Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/financialsystemrOOcaba B31 M415 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Financial System Risk and Flight to Quality Ricardo J. Caballero Arvind Krishnamurthy Working Paper 05-31 November 21, 2005 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, This MA 021 42 paper can be downloaded without charge from the Network Paper Collection at Social Science Research http://ssrn.com/abstract=86 1 484 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY DEC 1 2 2005 LIBRARIES Financial System Risk and Flight to Quality Ricardo J. Arvind Krishnamurthy* Caballero This draft: November 21, 2005 Abstract We present a model of flight to quality episodes that emphasizes financial system risk and the Knigh- tian uncertainty surrounding these episodes. In the model, agents are uncertain about the probability distribution of shocks in markets different from theirs, treating such uncertainty as Knightian. Aversion demand to this uncertainty generates for safe financial claims. own intermediaries to lock-up capital to cover their certainty over other markets. accelerator. A agents to require financial markets' shocks in a manner that These actions are wasteful lender of last resort It also leads in the aggregate is robust to un- and can trigger a financial can unlock private capital markets to stabilize the economy during these episodes by committing to intervene should conditions worsen. JEL Codes: E30, E44, E5, F34, Gl, G21, G22, G28. Keywords: Locked collateral, flight to quality, insurance, risk premia, financial intermediaries, lender of last resort, private sector multiplier, collateral shocks, robust control. •Respectively: We MIT and NBER; Northwestern University. E-mails: caball@mit.edu, a-krishnamurthy@northwestern.edu. are grateful to Marios Angeletos, Olivier Blanchard, Phil Bond, Jon Faust, Xavier Gabaix, Jordi Gali, Michael Golosov, William Hawkins, Burton Hollifield, Bengt Holmstrom, David Lucca, Dimitri Vayanos, and seminar participants Imperial College, LBS, Northwestern, MIT, Wharton, Conference, Bank of England, and the Central Bank assistance. Caballero thanks the NSF NY Fed Liquidity Conference, of Chile for their for financial support. comments. NBER MIDM Conference, at Columbia, UBC Summer David Lucca provided excellent research Policy practitioners operating under a risk-management paradigm may, at times, be led to "... When undertake actions intended to provide insurance against especially adverse outcomes confronted with uncertainty, especially Knightian uncertainty, medium to disengage from commitments to long-term human beings invariably attempt in favor of safety and The liquidity.... immediate response on the part of the central bank to such financial implosions must be to inject large quantities of liquidity..." Alan Greenspan (2004). Flight-to-quality episodes are an important source of financial instability. US episodes in the include the Penn Central and ending with the bailout the events that followed the attacks of 9/11. Behind each of these episodes may slowdown as lead to a prolonged Depression. in of these default of 1970; the stock market crash of 1987; the events of the Fall of 1998 beginning with the Russian default that Modern examples lies of LTCM; as well as the specter of a meltdown Japan during the 1990s, or even a catastrophe like the Great 1 From a broad-brush standpoint, flight-to-quality episodes involve an increase in perceived risk. However, the risk does not circumscribe a purely fundamental shock, and instead centers around the financial system. For example, the Russian default in the of As US summer of 1998 eliminated a small fraction of the trillions of dollars wealth. Although small, the default created circumstances that severely strained the financial sector. prices of illiquid assets fell, losses grew in commercial banks, investment banks, and hedge funds, leading investors to question the safety of the financial sector. Investors withdrew risk-capital from the affected markets and institutions and moved into short-term and liquid capital emerged as sophisticated parts of the economy were relatively unaffected. In this paper financial The primary we develop a model risk claims; and effects that arise during this episode was financial system of a flight-to-quality episode. and demand flight to quality into multipliers. risk. for safety are of risk. In practice, the occurrence of an unex- We take this during flight-to-quality episodes: agents financial bottlenecks develop that hinder capital increase in risk movement system were compromised while other sectors of the pected event triggers an increase in agents' perception of two important Bottlenecks in the assets. shock as exogenous, and focus on demand safe movement and segment a hallmark of flight-to-quality episodes. and certain financial financial markets. The Bottlenecks transform a macroeconomic problem by triggering and amplifying collateral shortages and financial It is this systemic dimension that motivates the Fed's reactions, as indicated by Greenspan's comments. Our model on promises of focuses on agent's perceptions regarding the ability of financial intermediaries to deliver credit. arise in their markets. 'See Table century. 1 Agents contract with financial intermediaries to cover liquidity shocks that may However, agents are uncertain about the probability model describing shocks in (part A) in Barro (2005) for a comprehensive list of extreme events in developed economies during the 20th markets different from collateral, agents intermediaries theirs, treating grow concerned that shocks may and compromise Knightian uncertainty or a conservatism and a risk such uncertainty as Knightian. demand their promises of credit. fall in for safety. financial intermediaries have limited markets that Such riskiness intermediation collateral. The will deplete the resources of rises either through an increase We show by formulating plans that are robust to their uncertainty regarding other markets. what happens in other some in increase in perceived riskiness generates We study the case in which agents shield themselves from the require financial intermediaries to lock-up in arise in other If capital to devote to their markets. Once locked-up, intermediaries' capital own markets' is that agents shocks, regardless of move not free to increased across markets response to shocks, resulting in bottlenecks and market segmentation. The interaction between Knightian uncertainty and limited intermediation collateral our analysis. The following example some liquidity needs, which are provided There are two states that can occur, reversed in S2- Thus it is A si A and Suppose that two agents, our example), that for and S2 it B, have must allocate between these two agents. with probabilities n(si) and has a higher marginal valuation of liquidity in "efficient" to at the heart of by contracting with an intermediary. However, the intermediary for has a limited supply of liquidity (one unit value liquidity in each state, our main ideas. illustrates is provide more liquidity to A in s\ 7r(s2). s\ While both A and B than B, with the situation and more to B in S2'- s2 s\ X 1 -X X>± B Now fashion. suppose that A and 1 B -x view the uncertainty over the realization of states In particular, suppose that A and B may S\ or S2 in are unsure over the probabilities 7r(si) potential problem with achieving this efficient solution in S2, he X is that since A is and a Knightian 7r(s2). Then a receiving a lower liquidity allocation overweight the chances that S2 will occur when making decisions. B may overweight s\. Consider an alternative "non-contingent" hoarding solution, where each agent hoards | unit of liquidity in each state, independent of their relative economic liquidity needs. s\ B s2 1 1 2 2 1 1 2 2 A and B may reject the efficient solution in favor of the non-contingent unknown robust to the hoarding solution because probabilities. In equilibrium, the desire for robustness may it is lead to a non-contingent allocation of liquidity. we develop In our model, we mean by "efficient" this example in and "non-contingent." a competitive, general equilibrium setting. We show that robustness concern vanishes. In terms of our example above, does not need to ration the liquidity between of si or S2, We One and the robustness concern is A if explain what intermediaries have sufficient collateral, the if the intermediary has sufficient liquidity, and B. Then A's allocation depends less it on the realization reduced. present examples to connect our model to the behavior of agents during flight to quality episodes. of our examples, as alluded to earlier, flight to quality, risk capital in the allocation of risk capital by a financial intermediary. In a is the intermediary locks-up risk capital to devote to individual markets, instead of allocating an efficient shock-contingent fashion across markets. In equilibrium, robustness concerns magnify an aggregate liquidity shortage consequences. We show how a central bank's commitment and potentially improve outcomes. In our model, the away from the hoarding solution and toward the Our paper Moore (1997) highlight how and have macroeconomic as a lender of last resort can affect equilibrium central bank can shift the private sector's allocation efficient solution. relates to several strands of literature. frictions in business cycle models. how We It helps to fill a gap in the literature on financial Papers such as Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1998) and Kiyotaki and financial frictions in firms amplify aggregate shocks. Instead, uncertainty in response to shocks, and financial frictions lead to greater (Knightian) we emphasize how this rise in uncertainty feeds back into the financial accelerator. Our paper sense, our also studies the paper is closer to macroeconomic consequences of frictions in financial intermediaries. In this Holmstrom and Tirole (1998) and Krishnamurthy (2003) that emphasize that with complete financial contracts, the aggregate collateral of intermediaries is ultimately behind financial amplification mechanisms. In terms of the policy implications, Holmstrom and Tirole (1998) study how a shortage collateral limits private liquidity provision (see also government can The key issue difference for liquidity provision. between our paper and those of Holmstrom and Tirole, and Woodford, limited. In our model, the provision is but and more also, Woodford, 1990). Their analysis suggests that a credible government bonds which can then be used by the private sector even a large amount of collateral in the aggregate centrally, The model we develop it may is government intervention not only adds to the private how a that we show how be inefficiently used, so that private sector liquidity improves the use of private illustrates of aggregate sector's collateral collateral. lender of last resort commitment to insure a low probability extreme event stabilizes the economy. 2 This result resembles Diamond and Dybvig (1983), where the benefit of a lender of last resort in equilibrium; the bad event bank runs is is to rule out a "bad" equilibrium. However, our just a low probability by depositors' concern that they will be extreme event. In Diamond and Dybvig, a run last in line to the bank run is is triggered withdraw deposits. In our model, agents exaggerate the odds that intermediaries will have exhausted their capital, and Diamond and Dybvig, model has a unique fail to deliver on promises of credit. In In our model, a coordination failure. on the other hand, flight to quality results from agents overweighting the chance of an extreme event. Flight-to-quality episodes have financial and real effects. On the financial side, papers such as Krish- namurthy (2002) and Longstaff (2004) document that spreads between assets widen during away from firms flight to quality. risky assets such as draw down credit lines Gatev and Strahan (2005) document that investors Commercial Paper and toward safe and liquid/safe illiquid/risky assets shift their portfolios bank deposits during these episodes, while from these banks. These actions are consistent with our model, as we predict that agents shift toward well capitalized financial intermediaries that are less sensitive to the robustness concerns of agents. A number of papers have also Commercial Paper and Treasury Bills is documented that the widening of the spread between a powerful leading indicator for cyclical downturns and Watson, 1989, Friedman and Kuttner, 1993, Kashyap, There is Stein, (see, e.g., and Wilcox, 1993). a growing economics literature that aims to formalize Knightian uncertainty (a partial Dow and Werlang contributions includes, Gilboa and Schmeidler (1989), (1992), Epstein and Hansen and Sargent (1995, 2003), Skiadas (2003), Epstein and Schneider (2004), and Hansen, As in much of this literature, Knightian uncertainty a class of applies These firms typically in in practice. mind. most similar to Gilboa and Schmeidler, max-min expected stress-test their The widespread policies. to describe agents expected utility. Wang of (1994), et al. (2004)). Our treatment in that agents choose a worst case We utility theory to agents who we of among interpret as running financial firms. models to various extreme scenarios before formulating investment use of Value-at-Risk as a decision Corporate liquidity management is making also criterion is an example of robust decision done with a worst case scenario for cash-flows view the max-min preferences of the agents we study as descriptive of decision rules that overweight a worst-case rather than as stemming from a deeper psychological foundation. In paper we list priors. Our paper making is we use a max-min device Stock refer to agents as robust decision making process much of the makers. This terminology most closely corresponds to the decision of the financial institutions that concern us in this paper. Routledge and Zin (2004) also begin from the observation that financial institutions follow decision rules 2 Easley and O'Hara (2005) study a model where ambiguity averse traders focus on a worst case scenario investment decision. Like us, Easley and O'Hara point out that government intervention effects. in a when making an worst-case scenario can have large They develop a model to protect against a worst case scenario. maker averse market and asks sets bids to facilitate trade of of market liquidity in which an uncertainty an asset. Their model captures an important aspect of flight to quality: uncertainty aversion can lead to a sudden widening of the bid-ask spread, causing agents to halt trading and reducing market liquidity. Both our paper and Routledge and Zin share the emphasis on financial intermediation and uncertainty aversion as central ingredients in But each paper captures episodes. different aspects of flight to quality. In our model, agents are only Knightian with respect to other markets stein (2001) explores the home flight to quality and not bias in international portfolios in a similar setup. modeling also highlights the difference between high risk aversion their own market. Ep- As Epstein points out, this and aversion to Knightian uncertainty. Moreover, our modeling shows that max-min preferences interact with macroeconomic conditions in ways that are not present in models with an invariant mediary collateral is plentiful, amount of risk aversion. We show that 1 we Knightian model. describe the environment and characterizes decisions and equilibrium. Section 2 explains the implications of our model for flight-to-quality episodes. resort in our inter- Knightian and standard agents behave identically. However when aggregate collateral falls, the actions of these agents differ, leading to flight to quality in the In Section when aggregate economy. Sections 4 and 5 Section 3 derives the value of a lender of last illustrate the interaction between aggregate collateral and robustness. Section 6 concludes. 1 We The Environment consider a continuous time economy with a a phase where liquidity shocks may exponentially with hazard rate 8. Liquidity take place, and We consumption good. At date single it exits this 0, the economy enters phase at some random date r, distributed study the economy conditional on entering this liquidity phase. demand There are two groups of agents, each with unit measure, whose members we label as agent-type B. Each individual derives utility from consumption at date 17*=u(4) where the log-utility assumption is primarily notation u(.) where convenient). There Each agent is endowed at date is = ln4 made A and r: ie{A,B}. for expositional reasons (1) (we retain the more general no discounting. with wo in consumption goods. These goods are perishable, and are used to purchase financial claims - see below. In the normal course of business, the agents can expect to earn a profit of phase, so that cv = II. However, the agents may II when exiting the liquidity receive a "liquidity shock" that reduces profits to unless they have some liquidity available to them immediately. the We fall in profits. such liquid funds, agents can insure against normalize the return on the liquidity investment to one, so that investing funds results in a consumption level of cT (l) The With liquidity shock is common to all = I of liquid I. agents of a given type. We will think of all agents of a type as belonging to a particular market, so that the shock has the interpretation of a market-specific shock. The shock occurs to each market at most once between A. The shocks and The t. arrival of the shock Poisson, with intensity is are uncorrelated across markets. Agents purchase financial claims that deliver some liquidity to them and thereby insure against the in the event of the liquidity shock fall in profits. Liquidity supply and aggregate collateral constraint The financial sector consists of intermediaries who liquidity insurance to sell think of these intermediaries as having some capital available to allocate across A A and B at date 0. and B's markets We in the event of shocks. Financial intermediaries are required to collateralize insurers have ready access to liquidity insurance in the by their consumption goods collateral. all sales at all dates, of liquidity insurance. and are only For now, we assume that collateral is We assume that restricted in their supply of riskless and worth Z, but later paper we relax this assumption and study situations where the collateral value varies over time and and across states (see Sections 5 The intermediaries' objective 6). is to maximize the date of the insurance resources disbursed at time s of /3 revenue from the sale of the insurance a cost per unit: U 1 = 4 + 001, and subject less /3>0 (2) to the collateral constraint that, in any state, the insurer does not write insurance exceeding Z. Financial claims Each agent is uncertain about whether he will be hit by a shock or not and about the order in which shocks will take place. There of both types of agents. s being the date s < first We one. y s (t) is a complete set of Arrow-Debreu claims contingent on the shock define x(s) as a claim that pays one at date is a claim paying one at date t, s, realizations conditional on the shock at date conditional on the first shock having occurred at t. Robustness Agents purchase financial claims from the intermediaries to insure against their liquidity shocks. making the insurance decisions, agents have a probability model In of the liquidity shocks in mind. But, while each agent knows the intensity of the shock in his the other agent-types' market. We own market, he unsure of the intensity of the shock in is explore the case in which agents formulate decisions that are robust to the intensity of the other agents' shock. We write all of our problems from the standpoint of agent(s) A, referring to the other agent-type as B, and denoting A's assessment More formally, we of B's intensity as Xb- follow Gilboa and Schmeidler (1989), max and express agent min Eo[u(c6) A is a class of alternative probability models that agent decision problem as: As.A^l I {x(s)},{y s (i)}A B 6A where j4's A deems as possible. 3 Discussion of setup Our model studies an episode. In practice, economy conditional on entering a we think that liquidity episode. It is silent the occurrence of an unexpected event, such as the We focus causes agents to re-evaluate their models and triggers robustness concerns. play out during the liquidity episode: How do agents' robustness concerns do these robustness concerns interact with aggregate constraints? What LTCM or Enron crises, on the mechanisms that affect prices is on what triggers the and quantities? How the role of an outside liquidity provider such as the central bank? We think of the agents in our model as financial specialists For example, the agents may be Alternatively, the agents firms in a single industry that may be banks we model the agents who We actively participate in a single market. susceptible to a temporary drop in cash-flow. that are susceptible to an outflow of deposits. may be hedge-funds/market-makers who cases, is who are susceptible to a shock to their trading capital. In case scenario analysis in decision affected goal is all of these are responsible for insuring against a temporary liquidity shortfall. view agents' max-min preferences as descriptive of their decision Our main Finally, the agents making example why to investigate by aggregate conditions. In rules. The widespread use of worst- of the robustness preferences of such agents. these robustness concerns are important in the aggregate principle, the demand for safety the Russian default, can be easily accommodated by the on asset prices or quantities. Yet, in practice, capital does not and are by a sector of hedge funds, say during rest of the capital move market, with negligible effects freely across markets to provide the necessary liquidity. There are bottlenecks, suggesting that there are constraints on the supply of capital. We model 3 We these constraints by assuming that financial intermediaries, who specialize in capital reallocation, study arrangements where the financial intermediary provides insurance, ruling out direct consumption insurance arrangements between A and B. In keeping with our collateral restrictions on the intermediary, we may think having no collateral and therefore being unable to support such insurance arrangements. of the agents to support If we assigned Z/2 of A and B as collateral to each mutual insurance, agents' robustness concerns would reduce such insurance. Intermediaries maximize the use of collateral. 4 See Routledge and Zin (2004) for a more extensive discussion of examples of max-min behavior among financial specialists. are limited by a collateral constraint. The collateral of the intermediary measures the maximum amount of capital they can supply to a particular market. Since the intermediaries are risk-neutral, they will supply how much insurance to our agents. But, in aggregate, the collateral constraints place a limit on the supply- side can respond to the robustness-concerns triggered during a liquidity episode. Our model assumes that there are complete liquidity-shock-contingent financial claims. Moreover, agents prearrange insurance against liquidity shocks at date in asset markets - for 0. In practice, liquidity shocks trigger dynamic trading example, by shedding risky assets and moving to Treasury responses are ex-post and not all ex-ante. We have chosen our strategy despite - so that agents' Bills its interpretability costs because, as usual, with complete Arrow-Debreu markets a dynamic problem can be more easily stated as a static one. More substantively, our objective is why to provide an endogenous explanation for capital does not move across markets, as opposed to making an exogenous segmentation/incomplete markets assumption. The assumption As a matter of complete liquidity-shock-contingent claims isolates the mechanism we highlight. of interpretation, the ex-ante insurance contracts can be thought of as collateralized contin- gent credit-lines. Decisions and Equilibrium 2 In this section we where robustness describe agents' decisions and equilibrium, is Flight-to-quality, which not a concern. and contrast them with a benchmark case we discuss more fully in the next section, is described in terms of the difference in agents' equilibrium decisions across these two cases. The 2.1 The problem cost of locking collateral of a financial intermediary order to maximize revenue Denote the price of the <?!>i(s) less to sell x(s) first-shock claims and y s (t) second-shock claims in the cost of providing liquidity insurance, subject to the collateral constraint. first-shock claim p(s) as the (true) probability of the We is first and the event, and price of the second-shock claim q s (t). 5 (i) as the (true) probability of the second event. 5 assume that the insurer has no robustness concerns and knows these true out that for most of the conclusions we derive, this is Also, denote without probabilities, but loss of generality. it turns Then the intermediary solves, max {x(s)},{y(s}} Jf ( \ (p(s) - /?<Ms))x(s) + / Js (<7.(0 - 0</> s (t))y s (t)dt) ds (3) J subject to, x{s) 5 With 4>i(s) = Xe-V+W 3 and 4>s(t) = 2 X e- Xs e-^+ x ^. < Z (4) = and x(s)+ys {t)<Z. (5) Constraints (4) and (5) are standard collateral constraints that agents impose on the intermediary. We Consider an agent looking to purchase first-shock insurance. balance sheet of the intermediary, i.e., assume that This gives the constraint collateral, Z, to cover all of his liabilities, x(s). first- if the intermediary has sufficient (4). the other hand, an agent looking to purchase second-shock insurance and second-shock insurance that the insurer has sold. Since concerned about both the we is paid only after up second-shock insurance claim buyers require that the effective collateral of the insurer covers insurance sold. Thus, all Z — x{s). is second-shock arrive at (5). Because of the linearity of the objective function, problem is second-shock insurance first-shock claims have been settled, the effective collateral that backs The second-shock can observe the the collateral levels of the intermediary and the claims the intermediary has sold to other agents. The agent only purchases first-shock insurance On this agent (3) yields that x{s) and ys (t) are at an the collateral constraints do not bind the solution to if interior only if, p(s)=0Ms) Qs{t) For example, when We (3 = 1, when insurance the second constraint binds in equilibrium for values, the first P4>s(t)- prices are actuarially fair at an interior solution. are interested in the case shadow = is limited by the insurer's collateral. In this case, assuming all (s,t) pairs, and denoting by (J- S {t) > the corresponding order conditions yield: q s (t)=l3<f> s (t)+»s(t), /oo H s (t)dt. Prices now rise to reflect the scarcity of collateral price of a second-shock claims for all > t s, (/j, > 0). Integrating the expression for q s (t) to obtain the gives: /oo q a (t)dt = 0<h{s) +(*{*), (6) with 2 The term is </>2(s) is ( s )= r°° / x &(t)<ft=0i(s)— X —6 the probability of the economy receiving two shocks before the liquidity event equal to the probability of receiving a single shock, 10 <j>i(s), (7) + is over. It multiplied by the conditional probability of receving one more shock £$. Thus prior to the end of the liquidity episode, q(s) is made sum of the of the expected cost of a two-shocks policy for the insurer, and the multiplier on the collateral constraint, m( s )- An important point to note about the expressions for q(s) and p(s) is that the multiplier both and does not depend on the probability of each of these events. That is, is common a tight collateral constraint pushes up the price of contingent claims regardless of the probability of the insurance-event. this is because the collateral constraint requires that curtailed for > all t Thus the opportunity s. if x(s) cost of writing is first-shock claims is claims can be offered. Both claim prices have to be in line because they both reflect a collateral. We The common in cost of locking terms of q(s): = q(8)+/3(4>i(*)-M*))- (8) cost of locking collateral arises because of the sequential shock structure of the economy. The second shock only occurs and after the first shock has occurred. If the x(s) two mutually exclusive events, then the intermediary could use the same in each event. is that less second-shock common can make this point more precise by solving out p(s) and writing p(s) p(a) Intuitively, on the second shock high, then insurance more to y(s) claims corresponded to collateral to back liquidity insurance In such case, selling more y(s) claims does not impinge on the intermediary's ability to sell x (s) claims, so that the prices of claims need not be aligned. We are most interested in the opportunity cost of using collateral, as To writing liquidity insurance. simplify some of our expressions, drop the second term on the right-hand-side of is the main result we assume for now that = /? and thereby (8) to yield: p(s) This pricing expression opposed to the actuarial cost of = q(s). (9) from modelling the supply side of the economy. It captures the equilibrium cost of "locking" collateral. A 2.2 benchmark Before turning to the agent's decision problem, we pause to establish a "benchmark" for the model there are no robustness concerns. In this case, max {x(s)},{y 3 (t)}5 where r)(t - s) = (A —+ + <5)e _ /•oo 5 - u(U) , \ ( + A+l5 )( t_s ) shock, while y s (t) term is in the objective the is is the amount /*oo 0i(s)u(i(s)) + Ms) / V(t - s)u(y s (t)) dt ds Js I represents the probability that a second shock takes place at time conditional on a second shock taking place at In this objective, x(s) directly at the planner's problem: r / JO we can look when amount some date greater than s. of liquidity insurance delivered to the of insurance delivered to the second agent who first agent who receives a receives a shock. the expected utility in the event that no shocks arrive and agents consume 11 t, The first II. This term invariant to the x(s) is expected utility from the date (exit) The and y s (t) first and where convenient we omit decisions, shock arriving at date 6 it. The second term and the second shock occurring s, at a date is the prior to t r. constraints in the optimization are: < < Z x(s) and 0<x{s)+ys {t)<Z. Since ,5=0, the only limitation on liquidity insurance delivered to the agents financial intermediaries. The second Thus the planner simply is the supply of collateral of allocates the limited collateral across time collateral constraint has to bind since subsumes the it first constraint, and agents. and there is no other cost of providing insurance than the collateral limitation. y s (t)=y(s) Thus we t. The find that y s (t) = Z-x(s). allocations are not a function of the time interval between the expression also reflects the cost of locking collateral that we first referred to earlier. Z to back x(s) insurance, or to back y s (t) insurance, but not both. In this sense, offering amount insurance restricts the We , V? 8 ?, m are, for each time with y(s) the ( ) for benchmark economy, [Ms)u(x(s)) / each For s. u'(x(s)) _ Ms) = u'(y(s)) 4>i(s) A A + [W> 5 the log utility case, the quantity of insurance claims are: v ( y»< * <57 A V2A + <5 satisfy: x^_ y We + fo(s)u(y(s))] ds, the first order conditions characterizing insurance decisions ^-(^A)z 2A + 3 of one kind of s, = Z — x(s). and hence more as: rrT u n + which can be solved by maximizing pointwise Proposition 1 In can either be used of the other kind. can then rewrite the planner's problem , and second shock, be _ \+5 ~ A also omit a 2 that should multiply the objective function throughout to weight the 12 two groups. an agent In words, once is hit by a liquidity shock, the planner has an incentive to allocate more than This half of the resources to the agent in distress. is because as long as 5 > there a chance that the is second agent never gets hit and scarce liquidity goes wasted. We note that x(s) episodes where S is is constant and increasing with respect to large (temporary phenomena). In these cases, the to inject funds aggressively to the In the We 5. first group of agents hit are interested in liquidity crisis benchmark reveals a strong incentive by a shock. benchmark competitive equilibrium without robustness considerations, the more x than y claims to purchase intermediary that we derived in the claims reflect a common follows directly from the pricing schedule of a collateral constrained As part of this section. first probable than the two-shock event. incentive for agents 5 rises, the single-shock event However, because the prices of both cost of locking collateral, the prices of first becomes more and second shock financial both claims remain equal, favoring the purchase of the first-shock claim over the second-shock claim. The 2.3 An agents' decision agent type A problem (henceforth agent A, for short) solves a decision problem where he chooses the paths of x(s) and y s {t), attempting to be robust to values of As. choice of x(s) and y s We {t) In this subsection, we characterize the optimal given a particular value of A^. define the expected utility function for /•oo V({x(s)},{y s (t)},X B ) = J A given choices of {z(s)} and {y s {t)} and r some value of Ag: />oo V (t-s)u(y s (t))dt 4>?(s)u(x(s))+4>£(s)J ds where, from the exponential distribution function, the probabilities (as perceived by A) are: 4>f{s) = P(First shock <p£(s) = P(Second shock is = A's, at s) is A e (<5+A+As)s A's, at t>s) = —+ A The agent maximizes s.t. f r {x(s)>0},{y,(t)>0} The budget endowment u>o- The first (p(s)x(s)+ Jo constraint reflects purchase of x(s) and y s of ^-r</>f (s). o V(-) subject to his budget constraint: ™« ^^(M 5 )}.^*)}.^) , , V f Js q s (t)y s (t)dt) ds <w (11) J given prices of p(s) and q s (t) and the initial (t), order conditions for the optimization are: 4>?(s)u'(x(s))=Ms) (12) and ^{s)-q{t where ip is - fl)u'(y.(t)) = iMO. the Lagrange multiplier on the budget constraint. 13 (13) We can simplify the characterization of the agent's decision using the result from our the intermediary's problem. There we found earlier analysis of that p(s) and q s (t) are related to each other by a of locking collateral. Integrating both sides of (13) with respect to t and using equation (9), common we cost find that, /oo T){t-s)u'(y s (t))dt Then, combining this relation with we can eliminate (12), ' U {X{S)) = each is only a function of s and not of the agent's insurance decisions s, (14) simplify this relation considerably by using the knowledge that in so that y s {t) for p(s) to find: vit-sWiy^dt W{S)J We can = l>p{s) t. sum Since to Z all all equilibria, = Z — x(s), y s (t) insurance has to be backed by the collateral of Z, in equilibrium. 7 Since the probability of receiving a second shock prior to the end of the liquidity episode conditional on having received a first shock at date Proposition 2 The solution s equal to is we can ^r^-, to the agent's decision simplify the right-hand side of (14), to find: problem, (11), given a value of Xb is characterized by the relation: which for u'[x(a)) = 44 {s) = u'(y(s)) cpf(s) _ X As one would benchmark, (10), expect, the solution to the agent's decision problem coincides with the solution in the when Xb than the second-shock. likely = A. 8 More generally, for As < X+S is Note that we are not imposing the requirement that y s (t) in equilibrium, ys{t) =Z— = Z— c(s). FVom the first 8 that, y s {t) Given equilibrium = A x(s) in agents' decisions. reallocates Instead, we demand to are using the Xb, all feasible t), A 5 c(s)e-< + >«-*>, order condition, (13), and using: *£(«) we conclude = first-shock decreasing with respect to Xb- x(s), only certain price functionals are possible. For a given q s (t) some is more against the expected to be hit by a shock, the more agent equilibrium price functionals, q s (t), must take the form (with respect to for agents insure Note, however, that the ratio of x to y claims the other agent knowledge that since +5 XB y(s) 7 [l0> +S log utility implies: x(s) The more AB X y(s), regardless of prices, p(s) and q(s), = rrr^W. +X Xbfrom (12) and / Js n(t -«)* = (13), as well as the x (s)=^-(X i, intertemporal budget constraint we find that: + 6)e-( 6+x B-l-»° (16) p(s) y{ s) = ^Lx B e-(^ B +»°-. (17) g(«) (Note that the multiplier on the budget constraint is V = ^~ JTX 14 f° r tne case °f '°S utility.) A second-shock claims. thereby ensures that he still payments receives if he is hit by a liquidity shock as well. Robustness and equilibrium 2.4 We now in turn to the robustness step. In equation (15) we characterized the decision problem for agent A choosing x(s) relative to y s (t), given a particular value of Xb- These choices defined an expected utility function V({x(s)}, {y s Xb)- {t)}, to alternative values of Xb The robustness chooses x(s) and y s (t), then "nature" chooses problem full for agent is make these choices while being robust A Xb £ A max-min expected minimize the to utility theory, utility of agent A ^/X ™*M m n ^W*)}. {»•(*)}, given equilibrium prices p(s) and q s (t) and the budget constraint. over which agents would like to be robust is an agent A, given his choices. We Ab) assume the (18) set of alternative models interval defined by: max{0, X - K} < XB < preferences of agents, with a larger X + K. K corresponding to a more extreme worst-case scenario. The following proposition presents the Proposition 3 The following insurance • For • K < 8, agents' decisions are as main result of this section: decisions constitute an equilibrium in the robust if Xb = X + K: x pr X yP r X We refer to this case as the "partially robust" case. For K> 5, agents' decisions are as if Xb = X + +5 +K 6: x fT yfr We 1. refer to this equal claims case as the "fully robust" case. In both cases, first is: / I i iA {x(s)>0} ,{y 3 (t)>0} A B SA K indexes the robustness to • In the game-theoretic language often used to describe The A step for agent agents' decisions are time invariant. 15 economy: When are as if K= Xb = 0, A. the model collapses to the benchmark model without the robustness concern, and decisions As K agents become concerned that they will receive a shock second, in which case rises, their larger purchases of first-shock insurance will and increase first-shock insurance be wasted. first they reduce their purchases of At the extreme, when reflects the intuition K is and second-shock claims, and thereby insulate themselves against their uncertainty over the likelihood of market make result, their purchases of second-shock insurance. large enough, they equate their purchases of The formal proof As a B receiving a shock. we have provided, but is their insurance decisions anticipating that the worst case complicated by two Xb issues. First, depend on those will agents decisions; and, second, equilibrium prices are a function of the anticipated worst case of agents (but in an individual agent's decision problem, prices are taken as given). Proof. we First, The market decisions in equilibrium as A. clearing conditions imply, x A (s)+yf(t) x where we have used the Since the relative B (s) + first y A (t) = Z, = fact that the collateral availability of demand Z, Z determines the supply of liquidity insurance. 9 satisfies x(s) we can Denote the Xb on which agents base derive the prices in the proposed equilibrium. To substitute to solve out for x(s) and y(s). _ X+5 find prices, we substitute the derived quantities into the order conditions for agent A, (12) and (13), to yield: p{s ) ^ = { X + S + X)e-^ +5+ ^ s (19) and, qs{t) Small K: = ^z (X + 5 + A)(A + ,5) e -(A+*+A),-(A+*)(t-,) (20) Consider the robustness step next. For small K, we wish to show that, at equilibrium prices, the highest utility attainable when solving, mmV({x{s)},{y max V= {i(s)>0},{y (t)>0} AbEA s (t)},X B ) (21) a occurs at x pr and y pr and given these choices by the agent, "nature" always chooses X B , no other choice of {:r(s)} and {y s (t)} can induce nature to choose a X B that = X + K. Moreover, results in a higher utility for the agent. 9 If agent economizes A receives a shock first, his limited collateral then his second-shock insurance claim disappears. The same applies to B. Thus, the insurer by only backing the two possible shock sequences of 16 A then B, and B then A. Given an assumed worst case of A max agents problem, (11), W = X + +S + X X = 6 _ e -(A*-*)«z and pr y , denote probability of a <j>2 and (20), the unique optimum to the and, = y(s) ys (t) A« _ +5+ X = X Using e -(A a -*)« Z knowledge, we can derive the this as, V{x p \ 4>? prices (19) Xg, x{s) and y(s) are constant functions of time. expected utility function for the agent where and equilibrium is: x f a) At A + K, = tfu{x pr + <i>$u(ypr ), XB ) (22) ) and second shock at any time first (as perceived by agent A), respectively: /•OO Using the envelope theorem, we which is values of pr ' 2/ apparent that the agent it is , As, since such a choice makes first-shock claims (i.e. = is X) and as long as x pr particularly unprotected Next, define V = X + K = V{x pr utility attainable in (21). pT (i.e. ,y pr ,Xb = Suppose there X + set in choosing A £ We now K). . Thus, since A is for small nature chooses to increase is over- weight in linear, for small optimum. If is utility if enough Xb = X + K, then choose Xb = A + K given the induced utility is result in they induce nature to choose x pT and y strictly lower pr than and nature continues V pr is K= 5. At is the highest V > V pr pr and y . this point, the agent becomes a unique to choose a worst Xb further lowers the utility of pr . robust with respect to any Xb, since fully It Xb < X + K. Note For large values of K, the gap between first-shock and second-shock claims narrows until disappears once K Moreover, since nature can always . the agent's deviation, nature's optimal choice of the agent. Thus, the agent can do no better than to choose x Large K: and {y s {t)} which V pr strictly concave, the first order conditions define the agent makes any choice other than case of argue, by contradiction, that exist choices of {x(s)} that since the optimization problem in (11) it when y, Vx B for pr highest value possible). should be clear that such choices can only increase = if y pr pr the agent considers only small deviations in the model), the utility of the agent at choices (x ,y ) minimized when Xb x > valuable to the agent, and the agent less Moreover, since the constraint holding these claims. \ find that, around the benchmark (Xb strictly negative K, x 91 > />oo \ any Xb- At K= 5, the agent attains utility of =0 V^ r = V(f-, f As = X+5). , Further increases in K expand the constraint set for nature, and thereby weakly decrease the highest utility attainable in (21). However, 17 the agent can guarantee himself V fr by choosing x = K> 5. attain the highest possible utility in (21) for all = f y . Thus, the fully robust choices continue to m Flight-to- Quality Episodes 3 We now discuss the connection between our model and shows how, given a limited capacity of the economy may for liquidity provision (Z), We further reduce the liquidity available to the economy. robust actions and how they reduce aggregate At a broad flight-to-quality episodes. liquidity. We level our model the actions of robust agents begin this section with examples of these then discuss the macroeconomic consequences of flight to quality episodes. We generate a flight to quality in the model as a comparitive static in which accounts of flight to quality As rises. In practice, episodes begin with an unexpected event that leads agents to reassess their models. In 1970, the unexpected event was the Penn Central default on Commercial Paper. In 1987, thesharp drop K rise in 5), which then leads more terms of financial intermediary 3.1 is clear enough. our model A fall in Z grow concerned that intermediaries may not have enough Agents worry about being second and in flight to quality in detail in Section 5, but the intuition risk as agents was to a rise in \b- For a fixed K, an alternative way to generate case in it terms of our model, a reassessment of models can be thought of as a in the stock market. In K< (for many raise \b- Some is We explain this to reduce Z. increases financial intermediary collateral to cover their shocks. episodes, such as the Fall of 1998, can be thought of risk. Example: Intermediary capital allocation In equilibrium, markets A and B are guaranteed liquidity of y In addition to the minimum level of insurance, = min{z,;y}. x - y > of liquidity is delivered to the first market that receives a shock. We can intepret this behavior in terms of intermediaries' capital allocation decision, y of the capital of an intermediary capital") to is locked-up to service each market ("committed capital"), and x move to the first market with the shock. As Xb to allocate flexibly across markets. In the fully robust case, In many flight to quality episodes, bottlenecks arise in mented. For example, in the Fall of rises, x—y x—y = the 0, falls — y capital and there is is less free ("trading trading capital and markets are segmented. movement of capital and markets appear seg- 1998 episode the markets where hedge funds specialized were particularly affected by the crisis, as capital did not flow into these markets. 18 Notice that segmentation is the market's response to agents' robustness concerns. Since agents require financial claims that are uncontingent on shocks outside their by committing intermediaries to segment their can interpret the financial claims of that intermediaries have a limited is x the market provides such claims capital. Example: Run on banks' credit facility/deposits 3.2 We own markets, A that = y, A amount and B of capital to back up these The credit lines. preemptively drawing down a credit line at complete in our model, the future action by Although the actions of agents in our a date when the fear of large A is prearranged at date 0, B shocks may = first. By As markets A are 10 y. model are most naturally interpreted as a run on banks' at a deeper level, agents' actions are also related to the setting be reflected by arises. by choosing x recognize robustness concern agents are worried that B's shocks will deplete the bank's limited credit facility they insulate themselves from this concern. In practice, the robustness action facility, The agents as credit lines from intermediaries. credit more commonly analyzed run on banks' As Diamond and Dybvig (1983) emphasize, a deposit contract implements an optimal shock- deposits. contingent allocation of liquidity. In the fully robust equilibrium of our model, agents choose an allocation that non-contingent on each other's shocks instead of the contingent liquidity allocation of the benchmark is economy. Agents each hoard Z/2 units of liquidity to cover their own shocks, independent of other markets' shocks. In this sense, robust agents' preference for shock independent liquidity allocations is related the behavior of panicked depositors in a bank run. The the essence of a flight-to-quality episode demand uncontingent insurance as \b for well collateralized financial institutions. financial claim demand for is is agents' that agents rises is With a demand for certainty. may shift their empirical counterpart of demands toward extremely less well collateralized institution, contingent on the other markets' shocks. Thus our model bank deposits and bank The accompanies credit lines that is an agent fears that his consistent with the increased flight to quality (see Gatev and Strahan, 2005). In Section 6 of their own we show that collateral. these actions by the agents trigger a reaction by insurers to ensure the safety Insurers increase their valuation of riskless assets relative to risky assets, which consistent with the widening of the spread between Commercial Paper and Treasury bills is that accompanies flight to quality. 10 We can also interpret robustness bank lobbies for more risk capital, in terms of the internal because of fear that desk risk B management of an investment bank: Desk will suffer losses 19 A of an investment soon, reducing the bank's total risk capital. Example: Liquidity suppliers become demanders 3.3 In the crises of the Fall of 1998, hedge funds were retrenching from many markets and thereby reducing the overall supply of liquidity (see Kyle and Xiong, 2001). became to markets We may The liquidating assets, natural liquidity providers liquidity demanders. think of the robustness concern in our model as corresponding in practice to hedge funds' (or their investors') fears that market liquidity outcomes, further reducing market investors) requires enough other causing the hedge funds to overprotect against adverse will fall, liquidity. A liquidity providers to participate in B robust hedge fund grows concerned that shocks in market from market A. As a result, the A For example, suppose a hedge fund in market make to (x) used currently for liquidity provision in market A, and instead increases the buffer (y) against the possible A The the business profitable. could cause other liquidity providers to pull back hedge fund reduces the amount of capital behavior reduces the liquidity of both market (or the fund's B shock. The conservative and B. In any flight to quality episode, the capacity of financial intermediaries - commercial and investment banks, hedge funds, trading desks, market makers, At the abstract level of liquidity to markets. our model, Z Our model does not distinguish economy and compounds an aggregate (13), to find the prices of first modes the various provide we of liquidity provision the behavior of robust agents reduces the effective Z of liquidity shortage. and second-shock P(«) As Xb rises, claims: = ?(*) linear <5 (24) . Z in K s, the exponential term in (24) increases the prices of both = g(0) = ^(A + 5 + increase in prices of the first-shock insurance contract second-shock insurance. As we have shown Because the model has only two shocks, on surviving until date fall. is liquidity insurance: first is and second-shock 11 The which order conditions for agent A, (12) = ^(A + + X B )e-^ +6+x ^ s term so that the increase p(0) claims first equilibrium prices of insurance change as well. For small dominated by the 11 how among can substitute the equilibrium values of x(s) and y{s) into the and constrained. Price of liquidity provision 3.4 We is reflects the capacity of liquidity providers, in aggregate, to observe in practice. Instead our model shows the - to provide liquidity to markets etc. the s when As is indirect, driven rises, large s occurs at the recessionary shock. 20 s = by increased demand robust agents decrease their for s sufficiently large, the increase in without a shock. In these cases, the exponential term The boundary between the small and half-life of earlier, A B ). A^ in (24) for demand lessens the odds that the agent places dominates and the prices of financial j^Vj; for 5 large relative to A, the boundary is at j for first-shock insurance. collateral for y They increase demand for and decrease the supply available to second-shock insurance, causing insurers to lock-up first-shock insurance, thereby indirectly driving up the price of first-shock insurance. The prices, p and q, represent the marginal cost of liquidity provision in the economy. Since intermediaries have a limited amount of collateral to back liquidity provision, at the aggregate capacity of the economy to provide liquidity to markets. As robustness rises the parameterizes the the cost of liquidity provision rises, Macroeconomic active. cost Suppose we introduce a small number of rational Savage agents into the economy. These agents, benchmark economy, will calculate that it is prices that the robust agents face. of insurance they purchase, economy-wide At these high is same inflated liquidity insurance non-robust agents will also reduce the amount to liquidity shocks (for low s). 12 In this sense, not just a problem affecting the decision rules of robust agents. It has an cost. robust agents lock-up resources in their desire for certainty, the financial system becomes inflexible in its response to shocks. promise to the first In the benchmark economy, x be > y be market that receives a shock. The freedom good chance that the second shock never takes An prices, the and leave themselves exposed our model flight to quality in as in the optimal to insure more against the first-shock as opposed to the second-shock. However, notice that these agents will have to trade at the When structure, the cost of liquidity provision will also be reflected as higher liquidity premia in the asset markets where the intermediaries are 3.5 Z Z of the economy. With a richer asset because the actions of robust agents reduce the effective rise in level, alternative way is , so that x be — y be of collateral valuable since as long as 5 > 0, is left there is to a place. to see the collateral waste associated to a flight-to-quality episode is to re-write the constraint +y < Z x in terms of the risky and riskless claims Z can support: (x The riskless claim consumes twice as much Recall that the change in prices depends on s. y) + 2y < Z. collateral as a risky claim. claims, as in the fully robust equilibrium, locks 12 - up For large Having collateral that goes s, all agents holding only riskless unused when 5 prices fall since the rise in Xb > 0. leads to a decline in the perceived probability of shocks taking place. Hence rational Savage agents lower early insurance (both of x(s) and y(s)) as a result of the presence of robust agents (the point we have highlighted) but increase late insurance. 21 In practice, systemic risk financial system becomes is the important macroeconomic concern in flight to quality episodes. inflexible, bottlenecks arise that When the can trigger accelerators and create system-wide problems. Locked Collateral and Extreme Event Intervention 4 In this section we study the impact of a lender of last resort on the economy. that obtains resources ex-post, at event. In practice, this pledge may be guaranteeing, against default, the markets. We some cost, which it We bank consider a central can credibly pledge to agents in the two-shock extreme supported by costly ex-post inflation or taxation and carried out by liabilities of financial intermediaries who have sold financial claims to both analyze the impact and marginal benefit of such a guarantee. Formally, we assume that the government credibly expands the collateral of the financial sector in the two-shock event by an amount G. Thus, the collateral constraints on intermediaries are altered to x Since we are interested in computing the marginal benefit of intervention, vention of G. 4.1 A The infinitesimal inter- Welfare criterion when agents have non-Savage also adopt the agents' preferences'? concerned with agents' ex-post average As noted earlier in the paper, Or, should utility we think decision rules of financial specialists why we study an intervention has no effect on the constraint for first-shock insurance. delicate issue arises bank + y< Z + G. (e.g., of robust control to central it In evaluating policy, should the central take a more paternalistic approach in which of the robustness preferences as a realistic depiction of the its From objective function that Sims (2001) has made may this perspective, it is this point in questioning the application bank policymaking. He argues that max-min preferences we begin by analyzing a to alternative, 4.2 more are simpy shortcuts first In what welfare function based on agents' expected utility functions, and then turn paternalistic, welfare criteria. Robust expected Consider not clear lead to obvious average losses, to generate observed behavior of economic agents, but should not be seen as deeper preferences. follows, it is from consumption? value-at-risk constraints). a central bank should build biases into just because agents exhibit these biases. preferences: utility the case where the central bank uses the agents' expected utility functions to evaluate welfare. In this case, the envelope theorem tells us that the indirect effect due to the change of insurance decisions 22 is second-order, and that the only benefit In our model, we have and (see equations (22) is the direct is direct, (23)) is, y, = XB ) (j>iu{x) more insurance against the second-shock whereas the effect on x is an indirect + <t>£u{y) leads agents to increase both x the effect on y Z can be computed assuming all of the Z is (25) J^^, j^^Z. = While there tially The y. y: VG = d4Av) = since y and reoptimization of agents' portfolios. However, using effect of the envelope theorem, the utility gain from an extra unit of spent increasing and y derived that the expected utility for an agent at the optimal choices of x V(x, Offering effect. same is a welfare benefit of providing a government guarantee, the value of the benefit in the benchmark and the robust economies. 13 In both fully insure agents against shocks. The benefit of the extra unit of agents more insurance against an adverse outcome. It Z is cases, the economy (1998). As we show substan- lacks collateral to limited to the direct effect of providing stems from our assumption that the government can create liquidity to insure a shock from sources that the private sector cannot, as in Holmstrom and Tirole is next, this logic does not apply if Woodford (1990) and we consider alternative welfare criteria. 4.3 bank Fully informed central Consider a welfare criterion based on agent's decisions, but evaluated at the reference envelope theorem argument breaks down for the robust from second-shock to first-shock insurance has first order economy and the A's. In this case the reallocation of private insurance Since in equilibrium the agent "exagerates" effects. the likelihood of a two-shock event relative to a single-shock event, the reallocation of resources toward shock insurance has a The expected first order benefit. value of the direct effect of intervention for the central bank is: (26) fcu'(y). 7r 13 Recall that a liquidity shock eliminates > 0. We find that in economy, even may eschew if first- all profits. We have explored a setup where the shock reduces profits to a this case the benefit of the lender of last resort policy agents' expected utility is the welfare criterion. When may be 7r is greater in the robust than in the sufficient large, agents in the level of benchmark benchmark economy insurance agains the extreme two-shock event in favor of increasing insurance against the single-shock event. In contrast, agents in the robust economy always insure against the two-shock against an extreme event, while agents in the event. Thus robust agents further value insurance benchmark economy have limited (expected) valuation for such insurance. Notice that here the benefit of the policy comes from the agent's valuation of the extra insurance rather than from the reorganization of its portfolio in the presence of the policy. 23 where (date <j> 2 is the (true) probability the central bank assigns to a two-shock event at the time of commitment 0). The total (direct plus indirect) expected value of the — government intervention dec is: dii VG = (t>W{x)—+4> 2 u\y)^. (27) where Vq denotes the expected value of intervention evaluated using the central banks's probability distri- bution. The first order condition for agents' optimization u'(x) Using VG = Finally, we divide = ^T^'(y) ^ this relation, as well as the constraint that is: -I- 4^ — 1, we find, ^y)(l + {^-l)%) by the direct this total effect of intervention (28) effect of intervention to construct a private sector multiplier of the lender of last resort commitment: M-(l + (£-l)§). Proposition 4 When X B benefit =X (benchmark economy), the and M For Xb total benefit of intervention is limited to the direct > X, there is an indirect benefit be = stemming from M r > When agents make the reoptimization of agents' portfolios: 1. economy stems from the Intuitively, the benefit of intervention in the robust to the central bank's guarantee. 1. reaction of the private sector their insurance decisions, they are overly concerned about receiving the shock second, and use too high an assessment of the likelihood of the two-shock event. This breaks the envelope theorem argument under the central banks' objective function. By offering to insure the two-shock event directly, the central bank leads the agent to free up resources to insure the more likely one-shock event 4.4 (^ > 0). Partially informed central Our assumption bank that the central bank knows the true A's of the economy, despite the fact that agents be unsure about these A's, is a strong requirement. requirement on the central bank. 24 In this section, we may consider a weaker informational Agent central A bank knows that X B £ [max{A — K, some non-degenerate symmetric robust economy). + K] joint distribution We (and likewise for agent B). about the values of the also uncertain is 0}, A and only knows that the A's, cb F(X A A^). , We study the case where suppose that the drawn from A's are K > 5 (i.e. the fully 14 Because of symmetry symmetric interventions, in F(-), i.e. it is straightforward to show that the central bank restricts attention to interventions that are equal regardless of whether it is A or B that is hit first, or second. we In this case define the multiplier as: [Vg (\a,Xb)] m= EEXaXb[DE(X a ,X b )}' XaXb where Vc{X A ,X B ) and DE(X A Xb) and respectively stand for the total , direct expected effect of the inter- vention conditional on X A and A^. Then, for the fully robust economy, EXaXb [Vg (X a ,Xb)} = where denotes the probability that agent Pr(z; Aj) economy, the promised resources event. ^u'(Z/2)EXaXb [Pv(A;X a Thus the marginal value by the probability that shocks hit i is of resources in the shock may )} equally across the Proposition 5 is u'(Z/2) times one-half. This value , i is hit first is weighted + Pr(B\A; X a ,X b )}, second given intensities X A and Asi is effect reflects that resources are all hit by a shock while j ' is For not, given spent in the event of the second shock. knowledge of the markets probability models If the central bank and second shock split Px(i\Noj;X A ,X B ) denote the probability that agent X A andAs. The direct intensity A*. In the fully robust is u'(Z/2)E XaXb [Pt{A\B; X a X b ) where Pr(i\j\X A ,X B ) denotes the probability that agent intensities its occur, to either agent. EXaXb [DE(X a ,X b = later use, let + Pt(B-X b )}, by a shock given two-shock event in the ) is limited to a non-degenerate symmetric joint distribution F(X cAb Ag) with some mass for finite and positive X A and X cg, the multiplier in , the fully robust economy is, M T > 1. Proof. From the symmetry of F(X Ab X CB ), we have that the multiplier can be written as , M 14 In T = EXaXb [Pt(A;X a )} 2E XaXb {Pv(A\B;X a ,X b ) the fully robust economy, the x and y decisions of agents are independent of A, which simplifies our analysis because avoid computing the central bank's expectations over agents insurance decisions. 25 we Thus, the proposition holds if: E XaXb [Pt(A- X A Expanding the left hand )} side of this expression, > 2E XaXb [Pt(A\B;X a ,X b )). we have EXaXb [Pr(i4; X A = E XaXb [Pv(A\B; \ a )} , Xb ) that: + Pv(A\NoB; X A ,X B + Pr(B\A; X A ) = EXaXb {2 Pr(A\B; X A ,X B + ) , X B )} Pr(A\NoB; X A) X B )}- Replacing this expression back into the inequality, we have that the latter holds and only if X B and positive X Ab since 5 > if E XaXb {Pt(A\NoB;X a ,X b )}>0, which is satisfied as long as F(X A , X'g ) has some mass for Intuitively, the proof exploits the central bank's exaggerates the probability of being second. Agent finite knowledge of symmetry B the distribution). Agent A does the same. Thus the total benefit of the lender of last resort reflects exaggerated probabilities of agents being second. the central bank knows that they are drawn from similar distributions. A, (in 0. Despite not knowing the true With a symmetric A's, distribution over the probabilities the central bank uses reflects that the agents cannot both be second. This information affects the central thereby sufficient to conclude that the multiplier on intervention 4.5 The symmetry information bank's calculation of the direct benefit of intervention. is is greater than one. Moral hazard critique Under the decisions. paternalistic view, the public provision of insurance leads to improved private sector insurance The complementarity between public and private provision of insurance in our model cuts against the usual moral hazard critique of central bank interventions. This critique to the provision of public insurance by cutting back on their own insurance is predicated on agents responding activities. In our model, in keeping with the moral hazard critique, agents reallocate insurance away from the publicly insured shock. However, when flight to quality is the concern, the reallocation improves (ex-post) outcomes on average. 15 Note that the central bank can achieve the same distribution intervene in the first shock. (likely) single-shock event. 15 Note that if is instead it commits to larger than the extreme event bank rather than the private sector bears the cost of insurance against the cost of this policy is Agents would reallocate the expected resources from the central bank to the the direct effect of intervention inconsistent. This result the policy if much However the expected intervention, since the central of insurance is insufficient to justify intervention, then the lender of last resort policy is time not surprising as the benefit of the policy comes precisely from the private sector reaction, not from itself. 26 two-shock event, which is what the exactly the opposite of central bank wants to achieve. In this sense, interventions in intermediate events are subject to the moral hazard critique. To see this, let us return to the case of the fully informed central bank. in the event of the first shock is 4>\u'{x), while the total effect ,' From this equation, dx A The direct effect of the intervention is, dx / follows that, it Vr <piu'{x) since AB That > is, < A and ^g- < 1. the lender of last resort facility, to be effective and improve private financial markets, has to be a last not an intermediate resort. Financial Intermediary Risk and Aggregate Collateral 5 Throughout the paper we have made assumptions aggregate collateral a fall in limited. In this section is we so that the some relax economy we and show that of these assumptions derive a comparative static to contrast the response of the the robust economy to a tightening of collateral. We in this case The only that insurers substantive modification now we make some Abundant that our baseline model Z We results characterizing the equilibrium. solutions illustrating the equilibria for both first in this section to we have discussed face a "consumption" cost of using insurance resources. solution for this case but present benchmark economy and find that the response to a collateral tightening qualitatively similar to the increase in preference for robustness that Suppose always in a situation where intermediation collateral can trigger a flight to quality. In this context, 5.1 is is in earlier sections. is to set cannot derive a full P > so analytical The section ends with numerical benchmark and robust economy. collateral is large enough so that, at equilibrium levels of demand, the financial sector is uncon- strained in selling insurance. In this case, the prices of the two financial claims just reflect probabilities: In the case of robust agents, using the first p(s) = 0Ms) q(s) = Pfa(a) order conditions (12) and (13) x[s) y[) 0* M*) 27 MM*)' we find that: It is easy to verify that the solution for robust agents for all s. 16 The argument resembles At equal (22) levels of x and y, the proof of Proposition the agent is equal to zero. Picking the point is = we X, y(s) = ya (t), and equal to. a constant 3. robust to any value of Xb = to set x(s) is Xb that nature chooses and V\ B in equation see that choosing the constant levels for x and y is the unique optimum for agents. If agents are fully informed about Xb, the same first the solution. Intuitively, since prices are actuarially likely order conditions, evaluated at Xb = X, determine agents choose to insure equally against both the fair, one-shock event as well as the unlikely two-shock event. The benchmark case solution in the is identical to the solution in the robust economy. Both economies respond equally to the typical (single shock) event, as well as to the extreme two-shock event. 5.2 Collateral tightening Let That is, when prices are "fair" Note Z_ represents the level of intermediation collateral which exactly satisfies agents insurance (ji = at this point that demand 0). when = /? in the collateral-constrained region. 0, Z — as in the previous sections, Henceforth let > oo so that the economy us specialize to the case with (3 = 1 so that is always when Z > Z_ prices correspond to the standard actuarially fair prices. Suppose now that Z falls constraint of the insurers where fj,(s) The = / n s (t) > first below and Z_. Then, at actuarially fair prices, agents' demand saturate the collateral prices rise to reflect the collateral tightening: p(s) = <t>i(s) q s (t) = 4>2{s)ri{t +n(s) - s) + fis (t), 0. order conditions for agents remain as in (12) and (13). For the x decision: ±-4>A(s)u'{x(s))=Ms) while for the y 3 {t) + n(s) (30) decision: 4^(s)r?(s - t)u'(y s (t)) = <t> 2 (s)v(s ~t) + n,(t). V As before, we can use the knowledge that y s (t) = y(s) to integrate this equation ^(s)u'(y(s)) = 4>2(s)+^s)In addition, at this solution, the multiplier on the budget constraint 28 is i/i = , find: (31) ip 16 and - x+s )wo We consider the effect of a collateral tightening by inspecting (30) and (31). multiplier More and /j.(s) raises prices, leading to interestingly, for a an equal change both x(s) and fall in tightening increases the y(s). in /i(s), the relative fall in x(s) and y(s) depends on the ratio Beginning from the case where x and y are equal, from (31) we can see that y -rfr- < response to the tight collateral constraint since ^ftthe decrease in y To prove yu(s) The = smaller in the robust is and these statements, for each of (30) and /i(s) > for the benchmark case the right-hand side across these two values of n(s) sides across the two values of in the x*(s) 1 A). For each of (30) and (31), the only difference in is + X and y°{s). Since -A^ < Using this knowledge, we find that, 17 1 when the constraint does bind. the percentage 1, (31). \y°(s) (s) are = Thus, the difference in the left-hand 0. /V(a) S and y l bind, x°(s) > due to n(s) x°(s) and y°{s) are the equilibrium values of x and y when the benchmark economy. = Where equilibrium values A, construct the difference between the case where = _A_ x°{s) > we are equal, for each of (30) fi(s) in (31), Xb (i.e more than x Moreover, since in the robust economy Xb 1. economy than falls fall in x is As constraint does not bind, and before, when the x 1 (s) constraint does not smaller than the percentage fall in y. Then it follows that 1 la: In the ^) - benchmark economy, the tightening a: (*)| 1 < |y (a) - v°(*)|. of the collateral constraint leads to a smaller fall in x than in y. Let us compare the robust economy next to the benchmark economy, where both economies are constrained. Subtracting (31) from (30) Xb In the robust case, right-hand side to rises beyond rise (recall we A. find: From that 0f(s) is the above expression decreasing in Xb we can for all s) see that increasing and x(s) to fall. Xb causes the Thus, x(s) is lower economy than the benchmark economy. in the robust To summarize: Proposition 6 Comparing levels of aggregate collateral, Z> we economy and the benchmark economy across two // • When Z < Z, x find: is lower in the robust economy than in the benchmark economy. robustness concerns only arise difference between "risk-aversion" when the aggregate constraint binds. and robustness in our setting. Indeed, this ^ = ZT vjq XT? x+6 *i ant^ s ecI ua l ' n these two cases. ' 29 is an important Comparing across two economies with different degrees of risk aversion yields differences independently of aggregate constraints. 11 different Z, the equilibrium in the robust economy and the benchmark economy are identical. • The equilibria in the robust Numerical example 5.3 Figure The Notes: A B and Collateral Squeeze 1: Xb figure illustrate the equilibrium selection of A (0.25) and X 4- 6 (0.75). Z is on the horizontal for As the axis. Z < Z_. Xb is where in the case last on average /? we = We 2 years. first Z and always falls, lies between robust agents become and therefore increase Xb above A. present a numerical example to quantitatively illustrate the workings of our model We 1. vertical axis financial sector's collateral of increasingly focused on the chance that the other market will receive a shock In this subsection, on the study the fully robust economy. choose A = We choose 5 = 1/2, to imply that recessions 1/4. If recessions occur once every 8 years, this choice of A implies that the two-shock extreme event happens about every 48 years. We normalize choose wq Figure \b begins II = 1. In order to prevent insurance by the agents, we assume = 0.3. 1 illustrates the effect of squeezing the financial sector's collateral With these parameters, to rise above A until Figure 2 illustrates the K effect of that is that wo^p < 1, and 1.8. maximum we discussed at A + 5. We on As. As Z note that this behavior falls is below Z, qualitatively earlier. squeezing the financial sector's collateral on the agents' choice of x/y. For the robust economy, x/y varies over This average behavior of x/y Z_= reaches a it similar to the effect of increasing As the full s. We present the probability-weighted average value of x/y over representative of the behavior of x/y for moderate values of s financial sector's collateral of Z falls, (s < all s. 3 years). robust agents become increasingly focused on the chance that 30 Figure 2: x/y and Collateral Squeeze Benchmark Robust The Notes: Z < Z_. x/y figure contrasts the behavior of is on the vertical Z axis. is x/y between the robust economy and the benchmark economy, over the range on the horizontal probability-weighted average value of x/y over moderate values of s (s < As the 3 years). on the chance that the other market second. Agents in the benchmark the more likely single-shock event. For the robust economy, x/y varies over The average behavior financial sector's collateral of will receive a shock economy account Thus x/y the other market will receive a shock second. Agents in the all s. axis. rises as first, first, of Z recession. When for the fact that collateral Z falls for the earlier, in the robust x is representative of the behavior of x/y for robust agents become increasingly focused is scarce, first or and direct insurance purchases to and insure roughly equally against receiving the shock benchmark economy account for the fact that collateral Z falls for is scarce, and n. When there lower in the robust economy. When constraint imposes that x is the benchmark economy. output responses to a typical single shock one shock during the liquidity episode, output economy than in the benchmark economy. As a there are two shocks, output +y= Z in is or first direct insurance there are no shocks during a liquidity episode, per-capita output in both the is present the benchmark economy. in insurance-portfolios translate into different and robust economy noted falls, is We and insure roughly equally against receiving the shock purchases to the more likely single-shock event. Thus x/y rises as These difference x/y s. simply ^p-. falls result, benchmark to ^j5 output is - As lower However, since the collateral both benchmark and robust economy, the output upon two shocks identical across both economies. 31 is Thus, in terms of output, the benchmark economy does robust economy suffers deeper "typical" recessions, because robust agents two-shock extreme event. This "over-reaction" example, when of GDP An 6 Z is high and close to Z, at more than the benchmark economy. in the robust than in the is 1.7, than the robust economy. The become overly concerned with the more severe when aggregate the robust Instead, economy when Z = 1.2, sees collateral is more binding. For output decline by only one percent the decline is five percent of GDP Extension to Risky Collateral when collateral are amplified as financing conditions tighten, reducing collateral values, is both an input into production as well as security feedbacks emerge between the financial and real side. Negative shocks for financial claims, potentially large and reinforcing the demand for collateral as a productive input, reducing financial tightening. can consider how Kiyotaki and Moore's insight applies within our model by assuming that the eral of the financial sector is (exogenously) risky, but related to the shocks in some understanding gives us more benchmark economy. Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) observe that We strictly better market A collat- and B. This exercise of the effect of collateral risk, without working out a full-blown production model. 6.1 Modeling assumptions The only uncertainty in the economy is number in the of shocks. zero or one, then the total collateral of the financial sector falls to z < Z. This could happen, for example, for collateral assets (such as The If Z, but assume that if if the number of shocks is there are two shocks, then collateral the second shock results in a fall in investment and demand real estate). introduction of risky collateral requires us to rewrite the collateral constraint of insurers: x < Z y < max{z — (32) x, 0}. (33) only one shock hits the economy, insurers have enough collateral to cover up to x financial claims. new constraint is that if The the second shock affects the economy, not only has some of the collateral of insurers been pledged to cover the 7T land or if is We first shock, but also there We also modify our model so that in = 0. When it > 0, agents effectively are is less collateral in total. the event of a liquidity shock, profits drop to "endowed" with 7r 7r > rather than units of first-shock and second-shock claims, so that their decisions are taken net of this n. In particular their decisions over x(s) and y s (t) are as described thus far, less n (or zero, if the net is negative). 32 • We assume that X' Z<n< X + tmn{K,5} Z 6-mm{K,5} ^ Then straightforward to show that for the benchmark case, it is the (low probability) second-shock that agents use probability) first case of the fully robust economy, =Z be K > we 5, still x-fr y to revert to the case where (3 = be = 0. demand second-shock insurance, and in the particular have that, Z =— _, r y 2 6.2 provides sufficient insurance against of their wealth to purchase insurance against the (high all economy continue In contrast, agents in the robust we tt shock: x Finally, - Z =— 2 0. Amplification Since in the benchmark economy, x be =Z agents recognize that the risk in collateral and y be is = 0, collateral risk has no not relevant for their payoffs. The effect events are sufficiently rare that forgoing insurance In the robust economy, both in the robust x and y are economy because when agents if there is amount relevant constraining the financial sector continues to be Z. Of course, by not insuring experiences large ex-post (distributional) utility costs on equilibrium because y, the of collateral benchmark economy a two-shocks event. Nonetheless, these optimal. is The positive. risk in collateral values has a significant impact insure against two shocks, the relevant collateral constraint for the single-shock shift to (33). Offering more y claims requires intermediaries to lock-up collateral. But this reduces the The event amount of liquidity insurance available for x. effective collateral for the robust (z). economy is the amount of collateral in the worst-case, two-shock Relative to the benchmark, insurance against the typical single-shock event falls by at least Z — z, amplifying the flight-to-quality problem we have identified. 6.3 Demand Because in the for Assets and Collateral Premia robust economy agents evaluate insurers based on their collateral levels in the worst-case scenario of two shocks, insurers have an incentive to shore up their worst-case collateral so as to increase their capacity. In a sense, the agents' robustness preferences induces "risk-aversion" in the insurers. contrast, in the benchmark economy the event. While still credibility of the insurer averse to losses, the insurer is is based on his collateral more concerned about moderate 33 losses. in the In one-shock We parameterize this effect by calculating the risk-premia that an insurer amount of the following the occurrence of the of the second shock. We two Arrow-Debreu claims: first The A shock; and (2) A (1) will assign to an infinitesimal claim that delivers an extra unit of collateral on claim that delivers an extra unit of collateral on the occurrence objective probabilities of each of these events are <t>\ and <p2- note that the claims are not typical Arrow-Debreu securities, since the events are not mutually exclusive. The The second shock can occur only once the shock has occurred, first valuations of the two claims are denoted as £i0i and £,24>2, 4>\ > where the intermediaries are willing to pay for claims on first-and second-shock events (i.e. 4>2- £'s are the price premia they are the premia on these claims after accounting for the probability of the events). In the is benchmark economy we have (recall that set P= binding), the extra collateral in the second-shock event On the other hand, the extra collateral in the selling x claims. claims. Thus the We note in the equilibrium price of an x claim In contrast, in the robust first &= o. shock is we have and that is in this case the single shock constraint useless to the insurer so that helpful since it loosens the collateral constraint on constructed, agents pay wq in total to buy Z insurance u/q/Z. Then, is economy the extra collateral in the second-shock event is valuable. Following the same logic to calculate prices in the worst case scenario, the value of an extra unit of collateral Then the collateral-premium assigned to this claim by the insurer /r _ w Z Collateral in the first-shock event subsumed by the is first-shock event However, the probability of the shock is The insurer in the robust 1 economy, because the second-shock event is higher than the probability of the second-shock event, thus, ^^<e Z 2 01 are ordered as follows: &> Proof. Follows directly from is, the extra collateral loosens the constraint in the worst-case scenario). er = Proposition 7 Collateral-premia wq/ z. 4>2 also valuable in the robust (i.e. first is Z> z economy and is (f>\ r t( > e > £r > &= 0. (j>2- most concerned about the worst-case event and the highest collateral-premia for claims that help him shore up the worst-case collateral 34 is willing to level. pay Moreover, > wo/Z, wq/z so that the robust insurer always pays a higher collateral-premium than the - even against insurer This pattern of prices first-shock events. is in keeping with an agent benchmark who more is "risk-averse" against losses. An empirical regularity during flight-to-quality episodes in risk premia. Demand for riskless assets between Commercial Paper and Treasury is money put options on the S&P500 and the rise The spread index, or the VIX phenomena are the financial intermediaries we too stylized to replicate these observed patterns precisely, these have identified are the marginal investors plausibly for safety widens during these episodes. Volatility sensitive Bills typically consistent with increased aversion to the worst-case scenario. broadly demand rise. Although our model If markets, then their risk-valuations affect prices, and in these asset match the observed phenomena. Our model also provides a new perspective on the cyclical indicator property of the Commercial-Paper to Treasury-Bills spread (see e.g., Stock and Wilcox, 1993). In our model the and Watson, 1989, Friedman and Kuttner, 1993, Kashyap, rise in the spread is a symptom Stein, of agents' robustness concerns, as But the robustness concerns trigger actions that lead to opposed to a contributing factor to a recession. underinsurance against the single-shock event, and 7 the increase in such as Treasury Bills or bank deposits increases. financial measures, such as the prices of out-of-the implied volatility index, is may thereby lead to a recession. Final remarks Flight to quality is a pervasive phenomenon that exacerbates the impact of recessionary shocks. In this paper we present a model of this phenomenon based on robust decision making by financial specialists. show that when aggregate intermediation collateral is plentiful, robustness considerations with the functioning of private insurance markets (credit intermediation collateral is scarce, they take a lines). do not We interfere However, when agents think that aggregate set of protective actions to guarantee themselves safety, but which leave the aggregate economy overexposed to recessionary shocks. In this context, a Lender of Last Resort policy events. The main events, which are very benefit of this policy rare, but from is useful if used to support extreme rather than intermediate comes not so much from the direct its effect of the policy ability to unlock private sector collateral during extreme during milder, and far more frequent, contractions. The implications of the framework extend beyond the particular interpretation and policymakers. For example, the policymaker as the IMF in the international context or other IFFs. Then, our we have given one could think of our agents as countries and model prescribes that the IMF not support the country hit by a sudden stop, but to commit to intervene once contagion takes place. 35 to agents The first benefit of this policy comes primarily from the additional availability of private resources to limit the impact of the initial pullback of capital flows. 36 References [1] Barro, R.J., 2005, "Rare Events and the Equity Premium," Mimeo, Harvard University. [2] Bernanke, B., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist, 1999, "The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework," Handbook of Macroeconomics, Taylor and Woodford, eds. [3] [4] Diamond, D.W. and P.H. Dybvig, Political Economy Dow, and J. Portfolio," [5] 1983, J., Liquidity," Journal of 91, pp. 401-419. Werlang, 1992, "Uncertainty Aversion, Risk Aversion, and the Optimal Choice of S. Econometrica 60, p. 197-204. Friedman, B., and Kuttner, K., 1993, Stock, "Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Watson, M. (Eds.), New "Why does the paper-bill spread predict real research in Business Cycles: Indicators economy activity." In: and Forecasting. University of Chicago Press, Chicago. [6] Easley, David and Maureen O'Hara, 2005, "Regulation and Return: The Role of Ambiguity," working paper, Cornell University. [7] Epstein, L., 2001, "Sharing Ambiguity," [8] Epstein, L. and American Economic Review, M. Schneider, 2004, "Recursive Multiple 91(2), 45-50. Priors," Journal of Economic Theory, 113(1), 1-31. [9] Epstein, L. and T. Wang, 1994, "Intertemporal Asset Pricing Under Knightian Uncertainty,' Economet- rica 62, 283-322. [10] Gatev, Evan, and Phil Strahan, 2005, "Banks' Advantage in Hedging Liquidity Risk: Theory and Evidence from the Commercial Paper Market," forthcoming, Journal of Finance. [11] Gilboa, I. and D. Schmeidler, 1989, "Maxmin Expected Mathematical Economics, [12] Utility with Non-unique Priors," Journal of 18, 141-153. Greenspan, A, 2004, "Risk and Uncertainty in Monetary Policy," Remarks for the AEA Meetings, January. [13] Hansen, L. and T. Sargent, 1995, "Discounted Linear Exponential Quadratic Gaussian Control,' IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control 40, 968-971. [14] Hansen, L.P. and T.J. Sargent, 2003, "Robust Control of Forward-looking Models," Journal of Monetary Economics 50(3), 581-604. 37 [15] Hansen, L.P., T.J. Sargent, G.A. Turmuhambetova, N. Williams, 2004, "Robust Control and Model Misspecification," April, [16] Mimeo. Holmstrom, Bengt and Jean Economy, 106(1), 2/98, pp. [17] "Private and Public Supply of Liquidity," Journal of Political Tirole, 1-40. Kashyap, Anil, Jeremy Stein and David Wilcox, "Monetary Policy and Credit Conditions: Evidence from the Composition of External Finance," American Economic Review, 83(1), 3/93, pp 78-98. [18] Kiyotaki, N. and [19] Krishnamurthy, Arvind, 2003, "Collateral Constraints and the Amplification Mechanism," Journal of J. Economic Theory, [20] Moore, 1997: "Credit Cycles," Journal of Political Economy, 105 (2), 211-248. 111(2), 277-292. Krishnamurthy, Arvind, 2002, "The Bond/Old-Bond Spread," Journal of Financial Economics 66(2), 463-506, 2002. W. [21] Kyle, A. and [22] Longstaff, Francis, 2004, Xiong, 2001, "Contagion as a Wealth Effect", Journal of Finance 56, 1401-1440. "The Flight-to-Liquidity Premium in U.S. Treasury Bond Prices," Journal of Business 77(3), 511-526. [23] Routledge, Bryan and Stanley Zin, 2004, "Model Uncertainty and Liquidity," working paper, Carnegie Mellon University. [24] Sims, Christopher A., 2001, "'Pitfalls of a Minimax Approach to Model Uncertainty," working paper, Princeton University. [25] Skiadas, Costis, 2003, "Robust Control and Recursive Utility," Finance and Stochastics [26] Stock, J. and Watson, M., 1989. New 7, 475-489. indexes of coincident and leading economic indicators. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 351-394. [27] Woodford, M., "Public Debt as Private Liquidity," American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 80, May 1990, pp. 382-88. 38 Financial System Risk and Flight to Quality ABSTRACT We present a model of flight to quality episodes that emphasizes financial system risk and the Knightian uncertainty surrounding these episodes. In the model, agents are uncertain about the probability distribution of shocks in markets different from theirs, treating such uncertainty as Knightian. Aversion to this uncertainty generates demand for safe financial claims. capital to cover their It also leads agents to require financial intermediaries to lock-up own markets' shocks in a manner that is robust to uncertainty over other markets. These actions are wasteful in the aggregate and can trigger a financial accelerator. A lender of last resort can unlock private capital markets to economy during JEL these episodes by committing to intervene stabilize the should conditions worsen. Codes: E30, E44, E5, F34, Gl, G21, G22, G28. Keywords: Locked collateral, flight to quality, insurance, risk premia, financial intermediaries, lender of last resort, private sector multiplier, collateral shocks, robust control. '.284 k2 R 2 4 2006 Date Due Lib-26-67 Ml I LIBRARIES 3 9080 026 7 9629