cases can involve substantial complexities and cast doubt on tne use of Paasciie and Lasoevres indices as appropriate bounds. monetary magnitude A It change into a price effect and that the money value of example, we changes. wish to speak of (or deflationary) a .,.__;..ut real change. Thus, for is observed to increase, and a real output change versus an effect. separate desired to is inflationary Similarly, when money expenditures on we may wish to speak of the extent to which this is inputs rise, simply due to changes in factor prices and the extent to which it represents In real increase a case the income (or decrease) of the consumer, a in tne use of resources. change in the value to De separated into a price effect and a is money of change in real income. One important thing that all such examples have in common is that is natural to think it changes the side of the markets being studied faced on under analysis unit deflation; supply price index. action — from by the supply prices for factors in the case prices for goods in the case of the of output demand prices for goods in the case of deflation; input of the price effect as coming consumer Then any change in real magnitudes must involve an on the part of the unit that is different from that which would have been observed had the unit, other circumstances with unchanging, been faced with the price changes. Consider a competitive firm producing change in costs is to be divided into real change in input usage. single output. A factor-price effect and a If we consider factor price changes as coming from outside the firm, would a a then it is natural to ask have happened to costs had the otner circumstances of what cne . effect had this amounts to asking what changes in factor prices would have had if the firm remained constant. firm the Clearly, remained on the same isoquant as in the base change any further change the pure price effect; is represents a That period. costs in real change. There is another way to think about this. Any solution to the problem of measuring real aggregate input use must oegin with an answer to the following question: vectors input ootain to Since we shall be reducing index-numser scalars, complete ordering for the resulting a vectors to wnich they correspond, input and since we \;e scalars and must choose classes for input vectors such that all equivalence wisn a to the set of vectors in the same equivalent class will be said to involve the same aggre- How is this to be done? gate input. In question the case of the single-output firm, immediately suggests itself — the use of the isoquants of the production function to define equivalence classes. given technology, this the answer to we will say thai: two input vectors With correspon- ding to the same output involve the same aggregate input use. factor prices change and the firra remains on the same a If isoquant, then any cnange in money input costs will oe considered as a pure price pnenomenon. Ooviously, price index . tiiis is i_,o..,orpnic to the theory of the consumer There the consumer faces prices as given from out- side and the equivalence classes are provided by the indifference curves In the case of production, however, matters need not always oe quite so simple. For one thing, the production unit involved have monopoly or monopsony power, may taken as given from outside. the principles just described. deflation and Thus, taken A change in the money . place had the production unit responded — — real to change. — we separate the world into price effects all cases, — would merely caused oy the ocher side of the markets being studied effects input in the case of altered supply conditions and the remaining In generalization input can then be separated into the change that of nave a firm with monopsony power, input prices cannot be a taken as given, but supply conditions can value be shall treat such cases in detail I Suffice it to say now that they involve later. of so that prices cannot — and real the actions of the productive unit being studied that are not merely reactions to the price effects. But the case of monopoly or monopsony points up the somewhat artificial nature of such a division. After all, when we scudy a unit as large as the entire productive system, the prices at which outputs can be sold not oe independent of the actions of the production will system itself, even if no monopoly power is involved. The answer monetary single here is simple. The division of change a into a single measurement of price change and value measurement of quantity change is necessarily In the true world of general equilibrium effects, is truly possible. In particular, sector, can production conditions). sector ask no such change if we wish to examine the wnat -would have happened if had faced different input prices Answering such questions provides a arbitrary. all we can do is to ask "what Instead, questions. we in if" production zhe original (or insight supply into whether real input usage has increased or decreased, even though actual change has consequences beyond the production any sector itself. 3*_SiG)£l£_lDBU£_D£flaliOD_iD_IJQrsJ2e£ail now concentrate on the easy case of simple input deflation I — deflation of inputs in the case of the Tnis firm. case a is quite instructive, single and the competitive propositions will be seen to be of quite general applicability, discussed so chat a gooo deal more than an example is involved. [FIGURE 3.1 HERE] the base-period isoquant is drawn with base- In Figure 3.1, period factor prices, input use notation, is v, I w, and total input costs C = wv . (For on the context to make clear what is intended.) current period, wv* . the oeen ease of omit transposition signs when writing inner products, relying lines. Optimal represented by the solid line. factor prices, w, In are denoted by the the dashed Actual factor usage is v* and actual money costs are C* = Had factor prices been w instead of w in the base period, output corresponding to the base-period isoquant would efficiently produced with inputs v rather than v and have money UN costs would have been C rather than C. tion The view of input-defla- taken here is that the change in costs from C to C* should be thougnt of as: (3.1) C*/C = (C*/C) (C/C) , with the first factor the increase in real aggregate input and the second reflecting price changes. usage more In general where C(w, x), base-period let the firm's cost output, x, function The construction just given is output. x input costs as C(w, the terms, and calculates the deflator x)/C(w, x) . be uses money for This deflator is divided into relative change in money input costs to give the measure of real aggregate input usage relative to the base period. It bounded the not harci co see that the deflator just is above by deflator oounded Laspeyres index of input prices. a oased below oy technology and a produced on the current period's Paasche index. a nomothetic isoquant map, Similarly, isoquanc In the case is will be unchanging of ooth deflators will oe the same and both bounds will apply. Evidently, phic Fisher-Shell approach leads to a of the cost-of-living index that to this theory of output deflation) . theory largely isomor(as well In considering sible objections to the theory oeing advanced, well what those same objections consider to to as therefore, imply the posit is about the relatively well-established theory of the cost-of-living index. 1. Space objections here. does not permit consideration of In particular, Diewert the parallel case of output deflation) (1983) all possible points out (using that the method here given will often not lead to a measure of real input usage that doubles if the firm exactly doubles its usage matters are taken up in Fisher (1988) One of every input. Such . such objection is as follows. The procedure just de- scrioed treats input vectors as identical if they can produce the output and treats same as an input increase. a movement to a higher-numbered isoquant But we are trying to build a input aggregation and measurement. theory Is it not odd that levels of outputs become central to the theory? Moreover, different firms different technologies facing the same set of input with of prices will have different: factor price deflators constructed for them. The answer lies in consideration of the object of the enter- prise. are treating the firm as the object of interest with We factor prices given from outside. of Any production-theoretic view input deflation must involve the production function as tne cost-of-living index describes price changes Just firm. the of from the point of view of the individual consumer, so the produc- tion-theoretic input price index describes factor price The the point of view of the individual firm. from different not firms have different points of view, valid objection. a prices. input To a fact that so to speak, The aggregation problem points cannot be solved by choosing changes to is which it firm-independent measure of do tnat is merely to impose on all firms a measure not relevant to any one of them. Two more comments on this before proceeding. the point of view of the input-producing sector be made up of firms if inputs are construction intermediate of an index of prices for (which could also products), sector. Here, to But output is a different enterprise with price changes taken originating in the purchasing sector. deflation, the its cu£pu£§ ought not depend on the production functions of its customers. deflation from First, in tne case of as input price cnanges are taken as originating in the selling Tnis is consonant with tne general view of price and quantity indexation taken above. Second, index the fact that the production-theoretic input will different for firms be with price production different functions does not mean that nothing can be said about the nature of such dependence. to On the contrary, interest certainly attaches the way in which such indices change as the production tion varies over firms or over time. with func- Such matters can be treated comparative static analysis (altnough space does not permit doing so in the present paper). When we examine more general (and more cases interesting) than that of the single-output competitive firm, the same princiIn each case, we shall examine what would have ples will apply. happened had the productive unit in question faced the new set of input prices will (or, more generally, input supply conditions). restrict the productive unit to an isoquant or to a We genera- lization thereof. Before proceeding to the details of that analysis, two They can be discussed at the subjects present, however, general level. are the treatment of corner solutions and the treatment of quality changes in inputs. 3*_CarD£r..Selu£iSDS The issues resolved. goods in The the involved in corner solutions here isomorphic case to that of new or analysis of the cost-of-living index production-theoretic output price index is that of are readily disappearing or a the of new or This does not seem to be disappearing factor of production. particularly interesting case unless we are considering as a fac- not primary factors but inputs of goods or materials tors If we do consider one sector or country buys from another. cases, then which, in is not hard to imagine it produces effect, technical a such discovery previously good that serves as a a which unknown factor of production from the point of view of the sector or economy that purchases it. Despite analysis — tioned. It (1972, plain is 99-105) for the there is no need to give from consideration of Fisher is reservation a problem for Paasche index a bounding The between em- intercept on the considered would be just indifferent factor it is c»i^ demand productive (This is the price at which the ploying the factor and not doing so; base-period not and period's base any price at or above its price. oeing Shell and Paasche index will be preserved if the factor price a chosen men- already isomorphisms production-theoretic input price index. property of lengthy a that the problem of what factor price to use new factor is only a sector cases, part because of the in pp. for so such demand curve.) Of all prices in that range, Paascne the demand reservation price produces the most efficient lower bound. Further, that price can also be interpreted as the shadow of price the constraint involved in not being able to employ the factor in question in the base period. It is which important to realize, however, that corner solutions arise through the appearance of new goods or the disappea- rance of old ones do not raise similar problems. the isoquant. relative to which the production-theoretic price deflator is calculated is defined for 10 This is because a input given set of output Just how those conditions are properly defined is a conditions. matter we consider below, be but however they are defined they will the same for both periods. question; change, New goods do therefore raise a the appearance of a new good, like any other technical will generally alter the isoquant which determines production-theoretic input price index. the This is quite a diffe- rent class of effects from those involved in corner solutions in £ac£or. space. To take the simplest example, describes isoquant suppose that the efficient factor combinations given set of goods in specified quantities. ducing a goods either includes the new one or it does not. is relevant the pro- for That set of What the set certainly affects the shape of the isoquant and the value of the resulting input price deflator but the fact that a different of goods would produce a different isoquant and a different set raises no problem for the construction of the deflator deflator using the given isoquant corresponding to a given set of goods. analysis of quality change The presents somewhat deeper problems. In the theory of the cost-of-living index, question is a fairly natural that of the treatment of quality change in more of the goods consumed. one or While such changes can be handled in principle as the disappearance of one good (with the old quality) and the appearance of a new good not done in practice and, theory of (with the new quality) indeed, the cost-of-living index, 11 , is rather awkward. quality improvement this is the In in a good is equivalent to an improvement in the opportunity consumed set facing consumers and tnerefore equivalent to a fall cost (1972, one living of pp. can and analyzed such effects and considered 26-37) treat Fisher prices remain constant. if quality improvement as equivalent to a rally done, oe change independent involved consumed dependent (e.g. The prin- gene- virtual price prices of all other only on the physical amounts and nature the of The necessary quality change) under very special circumstances. and virtual while this could could only be done with the it Shell whether a price decrease in the good whose quality had changed. cipal result was the demonstration that, the in sufficient conditions for such treatment are that the consu- mer view the new quality of good as exactly equivalent to a fixed number of units of the old quality, i.e., that the quality change enter the utility function as a shift in meter . >: (as b in U(bx, ± ties consume^ case "repackaging" good as a " c.;ic , x of . . i. U(.) n ) , a good-augmenting where the ;: . are the quanti- 1 is the utility function) We called since the consumer regards the repackaged" version of the old one, Obviously, this is a para- quality new so this to speak. very special case, and the result calls into question a whole class of methods used to adjust for quality change, a class of whic/i .i^acnics is the most sophisticated representative. The case of output price deflation has an isomorphic problem (considered turns out equivalent used in Fisher and Shell 1972, pp. 105-7)). There it chat one would scili wish to treat a quality change as to a price decrease. This is because the resources to produce the new quality of good could have been used 12 to produce different amounts of the original quality had desired it. In effect, quality change is interpreted as simply a in demand. shift The isomorphic statement to repackaging the is that quality improvement can be treated as a theorem decrease price of the good whose the in independent for frontier quality ' virtual changed has of prices and quantities of all goods produced under special circumstances. tions consumers such (PPF) only The necessary and sufficient condi- treatment are that the production possibility with the new quality good differ from the PPF with tne old one by a shift in a good-augmenting parameter. This is equivalent to requiring that the production functions for the new and old quality good differ by so that, of the a in terms of resource use Kicks-neutral technical change (rather than utility), one unit new quality of good is equivalent to a fixed num,ber of units of the old. Leaving the repackaging theorem aside for the moment, important quality to recognize the difference between the constructed technical deflator. treatment is of change and that of technological change in the theory of The production-theoretic output price deflator output deflation. is it from the point of view of a specific will shift that PPF and (usually) change However, PPF. change A the the PPF used to construct the deflator will be constant when comparing base and current period prices even if the technical change occurred oetween the two periods. This is because the question to be answered concerns the responses an sets economy with of prices. a which given PPF would have made when faced with A shift in the PPF may increase real output 13 cwo — if it leads to a greater value of production than would have been achieved — prices the base period's PPF and with period's but this is do£ because the change is equivalent to With base-period and current-period prices price decrease. a the deflator will be unity whichever. PPF is used to the same, current the con- struct it. Quality guous. It on the other hand, change, is treated as unambi- is treated as though the choice between new and quality of goods reflected not a £emaDy conditions. quality change requiring more Hence, a change in supply but change in a re- to produce the new quality than to proauce the old leads sources to an unambiguous increase in real output if the number of of old units the new quality of good produced in the current period is the as the number of units of the old quality of good same in the base period, The decrease. Indeed, because with the production of all other goods quality constant. produced change prices is thus equivalent to price a will be treated as declining of the quality change, held solely even if money prices remain the same in the two periods. Obviously, whether a it is a matter of some importance theory of the cost-of-living index, the decide whether or a 2. and Shell This demand. it given change is a taste change, quality change due to supply. a decide given change should be treated as technological and due to supply or as a quality change and due to in to 2 ) is important due to 7-8). 14 to demand, The basic question to is not always as simple as it looks. (1972, pp. (Similarly, be See Fisher asked is always whether, if prices do not change, one wishes to consider the value of the deflator as necessarily altered by change under consideration. Now, If so, then it is a quality change. question of how a given change sno^id be the arises again when we consider input deflation. to ask is whether, say treated Here the question with money input prices the same, that input prices have gone down as we wish to result of the a then the change will be treated as If so, the quality a change. change; if not, then it will be treated as a technical change. inside important to realize here that is It change that unit whose input prices are to be deflated the treated as a a technical change (just as such a occurs change in the of households is treated as a shift in taste). be will case In general, the of a more efficient process within the production unit discovery itself will not be considered as a decrease in input prices. price input index is to measure the cost usefulness of inputs once they are used. other hand, means a which Changes in we inputs, not the A quality change on the decrease in input costs for §DY technology Thus, the kind of quality change used by the production sector. with of An are here concerned is change in eu£py£ quality will simply ae treated changes for purposes of input deflation. treat an su£pu£ quality improvement as a iopy£ as quality. technical It is not reasonable to virtual decline in iBPy£ prices. 3. Uote the reversal of roles from the case of output price deflation. There technical change — quality change in an iDPut was treated as a a change in the PPF 15 . Here it is treated as a a On the other hand, a quality change in an cu£2u£ quality change. — — there treated as such is here treated as a technical change change in the isoquant. a To suppose that the change in question concerns fix ideas, quality the more productivity is due to a productive. change and not as inputs. education of labor, increase in as a decrease in the effective cost a of the increase is due to oetter then one may very well wish to treat it as in input costs and a reduction decrease virtual that If then this will be treated the other hand, on If, factors (other discovery on the part of firms as to how use labor more efficiently, tecnnical labor labor, so that of constant) becomes to — input the in a price deflator. The issue is not workers the simple one, suppose being that the production sector whose input inputs — For quality a more efficient way of using "raw" labor. those cases in which theorem are a they Or do given set applies a a given change is treated as result isomorphic to that of and is very natural. A in the price of that a the quality improvement in an input can always be treated as equivalent to decrease of Either answer is possible. change in an input, repackaging costs Do better edu- cated workers represent lower virtual input prices? reflect to training. on-the-job considered is that of the entire economy. simply prices this is not so (or at least not obvi- if the education comes through so) educated Better however. may represent an effective decrease in input firm that hires them; ously Now a a input with input quality constant. 16 price That decrease will be independent of purchases only under special conditions, input however. prices Necessary and sufficient conditions for such independence are that the change quality can be represented within the productive technology as shift in parameter augmenting the factor whose a In other words, changed. unit one and ' a has quality the quality change must be such that of the new quality of factor is exactly equivalent in old quality of the repackaging production to fixed numbetf of units of the a factor. may It condition thought that this version be seems more likely to oe satisfied in the present quality changes in factors than in either the case of augmenting changes function the utility in — in production functions changes spectively. considered change not Once as a too augmenting. the conditions that apply strictive quality change in a than factor rather stringent to suppose that tne cnange But is this really so? index tion a is worker, a then — it — perhaps deflation is not obvious that factor totally natural assumption. for example, is be a may factor- quality change already supposes in the case of output price than re- as it to Aside from the fact that the restrictive set of circumstances cost-of-living cated deflator, one has decided that a given change is to decision to treat the change as fairly good- of in technology affecting how that factor is used, seem case Hicks-neutral or cost-of-living index and to the output price the a of Can an more re- or the augmentaeducated really do eysiyibiog oetter than an unedu- one and better in the same proportion no matter 17 what the task? not ging If not, then the quality change involved in education is merely factor-augmenting in the way required by the repackatheorem. simple adjustment in wages will No suffice to production-theoretic account for the effect of the change on the input price deflator or on the corresponding production-theoretic index of real input use. 5 J _Tbe - Eully_QpeD-£§§e As already indicated, the easiest case for the analysis economy-wide input price deflation is that of my. In fully open econo- a the present circumstances this amounts to assuming that the productive sector sell of (like a multiproduct competitive firm) all the outputs it wants at fixed output prices. can The iso- quant relative to which the input price deflator is defined then becomes the locus of all efficient input combinations which will produce output The plans bundles of equal value. economic F(x,v) x production efficient can be summarized in terms of the production (5.1) where unit's technologically relation = 0, We are is the output vector and v is the input vector. also given a vector of output prices p = (p, , . . . , p ) and a money value of output, y. The tneoretic isoquant to be used in constructing the production- input price deflator is defined in the following Choose any output vector, x, whose value at prices p is y. consider the set of v corresponding to that x and the function F(x,v) = 0. Next production This is an isoquant for the production 18 way: of . the given vector x. Consider the family of isoquants generated in this way by varying x over all vectors satisfying px = y. The isoquant that will be used for input price deflation is the lower envelope of this family. Each point, on that envelope also v, on some isoquant defined for x fixed for some x with lies total value of output at the given output prices is equal to y. Formally, we have: I__ = {v| v is minimal subject to F(x,v) (5.2) Given the isoquant I pn the construction of the correspon- r ding production-theoretic input price index is application given two input price vectors, w A and w C (5.3) B We above. First . straightf orward a the general approach discussed of and px = y}. = are define v/e A = A min w v subject to v lying on I^q. v Let be the minimizing value of v in Problem (5.3); v h,— ave C t\ »*i = w v = C we c\ . Similarly, (5.4) thus, we define min w v subject to v lying on v I po . •p be the minimizing value of v in Problem (5.4); Let v B B = w v nave „B C The . production-theoretic money costs at input prices w A input price index quant, Ir,^, which comparing . value is held constant at y is then This index is, for . to money costs at input prices outputs can be freely sold at fixed prices, when thus, we A (C /C R ) is determined by technology 19 B and output p, defined relative to of course, w a given iso- (4.1), output prices, output logy, period bound prices, indexed as B) , and output value of the base period (the then a Laspeyres input price will If they are the technology, output prices, above. and output value of current period (indexed as A), then a Paasche input price will bound the corresponding production-theoretic index index from below. If the two isoquants are production-theoretic two the index corresponding production-theoretic index from the the If these are the actual techno- and output value, y. p, parallel along rays, indices will be equal then botn and oounds will apply. will such isoquants be parallel in this When conditions are: cient (i) common to both periods; and (ii) Suffi- way? The production technology F(.,.) F(.,.) is is constant returns to scale; the output prices, p, are proportional in both periods. (iii) These conditions — — particularly that of constant returns are far stronger than necessary. When such parallelism along rays is not present, production-theoretic input differ price indices will and Laspeyres bounds need not both hold Paasche the two and the simultaneously. Sa.CeDgfsl-SsBSD^^CsDdiiioDsi-Tbs-UflDeppiisiic^gase The are where fully open case just analyzed in which output demands perfectly elastic is the appropriate one for input deflation the productive sector involved is small — a firm or a small group of firms in competition, or a small country in inter- national trade. Larger units or aggregates, so simply treated. however, cannot be We must therefore analyze the case of decli- ning demand curves. 20 It turns out to matter a good deal whether or not the agents in the production sector realize that they face declining demand curves and take that fact into account in their decision If they — do simpler — than if they do not behaves firm the case of monopoly present — the analysis is open section takes up the monopoly case; each situation. The the more difficult competitive case is treated later. production plans are efficient before, As somewhat where the competitive case as if it were in the fully (and more interesting) making. given by the relation F(x,v) = (6.1) , where x Let p be the corresponding r-vector of output is an r-vector of outputs and v is an m-vector of inputs. prices; outputs are sold according to the demand schedule (6.2) x = x D (p) If demand for some good is perfectly elastic at a constant price, then the corresponding component of price, zero above it, and any value in x is infinite [0, +oo] below that at the exogenous- ly given price. that we observe the economic unit in question Suppose convenience, prices revenue, the "economy") producing an output vector p* so that its total revenue is y* = p*x*. y* , Fixing (for x* at total what are the output combinations which the economy could have sold? The answer depends on what is assumed about the output demand conditions which the economy faces. 21 In Figure 6.1, the point For the fully x* is indicated. economy, open line shows the output combinations consistent with dashed revenue, y* i.e. , {x | p*x* = y* } . the total Points to the northeast of the dashed line produce more revenue for the fully open economy The solid curve represents the output combi- it receives at x*. nations consistent demand schedules, x (p*). than i.e. economy y* for the with {x | x = x (p) declining facing and px = y* where x* } , = The solid curve lies to the northeast of the dashed line reflecting fact that increased outputs can only be sold the at lower prices. From Figure 6.1, we see that the fully open model provides more "optimistic" isoquant than does the declining demand dule model. showing This is reflected in the fact that a sche- the isoquant to generate the efficient factor combinations required the given revenue y* shows greater required inputs with declining demand than in the fully open case. It theoretic not hard to see, is price input demand-curve therefore, that deflator constructed in case will be less than that for production- the declining- the corresponding the fully open case because the fully open economic unit with a given isoquant responds more fully to factor ojI^l. changes than the unit facing declining demand curves. Hence a does given change in the money value of costs will be considered more of a real change and less of a monetary one when declining demand curves are present than when they are not. The isoquant for the general case of unit facing declining demand curves, 22 IM , is a monopoly economic defined as follows: } (6.3) = I "K {v is minimal subject to F(x,v) v | = x x It and px = y , important to realize that this isoquant is based is assumption that the economic unit "sees" and acts the entire demand schedule. but px (p) = 0, minimizes rather D (p) its It does not take output prices as given subject cost its In other words, = y. upon on in deriving constraint the to we have assumed the I.., economic unit to have monopoly power in its product markets. The case of competition with declining demand is studied later. Wow, assume that I., is derived from technological and output market conditions actually prevailing in the base period. by the superscript B, conditions these that so Denote isoquant the becomes 3 (6.4) I = . {v v is minimal subject to F | x = x Assume that v , DB , P (x,v) 0, , and px = y , (p) = , , } . period the actual vector of base inputs a minimizes constraint, F 3 (x,v) = 0, the demand constraint B revenue constraint px = y in and I„^, ru (6.4) share (5.2)) B of I„~. 4 I isoquant market B . DB I., 3 defined I,., isoquant the corresponding fully open but and the (p) (see lies above and to the right denote the production-theoretic input price 37. would lie below and to the left of defined basket = x x Then the two isoquants, . common point, a Let 4. subject to the technological costs at factor prices w of v/ith perfectly inelastic outputs — a demands but the latter is of interest. 23 closed" "fully — very a fixed little deflator defined relative to input price deflator defined L 2 (6.5) jJJ I ,. and J pn the production-theoretic relative to I,,,-. Then we have: i Jp where L denotes the Laspeyres input price index. Similarly, for the indices derived from current-period conditions, (superscrip- ted A) we have: P * J (6.6) A < [v; j£ Q , where P denotes the Paasche input price index. Note flator that because the production-theoretic input price de- for the monopoly case is always greater than or equal corresponding a given real input usage in the fully open case than in the case of monopoly. This the increase in deflator for the fully to open money costs will be attributed more to corresponds to the isoquants drawn in Figure 6.1. case has a flatter isoquant, a case. Cost The fully open so that factor price changes will the monopoly changes resulting from movements along an isoquant greater movement in factor usage than in induce case, are counted as monetary only. now turn to the important case of I unit (an industry, There taking competitive The economic unit faces demand coniditions as in the preceding section not know it. output prices economic facing declining output demand schedules. is no monopoly power. general does say) a The firms which make up the as given as 24 in the fully same the — but it unit optimize open case of Section above. 5 In fact, however, not in a fully open environment, taken all together, they are and output prices do depend on the sum of their decisions. This view fact raises a new problem. production-theoretic input deflation asks what the economic unit would of spent The inputs at the new input prices holding on output constant. have value the of But now holding output value constant is not a simple matter. It cannot be done, as in the fully open case, by restricting the output vector to an isovalue line at fixed output because output prices are not fixed. prices, it cannot be done, economic unit On the other hand, as in the monopoly case, by assuming that the minimizes cost subject to outputs lying on an isorevnue curve, because the economic unit does not in fact solve such problem. a theoretic input Indeed, price the construction of the deflator in this case is problem in constrained optimization; a demand in that construction also cases so far considered. and statics far more difficult than in the Further, a in- supply This makes comparative all output markets. (not treated in this paper) merely not fixed-point argument ensuring equality of volves production- other Paasche and Laspeyres bounds need no longer apply. As in the preceding section, technology is summarized by F(x,v) (7.1) 5. industry. =0 5 Note that (7.1) gives the production technology for In the absence of constant returns, 25 the this will general- : } . ly not also be the tachnology for the individual firm. This is a matter of no consequence here, however. demand by and output (7.2) = x x D (p) Firms in our competitive industry face a given output vector, p, perceive Section god ac£ as. Thus, the firms ds£ affsci i£. £}p as operating in a fully open economy as themselves 5. if they price If that perception were correct, industry facing output prices, in the isoquant for the and earning total revenue, y, p, would be I„_(p) t u (7.3) = v is minimal subject to F(x,v) {v| and px = = y By fixing total revenue, y, and varying output prices, p, we derive from (7.3) the implied industry supply can outputs schedule for (parametric on y, of course) (7.4) = x S (p) x How, we cannot case the analysis of our competitive industry on the isoquant, I^Cp), defined in (7.3). derived for fixed output prices, at the industry level. the Second, First, The fact that x D , (p) is and output prices are not fixed I (p) does not take into account industry-wide constraint that supply and demand for must be equal, i.e., that Ic (p) = x S (?) this constraint is not recognized competitive industry makes the analysis complex. 26 outputs by the Tnis is because equilibrium output prices which equate output the demands and themselves depend on factor prices since output supplies so depend. Thus, while the competitive industry, given y, mini- mizes costs while remaining on I^-Jp) depends on factor prices, is supplies for some p, that whj,£h p Were w different, p would also w. be different, and the competitive economy would solve a different problem. must therefore take this into account and (in principle) We use the p that corresponds to equilibrium in output markets given the factor prices involved. defining the production-theoretic input price index In the competitive general case, relation (7.1), J n r-r total revenue, First, production we are given the the output demand schedules y, (7.2), and two input price vectors, w for A and w take the output price vector, B . as a parameter and p, let C A (p) = A min w v x,v (7.5) subject to F(x,v) = (C A is the (p) is thus money cost at factor prices, on I„_(p).) r O w and px = y A , given that input Let the minimizing input vector be v resulting vector of optimal output supplies be x SA (p) find that value of p (for convenience assumed to be unique) A D SA that x (p) = x (p); call it p . Similarly, let 27 and (p) . Now such C B = (p) B min w v x,v (7.6) subject to F(x,v) Let the minimizing input vector be v of optimal output supplies be x SB (p) CO (assumed unique) such that x The and px = y = (p) and the resulting vector . Now find the value of = x (p) p D V) (p) call it p ; production-theoretic input price index . appropriate to the competitive general case is then defined by J (7.7) The = CG C (p )/C B B (p ) fact that the firms making up the competitive unit behave unit as the difficulties for whole does not creates a First, becomes difficult. parameter practical comparative static analysis (not here The effect of a shift in given a does not only involve changes in the solution now the unit's optimizing proolem given that shift handled economic as though they face flat demand curves whereas further analysis. treated) A A by the Envelope Theorem) . Such a to (which are readily shift involves also shifts in the other parameters of the unit's optimization problem through changes markets. in the position of equilibrium in output all Without more information as to demand schedules, such shifts cannot be studied. Second, and more important for the practice of price index construction, Laspeyres and Paasche bounds are no longer guaran- teed to hold. To see this, Let B denote actual base-period and A 3 actual current-period conditions, respectively. Then C denominator Laspeyres of J ,,_ and the denominator 28 of the (p ) , the input . price index will be the same. establishing J C CG , which A the A (p situation (p ) bound would be to show that the This is no longer guaranteed. in which the value of v (just for good measure), by Plainly, . B numerator of w A (repre- is lower than C A A (p at prices the value of v the slopes of the solid lines) Laspeyres period) Figure 7.1 shows a at factor prices the slope of the dashed lines) by (represented C of is the value of the solution to a minimum problem in ) was feasible. Further method the usual (the actual input combination used in the base v sented However, w L lower is ) than and Paasche bounds are inapplicable here. Except where demand curves can in f§£i The moral is clear. be taken as approximately flat because the unit is Paasche Laspeyres and for output price deflation. than enough, another case generating in There, — if the unit inappropriate to assume Here, laige is fixed, as economy that of tne fully colsed which Paasche and Laspeyres bounds apply. Fisher and Shell 1972.) the The case is even worse appropriate to treat factor supplies is it bound input price indices will not production-theoretic input price indices. small, very (See Essay II no matter how big the unit, that the demand curves it is faces it of are perfectly inelastic. and Laspeyres input price indices will thus give Paasche picture except for very small misleading other cases, general, of detailed economic technology as well) will be required. (and, One assume that changes in input prices leave output prices ted, and this creates a serious proolem. 29 For units. knowledge of demand schedules a in cannot unaffec- course, Of dices this difficulty with Paasche and Laspeyres It comes about because is a form of aggregation problem. the situation facing an entire industry is not that perceived the firms that make it up. of If at prices from the point of view of Laspeyres weights would have to be quantity sponding to an individual firm's purchases). input narrow used an quantity measurement, however, is on an industry or economy-wide basis, production theory is not those Paasche corre- Input deflation and seldom done from When Paasche or Laspeyres indices a point of view. a strong one. 30 to individual such problems would not arise (although even then firm, and input by (parallel to the case of the cost living index and an individual household) we were content look in- their grounding so are in . Diewert, W. E. (1983), "The Theory of the Output Price Index and the Measurement of Real Output Change." University of Bri- tish Columbia, Department of Economics, Discussion Paper No. 83-10. Fisher, and P.M. (1988), "Production-Theoretic Input Price Indices Measurement the DS3SUX£ffi£Qt_iD_5fiflD2IDiS5 Aggregate Real of (W. Eichhorn, Input ed . ) , Use," in Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag Fisher, F. M. and K. Shell (1972), TQQ„E£QnsRi£^Tb£QL}l-QL*.'ELi££ lB$iS§§r New York: Academic Press. Muellbauer, J. Indices." N. J. (1972), "The Theory of True Input Price University of Warwick, search Paper 17. 31 Revision of Economic Re- V, Figure 3.1 Economy with declining demand schedules Fully open economy Figure 6.1 1 V- C B (p B ) WB V A (Ap*) WA V B Ifo(p V Figure 7 367 1339 7. B ) Date Due Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 =1060 00b7TM32 2 mm BM JH 111 1IH bhHIHBB IBimiBWHfflBI HHH Jl fffiMrff H '''«' Bill ' - : JWHWIH T— HHr Hi Hi mm m mi /:« HHU si