"°°" MIT LIBRARIES MWvUiJrniWl^WFIl 3 9080 02527 9669 ;|lii|!!' /fiitifiiii'tiitiiuitktiitLniiiitkiaditiittiiiiMtMii:' Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/risingwageinequaOOauto ^^l/Vfy HB31 .M415 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series WAGE INEQUALITY: THE ROLE OF COMPOSITION AND PRICES RISING David Autor Lawrence F. Katz Melissa S. Kearney Working Paper 05-22 August 18,2005 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 021 42 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://ssrn.com/abstract=803925 SEP 2 8 2005 LIBRARIES Rising Wage Inequality: The Role of Composition and Prices* David H. Autor MIT and NBER Lawrence F. Katz Harvard University and NBER Melissa The Brookings S. Kearney and Institution NBER August 2005 Revised from December 2004 Abstract During the early 1980s, earnings inequality in the U.S. labor market rose relatively uniformly throughout the wage distribution. But this uniformity gave way to a significant divergence and lower tail (50/10) inequality (1987 to 2003). This paper applies and extends a quantile decomposition technique proposed by Machado and Mata (2005) to evaluate the role of changing labor force composition (in terms of education and experience) and changing starting in 1987, with upper-tail (90/50) inequality rising steadily either flattening or compressing for the next 16 years labor market prices to the expansion and subsequent divergence of upper- and lower-tail We show that the extended Machado-Mata quantile decomposition corrects shortcomings of the original Juhn-Murphy-Pierce (1993) full distribution accounting method and nests the kernel reweighting approach proposed by DiNardo, Fortin and inequality over the last three decades Lemieux (1996). Our analysis reveals that shifts in labor force composition have positively impacted earnings inequality during the 1990s. But these compositional shifts have primarily operated on the lower half of the earnings distribution by muting a contemporaneous, countervailing lower-tail price compression. The steady rise of upper tail inequality since the late 1970s appears almost entirely explained by ongoing between-group price changes (particularly increasing We wage differentials by education) and residual price changes. Chemozhukov. Paul Devereux, Francis Kramarz, Justin McCrary, comments aiid to Michael Anderson and Tal Gross for excellent Autor acknowledges generous support from the National Science Foundation (CAREER SES- are particularly grateful to Josh Angrist, Victor Thomas Lemieux and Derek Neal research assistance. 0239538) and for valuable the Sloan Foundation. Katz acknowledges financial support from the Spencer Foundation. Introduction During the early 1980s, earnings inequality in the U.S. labor market rose relatively uniformly throughout the wage distribution. Between 1979 and 1987, the male 90/50 log hourly earnings ratio rose by 8.5 log points and the 50/10 earnings ratio rose by 13.0 log points (see Figure This simultaneous expansion of upper and lower- tail inequality gave way 1). to a significant divergence thereafter. During each of the two subsequent 8 year intervals, 1987 to 1995 and 1995 to 2003, 90/50 inequality rose by an additional 5.2 and 9.7 log points respectively, while 50/10 inequality contracted to levels roughly comparable to 1979. In fact, fully increase in male 90-10 earnings inequality between 1979 and 2003 the 90-50 wage gap. Residual inequality - that is, wage is 90 percent of the net accounted for by the rise in dispersion within demographic and skill groups defined by sex, education, and experience (age) - followed a roughly similar pattern, rising both (Figure 2).' above and below the median between 1979 and 1987, and then diverging thereafter As discussed in Autor, Katz and Kearney (2005), this divergence in inequality trends presents a puzzle for canonical explanations for rising falling real (often minimum wages, viewed as driven by wage inequality.^ declining unionization, and monotonicaliy rising Skill we demand for 'skill' Biased Technical Change 'SBTC') do not generally predict steadily increasing upper-tail inequality paired with fluctuating lower In this paper, Hypotheses such as tail inequality. explore one potential explanation for the disparate patterns of upper and These figures describe hourly wages for all male wage and salary workers from the merged monthly Outgoing Group (ORG) files of the Current Population Survey (CPS) for years 1979 to 2003. Similar calculations Rotation performed using the March CPS reveal comparable results (also shown in Figure ). Appendix Table 1 demonstrates qualitatively similar patterns for full-time workers in March and ORG samples. Details of all samples and calculations are found in the Data Appendix. 1 The overall rise in the variance of male log hourly wages in the May/ORG CPS was 7.3 log points between 1979 and 1988 and 2.3 log points between 1988 and 2003, Estimated using a flexible Mincerian wage regression (see equation (1 )). the residual component of this rise was 2.8 log points between 1979 and 1988 and 0.2 log points between 1988 ^ and 2003. The very modest rise in inequality in the May/ORG CPS after 1988 is at odds with the March CPS data, which show an overall rise of log wage inequality of 6.1 log points between 1979 and 1988 and 6.1 log points between 1988 and 2003. The contribution of the residual to this rise is also substantial in both periods: 3.1 log points between 1979 and 1988 and 3.2 log points beUveen 1988 and 2003. In section V, we analyze the discrepancies between the May/ORG and March data. All analyses in the paper are performed using both samples. '' The differences in the growth of the 90-50 and 50-10 wage differentials have previously been emphasized by Mishel, Bernstein and Boushey (2002). lower-tail inequality observed in the last two decades: the changing age and educational composition of the U.S. labor force. As shown in Figure 3, the education and experience of the U.S. labor force rose substantially over the last 25 years as the large 1970s college cohorts reached mid-career during the 1990s. The full-time equivalent employment share of male workers with a college degree rose from 18 to 32 percent of the U.S. male labor force between 1973 and 2003 and the employment share of workers with high school or lower education 41 percent. Gains in potential experience were similarly pronounced: the mean fell from 62 to potential experience of males of high school or greater education rose by 2 to 5 years between 1973 and 2003, with the largest gains experienced by the most educated groups.'' Increases potential experience These large among female workers were behavior of upper and lower tail inequality. As to contribute to the divergent highlighted in an insightful paper by Lemieux (2005), the canonical Mincer (1974) earnings model implies may education and similarly large. composition have the potential shifts in labor force in Thomas that earnings trajectories tend to fan out (become more dispersed) as workers gain labor market experience (see also Heckman, Lochner and Todd 2003). And hourly wage dispersion graduates than for less-educated workers. Consequently, changes or experience of the labor force may give rise to changes in is typically higher for college in the distribution of education earnings dispersion. These compositional effects are distinct from the standard price effects that are often invoked to explain fluctuations in earnings inequality. Holding market prices constant, changes in labor force composition can mechanically raise or lower residual earnings dispersion simply by changing the employment share of worker groups in have more or less dispersed earnings. Similar!},', changes workforce composition can also raise or lower overall earnings dispersion by increasing or reducing heterogeneity Juhn, * that Murphy and The average in observed tlie (education and experience), a point emphasized by Pierce (1993). These observations suggest that measured earnings dispersion potential experience decline reflects skills of male high school dropouts actually fell by 2.6 yeai^ during 1973 to 2003. This in the "dropout" group as adult educational attainment has increased share of employed teenagers risen (as our sample covers ages 16 to 64 years). An influx of younger, less educated immigrants has also contributed. may change due to the mechanical impact of composition without any underlying change market prices.^ - Building on this observation, Lemieux (2005) argues that the bulk of the growth wage - and dispersion in the U.S. between 1973 and 2003 explained by mechanical effects of changes in Lemieux concludes these compositional effects, inequality in the U.S. labor market — is of the growth al] after workforce composition rather than residual inequality within defined skill groups (what 1980s in we call price effects). in residual 1988 - is shifts in After adjusting for that the widely discussed rise in residual earnings primarily attributable to institutional factors during the in particular, the declining real minimum wage - and to the mechanical effect of composition during the 1990s. In this paper, we consider the Lemieux composition hypothesis in an analysis of the divergent trends in the upper and lower tails of the aggregate and residual Our work three decades. First, in differs from Lemieux's analysis keeping with our focus on trends in in distribution. Second, we in wage distributions over the last two key substantive dimensions. upper and lower analyze the contribution of composition to changes median of the in wage tail inequality, we separately inequality above and below the assess the contribution of compositional shifts to changes both overall and residual inequality since composition may impact wage dispersion through either channel. To perform the analysis, we by Machado and Mata (2005). ' * apply and extend a quantile decomposition technique proposed This decomposition uses quantile regressions to partition the Labor force composition will also affect wage dispersion though general equilibrium effects of quantities on prices. focus here on the partial equilibrium effects and discuss general equilibrium considerations later in the paper. We ^ By Murphy, and Pierce (1993) find that the contribution of labor force composition to overall male weekly earnings inequality growth over 1964 to 1988 is negligible. They do not consider- and their contrast. Juhn, full-time decomposition method does not readily admit -an effect of composition on residual inequality. ' This contrasts to Lemieux's focus on the overall dispersion of wage residuals, measured by the variance or the 90/10 ratio ' of log wage residuals. We also discuss results for these The simple extension of the Machado-Mata method independently developed by Melly (forthcoming), growth over 1973 dirough 1989. Because the measures below. to residual inequality who proposed and implemented here applies this tool to analyzing sources of US Melly analysis only extends to wage is inequality 1989 and does not distinguish between observed distribution of earnings into 'price' components (wage coefficients) and 'quantity' components (labor force composition) and changes wage in overall dispersion. We calculate, through simulation, the impact implement this of each on decomposition using representative earnings data from the Current Population Survey (CPS). Samples include hourly earnings data from the May CPS and Outgoing Rotation Groups (May /ORG) for weekly earnings data from the March CPS Annual Earnings Files 1973 to 2003 and hourly and 1976 to 2004 (earnings for years 1975 to 2003). The Machado-Mata method for calculating counterfactual densities kernel reweighting approach proposed by DiNardo, Fortin and and extended by Lemieux (2002, 2005). attractive. First, it It Murphy and analyzing inequality introduced by Juhn, kernel reweighting proposed by Lemieux (1996; 'DFL' has two features that provides a precise link between the 'full we believe ' JMP' DFL. As we show below, both can be (as we do inequality and residual inequality. wage counterfactual it particularly hereafter) and the interpreted as applications to the analysis distributions rather than (exclusively) conditional means. Second, the can be readily extended make hereafter) variance accounting' technique for Pierce (1993; of the canonical Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition, extended closely related to the is of conditional fiill Machado-Mata approach here) to provide a uniform, consistent treatment of both overall By comparison, alternative approaches for analyzing distributions apply a hybridized set of methods and conceptual models (OLS regressions, parametric probability models, and kernel reweighting) to separately develop counterfactuals for overall and residual inequality. Our main results are as follows. We find that changes in labor force composition do not contribute to an explanation for the diverging path of upper and lower aggregate or residual) First, we show trends in in the past that the upper and lower-tail inequality, inequality (either two decades. The composition hypothesis impact of changes (though similar to Lemieux 2005). tail its in labor force composition on fails for wage two reasons. dispersion occurs substantive conclusions are almost entirely different from tliose here almost entirely below the median of the earnings distribution sample period This in turn 1980s and 1990s due Second, in the is we show changing labor market prices not mechanical effects of composition. to is , slightly by tail shifts in of rising and then stagnating or falling lower made more puzzling by adjustments actually the 1980s, increasing lower augmented On net, inequality During for composition. composition. In the 1990s, by contrast, changing market prices by compositional inequality to increase). tail inequality appears explained by changing labor market prices, generated considerable compression in lower substantial part offset the lower tail) during the implies that the steady growth of upper-tail inequality during the that the puzzle 1980s and 1990s (i.e., in we shifts tail inequality, but these price effects were in (which would otherwise have caused lower tail find that changes in the education and experience composition of the labor force plays only a secondary role in the evolution of overall and residual inequality since the early 1970s; the persistent rise of upper-tail inequality and the rise and then stagnation of lower-tail inequality are both primarily accounted for by changing labor market prices. These results lead us to differ from the interpretations offered by Lemieux (2005). Lemieux's conclusion that the rising education and experience of the labor force can mechanically explain the plateauing of residual inequality during the 1990s appears to aggregate over countervailing forces. The due to first is compressing residual rise in upper-tail inequality, two the contraction in lower-tail inequality in the 1990s, 'prices' partially offset which by changing composition. The second which appears entirely explained by price changes. composition over-explains the former phenomenon and under-explains the is is the Because latter, it is technically accurate to say that composition can "fully explain" the aggregate trend in residual inequality during the 1990s. But when upper and lower-tail inequality are considered separately appropriate given their substantial divergence explanation for either. and lower tail We - composition does - as seems not appear a satisfying discuss possible alternative explanations for the divergence of upper inequality in the conclusion (also see Autor, Katz and Kearney 2005). In the next section, we summarize trends in U.S. overall and residual earnings inequality for 1973 to 2003. In section counterfactua! wage II, we develop distributions distributions. Sections III the Machado and Mata methodology and discuss our extension A. March and May/ORG CPS Data sources and basic trends I. it for analysis and IV present our decomposition of trends inequality into price and quantity components. Section inequality trends between to V in for forming of residual wage aggregate and residual analyzes discrepancies in residual data sources. Section VI concludes. in overall and residual inequality March and May/ORG Current Population Survey data Our analysis draws on two data sources CPS and the for measuring trends been widely used in studies year's annual earnings, to inequality: the March Data Appendix. The March weeks worked, and hours worked per week. salary workers. CPS data have of wage inequality and provide reasonably comparable data on prior 2004, covering earnings from 1975 wage and wage combined CPS May and Outgoing Rotation Group. These sources are described briefly here, with additional details provided in the 1976 in Hourly earnings to We use the March CPS of 2003, to form a sample of real log hourly wages of in the March data are calculated as the ratio of prior year's annual earnings to prior year's annual hours. We complement the March series using the Outgoing Rotation Group samples wage data for all wage and for May CPS for 1973 through 1978 and 1979 through 2003 (CPS salary workers May/ORG) to in the March CPS, provide point-in-time measures of usual hourly or weekly earnings. We the May/ORG data weight both March and data by hours worked to provide a measure of the entire distribution of hours paid.'" Both March and period studied. ' construct hourly employed during the CPS sample survey reference week. Unlike the retrospective annual earnings data May/ORG CPS As May/ORG CPS surveys have features that limit their consistency over the price and earnings levels have changed, each survey has applied successive Prior to the 1976 survey, usual hours worked per week in the earnings year are not available. The March data are weighted by the product of weeks worked and hours per week in the prior \ ear. The May/ORG data are weighted by hours worked during tlie survey reference week. Weighting by weeks is implicit in the May/ORG sample since the probability that an individual is obser\'ed working during tlie sample reference week is proportional to '" weeks in the labor force. increases to the maximum top-coded issue for our analysis since A potentially more earnings values. These changes probably present a minor we focus on significant issue earnings quantiles between the lO"' and 90"' percentiles." is posed by the redesign of the CPS ORG survey 1994. in This redesign changed the format of most survey questions, centralized the interviewing process and introduced the use of Computer Assisted Personal Interviewing (CAPI). Perhaps most important, the 1994 redesign revised the procedure used to collect earnings and hours information with the goal of increasing the accuracy of earnings reports and reducing the undercount of workers with part-time schedules (Polivka and Rothgreb 1993; Cohany, Polivka and Rothgreb 1994). Prior to 1994, CPS May /ORG earnings to the survey taker. respondents directly reported their usual weekly and hourly Commencing with the 1994 redesign, respondents were allowed select a preferred pay frequency for earnings reporting (hourly, weekly, biweekly, monthly) to report the corresponding earnings of the revised procedure on the (see Polivka 2000), but seems plausible its that the effect and amount. Using the respondent's self-reported usual hours, the surveyor calculates an implied hourly effect to wage and level verifies the figure with the respondent.'" The of reported hourly wages has received careful study on the precision of earnings reports has not been explored. enhanced procedure raised the precision of earnings reports It (as designed) and so may have reduced measured earnings dispersion. Adding ('flag') to the uncertainty surrounding the imputed earnings observations in the first January 1994 to August 1995. Consequently, observations, although May/ORG the we exclude imputed we redesign, the CPS ORG did not identify 21 months following the survey redesign of are unable to exclude these earnings observations from all imputed other March and samples. Earnings imputations are potentially a non-trivial issue: the imputation rate CPS ORG One CPS rose substantially after the redesign, from 15.3 percent in 1993 to 23.3 percent in topcoded value for secondary wage and salary earnings in the March CPS fell to $37K in 2004). This does not appear a major issue since fewer than 1 percent of workers have top-coded secondary wage/salary earnings at the lower topcode value. unfortunate exception from $99K '" to S25K For respondents in who is that the 1996 (before rising report that they are paid hourly, the self-reported calculations, regardless of the preferred reporting interval. wage is always used without fijrther in the last quarter of 1995 (the rise thereafter, reaching 3 first quarter in which allocation flags are available) and continued to percent by 2001 (Hirsch and Schumacher 2004). Since the redesign 1 coincides with a sizable and sustained rise in the identification the earnings iinputation rate and a 21 in of imputed observations, particularly difficult to it is gauge how the survey affected the comparability of the earnings series before and after 1994. A final issue affecting the consistency of the earnings reports composition of pay reporting seen in the May/ORG samples. is month hiatus changes to ''' a secular change in the As documented by Hamermesh (2002), the share of workers who forward, and this increase found within education and experience groups (Lemieux 2005). This is report being paid by the hour increased substantially from 1973 May/ORG CPS matters for inequality measurement because direct hourly earnings reports in the appear to have greater precision than non-hourly wage reports earnings to hours). Rising hourly pay reporting residual variation in the May/ORG may inequality series. earnings measure (total annual earnings) for all tend to (i.e., mask any underlying The March survey uses an hourly workers March CPS in the in to overstate the growth in essential trade-off between the is March-May/ORG samples greater for hourly than for non- wage inequality in a period of an further explore these issues in Section V. March and May/ORG wage data is one of temporal consistency versus point-in-time precision. The data collection procedures in the more major '^ stable since the mid-1970s, CPS ORG due to the shift Earnings imputations are not an issue confined to 1 1.8 percent in calendar year 1 tlie percent sizable and discontinuous than the increase in the 1 from May to monthly ORG March samples data are in 1979, the redesign in 1994, and the changing frequency of hourly pay reporting. But. as sample rose during the same period from of 1995 (and 22. identical implies the rise in hourly pay reporting could lead the residual (hourly) We increased share of hourly workers. The computed hourly wages March sample. This ('true') rise in respondents regardless of the pay period. Nevertheless, Lemieux (2005) presents evidence using matched suggesting that measurement error those calculated as the ratio of 996). May/ORG CPS. The in 1993 to 13.5 earnings iinputation rate in the percent CPS May/ORG from in March 1996, This increase appears less 15.3 in 1993 to 23.3 percent in the last quarter stressed by Lemieux (2005), the May/ORG, measure at each point in time. We is likely to provide a May/ORG use both March and more precise hourly earnings series throughout and compare the sensitivity of our results to the choice of sample. B. Trends in overall inequality Table 1 presents several 1973 to 2003 from the summary measures of trends CPS March and May/ORG in hourly earnings inequality for years samples (plotted Figure in Overall male I). hourly 90/10 earnings inequality rose by 30.2 log points between 1973 and 2003 May/ORG. Twenty-one 9.1 log points this period. in the CPS log points of this rise occurred between 1973 and 1988 and an additional between 1988 and 2003. Earnings inequality did not grow uniformly throughout Between 1973 and 1988, the growth in upper and lower-tail inequality approximately symmetric above and below the median; after 1988, May/ORG the upper-tail. In fact, the inequality between data show a 4.7 it was . of the overall expansion of the male 90/10 log earnings Subsequent rows of Table earnings samples from the 1 confinn entirely concentrated in log point compression in lower-tail 988 and 2003 Rising upper- tail inequality accounts 1 for over three-quarters between 1973 and 2003. ratio that these patterns are also evident for March CPS. As is was the case with the CPS May/ORG, male hourly lower-tail inequality rises sharply from 1979 to 1988 then halts or reverses thereafter. Upper-tail inequality grows steadily throughout, ultimately accounting growth from 1975 tail to 2003. inequality appears far Figure 1). Whereas indicate almost no the One discrepancy between more pronounced May/ORG data The in show the the data series May/ORG lower-tail rise in inequality is in that the plateau of lower- after 1988, the March an important issue to which May/ORG versus March is somewhat data we sainples. also evident for females (lower panel female 50/10 earnings inequality however, and roughly half of the overall growth is in the is than March samples (see also compression where we consider potential biases The asymmetric growth of earnings 1). over three-quarters of total male inequality movement between 1988 and 2003. This return in Section V, Table for of larger than for males, female inequality occurs in the lower tail As (relative to two-thirds for males). compression of lower Whereas female March March hourly data show inequality for females after 1988 than series indicates a continued rise May/ORG do the CPS lower-tail inequality ceased rising after 1988 in the much slower pace C. tail the case for males, the is CPS May/ORG less data. data, the of lower-tail inequality during the 1990s, though at a than during 1975 to 1988. Trends in residual inequality To measure trends in residual earnings inequality, we fit the following earnings model separately by sample, year and gender: In w, (1 =a In this equation, -(- vv, 5, is X, -I- + (5, xxj + e^. the log hourly or weekly wage of individual /, is 5, a vector of five schooling completion categories corresponding to less than high school, high school graduate, some college, bachelor's degree, and post-college schooling, experience categories ranging from The inclusion of a complete set to 38 years in their hourly data, pay on an hourly we of interaction terms also include a basis, as well as a set schooling dummies. Changes measured residual affect partial adjustment for in the ( 5, '^ In a wage x ''' x, ) is an error term. equation (1) to the is fit variable equal to one for workers of interactions between this pay control dummy in the in and the May/ORG CPS may equation (1) pennits inequality increased sharply in the 1980s for in men and women regardless of equation (1) with a more conventional interaction temis are replaced with a quartic in potential experience interacted with four education groups (high school dropout, high school graduate, components The report and Figure 2 display the residual wage inequality series by which the 65 education-by-potential-experience college or greater). who subsequent variance decomposition. subsequent section, we re-estimate the residual inequality model specification in e, schooling and experience frequency of hourly pay reporting this factor in the 1 among When inequality. Inclusion of the hourly The right-hand panel of Table sex. Residual dummy a vector of thirteen potential 3-year increments, and categories allows for a very flexible earnings equation. May/ORG is .t, results for trends in residual inequality and its decomposition into "price" some college, and 'quantity' are essentially identical. 10 the wage measures March CPS in the or sample used. Residual shows but little change wage in the inequality began rising in the 1970s for males 1970s for males Consistent with the trends for overall inequality, trends parallel in the upper and lower rose sharply prior to 1 tails 988 and slowed or declined series, there is in residual thereafter. in the Upper move tail in inequality inequality rose steadily tail a parallel rise in upper-tail inequality from the CPS In the mid-1970s forward. This upward trend its CPS.'^ inequality did not March CPS samples. over 1994 to 1999 and then resumes rise plateaus or reverses May/ORG of the earnings distribution. Residual lower from the mid-1970s forward for males and females May/ORG in the in 1999 to 2003. Tables 2 and 3 present the evolution of earnings inequality within narrow gender, education and experience groups. high school degrees We tabulate inequality metrics at potential for those with exactly college and exactly experience levels of 5, 10, 15 and 25 years. Because these groups are (a subset of) the gender-education-experience categories directly controlled (with in dummies) our 'residualizing' specification above, inequality within these cells corresponds precisely to We the residual inequality construct used throughout our analysis. '^ period of 1975 to 2003 when both data series are available. We point to enhance precision (hence comparisons are centered on Tables 2 and 3 reveal that the trends shown in example, Table in 1 in limit the comparison pool three years of data 1 976, 1 each 988 and 2002). aggregate lower and upper-tail res idual inequality are robustly visible within detailed gender-experience-education cells. CPS May/ORG and March at to the series, upper-tail inequality rises markedly For for both genders and within most education and experience groups during both halves of the sample (the one exception being female high school graduates). The data also confirm noticeable compression (or plateauing) of lower- tail inequality within detailed gender, education and experience groups. This compression '"^ Our inability to remove allocated observations from the likely accounts for the visible Standard errors upward jump in these tables are in residual May/ORG in much more pronounced January 1994 through August 1995 inequality in 1994 followed by a downward jump bootstrapped using 100 sample-weighted replications for each Tables 2a and 2b present the levels (rather than the changes) e.xperience cells and sample is shows higher wage dispersion for in these inequality in statistic. 1996. Appendi.x measures for narrow gender-education- more experienced and educated groups. 11 among less-educated workers; in fact, the 50/10 earnings ratio widened in the latter half among of the sample, though less rapidly than in the earlier These detailed comparisons underscore several substantive points because the education rise in upper-tail residual inequality is cells, it for our analysis. First, evident within detailed gender-experience- this rise is not likely to be a survey design artifact since data sources. Third, the fact that the compression of lower-tail inequality among high for our decade. cannot be ascribed exclusively (or even primarily) to changing labor force composition. Second, all college males and females is it is confirmed by concentrated school graduates and high school dropouts (not shown) has an important implication subsequent decomposition exercise: the roles attributed depend sensitively on the weight given to less educated to prices and quantities will and experienced groups (which experienced more compression) versus more educated and experienced groups (which experienced more expansion). This observation is especially important because, as above, the experience and education of the U.S. labor force rose substantially after 1980. Consequently, demographic groups increasingly uncommon greater expansion. II. that experienced the as the most residual compression after 1980 become sample progresses, and vice-versa for groups We explore these points in that experienced our decomposition. Labor force composition and wage inequality: A quantile decomposition To evaluate the contributions of changing labor market prices and quantities to the shifts overall and residual inequality documented in Tables 1 through 3, decomposition technique proposed by Machado and Mata (2005, we apply and extend 'MM' hereafter). The in a quantile MM technique uses quantile regressions to partition the observed distribution of earnings into "price" components (wage coefficients) and "quantity' components (labor force composition) and calculate, through simulation, the impact of each on changes in aggregate A. wage dispersion. Theory Let Qg{w\x) for 6*6(0,1) denote the 0''' quantile of the distribution of the log wage (ir) 12 We model these conditional quantiles as given the vector x of covariates. 0,(w\x) = (2) where x (QR) is x'/3(d), a k-<\ vector of covariates coefficients. e For given (0, 1) and /?(i9) is a conformable vector of quantile regression /3{0) can be estimated by , minimizing in /^ n ;7-';^/7,(w, -x;/?) with (3) i=i ' where the for !/ [(d-\)u for M<0 expression latter > idii is referred to as the 'check function' (see Koenker and Bassett 1978, Buchinsky 1994, Koenker and Hallock 2001, and Angrist, Chemozhukov and Femandez-Val forthcoming). As discussed by Machado and Mata, quantile process - that is, Qgiw\x) if equation (2) is conectly specified, the conditional as a function of 6'e(0,l) the conditional distribution of wages given x . - provides a In this case, realizations of full m', characterization of given x^ viewed as independent draws from the function x\P{6) where the random variable uniformly distributed on the open interval (0,1) in a . The conditional quantile model is will hold exactly case where both location and scale depend linearly on the covariates (for example classical location shift model cases, the conditional quantile w = x' p + s where ^ model may provide is a normal, iid error tenn). In a reasonable approximation can be in the more general to the true conditional quantile, and this approximation can generally be improved by specifying flexible functions of x quantile model Having fit when estimating P{6) to the observed data is . We show below that, in our application, the fit of the quite accurate. the conditional quantile function, the estimated parameters can be used to simulate the conditional distribution of transformation: If ^ is u' a unifonn given x via an application of the probabilify integral random variable on [0,1] , then F~'{U) has the density F . 13 Thus, if 6^,6,, ...,0 are drawn from a uniform of the conditional quantiles of wages at x, (0,1) distribution, the w, , = {^'A^, (estimated) conditional distribution of wages given )},''=i corresponding j estimates constitute a . random sample from the x, This simulation procedure characterizes the conditional quantiles of the data for any given x It does not provide the marginal density of both the conditional quantile function, generate a for each m;^ = /?( 6*) w , . This is because the marginal density depends upon and the distribution of the covariates, g{x) random sample from marginal density of w we can draw rows of data from gi^ , row x, x,/?'(^, ) ' , draw a random which procedure repeatedly, is 6^ from the uniform (0,1) distribution. We then .''' we ) and, form draw from the wage density implied by the model. By applying a To this can draw an arbitrarily large random sample from the desired distribution. This procedure - successively drawing from g{x) and 6 to form w - is equivalent to numerically integrating the estimated conditional quantile function ^^(m'I x) over the distribution of X and 6 to form f(\v)= \\Qg{M>\x)g{x)dxd0 .^^ x,e For the purposes of decomposition, the conditional quantile MM procedure has two attractive properties. model conveniently divides 'quantity' components.' This is the observed By contrast, the conditional quantile this case, the "For '* '" OLS As with We all is mean model only characterizes we treat g.i- ) model characterizes both througliout as uniformly distributed on tlie OLS the central function, describing 'between-group" inequality)- the central tendency of the data (in median) and the dispersion of the outcome variable conditional on x, simplicity, Because 9 set. the conditional (i.e., distribution into 'price" and similar to a standard Oaxaca-Blinder procedure using regression coefficients, with the key difference that the tendency of the data wage First, the i.e., the wage known. unit interval, measures of 'residual' inequality, /(d) - this division 1 . depends upon which .v'^are included in tlie conditioning return to this point below. 14 'residuals.' residual This feature wage is impact of composition on the shape of the critical for estimating the distribution. Second, under the convenient (but economically unappealing) that aggregate quantities of skills in the labor market do not affect partial equilibrium assumption skill prices, we can use the conditional quantile model to simulate the impact of changing composition or prices on distribution of wages."" In particular, by applying the labor force composition data g, given time period / to the price matrix P^{6) from any other time period r , we can (,v) from a simulate the counterfactual distribution of wages that would prevail if labor force composition were given as time period in / and labor market prices were given as li,{9) matrix describes the conditional distribution in time period r Note that because the . of wages for given values of x , this simulation captures the effects of composition on both between-group and residual inequality. Although the Machado-Mata approach was not specifically developed counterfactual measures of residual inequality, the coefficient vector y9(50) as our /? = /?(50) . /? y^i-,^ can be extended to y5,„j in conditional is Following this logic, we is . In their analysis it as it In our application, the central . The difference between not empirically important in our application. define a measure of within-group inequality as the difference between the estimated coefficient vector /][&) and the median coefficient vector "" refer to provides a measure of between-group inequality because the conditional median, estimated by /] means and medians We define a conventional Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition. In estimates the central tendency of the data conditional on x tendency measure this application. measure of between-group inequality, and we serves a role akin to the conventional application, it for estimating of tlie contributions of price and quantities to /?* nsing inequality during the 1980s, DiNardo, Fortin and Leniieux (1996) perform supply and demand adjustments for obsen'ed wages by education by experience cells (in addition to applying a kernel reweighting procedure). These supply-demand adjustments are shown by DFL to be quantitatively important, explaining 21 to 33 percent of the growth in male 90/10 log hourly earnings inequality between 1979 and 1988 (Tables 111 and V). This indicates that the independence assumption supplies do not affect skill prices) is likely to be far from innocuous. (i.e., that aggregate skill 15 r{9)^[m-p']ioreem). (4) Notice by construction, p" (50) = that, . Hence, the residual quantile coefficient matrix w purged of 'between-group' inequality, and measures the expected dispersion of value of -V holding the conditional median , distribution of covariates, g(x) , we can is If, for example, p{0) = the (correctly specified) conditional quantile characterization of the distribution of m' as a function covariates, g(x), the vector of between-group prices, (residual) prices (9 that to the is then residual , P" We write /(w,) . model provides a complete of three components: the distribution of /?'', and the matrix of within-group = fisX^XP^'k)- Implementation and proof of concept We steps. implement the augmented Machado and Mata quantile decomposition procedure We first May/MORG models and March samples we estimate a wage model equivalent OLS model fit for the median (quantile 'prices" for our simulation exercise. Here, coefficients, m is In the P, ,a the where k the 50.0). P(d) step, we These a is in kxm we . fit estimate centile, with P(d) above, one provide the matrix of quantile regression the intercept in equation (1)) in x 0. calculate the residual price vector vector of between-group prices, and P" of a QR coefficients, number of elements (65 including number of quantiles (501) estimated second kx\ is to equation (1) regressions. For each sample, year, and gender, for quantiles [0.1, 0.3, ...,99.7, 99.9] at intervals of one-fifth additional in three estimate quantile coefficient vectors for each time period and gender. Using the using quantile rather than and P V vi' /?" zero in this model. To summarize, B. any given applying the coefficient matrix calculate the (estimated) dispersion of exclusively attributable to residual inequality. inequality By at zero. at is P" using equation ,akx (m - 1) (4). This >-ields matrix of within-group prices. 16 In the final step, the price matrices Under we draw simulated P'^ data from the distribution /(g,(x), /?,'',/?,") by applying to g,(x).^' ,13" the maintained assumption that labor market prices and quantities can be treated as independent, this procedure may be used to simulate any counterfactuai distribution of overall or residual earnings inequality simply by pairing the quantity series from one time period with the price series (overall and/or residual) Before applying this g, (x) we technique to simulate counterfactuai distributions, performance of the model inequality. from another. in replicating first check the observed ( actual ) distributions of overall and residual To benchmark the model, we apply QR the coefficients /?,'',/?," to the quantity series, from the contemporaneous time period to generate simulated wage distributions. The simulated series are shown in Appendix Figure conditional wage distributions, these series between the actual statistic 1 . If the QR model were a perfect would exactly overlap. and the model-based simulations is fit to the In practice, the discrepancy small enough to be almost undetectable. Other distributional statistics for the simulated data, such as the 90/50, 50/1 0, and variance of wages, are also extremely close to the corresponding values for the source data. To benchmark the performance of our simulation procedure for residual compare simulated and Figure 2. The actual 90/10 residual series labeled wage wage inequalit>', dispersion by year and gender in 'Observed Median Reg Residual' is we Appendix formed from median regressions of log hourly earnings on the covariates above. The series 'Simulated Median Reg Residual' presents the corresponding statistics for the simulated series formed using simulated residual series also fit the finer gl^ ) ) with replacement. this means CPS An analysis by Angrist. that our simulated data set data (500 times larger, to be exact). Angrist, Autor and and coarser bandwidths verisimilitude in gi. finds that greater precision can be obtained simply by multiplying the endre by the transposed P(d) coefficient matrix. In practice, the original and g,{^) The observed data quite accurately. ' Machado and Mata recommend drawing rows from Chemozhukov (2004) /?," for the quantile estimation is gi many Autor and ) distribution times larger than Chemozhukov (2004) experiment with and find that 500 quantile intervals provides excellent samples, while finer bandwidths produces little marginal gain. using Since almost for all prior residual decompositions analyze comparison the 90/10 residual inequality visible in Appendix Figure 2, OLS OLS regression residuals, series for an identically specified also plot model. As is and Median Regression residuals have nearly identical dispersion in our application, indicating that the distinction between is OLS we mean and median regression not substantively import for interpreting our residual decomposition results. These benchmarks provide assurance that our approach We next apply this we able to capture relevant features of earnings distributions. We decomposition to the inequality data. quantile regression version of the Subsequently, is first propose and implement a well-known Juhn, Murphy and Pierce (1993) decomposition. use the quantile model to implement a variant of the extended DiNardo, Fortin and Lemieux (1996) kernel density reweighting approach. As we show below, these two approaches are nested in the quantile model. The contributions of between-group III. composition: As we implement "JMP") decomposition. In a quantile analog of the well Appendix 2, we write the observed distribution of wages at time distribution of worker characteristics, g, (x) , t fi, in inequalit}' components using / Murphy and Pierce decomposition. As before, we components: the the between-group prices for those characteristics, /?/' (suppressing "hats" on the and r . between any two periods, t and r can be decomposed the following sequential decomposition. Let AOg = Qg(f,{w)) — Og(f,{'^^')) periods Juhn, vectors). The observed change into three JMP as a function of three and the within-group prices for those characteristics, estimated known provide a more thorough discussion of the differences between our quantile approach and the canonical /?*, and decomposition a compact method of summarizing the contributions of prices and quantities to rising earnings inequality, (1993, prices, residual prices, A quantile JMP equal the observed change in the d" wage quantile between We define 18 Ao; = (5) a(/(.?.(^-), as the contribution of Ao: = (6) ^Q: = a ifigr i^i Pi a ifig, (-V), as the marginal contribution Notice that This is this A" ))-&,(/(§,(>••), A'- A")) changing quantities (labor force composition) as the marginal contribution (7) /?;, ^ to AO^ . We define p: ) - Qe ifisr i^\ p" ^pn of changing between-group prices p: p: ) . a (/(§, c^-). an important advantage over the total . finally define - to AOy . observed change: AC'p + AC>* + JMP procedure, component' must be estimated as a remainder term AO^ And, we a: p: ) of changing within-group prices decomposition sums to the to in AOJ = Ag^ which the 'residual price and quantity after the other two components are calculated.^' As is well known, the order of a sequential decomposition implicitly corresponds to a set of weights reflecting which characteristics are held components (A()J, AC*^, are changed, with the share of at their start or end period values as other any observed change attributed to each component AOJ) depending on which other components decomposition above using two orderings. In the first, we are varied first first. A. between-group prices and Quantile perform the vary labor force characteristics, then between-group prices and finally within-group prices. In the second, prices, then We we vary within-group finally labor force composition. JMP i^esults Table 4 presents results of the quantile inequality data. As shown between 1973 and 1988 is in the upper left JMP decomposition for the CPS May/ORG hourly panel of the table, the rise of male earnings dispersion almost entirely accounted for by prices rather than quantities. Of 21.1 log points rise in male 90/10 inequality over this period, the decomposition attributes a small offsetting roll (-1.0 log points) to quantities, versus 16.8 points to "" The .IMP decomposition - that is, 5.3 "add up" unless the conditional distribution of residuals is homoskedastic depend on the x 's. As Tables 2 and 3 demonstrate, this assumption is amply will not generally residual dispersion does not rejected by the data. See between-group prices and Appendix 2 for discussion. 19 When we points to within-group prices.'^ reverse the order of the decomposition, estimated contribution of labor force composition to inequality is in the rise patterns prevail when upper and lower tail B for females also finds a of earnings inequality. But than for males and also more pronounced in the lower tail inequality are find that the within rounding error of zero, with only a slightly larger role attributed to within-group prices." Panel comparatively small role for composition we this role is larger of the earnings distribution. Similar decomposed separately: composition never explains more than a third of the growth of any 90/50 or 50/10 inequality metric during 1973 to 1988; the remainder When we perform this is explained by prices." decomposition for the growth of inequality between 1988 and 2003, an important contrast with the earlier period emerges. Both prices and composition play an economically significant role in explaining changes in lower-tail earnings inequality after 1988. Male 50/10 inequality contracted by the change in composition alone 4.8 log points during 1988 to 2003. Holding prices constant, would have been expected 4.3 log points, reflecting, as noted to increase lower tail inequality by by Lemieux (2005), the increasing education and experience of the labor force. Offsetting this force, between and within-group price changes reduced lower-tail inequality by -1.2 and -7.9 log points respectively during the same interval. On net, the 4.8 log points of observed lower-tail compression reflects the countervailing impacts of 'falling' prices and an increase in the prevalence of characteristics associated with higher earnings dispersion. But these discrepant forces are not responsible ^' Small discrepancies between the tabulated changes 4 and 5 reflect simulation error, that distribution. make These discrepancies is, instances for trends in in overall inequality in where are quite small (never upper Table 1 tail inequality. In fact, the and the changes shown in Tables the quantile simulation does not perfectly capture the obser\'ed more than 5 percent of the observed change) and we do not further adjustments for them. ^' Note that when we decompose the change in inequality subcomponents of tlie quantile decomposition do not sum 1973 to 2003 period (third panel of Tables 4). the subcomponents of tlie decomposition for the subperiods 1973 to 1988 and 1988 to 2003. This is because the implicit decomposition weights differ between panels. In the final panel, we apply 1973 quantities to 2003 prices and vice versa; in the prior two panels, the dates for the quantities and prices do not differ by more than 15 years (i.e., 1973 vs. 1988 and 1988 vs. 2003). "' It is common in a sequential decomposition for the full to the for die factors that are varied first (e.g.. quantities or prices) to credited with a larger contribution to the change in the outcome. That is not tlie case here; in fact be the role of composition appears more important when we vary education and between-e.xperience group gaps when we first vary allow these 'prices' to vary, it third rather tlian first. The explanation seems to be that betweenwage variance became more pronounced during 1973 to 1988. Hence, the subsequent quantity adjustments become more important. in 20 contribution of changing labor force composition to rising upper both males and females. The rise of upper-tail inequality after 1988 by rising between and within-group prices, as was the case inequality tail is is negligible for almost entirely explained for the period of 1973 - 1988. These price increases are comparable in magnitude during 1973 through 1988 and 1988 through 2003 with the estimated rise in within-group prices for males somewhat is larger in the latter period. Table 5 presents the comparable decomposition for hourly wage inequality data. The conclusions period, the March in the March CPS are qualitatively similar to those from Table 4. In particular, in the earlier data show a small role for composition (though larger for females than males) and a predominant role for rising between and within-group prices gro'Mh of upper and lower inequality. Like the tail May/ORG in explaining the parallel data, the March data reveal countervailing effects of prices and quantities in the lower half of the distribution and almost no role for quantities (i.e., composition) descriptive results in Table distribution in the 1, we test, we upper half of the distribution. Consistent with our find less price compression in the lower March data than As a robustness in the in the May/ORG tail of the earnings data."*^ also repeated the estimation exercise in Tables 4 and 5 using a conventional Mincer model featuring a quartic in potential experience - replacing the 13 experience categories in qualitatively identical to our Appendix Tables 3a and that a focus only on trends in wage over 1988 to 2003 was 7.9 log points. Adjusting for changes A 90/10 inequality (or all prices at their 1988 level, we in variance in the lead to an incomplete view of the roles of prices and quantities in periods. For example, the overall rise in male 90/10 hourly period and holding 3b, are main estimates. These results demonstrate may dummy our main model - interacted with four education categories. The substantive findings of this alternative model, reported in of log wages) more inequality in the CPS May/ORG composition during calculate that 90/10 inequality comparable analysis for the March full-time data (not shown) echoes these conclusions, though is even less lower-tail compression than in either hourly sample. some this time would in the full-time data there 21 counterfactually have risen by 4.8 log points. thirds of the rise in inequality during One could conclude from 1988 to 2003 is this exercise that "explained by" compositional This conclusion, however, ignores a substantial contemporaneous rise prices. Holding residual prices constant, we estimate that rising in two- shifts. between-group between-group prices would have counterfactually raised 90/10 inequality by an additional 7.0 log points. Thus, between-group What prices could be said to "explain" 90 percent of the rise in 90/10 inequality. claims is that within-group prices compressed significantly over the same reconciles these interval - reducing 90/10 inequality by 3.8 log points ("explaining" minus 48 percent of the phenomenon). Although none of these statements findings in Tables 4 and 5 is that: is factually incorrect, a more precise statement of the over 1988 to 1993, a (1) upper-tail inequality rose steadily rise almost entirely explained by rising between and within-group prices; (2) lower-tail inequality plateaued or compressed during the changing composition (leading prices (leading to interval due to the countervailing effects of more expansion) and changing between and within-group more compression). IV. Quantile decomposition: In this section, Methodologically, we An extended DFL approach extend our analysis to the decomposition of residual inequality. we demonstrate how unify alternative models for Substantively, to same time the quantile decomposition technique wage density decompositions we demonstrate how our core findings - (e.g., i.e., JMP, DFL may be used to and extensions). that prices, not quantities are the predominant force explaining the growth of aggregate and residual inequality -can be reconciled with the conclusion of Lemieux (2005) that changes in labor force composition essentially explain the entire rise of residual inequality after 1988. We begin with a quantile implementation of the extended DiNardo, Fortin and Lemieux (1996) procedure proposed by Lemieux (2002 and 2005). The original observed wage densities to account for compositional (and other) DFL shifts. procedure reweights Lemieux (2002 2005) extends this technique to the analysis of counterfactual residual wage densities. The extension 22 involves estimating flexible wage models similar to our equation quantile regressions), assigning each observation distribution of x's to account for compositional its ( 1 (using ) OLS rather than regression residual, and reweighting the between any two time periods. shifts To the extent that reweighting generates a counterfactual residual distribution that approximates the observed change in the residual distribution, the changes to compositional In DFL extended procedure ascribes the observed shifts." our notation, the Lemieux approach (superscripted by L below) estimates the following quantity: AOj = (8) a ifigr (X), /?' = 0, js; )) - a (fig, = (.V), /3' 0, /?; )) Here, the counterfactual contribution of changing labor force composition to the change quantile of the residual distribution is estimated by replacing the x distribution from period with X distribution from period r while holding residual prices setting between-group prices Lemieux/DFL quantile Juhn-Murphy-Pierce decomposition component ( AQ^ ) base (period at their t ) t level and to zero. Inspection of equation (8) reveals that the full in the 0' .'^ of the three component quantile More JMP calculation specifically, is it is a subcomponent of the identical to the first decomposition above (and hence straightforward for us to implement using the quantile tool) except that the calculation sets /J* to zero in both time periods, thus suppressing the role of between-group prices. The utility of this extension is that it exclusively analyzes the contribution of labor force composition to changing residual inequality, abstracting from the role played by with labor force composition." ^' Lemieux A potential between group prices and limitation of this partial-decomposition also proposes a variance decomposition that explicitly models " It is not a subset of the original the residual ' wage JMP distribution (see The DFL approach does not wage variance is that the 90/10. 90/50, etc.) and we do is of not suited for analyzing not implement it here. decomposition, however, which does not account for the heteroskedasticity of Appendix explicitly Rather, the contribution of prices (e.g., is the conditional heteroskedasticity regression residuals and applies this to the U.S. residual distribution. This decomposition inequality measures other than the their interaction 2). model the role of prices calculated as a residual - that in shifting the overall is the component that or residual wage distribution. remains after the quantity 23 allocation of total arbitrary since it wage depends upon the and within-group inequality A. is, of x set 's included however, invariant in the conditioning set. is inherently The sum of between to the conditioning set. Extended DFL decomposition: Results for overall inequality For comparison with the prior overall inequality using the results, May /ORG we data. by applying the labor force composition ( components variation into 'between-group' and 'residual' first implement the Lemieux-DFL analysis We evaluate data, g,{x) , for the importance of compositional shifts from each sample year to the price series from four different years: the contemporaneous year — thus producing that year's P'^ ,P]' ) observed level of inequality - and the price series for years 1973, 1988 and 2003. Aggregate inequality statistics (90/10, 90/50, 50/10) for these counterfactual densities are plotted in Figure 4 (see also Table 6). The differences figure reflect the effect of in the vertical height at their The over-time change of each series the x-axis) reflects the effect of changes in labor force composition, holding prices results stand out in Figure 4. First, there not attributable to compositional changes. reflected in the shallow is a large rise in overall earnings inequality that The magnitude of the compositional upward slope of the counterfactual substantial rise in inequality observed when comparing series between 1973 and 2003. Holding composition estimate that this earnings ratio at the is that revveights is - small relative to the ratio rose by 29 log points 1973, 1988 or 2003 levels respecti\'ely. would counterfactually have Second, compositional and price shifts play distinct roles reweigliting - effects the price changes over the three decades of the sample. For example, the male 90/10 log hourly earnings between in the level 1973, 1988 or 2003 level. Two is in the between and within-group prices on earnings inequality, holding labor force composition at the appointed year's level. (moving along of each series within a given year risen we by 22 to 25 log points. in the upper and lower tails of the implemented. Leibbrandt, Levinsohn and McCrar)' (2005) propose an extension to tlie DFL approach wage distribution for changes in prices as well as quantities, though it also does not differentiate tlie 'residual' and 'between-group" prices. 24 wage As distribution. visible in is tlie middle two panels of Figure inequality over the entire three decades and within-group prices. x's ), When is evaluated series The comparable analysis - is of upper tail almost exclusively a consequence of changing between at any point along the x-axis the counterfactual rise in upper-tail inequality between the three price 4, the rise — measured by (i.e., using 1973 to 2003 the vertical difference (about) equally pronounced during both halves of the sample. for lower-tail inequality, shown lower panels of Figure in the 4, also reveals an important role for prices in the plateauing of 50/10 inequality after 1988. Here, the role of prices is the opposite of that above; price compression substantially reduced lower inequality after 1988 the 1988 series - - seen by the lower height of the 2003 counterfactual a fact that is tail price series relative to also robust to the choice of the quantity series for any year. Labor force composition also played a role - by offsetting lower-tail price compression. Using any of the three counterfactual price series (1973, 1988, 2003), the simulated 50/10 log earnings ratio slopes gradually upward from the late raised observed 50/10 inequality B. Extended We now DFL above what would have occurred had prices alone compressed. use the extended The MM quantile tool results confirm the Lemieux findings and, The top panel of Figure 5 to implement the Lemieux/DFL decomposition of this decomposition for the we shows May/ORG sample once at believe, substantially alter their interpretation. that holding composition constant at the 1973, 1 988 or 2003 90/10 residua! inequality rose sharply between 1973 and 1988 (compare the height of the 1973 versus 1988 by about 15 finding of series). to 30 percent Between 1988 and 2003, however, of Lemieux (2005) vertical differences that 980s, indicating that changing labor-force representation decomposition: Results for residual inequality for residual inequality. level, 1 among its original rise, holding composition constant. This confirms the that residual inequality plateaued or contracted after 1988. But the these three counterfactual series at each point along the x-axis reveal changing 'residual prices" are primarily responsible residual inequality in the residual 90/10 inequality contracted first for the rise and then contraction and second halves of the sample. These in shifts in residual inequality 25 occur with composition constant. What upward slopes of each counterfactual role did series composition play? As (moving along the may be seen by shallow x-axis), compositional shifts also contributed to rising residual inequality (holding residual prices constant), particularly after 1988. But these compositional How can explain the shifts are modest relative to the price effects. these modest effects be reconciled with the claim that compositional changes full rise in residual inequality after 1988? from 1988 actual net rise in estimated residual inequality residual"). it at 0.4 The observed The answer may be seen by studying rise in residual inequality can be said rise in residual inequality for this period. price contractions were economically inequality As shown in the lower (series labeled But what Figure 5 reveals as or continued to rise for in the quite small; more than is all) to upper and lower two panels of Figure opposite direction. By we estimate of the observed that the offsetting effects more important than these compositional 5, tail shifts. residual inequality treated is entirely a price effect; contrast, upper-tail residual inequality both genders between 1988 and 2003 - and substantially so for males, as did in the prior half of the sample. In fact, only when of composition-constant lower- tail unambiguously contracted between 1988 and 2003. This composition effects work is "observed modest contribution of compositional to explain all (in fact, These points apply with even greater force separately. 2003 over 1988 to 2003 log points (Table 7). Accordingly, the relatively shifts to rising residual inequality to the it labor force weights from 1973 are used in place of labor force weights from 1988 or 2003 does this rise appear muted for males and reversed for females. What explains the sensitivity to the choice of weights? Recall from Tables 2 and 3 that 90/10 inequality rose among better educated workers after 1988 but fell during the same interval. Since the labor force highly educated workers and considerable in among less educated workers 1973 was composed of considerably fewer more high school graduates and dropouts than in 1988 or 2003, the use of 1973 labor force characteristics puts substantial weight on the groups that experienced falling inequality and puts proportionately less weight on the groups that experienced 26 rising inequality, suggesting a smaller rise in counterfactual residual inequality than the comparison made using 1988 or 2003 characteristics. prices and quantities are independent, no one weighting scheme conclusions about trends in inequality to the Under same the maintained assumption that is correct. But the sensitivity of choice of weights cautions researchers against focusing exclusively on one set of labor force characteristics. In summary, we patterns of overall find that composition plays only a secondary role in explaining the time and residual inequality in the CPS May /ORG; the ongoing rise of upper-tail inequality and the rise and then stagnation of lower-tail inequality are both primarily accounted for by changing labor market prices. Comparison with the March CPS C. The right-hand panels of Tables 6 and 7 present counterfactual simulations for March hourly earnings inequality, and Figures 6 and 7 plot these counterfactuals. The pattern of inferences March versus May/ORG quite similar for the rise of overall or residual inequality negligible - as would be expected from that lower-tail inequality (both overall than May/ORG on the observed This finding rise is at is But the estimated contribution of composition considerably smaller earlier tables. The in these less to data - though not principle reason for this discrepancy and residual) contracted by considerably weight on data. Placing greater holding composition constant data. is educated workers in the less in the is March March data (by an early period level) has a comparatively lesser offsetting effect of overall or residual inequality during qualitatively consistent with this period. Lemieux (2005), who also reports that the March data reveal a smaller role for composition and a correspondingly larger role for prices in the growth of residual earnings. Interestingly, May/ORG and March results for the role believe the source of the difference residuals while ours is Appendix Tables 2a and 2b, Lemieux's analysis, the discrepancy between the of composition that decomposes wage in is far greater than we report here. We Lemieux's analysis decomposes the variance of wage quantiles (90/10) and their subcomponents. As shown there are substantially greater discrepancies between the in March and 27 May/ORG data for variance than quantile measures, and this difference becomes particularly pronounced between 1988 and 2002. The particularly high variance of the wage residual measures in the March data appear likely to reflect the fact that hourly wages are calculated in these data using prior year's earnings divided by which exclude the tails of the distribution, are likely construction of hourly wages in the Is the hence we is less sensitive to outliers is more reliable than the other? March and May/ORG Bias in the V. A key issue in May/ORG May/ORG of workers who and March versus March CPS wage in data: Levels or trends? whether the differences in the March CPS of workers with well- measured hourly wages increases hourly wage measurement earlier, the share wage reporting may make the May/ORG CPS inequality relative to the mean it in a relative to the the ORG/May CPS, May/ORG May/ORG. Although more accurate measure of becomes a preferred measure March CPS. simple variance decomposition can help clarify these issues. Let o index the in points out that a growth in the share of hourly workers will tend to lead to a inequality at a point in time, this does not necessarily of trends A is CPS (Hamermesh 2002; Lemieux 2005). measured residual hourly wage inequality in I. report being paid by the hour has increased substantially since 1973, both in Lemieux (2005) growth Section inequality. have remained stable over time. As noted aggregate and within education/experience groups as the share in data both have advantages and disadvantages and provide comparing wage inequality trends error in the in that sample prov ides a more accurate measure of the hourly wage distribution and complementary sources of information on the evolution of U.S. wage this Lemieux argues a preferred data source for analysis of U.S. wage inequality. As discussed believe the growth generated by the March CPS. there reason to believe that one series May/ORG CPS weeks and earnings. The quantile measures, m j index sex-education-experience group, hourly workers (those paid by the hour), and n index non-hourly workers. index the March CPS, / index year, h index We define V"' and V° 28 wages as the observed variances of hourly workers year in in / ; CPS; and group j in year t. We a^,^ as workers in measurement the variance of March CPS. The measurement May/ORG CPS in year error in hourly measurement wages error in hourly by al^ and a^^ . We respectively for wages for hourly wages variances for hourly and error are analogously given group j March and May/ORG CPS also define Cji as the true variance in hourly as the variance of (j,^„, in the group j for workers in March for non-hourly workers in non-hourly workers also let //^^qua the in the share of hourly 1 t Under the assumption of white noise measurement variances of hourly wages for group J in year t in the error in hourly wages, the observed March and May/ORG CPS can be written as: Based on the estimates from matched March-May/ORG samples presented we assume that March CPS: hourly wages are more accurately measured cr^,„ hourly workers is > crl^ . We also assume that measurement essentially equivalent in the is also reasonable to assume that hourly than non-hourly workers in the in levels than wages May/ORG CPS are error in the hourly than in the wages a'^^^ = a^^ for . non- These generates higher (and less accurate) does the May/ORG CPS: more accurately measured samples: a^^ > Lemieux (2005), May/ORG CPS March and May/ORG CPS: assumptions imply, as Lemieux notes, that the March measures of residual hourly wage inequality in the in <jI^ . Although there K"' > V° . It for hourly workers is little reason to believe in differential measurement error for the hourly wages of non-hourly and hourly workers in the March CPS, Lemieux's estimates imply We residual o"," next consider the accuracy of the different wage inequality from period t to period r > a' . CPS samples when the for measuring changes in share of workers paid by the hour is 29 rising - hourly - as has been the case since the 1970s. Let Ax, wage variance for group J from Mo -.v, x, r in the different . The changes CPS in measured residua! samples are given by ^^^^^^^M"-""^"-^' (10) so that AV:-AV;=AH,[{cTl,-al) + ial-aly]. (11) Under is the assumptions given above, this difference rising in the share of workers paid by the hour: AF"' Thus, as emphasized by Lemieux (2005), a rise in the systematically lead to a rise in measured residual the in contrast to the -AV° =AHj,{a^^ -o"^)>0 is positive >0. if A//^, share of hourly workers should wage inequality in the conclusion drawn by Lemieux (2004), series does not imply that the actual residual downward wage May/ORG CPS March CPS relative to is rising (since upward biased measure of changes induce in the May/ORG CPS, we < cj]^). inequality In contrast, the in actual residual wage ( AF° < Acr^", ) at its base (1974) level. '° inequality if cr^^^ in residual inequality, a^ > provides a when frequency of hourly pay reporting at its start . cells for in wage may inequalit)' in is formed using the each year to maintain the of period level within the gender by education by increase the precision of this simulation by using the by experience by gender the holding the frequency This counterfactual series MM quantile simulation procedure, reweighting the data in March CPS provides an plot in Figure 8 observed trends in residual alongside counterfactual trends of hourly wage reporting We cr^^ wage May/ORG CPS a rough direct assessment of the bias that the rise of hourly pay reporting May/ORG CPS extended divergence between the provides a more accurate measure of changes biased measure of changes in actual residual To provide this inequality. Rather, equation (11) implies that the share of hourly workers '° May/ORG May/ORG CPS. But the between March and mean frequency of hourly pay reporting within education 1973, 1974 and 1975. 30 experience cells used our analysis. in No made other adjustments are for compositional changes Hence, the contrast between the observed and counterfactual in the counterfactual series. series is exclusively due to hourly pay reporting. To provide more detailed look a at the hourly reweighting bias, Figure 9 plots the gap (by gender) between estimated 90/10 residual inequality and the hourly-reporting-corrected series alongside a chain-weighted index of the evolution of hourly pay reporting in our sample."" Figure 9 indicates that the rise in hourly pay reporting has probably led to a non-negligible bias in measured trends in residual inequality in the May /ORG CPS. cumulates over 1973 to approximately 1989, plateaus between 1997 and 2002. For females, the bias sharp rise in 1991.^" The is to 1994, and then appears of hourly pay reporting this bias to increase again 1979 but then begins a relatively stable after further rise in the hourly-pay bias in the particularly puzzling since the frequency For males, downward MORG samples after in the May /ORG 1994 is plateaued in the early 1990s. This suggests that the difference between the precision of hourly and non-hourly wage reports became more pronounced Notably, the hourly-pay bias in the after the 1994 CPS CPS May/ORG redesign. can potentially be 'controlled' by making adjustments for hourly pay composition comparable to the ones experience. In fact, our simulation procedure for the throughout. Specifically, we in the and residual) and we reweight this covariate accurate adjustment " May/ORG if the In the base year, this index add cell, '" the to it is data makes this adjustment conditioning set used for the quantile analysis (both overall along with other x's in the simulation. possible that our analysis of residual inequality in apply for education and include an indicator variable for hourly pay reporting, interacted with each education category, inequality trends May/ORG we may It is therefore correct for the hourly-pay bias in residual sample. However, our procedure is unlikely to provide an relationship between hourly pay and earnings precision in the CPS equal to the observed frequency of hourly pay reporting. In each subsequent year, we sum of year-over-year change in hourly pay-reporting in each education-by-experience group weights are the employment share of each cell over the prior two years. the weighted where the Notably, the bias for females is particularly pronounced the plateau in female 50/10 inequality after 1989 is in the lower-tail an artifact of changes of the distribution. This suggests in that part of hourly earnings reports. 31 survey undergoes a discontinuous change - as In summary, although residual hourly wage residual hourly Lemieux wage fiirther measurement March CPS inequality while the error in hourly for May/ORG may trends) in provide a downward biased estimate/^ March-May/ORG samples wages within hourly and non-hourly workers increased over March and May/ORG samples with males and of similar magnitude that both are attempting to capture the in 1994. analysis suggests that there are reasons to argues and presents evidence using the matched assume white noise measurement error in in provides a more accurate measure of the level of March CPS, our variance than the past three decades in both the changes CPS occurred March CPS may provide an upward biased measure of changes (and suspect the that the IVlay/ORG may have that is same in the the the rise being larger in the two samples for females. These estimates uncorrelated across the two samples and assume true measure of hourly earnings. But there are real the labor market and structure of compensation that could generate actual divergences earnings inequality measures based on a comprehensive measure of annual earnings from the March samples versus a the May/ORG 1990s more is straight-time hourly wage rate or usual weekly earnings measure from samples. For example, the growth of bonuses and other contingent pay likely to be captured in the in the March data than the May/ORG earnings measure (Lebow, Sheiner, Slifman, and Starr-McCluer 1999; Lemiuex, MacLeod, and Parent 2005). Changes in the importance of transitory versus permanent components of earnings could also reduce the true covariance between annual and point-in-time measures of earnings. Furthermore, most of Lemieux's estimated growth ORG samples comes more that We "'' in the 1990s greatly affected the therefore wage to measurement error in the March versus period overlapping the major 1994 revision of the the CPS data. do not concur with Lemieux's (2005) suggestion in the to researchers to use the March and May/ORG samples are smaller for samples limited to full-time in Appendix Table 1. The persistent rise in upper-tail analyses of full-time, weekly earnings as indicated inequality earnings. in the ORG The divergences of inequality trends workers and in the relative combined with A substantial the post- 1988 stagnation of lower-tail inequality rise in residual wage inequality after 1988 samples when examining full-time weekly earnings. is is also apparent for full-time apparent in both the March and weekly May/ORG May/ORG CPS rather than the recent decades. To be clear, March CPS both CPS to study the evolution samples have strengths and limitations. actual labor market changes and data processing changes of missing wage infoiTnation, changes the actual earnings and the of U.S. wage inequality over in the in many there are - ranging from top coding, imputations questions - that wage and hour measurement error And wage measures may in the different differentially CPS samples. Researchers would be wise to combine information from both sources for measuring changes wage the U.S. in structure. VI. Conclusion This paper set out to evaluate one potential explanation for the diverging trends of U.S. inequality during the 1990s. Our analysis may have the U.S. labor force dispersion from 1990 forward. tested whether the rising experience and education of led to a mechanical We fail to confirm (i.e., not due to price changes) rise in earnings this hypothesis. Shifts in labor force composition have affected earnings inequality during the 1990s. But these compositional have primarily operated on the lower primarily served to tail of the earnings distribution and, moreover, have mute a contemporaneous, countervailing contrast, the steady rise of upper tail shifts lower-tail price compression. By inequality since the early 1980s appears almost entirely explained by ongoing between-group and residual price changes. The source of the asymmetric inequality and some evidence of flat making adjustments pattern is workers earnings inequality with a steady rise in upper-tail or declining lower-tail wage wage inequality (particularly after composition) since the mid-1980s remains poorly understood. This suggestive of a "polarization" of the labor market with a particularly strong market for the middle, demand for in the top part Mumane rise in of the skill distribution, deterioration in and reasonably steady market conditions market conditions for workers for those near the bottom. Autor, in Levy, and (2003) postulate that computerization could have such non-monotonic impacts on the for skill: sharply raising demand for the cognitive and interpersonal skills used by educated professionals and managers; reducing demand for clerical and routine analytical ' skills -33 that comprised many middle-educated white collar jobs; and reducing demand for routine manual skills of many previously high-paid manufacturing production jobs. But computerization has probably had little impact on the skilled' (in-person) service jobs framework suggests demand for the non-routine skills that computerization - may have raised demand left Goos and Manning (2003) call distribution comparatively unscathed. "polarization of work," and argue that distribution in the United We it may have Kingdom in many etc. 'low- This as well as the increased international outsourcing (off- workers, depressed demands for 'middle-skill' workers, and wage used such as health aides, orderlies, cleaners, servers, shoring) of routine cognitive and manual tasks - skill manual for skill among the bottom of the high- wage such a process the contributed to a similar hollowing out of the during 1975 to 2000 finally stress that the informativeness of the counterfactual exercises undertaken in this study depends critically on the maintained partial-equilibrium assumption that prices and quantities can be treated as independent. If this assumption is substantially violated, the counterfactual inequality series developed will not correspond to any potential state of the world since altering labor force characteristics will necessarily alter the prices associated with those characteristics. Lending weight to this concern, the careful analyses of earnings premiums by experience, age and education group performed by Card and Lemieux (2001) and Borjas (2003) strongly affirm that the relative responsive to own wages paid to education, experience supplv as well as aggregate supply. Hence, and age groups are quite shifts in composition and prices will generally negatively covary, particularly over long time intervals - such shifts as the three decades above. This underscores that the impact of changing composition on prices could potentially be a first order source of bias remains an important item in these counterfactual exercises. Assessing this bias for analysis. 34 References VII. Wage Decompositions: Minimum Wage." Work in Angrist, Joshua, David Autor and Victor Chernozhukov. 2004. "Quantiie Estimation and Inference, with an Application to the U.S. Progress, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Angrist. Joshua, Victor Chernozhukov and Ivan Fernandez- Val. Forthcoming. "Quantiie Regression under Misspecification, with an Application to the U.S. Wage Structure." Econo?netrica. Autor, David H.. Lawrence F. Katz, and Melissa Inequality: Re-Assessing the Revisionists." Autor, David H., Frank Levy, and Richard An Technological Change: J. S. Kearney. 2005. "Trends MIT Mimeograph, Mumane. in U.S. Wage September. 2003. "The Skill Content of Recent Empirical Investigation." Quarterly Journal of Economics 1 18 (November): 1279-1333. Blau, Francine D. and Lawrence Wage Differential in Blinder, Alan. 1973. ofHuman Borjas, J. M. Kahn. 1997. "Swimming Upstream: Trends 980s." Journal of Labor Economics, 15(1), Part "Wage Resources. George 1 1 , in the January, Gender 1 Discrimination: Reduced Forms and Structural Estimation." 8, - 42. Jowwa/ 436 - 455. 2003. "The Labor Demand Curve Is Downward Sloping: Reexamining the Impact of Immigration on the Labor Market." Quarterly Journal of Economics (November): 1335-74. Buchinsky, Moshe. 1994. "Changes in the U.S. Wage Structure 1963 1 18 - 1987: Application of Quantiie Regression." Econometrica, 62(2), 405 -458. Card, David and John E. DiNardo. 2002. "Skill-Biased Technological Change and Rising Inequality: Card, David and Some Problems and Wage Puzzles." Journal of Labor Economics 20 (October): 733-83. Thomas Lemieux. 2001 "Can . Falling Supply Explain the Rising Return to College for Younger Men?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 1 16 (May): 705-46. R., Anne E. Polivka and Jennifer M. Rothgreb. 1994, "Revisions in the Current Population Survey Effective January 2004," Current Population Survey Technical Cohany, Sharon Documentation CPS-94, Attachment 5, Bureau of the Census: Washington, DC. David M. and Lawrence F. Katz. 1992. "Rising Inequality? Changes in the Distribution of Income and Consumption in the \9%Qs." American Economic Review 82 (May): 546-51. Cutler, DiNardo, John. Nicole Fortin and Thomas Lemieux. 1996. "Labor Market Institutions, and the Distribution of Wages, 1973-1992: A Semiparametric Approach." Econometrica 64 (September), 1001-1044. Goos, Maarten and Alan Manning. 2003. "Lousy and Lovely Jobs: The Rising Polarization of Work in Britain." Unpublished paper. Center for Economic Performance, London School of Economics, September. 35 Hamermesh, Daniel. 2002. "12 Million Relations Review, 55(4), July, Heckman, James J., Regressions." Lance NBER Salaried Workers are Missing." Industrial and Labor 649 - 666. J. Lochner and Petra E. Todd. 2003 Working Paper No. 9732, May. "Fifty Years of Mincer Earnings Edward J. Schumacher. 2004. "Match Bias in Wage Gap Estimates due Earnings Imputation." Journal of Labor Economics. 22(3), July, 689 - 722. Hirsch, Barry T. and Jaeger, David A.. 1997. "Reconciling the Old and Recommendations for Researchers," New to Census Bureau Education Questions: Journal of Business and Economics Statistics, 1 5, 300— 309. M. Murphy and Brooks Pierce. 1993. "Wage Inequality and the Rise in Returns to Skill." Journal of Political Economy, 101(3), 410 - 442. Juhn. Chinhui, Kevin Katz, Lawrence F. and David H. Autor. 1999. "Changes Inequality." In O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, eds. in the Wage Structure and Earnings Handbook of Labor Economics, volume 3, North Holland. M. Murphy. 1992. "Changes in Relative Wages, 1963-87: Supply and Demand Factors." Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (February): 35-78. Katz, Lawrence F. and Kevin Karoly, Lynn and Gary Burtless. 1995. "Demographic Change, Rising Earnings Inequality, and the Distribution of Weil-Being, \959-\9S9." Koenker, Roger and Kevin F. Hallock. Demography 32 379-405. : 2001. "Quantile Regression.'^ Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(4), Fall, 143 ~ 156. Koenker, Roger and Gilbert Bassett Jr. 1978. "Regression Quantiles," Econometrica, 46(1), 33 - 50. Lebow, David Trends in E., Louise Sheiner, Larry Slifman, and Martha Starr-McCIuer. 1999. "Recent Compensation Practices." FEDS Working Paper No. 99-32, Federal Reserve Board, July. Lemieux, Thomas. 2002. "Decomposing Changes in Wage Distributions: Canadian Journal of Economics, 35(4), November, 646-688. Lemieux, Thomas. 2005. "Increasing Residual Wage Data, or Rising Demand Inequality': for Skill?" University A Unified Approach," Composition Effects, Noisy of British Columbia, May. Lemieux, Thomas, W. Bentley MacLeod, and Daniel Parent. 2005. "Bonus Pay and Wage Inequality." University of British Columbia, April. Leibbrandt, Murray, James Levinsohn, and Justin McCrary. 2005. "Incomes Since the Fall of Apartheid." NBER in South Africa Working Paper No. 11384, May. Machado, Jose and Jose Mata. 2005. "Counterfactual Decompositions of Changes in Wage Distributions Using Quantile Regression." Journal of Applied Econometrics, 20(4), 445-65. 36 Melly, Blaise. Forthcoming. "Decomposition of Differences in Distribution Using Quantiie Regression," Labour Economics Mincer, Jacob. 1974. Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. New York: NBER. Mishel, Lawrence, Jared Bernstein, and Heather Boushey. 2002. The State of Working America: 2002-03. Ithaca, ILR Press. Murphy, Kevin M. and Finis Welch. 1992. "The Structure of Wages." Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (February): 285-326. Oaxaca, Ronald. 1973. "Male-Female Wage Differentials Economic Review. 14, 693 - 709. in Urban Labor Markets." International Heum, "Estimation of Sheepskin Effects and Returns to Schooling Using the Old and Measures of Educational Attainment." Princeton University, Industrial Relations Section Working Paper No. 338, December 1994. Park, Jin the New CPS Polivka. Anne. 2000. "Using Earnings Data from the Mimeograph, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Monthly Current Population Survey." October. Anne E. and Jennifer M. Rothgreb. 1993. "Redesigning the CPS Questionnaire," - 28. Monthly Labor Review, September, Polivka, 1 37 Appendix A. Basic processing of May/ORG We use the May CPS for 1973 to 1: Data CPS data 1978 and the CPS Merged Outgoing Rotation Groups for years 1979 to 2003. All samples include wage/salary workers ages 16 to 64 with to 39 years of potential experience in current employment. Earnings weights are used in all calculations. Full- CPS sampling time earnings are weighted by product of CPS weights. Hourly earnings are weighted by the sampling weights and hours worked week. Full-time earnings are the wages are the logarithm of hourly earnings for those paid by the hour and the logarithm of usual weekly earnings reported divided by hours worked last week (not usual weekly hours) for non-hourly workers. We use hours last week instead of usual weekly hours because usual weekly hours is not consistently logarithm of reported usual weekly earnings. In available: starting with the CPS all in the prior years, hourly redesign in 1994, workers who report that their weekly hours vary are not asked to report usual weekly hours, yielding a non-report rate of 7.0 to 8.5 percent of workers 1994 to 2003. To check in sensitivity, we have tabulated and plotted overall and residual inequality measures using imputed usual weekly hours in place of hours last 1973 -2003. This has little impact on our week in all years results. Topcoded earnings observations are multiplied by 1.5. Full-time earnings of below $67/week in 982$ ($ 2/week in 2000$) and hourly earners of below $ .675/hour in 982 dollars ($2.80/hour in 2000$) are dropped, as are hourly wages exceeding l/35th the topcoded value of weekly earnings. All earnings numbers are deflated by the chain-weighted (implicit) price 1 1 1 1 1 consumption expenditures. Allocated earnings observations are excluded in where allocation flags are unavailable (January 1994 to August 1995). As discussed by Hirsch and Shumacher (2004), only about 25 percent of allocated observations in the MORG CPS are flagged as allocated between 1989 and 1993. Following Lemieux (2004), we identify and drop non-flagged allocated observations by using the unedited earnings values deflator for personal all years, except provided in the source data. Basic processing ofMarcIt B. We use the CPS data March Current Population Survey for earnings years 1975 to 2003 for workers age 16 39 years of potential experience whose class of work in their longest job was private or government wage/salary employment. Hourly earnings are calculated as annual earnings divided by the product of weeks worked and usual hours in the prior to 64 (during the earnings year) with year. Full-time, full-year to workers are those who work 35 hours per Bureau's full-time worker flag) and worked 40+ weeks in the week (using the Census previous year. Full-time weekly earnings are calculated as the logarithm of annual earnings over weeks worked for the full-time, full-year sample. Allocated earnings observations are excluded using family earnings allocation and individual earnings allocation flags. Weights are used in all calculations. Full-time earnings are weighted by the product of the CPS sampling weight and weeks worked. Hourly earnings are weighted by the product of the CPS sampling weight, weeks worked, and hours worked in the prior year. Prior to March variable, 1 989, all wage and which was topcoded at salary income in the March CPS was values between $50,000 and $99,999 in reported in a single years 1975 to 1988. For we multiply the topcoded earnings value by 1.5, following Katz and Murphy Commencing in 1989, wage and salary incomes were collected in two separate earnings these cases, (1992). variables, corresponding to primary and secondary labor earnings. After adjusting for topcoding. we sum these values to calculate total wage and salary earnings. Topcodes after 1988 are handled as follows. For the primaiy earnings variable, topcoded values are reported at the topcode maximum up to 1996. We multiply these values by 1.5. Starting mean of all earnings values are assigned the the topcoded value and, again, multiply by maximum is set at to 37,000 in 2004. 99,999 from 1 989 to 1 1 in 1996, topcoded primary topcoded earners. In these cases, .5. we simply reassign For the secondary earnings value, the topcoded 995 and then For lack of a better alternative, falls to we again 25,000 in 1 996 to 2003, and rises use the topcoded value multiplied by 1.5. making adjustments for topcoding, full-time earnings of below $67/week in 1982$ 12/week in 2000$) and hourly earners of below $1 .675/hour in 1982 dollars (S2.80/hour in ($1 are dropped, as are hourly wages exceeding l/35th the topcoded value of weekly earnings. 2000$) After C. To Coding of education and potential experience in CPS samples comparable educational categories across the redefinition of Census Bureau's education CPS, we use the method proposed by Jaeger ( 997). In CPS samples coded with the pre-1992 education question, we defined high school dropouts as those with fewer than 12 years of completed schooling; high school graduates as those having 12 years attain variable introduced in 1992 in the 1 of completed schooling; some college attendees as those with any schooling beyond 12 years (including an incomplete 1 S"" year) and fewer than 16 completed years; college graduates as those with 16 or 17 years of completed schooling; post-college as those with more than 17 years of completed schooling. In CPS samples coded with the revised education question, we defme high school dropouts as those with fewer than 12 years of completed schooling; high school graduates as those with either 12 completed years of schooling and/or a high school some college as those attending some college diploma or G.E.D.; or holding an Associate's Degree; college as those with exactly a baccalaureate degree; and post-college as those with a post- baccalaureate degree. To calculate potential experience in data years coded with the revised education question, we from Park (1994) to assign years of completed education to each worker based upon gender and highest degree held. Years of potential experience were calculated as age minus assigned years of education minus 6. rounded down to the nearest integer value. figures use race, 39 Appendix JMP Comparison of traditional and quantile 2: decompositions propose a model for wage inequality as a function of the distribution of covariates, the vector of between-group prices where 9 e [0,1] the resulting wage vi'_^ JMP . JMP wage implement j3's ( JMP's =x„'y9, +/|(^,) where fitting F~\9) which , =/^~'(e„)and e„ is OLS regressions to estimate /? and using the inverse cumulative empirical residual Vs wage, w, can be written notation, individual 9,, g(.r) and the cumulative distribution of the residual, F{9) model by this residuals to form distribution. In ) is as: V s wage residual from the regression. JMP use this methodology to decompose changes in the wage distribution over 1963 to 1989 into components due to changes in prices ( A/? ), changes in quantities ( Ag(x) ), and changes in the residual distribution ( AF{9)). The principle virtue of the Blinder-Oaxaca method counterfactual wage various wage is that it JMP decomposition over the standard can potentially be applied to simulate any feature of a JMP's distribution. Indeed, principle focus is on earnings inequality among quantiles: 90/10, 90/50 and 50/10. JMP methodology has two shortcomings that are solved by the quantile model. The first that the OLS wage regression at the heart of the JMP technique provides a model for the The conditional quantiles. that mean of the wage For example, there distribution and =x,' /], + i^(50) This inconsistency . J', its results do not extend naturally no presumption that /^(50) = is , and so it may not present in the quantile model, which provides a is decomposition need not sum distribution in period t for the t is depends on both . that the components of the in is are random JMP that knowledge of the marginal and covariance (i.e., distribution . is when of x'/? and w = x'/? + F(9) = x.' /3+ F(9,)) their joint distribution). This covariance decomposition unless F{9) F{9) This counterfactual observed wage variables, the distribution of their sum, g{w^ is one special case where the marginal distribution of distributions of x' /3 and JMP each of the three accounting components between zVF((9)), will not generally recover the The reason their variances not accounted for by the is change is observed change. Specifically, adjusting the wage not generally sufficient to characterize the marginal distribution of Because x'/? and F{9) There of the method to the total and r (A/?,Ag(x) and distribution in period r F{d) this not be substantively important, however. A more significant shortcoming periods wage need not be the case uniform treatment of between and within-group price measurement. In practice, inconsistency to is allowed vv is to depend explicitly is on x .''' recoverable from the marginal the distributions are independent. Under classical OLS assumptions - in particular, a normally distributed, homoskedastic error term —this independence condition will hold. But as underscored by Lemieux (2005), this error structure odds with the predictions of human capital theory. Moreover, the evidence clearly demonstrates that trends in residual inequality differ experience groups. Hence, the homoskedastic error structure wage is at Tables 2 and 3 markedly by education and is strongly rejected for the U.S. distribution.'^ Lemieux (2002) provides " JMP in recognize tlnat a thorough discussion of these points. the 'adding up' property does not hold in their decomposition and recommend calculating the contribution of the 'residual price and quantity component" as a remainder temi. after accounting for obser\ed prices and quantities. 40 Unlike the original JMP decomposition, the quantile the full conditional distribution of wages independence nor homoskedasticity is is JMP decomposition does "add up" because allowed to depend upon x through /?'',/?" . Neither assumed. 41 Figure 1. Hourly Overall Male 90/10 Hourly 1973 1976 1S79 ' 1982 CPS 1985 1976 1979 s 1982 1985 Hourly 1988 Inequality 1991 1994 Overall Male 50/10 Hourly in May/ORG and March CPS Wage Inequality 1991 1994 CPS 1997 2000 2003 1973 1976 Inequality 1991 1994 1979 2000 2003 1973 1976 - 2003 Female 90/10 Hourly Wage 1982 Oveia'i 1997 1973 1985 1979 Female 90/50 Hourly Wage 1982 1985 Overall 1997 2000 2003 2000 2003 2000 2003 CPS May/ORG 1988 Inequality 1997 1994 1991 CPS May/ORG CPSMarcti s Inequality 1994 1991 CPS March = Ivlay/ORG Wage Series, Overall CPS May/ORG e CPSMarcti Inequality Wage » Blardi OwssS Mais 90S) 1973 1988 Wage Female 50/10 Hourly Wage Inequality s o 1973 1976 1979 ' 1982 1985 CPSMarcti 19 1997 CPS May/ORG 2000 2003 1973 1976 1979 » 1982 1985 CPSMarcti 19 1991 — 1994 1997 CPS May/ORG Figure 2. Hourly Residual Residual Male 90/10 Hourly 1973 1976 1979 » 1982 1985 CPS 1988 1976 1979 o 1982 Residual 1973 1976 1979 8 1985 1988 CPS March 1982 I^lale 1985 CPS March 19 in May/ORG and Wage 1997 2000 2003 1973 1975 1991 1997 2000 2003 1973 1976 1979 « Series, 1973 1982 1985 1988 CPSMarrt 1982 CPS 1985 19 1997 CPS May/ORG 2000 2003 1973 1976 1979 « 1982 1985 2003 Inequality 1994 1991 1997 2000 2003 2000 2003 2000 2003 CPS May/ORG Wage Inequality 1994 1991 1997 CPS May/ORG Marcti CPS March - Wage e Residual Female 50/10 Hourly Inequality 1994 CPS Residual Female 90/'50 Hourly CPS May/ORG Wage 1979 e Inequality 1994 1991 Marcii Residual Female 90/10 Hourly CPS May/ORG 9 50/10 Hourly Inequality Inequality 1994 1991 6 Marcti Residual Male 90/50 Hourly 1973 Wage Wage 19 Wage 1991 Inequality 1994 1997 CPS May/ORG Figure 3. Education and Experience of U.S. Labor Force, 1973 fvlay/ORG) A. Full-Time Equivalent - 2003 (CPS Employment Shares by Education Males Females I, 1973 1 1 1 1 1978 1983 1988 1993 2003 1973 1978 1983 1993 1998 2003 College Grad Dropouts College Grad High School Post-College High School Post-College Mean Some College Potential Experience of College Employed Workers by Education Females Males 1973 1988 Dropouts Some B. 1— 1 1998 1978 1983 19 1993 — Dropouts -a High School -« Some College — 1998 2003 1973 1978 1983 1993 19 College Grad Dropouts -' Post-College High School -' Some College 1998 2003 College Grad Post-Coliege Figure 4. Actual and Counterfactual Overall Hourly Wage Inequality 1973-2003: Actual and Counterfactual Overall Inequality (I^ORG)^ Male 90/10 CPS May/ORG Actual and Counterfactual Overall Inequality (fylORG); Female 90/10 en ^— T^^ °,°. N^ v-^ 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 — 1973 -e 2003 B's 1988 1994 1991 B's 1976 1979 1982 1935 1976 1979 1982 2003 1973 1976 1982 1979 1985 Actual 90/10 -e 2003 B's Actual 90/10 (MORG); Mas S^SI 1994 1991 1997 2000 Actual and CounterfacTjal OvsHii tnenuafity 2003 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 B's -e 1973 B's 2003 B's Actual 90/50 -^ 2003 B's 1985 1973 B's -« 2003 B's 1988 1991 —— » 1994 1988 ffs 1973 B's o 1991 1S73B's Actual and Counterfactual Overall Inequality 1973 2000 - Actual and Counterfactual OveiaB Insqusfiiy 1973 1997 1988 B's (MORG): f^ale 1994 1997 2000 2003 (MORG): Female 90/50 1994 1997 2000 2003 Actual 90/50 Actual and Counterfxtual Overall Inequality (IWORG): Fennale 50/10 50/10 2000 1991 1997 2003 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 B's 1973 B's Actual 50/10 2003 B's 1988 1991 ~-v,— 1994 Actual 50/10 1997 2000 2003 Figure 5. Actual and Counterfactual Residual Hourly Actual and Counterfactual Residual Inequality (MORG); Male 90/10 Wage Inequality 1973-2003: Actual and Counlerfactual Residual Inequality _ — 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 -• 1973 Residual B's — -e 2003 Residual -9 teiuai B's aad Counteiaciual Residual — Inequality 1994 2000 1997 1988 Residual 2003 1973 B's Observed Residual (MORG): Ivlale CPS May/ORG 1976 1979 1982 1— 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 -• 1973 Residual B's 1988 Residual B's -6 2003 Residual B's Observed Residual Actual and CouraeriBoua! 90/50 (MORG); Female 90/10 Rsadud iBsjiaHy (MORG): Female 2003 90/S) -0—«—#—e—^;y^ 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 1988 Residual B's 1973 Residual B's 1988 Residual B's 2003 Residual Observed Residual 2003 Residual B's Obsen/ed Residual B's Actual and Counteilactual Residual Inequality (IvIORG): Male 50/10 1973 1976 1973 Residual B's 1979 1982 1985 -9 1973 Residual B's -« 2003 Residual B's 1988 1991 1994 1997 1988 Residual 6 B's Observed Residual 2000 Actual and Counterfactual Residual Inequality 2003 1973 1975 1979 1982 1985 1991 2000 2003 (MORG): Female 50/10 1994 1997 1973 Residual B's 1988 Residual B's 2003 Residual B's Observed Residual 2000 2003 Figure 6. Actual and Counterfactual Overall Hourly Wage 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1978 1981 1996 B's 1988 2003 B's Actual 90/10 tetu^ and Counterfactual Houriy Earnings 1975 1993 1975 1984 1987 1990 1999 2002 1975 1993 1996 Mate 90!W 1978 1981 1981 1999 2002 1984 1987 Actual 90/10 B's 1975 1978 1961 1984 1987 1988 B's 1975 Bs 2003 B's Actual 90/50 2003 1990 1993 1996 B's 2002 B's 1990 -s 1993 1996 Actual 50/10 Female 90/10 1999 2002 Female S)/50 1999 2002 Actual 90/50 Actual and Counterfactual Hourly Earnings Inequality (March): Female 50/10 1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1975 Bs 1975 B's 2003 1999 1996 2003 B's 1987 1993 1988 B's 1975 1984 1990 1975 B's AGiiai and Counterfxtual Hourly Earnings Inequality (March): Actual and Counterfactual Hourly Earnings Inequality (March): Male 50/10 1975 1978 B's Inequality (Maroi): CPS March Actual and Counterfactual Hourly Earnings Inequality (March)' Actual and Counterfaclual Hourly Earnings Inequality (March): Male 90/10 1975 Inequality 1975-2003: 2003 B's Actual 50/10 1999 2002 Figure 7. Actual and Counterfactual Residual Hourly Actual and Counterfaclual Hourly Residual Inequality (March); Male 90/10 Wage Inequality 1975-2003: CPS March Actual and Counterfactual Hourly Residual Inequality (March): _ Female 90/10 -9—«—» 1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1993 1990 1996 2002 1999 1975 Residual B's 1988 Residual 2003 Residual B's Observed Residual 1975 1978 B's Actual and Counterfactual Hourly Residual Inequality (March); Male 90/50 1981 1984 1987 1993 1990 1995 1999 1975 Residual B's ISBSRssidiaiB's 2003 Residual B's OtEerved Residual Actual and Counterfactual Hourly Residual Inequality (tifeii): Fsnais 2002 9ffi3) °/°'^&-^ '^ /^ V Q-^ 1975 —&—e— —e —«—9—o—e—o—s—e—o—o—*—*— « 1978 1981 1984 •-" 1987 1993 1990 -B 1975 Residual B's — -o 2003 Residual -Q B's — 1996 1988 Residual 1999 2002 1975 Observed Residual Actual and Counterfactual Hourly Residual Inequality (March); Male 50/10 1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1975 Residual B's 2003 Residual B's 1990 1993 » — 1978 B's 1995 1988 Residual 1999 B's Observed Residual 2002 Actual 1975 1981 1984 1987 1996 1999 1988 Residual B's 2003 Residual B's Observed Residual and Counterfactual Hourly Residual 1978 1993 1990 1975 Residual B's 1981 1984 1987 1975 Residual Bs 2003 Residual Bs Inequality (March); 1993 1990 ' ! 1996 2002 Female 50/10 1999 1988 Residual B's Observed Residual 2002 Figure 8. The Growth of Residual Inequality in the CPS I^ay/ORG data 1973-2003: Accounting for the Rising Frequency ofHourly Pay Residual Male 90/10 Inequality in CPS May/ORG: Observed Residual Female 90/10 Inequality and Hourly Pay Constant in CPS ftey/ORG Observed and Hourly Pay Constant B*=. tOr— s 1973 1976 > 1979 1982 1-985 Residual IWale 90/50 Inequality 1988 » Observsl 90/1G in 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 1973 CPS May/ORG: Observed 1976 « rimrtrPsyConaanl 1974 and Hourty Pay Constant 1979 1982 1985 1988 « Otiserved 90/10 Residual Female 90/50 Inequality in 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 Hoiffiy?^(;anraffi'!S4 CPS May/ORG: Observed and Hourty Pay Constant Sin 1973 1976 e 1979 1985 1982 Residual Male 50/10 Inequality 1988 « Observed 90/50 in 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 1973 CPS May/ORG: Observed 1976 e Hourly Pay Constant 1974 and Hourty Pay Constant 1979 1982 1985 1991 Residual Female 50/10 Inequality 1994 1997 2000 2003 Hourly Pay Constant 1974 Observed 90/50 in CPS May/ORG: Observed and Hourly Pay Constant Sin- 1973 1976 ' 1979 1982 Observed 50/10 1985 1988 » 1991 Hourly 1994 1997 Pay Constant 1974 2000 2003 1973 1976 » 1979 1982 Observed 50/10 1985 19 — 1991 1994 1997 Hourly Pay Constant 1974 2000 2003 Figure 9. Estimated Hourly Pay Bias for Residual 90/10 Inequality by Gender Hourly Pay Bias in IVlale in CPS May/ORG, 1973 90/10 Residual Inequality in - 2003 CPS May/ORG: Corrected-Observed "a r^ TO Q. "a CO £ o crtM CO (U CO Oo 1 1973 1 1979 1976 Hourly Pay Bias in 1982 1985 1^ 1991 1994 1997 Understatement of 90/10 Residual Inequality (left Chain-Weighted Share (right axis) of Female 90/10 Residual Males Paid Hourly Inequality in 2000 2003 axis) CPS May/ORG: Connected-Observed CO ca E o • CO Oo to O) O 1973 1976 1979 1982 Understatement 1985 1991 of 90/10 Residual Inequality Chain-Weighted Share of 1994 (left Females Paid Hourly 1997 axis) (right axis) 2000 2003 >- ^' ro o > rr -S* Q) CD 3 c E f? ' (D Q) _C E ::3 o u5 (D > O T3 (U _ro E El 21 VI 91. S'l. O!)EJ^BBM0^/06 Boi V'l Z'l Z'l ri Z\- I'l o!}ej96emoi,/06 6oi E £L 2'1. 0!)BJ 36emoi,/05 LL Bo"| 9'L SI VI i'l o!]bj36b/«oi./06 Bo"! tr CO OT Q o rn ce >- o 4-1 CO en 03 cr CO 3 (U c H-t cu CD :^ CD ^ cr en m ^ 3 T3 cr ^ cc IT ce o 5; Em o (n ID a: (U CD F Oo 4-J in 3 E Sll m 901 96' 98' 931. 9I.1. 901. 95' O!)BJ0L/06Bo| ORBJ 01./06 6o| tn •a (D e (U U) JD O u_ O c o U) 1_ ro Q. CD cn S2 CD m > a> (T Q fi rr E o u en cz fM 0) L. 3 Ol 00 ;>:• ro 3 cr X T3 C en OJ 0) 03 ce ca OJ 5? OJ Q. Q. < o 911 SOI. oiiej 56' 01/06 6o| 98' 921 911 90'L oijejol/OBBoi 96' Table 1. 100 x Changes in Overall and Residual Hourly Earnings Inequality: 1973 - 2003 (March CPS) 2003 - (May/ORG CPS) and 1975 B. Residual Inequality A. Overall Inequality 1973- 1988- 1973- 1979- 1989- 1979- 1973- 1988- 1973- 1988* 2003 2003* 1989 1999 1988* 2003 2003* 1999 1979- 1989- 19791989 1999 1999 Males May/ORG CPS 90-10 90-50 50-10 21.0 10.1 10.9 9.1 13.8 -4.7 30.2 24.0 6.2 9.5 1.2 7.3 21.0 17.0 3.0 -0.4 4.1 6.4 3.8 -2.7 14.2 9.7 6.9 4.5 10.6 6.8 8.5 -2.1 6.4 2.9 3.7 3.8 5.6 0.9 -3.0 2.6 5.1 -2.5 12.6 9.4 2.6 March CPS 90-10 90-50 50-10 19.1 10.7 8.4 13.2 14.4 32.3 25.1 -1.2 7.1 17.3 10.6 6.7 5.3 6.6 -1.4 22.6 17.3 12.0 8.3 5.2 7.9 20.3 13.1 10.0 4.3 5.3 6.8 0.4 7.2 5.7 3.0 19.5 18.2 -1.9 16.3 3.7 3.2 Females May/ORG CPS 90-10 90-50 50-10 25.1 10.5 14.7 9.9 10.1 -0.2 35.0 20.5 14.5 30.4 9.1 8.0 10.3 22.4 -1.2 39.6 18.3 21.2 16.5 7.8 2.3 10.1 3.8 -0.1 8.7 0.7 9.3 14.4 -1.8 12.6 15.5 6.1 5.4 5.2 3.3 3.4 17.4 8.6 9.6 0.7 21.6 11.3 10.3 14.1 5.9 8.9 -0.1 8.8 March CPS 90-10 90-50 50-10 9.1 14.6 9.6 14.0 5.0 23.1 37.7 18.7 19.0 24.3 8.4 8.3 4.9 16.0 3.5 32.7 13.2 19.5 * March hourly series begin in 1975 rather than 1973. Source data: May/ORG CPS 1973 - 2003 and March CPS 1976 2004. Table 2. 100 x Changes in Male Hourly Earnings Inequality Within Narrow Education and Experience Categories: 1976 to 1988 and 1988 to 2002 (May/ORG and March CPS) Colleqe Grad uate Potn'l 1976 Exp ORG - 1988 March Ma les 1988 - ORG High School Giraduate Males 2002 March 14-16 24-26 34-36 14-16 24-26 34-36 14-16 24-26 34-36 1988 ORG - 2002 March 17.4 14.3 5.5 10.7 7.6 8.4 -15.3 3.2 (4.5) (2.9) (4.6) (2.1) (2.4) (2.0) (2.7) 8.6 -0.8 14.2 21.2 15.6 28.2 -3.6 -5.5 (6.6) (6.7) (3.1) (6.0) (2.3) (3.6) (1.8) (3.1) 5.1 -0.8 7.9 18.2 4.0 25.3 -0.2 -4.0 (7.9) (7.3) (4.6) (6.4) (3.9) (3.9) (2.0) (3 A) 7.6 27.5 -7.1 16.5 14.7 22.6 -6.8 -0.1 (13.7) (10.1) (8.6) (10.4) (3.1) (4.4) (2.8) (4.8) 90/50 5.0 2.0 6.6 10.7 4.9 4.8 -3.0 7.1 (1.9) (2.4) (1.8) (2.4) (1.6) (1.8) (1.8) (2.0) 8.1 4.7 10.1 18.0 9.2 11.0 7.8 3.7 (3.7) (3.5) (2.4) (3.3) (1.4) (1.8) (1.4) (2.0) 4.8 0.7 1.1 12.6 1.7 5.3 3.9 8.3 (6.8) (6.1) (3.9) (5.9) (2.2) (2.7) (1.4) (2.2) -1.2 7.6 -5.9 15.0 1.9 6.4 5.5 8.7 (9.0) (6.6) (5.5) (5.9) (2.1) (3.4) (2.2) (3.9) C. 4-6 1988 March (2.6) B. 4-6 ORG - 90/10 A. 4-6 1976 50/10 12.3 12.3 -1.1 0.0 2.7 3.5 -12.3 -3.9 (2.3) (4.0) (2.5) (4.1) (1.7) (2.0) (1.3) (2.4) 0.5 -5.4 4.0 3.2 7.3 17,2 -11.4 -9.2 (5.2) (6.2) (2.3) (4.9) (1.9) (3.2) (1.2) (2.4) 0.3 -1.5 6.8 5.6 2.3 20.0 -4.1 -12.3 (5.2) (5.9) (3.2) (4.7) (3.2) (3.1) (2.0) (2.8) 8.8 19.8 -1.2 1.5 12.7 16.2 -12.3 -8.9 (10.6) (8.7) (6.5) (8.9) (2.9) (3.9) (2.3) (3.8) Source data: May/ORG CPS 1975 2003 and March CPS 1976 2004. on indicated year. Standarderrors in parentheses are bootstrapped using 100 replications. College graduates are those with 16 or 17 years of completed schooling (surveys prior to 1992) or a baccalaureate degree only (1992 forward). See the Data Appendix for further details. - Statistics pool three years of data centered - Table 3. 100 x Changes in Female Hourly Earnings Inequality Within Narrow Education and Experience Categories: 1976 to 1988 and 1988 to 2002 (May/ORG and March CPS) High School Greiduate Females College Gradijate Females Potn'l 1976 Exp ORG - 1988 March 1988 - ORG 2002 1976 March ORG 14-16 24-26 34-36 16.2 10.6 0.6 14-16 24-26 34-36 14-16 24-26 34-36 - 2002 March 13.6 8.4 -14.2 0.4 (1-7) (3.0) (1.7) (3.1) (3.2) (4.9) (2.7) (4.4) 7.8 -1.4 10.5 25.2 15.1 14.8 -11.7 -4.6 (3.4) (1.6) (3.1) (5.8) (7.1) (2.8) (5.1) (1.9) 14.0 3.3 11.4 8.9 19.4 15.2 -6.1 -0.7 (5.2) (8.9) (2.4) (6.9) (2.8) (4.2) (1.9) (3.2) 33.5 30.6 6.5 12.4 17.0 3.6 -6.4 9.1 (8.7) (14.6) (7.2) (11.6) (2.9) (4.3) (2.2) (4.5) 90/50 4.7 9.2 4.5 2.5 5.3 2.5 -5.6 3.3 (2.4) (3.1) (1.9) (2.7) (1.4) (2.4) (1.6) (2.7) -0.7 -0.5 8.1 14.5 2.4 6.7 -4.9 -3.4 (3.8) (5.3) (2.4) (3.0) (2.1) (2.3) (1.3) (2.3) 12.7 -2.0 8.0 10.2 7.7 8.1 0.1 -0.7 (4.0) (4.4) (2.3) (3.3) (2.6) (2.9) (1.6) (2.5) 11.1 12.1 7.9 14.2 6.8 -2.7 0.5 2.1 (6.5) (8.6) (4.0) (8.6) (2.7) (3.4) (1.9) (3.3) C. 4-6 1988 ORG 1.3 B. 4-6 1988 March 90/10 A. 4-6 - 50/10 11.5 1.4 -3.9 -1.3 8.2 6.0 -8.7 -2.9 (2.1) (4.0) (2.0) (3.5) (1.1) (2.3) (1.2) (2.2) 8.6 -0.9 2.4 10.7 12.7 8.1 -6.9 -1.3 (4.8) (4,9) (2.1) (4.2) (1.7) (2.4) (1.4) (2.4) 1.3 5.3 3.4 -1.4 11.7 7.1 -6.2 0.0 (4.7) (7.9) (2.5) (6.3) (1.8) (3.1) (1.4) (2.4) 22.4 18.5 -1.5 -1.8 10.2 6.4 -7.0 7.0 (6.9) (12.0) (6.6) (8.9) (2.3) (3.0) (1.8) (2.8) Source data: May/ORG CPS 1975 2003 and March CPS 1976 2004. on indicated year. Standarderrors in parentheses are bootstrapped using 100 replications. College graduates are those with 16 or 17 years of completed schooling (surveys prior to 1992) or a baccalaureate degree only (1992 forward). See the Data Appendix for further details. - Statistics pool three years of data centered - Table 4. Quantile JMP Decompositions of Hourly Earnings Inequality into Price and Quantity Components, May/ORG CPS 1973 (100 X log point 1973 Total - 1988 1988 Quan- Btwn Within tities Prices Prices 90-10 90-50 50-10 21.1 9.9 11.2 -1.0 16.8 0.4 -1.4 9.0 90-10 90-50 50-10 21.1 9.9 0.0 -3.0 14.4 11.2 3.0 4.5 7.9 9.9 Total 25.0 11.5 13.5 90-10 90-50 50-10 25.0 11.5 13.5 - 1973 2003 Btwn Within titles Prices Prices Total A. Males Order: Quantities, Between B's, Witiiin B's -3.8 5.3 7.9 4.8 7.0 29.0 0.6 12.7 0.5 8.1 4.1 22.6 -4.8 -1.2 -7.9 4.7 4.3 6.4 Order: Within B's, Between B's, Quantities -1.3 6.7 7.9 4.3 4.9 29.0 3.0 12.7 0.5 5.3 5.9 22.6 -2.0 -7.2 3.7 -4.8 4.4 6.4 - 2003 Quan- Btwn Within tities Prices Prices 22.7 17.0 2.6 3.0 0.6 5.7 0.0 6.8 -J.VJ 0.1 19.2 14.2 6.7 5.0 -5.3 10.7 12.5 11.9 4.1 6.7 10.3 6.6 5.9 1.5 3.6 2.6 3 n 8.3 Females 2.2 9.5 -2.4 5.3 3.6 3.7 Order: Quantities, Between B's, Witliin B's 13.3 10.3 5.0 5.1 0.2 35.2 6.0 9.6 1.8 3.1 4.8 21.1 -4.6 6.1 0.7 3.2 2.1 14.2 4.3 7.0 Order: Witliin B's, Between B's, Quantities 13.6 -3.0 10.3 10.1 3.2 35.2 13.6 10.7 1.2 3.2 7.1 9.6 2.3 3.6 3.7 21.1 3.9 8.0 10.9 9.2 3.2 3.8 6.5 0.7 7.9 -0.4 -6.8 14.2 9.7 2.7 1.7 Source data: May/ORG CPS 1973 procedure. 2003 Quan- B. 90-10 90-50 50-10 - changes) - 2003. See text for details of quantile decomposition Table 5. Quantile JMP Decompositions of Hourly Earnings Components, March CPS 1975 (100 X 1975 Total - • log point 1988 1988 Quan- Btwn Within tities Prices Prices Total Inequality into Price and Quantity 2003 - changes) - 1975- 2003 2003 - Quan- Btwn Within titles Prices Prices Total Quan- Btwn Within tities Prices Prices A. Males Order: Quantities, Between B's, Witiiin B's 90-10 90-50 50-10 18.8 -0.6 8.2 11.1 13.4 2.1 5.6 5.7 32.1 2.8 14.3 15.1 9.5 -1.2 5.8 4.8 14.5 -1.4 6.3 24.0 1.2 11.5 11.2 9.3 0.6 2.4 6.3 -1.1 3.5 -0.7 9.6 -3.9 8.2 1.6 2.7 3.9 90-10 90-50 50-10 18.8 9.5 1.0 -1.1 6.4 4.0 9.3 2.1 2.4 Order: Within 11.4 13.4 6.6 14.5 4.7 -1.1 5.5 6.3 1.6 4.3 4.3 9.5 -1.6 2.1 9.0 19.7 3.9 2.0 7.8 4.5 2.3 3.0 -0.8 18.2 2.8 -1.5 6.5 4.6 7.1 4.3 2.0 7.5 23.9 10.2 13.7 90-10 90-50 50-10 23.9 10.2 13.7 Quantities 5.9 4.7 7.6 1.5 9.4 9.0 14.9 5.2 32.1 24.0 7.9 1.7 1.0 0.7 -2.8 8.2 6.3 0.4 1.4 Order: Quantities, Between B's, Witiiin B's 12.1 14.0 0.7 5.2 8.2 37.9 7.5 11.7 18.7 1.9 5.5 12.3 5.6 6.2 6.4 0.1 11.0 16.8 2.5 7.4 9.7 7.6 3.6 7.1 Order: Witiiin 14.5 14.0 Source data: March CPS 1976 procedure. B's, 2.7 B. 90-10 90-50 50-10 Between B's, - B's, 13.4 Females Between B's, Quantities 4.6 4.9 9.5 4.5 -0.4 4.8 5.1 4.5 4.9 -0.2 -0.2 37.9 19.7 18.2 2004. See text for details of quantile decomposition Table 6. 100 x Observed and Composition-Constant Changes Overall Hourly Inequality Measures A. M ay/ORG CPS B. 1973- 1988- 1973- 1975- 1988 2003 2003 1988 in March CPS 198819752003 2003 A Male 90/10 Observed 1973 X's* 1988 X's 2003 X's 21.1 7.9 29.0 18.8 13.4 32.1 21.1 22.1 1.1 22.2 17.7 5.5 24.3 3.0 19.3 10.7 30.0 22.2 3.1 25.2 25.3 18.1 11.2 29.3 6.S 14.5 11.8 12.8 15.9 24.0 22.4 23.4 22.7 8.2 A Male 90/50 Observed 1973 X's* 1988 X's 2003 X's 9.9 12.9 12.7 9.5 7.4 12.2 9.5 12.2 22.6 22.5 21.8 19.6 9.5 10.6 10.7 A Male 50/10 Observed 1973 X's* 1988 X's 2003 X's 11.2 8.2 12.6 14.8 -4.8 5.4 93 -1.1 -8.5 -0.3 7.1 -5.3 1.8 -9.2 3.4 8.7 -2.1 5.5 -9.1 5.7 11.3 -4.6 6.5 23.9 21.1 18.4 14.0 5.7 17.1 13.3 37.9 27.8 27.9 30.4 A Female 90/10 Observed 1973 X's* 1988 X's 2003 X's 25.0 20.5 22.8 19.2 10.3 1.0 0.1 5.3 35.2 21.5 22.9 24.5 9.5 A Femahe 90/50 Observed 1973 X's* 1988 X's 2003 X's 11.5 9.5 21.1 10.3 6.9 17.1 12.9 7.4 20.3 8.6 9.9 18.5 9.1 7.9 17.0 6.7 11.1 17.8 10.2 11.7 19.7 17.2 9.5 5.5 A Femah2 50/10 Observed 13.5 0.7 14.2 13.7 -5.9 1973 X's* 10.3 4.5 9.4 -7.2 1988 X's 9.9 2.5 9.8 -2.5 2003 X's 10.1 10.4 7.5 Source data: May/ORG CPS 1973 - 2003 and March CPS 4.5 18.2 1.2 10.7 -0.4 9.4 12.5 2,2 1975 - 2004. Table 7. 100 x Observed and Composition-Constant Changes in Residual Hourly Inequality l^easures May/ORG CPS A. B. 1973- 1988- 1973- 1975- 1988 2003 2003 1988 March CPS 198819752003 2003 A Male 90/10 Observed 1973 X's* 1988 X's 2003 X's 10.2 0.4 10.6 13.2 7.6 11.5 -5.1 6.4 14.3 3.7 18.1 11.4 10.3 -3.6 7.8 6.3 20.1 -2.1 8.1 13.8 12.5 7.0 19.6 7.3 13.1 20.8 A Male 90/50 Observed 1973 X's* 1988 X's 2003 X's 3.6 2.9 6.6 5.8 5.8 1.5 7.3 6^ 6.0 3.6 2.3 5.9 6.1 5.8 12.3 13.0 1.6 2.5 4.1 5.3 7.6 12.9 A Male 50/10 Observed 1973 X's* 1988 X's 2003 X's 6.6 -2.5 4.1 7.4 0.3 7.7 5.7 -6.6 -0.9 8.0 -2.3 5.7 7.7 7.2 -0.5 7.2 -0.5 6.7 6.7 21.4 2.0 15.5 3.9 17.3 5.8 20.1 11.2 7.8 -5.9 1.9 8.7 -4.6 4.1 A Female 90/10 Observed 1973 X's* 1988 X's 2003 X's 15.9 3.1 19.0 13.5 -1.5 12.0 13.8 -2.6 11.2 14.7 13.5 13.4 13.6 -0.6 13.0 14.3 A Female 90/50 Observed 1973 X's* 1988 X's 2003 X's 7.5 2.4 9.9 5.9 5.3 6.9 -0.5 6.3 6.6 1.6 8.2 6.5 -0.4 6.0 5.4 3.7 9.1 5.6 1.9 7.5 5.0 5.9 10.9 10.2 A Female 50/10 Observed 8.4 0.7 -1.0 1973 X's* 6.6 -2.2 1988 X's 7.3 -2.4 2003 X's 7.9 Source data: May/ORG CPS 1973 - 9.1 8.9 1.4 5.7 6.9 0.4 7.3 5.1 8.0 0.2 8.2 5.5 9.3 -0.1 2003 and March CPS 1976 9.1 - 2004. Appendix Table 1. 100 x Changes 1973 A. Overall I in - Overall and Residual Full-Time 2003: May/ORG and March CPS nequality 1973- 1988- 19731988 2003 2003 Weekly Earnings Inequality, B. 1979- 1989- 19791989 1999 1999 Residual Inequal ity 1973- 1988- 1973- 1979- 1989- 1979- 1988 1989 2003 2003 1999 1999 Males May/ORG CPS 90-10 90-50 50-10 34.0 16.4 17.6 9.6 11.6 -2.0 43.6 28.0 15.6 26.9 17.4 9.6 5.6 6.8 -1.2 32.5 24.2 24.9 13.3 13.4 8.3 11.7 28.5 11.8 10.2 5.6 38.7 17.4 5.2 38.3 21.5 16.8 16.7 4.6 21.3 8.2 March CPS 90-10 90-50 50-10 23.2 9.8 17.9 15.7 13.4 2.2 41.2 25.5 15.7 20. 11.2 9.6 10.3 10.5 31.3 21.7 17.5 10.4 28.0 12.8 6.3 7.0 8.8 15.8 6.1 5.0 19.0 11.1 0.0 9.6 10.5 1.6 12.2 6.7 1.3 8.0 Females May/ORG CPS 90-10 90-50 50-10 22.3 8.6 13.7 10.4 13.7 3.3 36.0 19.0 17.0 24.6 7.4 17.2 12.6 7.8 4.8 37.2 15.2 16.1 8.4 3.2 18.6 5.4 24.5 15.0 15.4 9.6 5.1 3.6 8.8 22.0 6.5 3.0 9.5 10.2 -0.4 9.8 25.2 15.0 10.2 18.8 2.6 21.4 5.8 3.3 9.1 13.0 -0.6 12.3 March CPS 90-10 90-50 50-10 18.5 6.8 11.7 8.7 8.0 0.7 27.2 14.8 12.3 Source data: May/ORG CPS 1973 14.5 4.7 19.2 19.5 5.7 6.7 4.4 11.1 9.7 5.3 7.9 0.3 8.1 9.8 0.4 - 2003 and March CPS 1974 - 2004. C 1 ) cn rM i-H rsl T-H T-H IX) U3 o LTI ro r^ T-l tH tH o o tH Ln LD in O O en fN QJ W Ql o 00 O in r^ rNj in Ln ID Ln U3 ID 00 ID cn VD m o O rM ro o o o O o 00 O tH rM 1— rsl o o o o o 1^ Ln o Ln Ln ^D Ln Ln o o o o O O 00 U3 Ln Ln ID Ln rsl t-f (N I-NJ QJ ro o Dl TO ::^ T3 4-J 'l_ 0) ro QJ U CTi i-H t-H tH 1-H i-H o 1^ <U u c rM m 00 Ln Ln o o o o o o CO rM i-H f-H q q 00 oo in u ID o 00 1^ ID CO i\ o o o o o iH ro O Ln q q q q Ln Ln 1— ID Ln rM rM (X) CJi rM rM o o o o o U3 o (M IN rM i-H 1/1 rM r^ rM 1-H X) c c o rsl QJ OJ 'l_ OJ o ro o o o o rsl X tH T-H 1—1 i-H 1— ro U5 O o Ln o o O O o (J ro ro cn VD rM CO to Q. 00 X C TO C o O O q q q •— rM ro CO CT'. ro o tH rM rM o o O o o Ln O CO rM o VD o o o O o cn o Ln Ln Ln ID CO Ln Ln '5; 1^ Ln CTi uo rsj I-H -"-f U o 1_ rM O h o o CL U rM ro .-1 I-H rsl rsj ro (.'J JZ 1_ ro D "a "^ i_ CJ O , — ro U Ol O r^ rsl ID ID i-v ro LO 00 ro rsi VD q q q q CO ro Ln UJ rM TJ- ,-H Ln uo rsj cri UJ ro Ln UJ in UJ CO rsl UJ CO UJ UJ UJ CD ro 00 cn U) o U UJ ro ro rsl (1) u r cn rsl rM 00 rsl rsl rsl ro 1-H U) Ln rv rv 1-H rsl rsl rM r^ ro i_ ro > o Q a QJ rsl rsl <-> Ln cn UJ U) o m Ln ro o o o o O o rM O q q ro rsl CD ro ro r-. en Ln t-t rsl rsj Ln CO O o o o o o CO q r^ q r^ rsl <r ID rsl rv ro cn ro _QJ "o I en CI Qi OJ > OJ -* Ln O S o 0^ 1-1 5? cr 1-H O i_ =) I-H 5: q: >^ 1— o o 1^ O o O o o t3 LO ID rsj o in i_ ru (D .c ro u rsl , rv rsl UJ rv. cri rsl rsl 1-H ro ro o 1-H 1-H iH 1-H c o o !;; rsi cn QJ 13 q CO TO 00 1-H rsl rsl Ln ro m LD UJ o o o o o o ro CO UJ in r^ CO rsl 00 Ln cn UJ ro UJ rsl Ln rsl rv r^ ro U3 o o o o o 1-H Ln o rsj ro o o o o O u> ID 1-H Ln rv ro rv r^ i\ UJ T-l rsl rsl rv ro rsl ro rv ro r^ CTi ro ro 03 ro UJ ro i\ ro r^ rsl ^§ ^ O I CO CO a^ n u i_ Ln f in ^ ro -t CTl O o o fM O a: O QJ > o o rtJ rsl rsl o Ln UJ "^ o o Ln Ln rv UJ ro U) ro cn ro UJ ^3- Ln UJ I-H I-H tH 1-H iH CO UJ ro I-H 1-H ro rsl i-H T-H I-H 1-H 1-H cn rM CJJ 1-H ro CO 1-H rsl CTi q (N o o CO o o o o •I-H ^_ Ln _aj rsl CO UJ rv rv. 00 00 Ln UJ UJ LO 1^ CO '"' Ln 00 UJ Ln Ln Ln o d cJ dl ro CO rsl Ln CO UJ rsj rv o rv rv Ln UJ cn UJ OJ UJ o o 1^ UJ '^ Ln o 1-H Tj- UJ UJ UJ q r^ CO UJ ro 00 CO d ^ 72 1^ [V. CO Ln rsl rsl rsj rsl ro ro ro CO rM rsl ro ro rv CM 03 rv rsl oo 1-H rsl ro ro ro Ln rv OJ 1-H rsl ro LO rv al o o o CL u rM UJ o rv rsl ro rsl rsl rsl d d rsl O >ro jQ CO o UJ rv cn rv rsl 1-H rsl I-H rsl Ln ro Ln UJ UJ Ln CTi Ln ^D Ln ro U) UJ U3 rsl U) CO U) 00 rsl 1-H rsl U) rM rsj d d c QJ U) Q. CL < ro O O O d rsl O CL UJ ro 03 ro UJ UJ rM U) ro 00 ro UJ UJ UJ 1-H rsl UJ ro 00 ro rsl UJ ro rsl ro UJ UJ I UJ rsj ro rsl ro 1-H rsl ro r iH 2 o o rsi rsi I/) rsi rsi i_ T-H T-i CO LD T-H r-i m O o O I 'J Qi in n in in vn o o o o o m ^ to ^ o o o o o 00 CO o Ln Ln Ln Ln Ln Ln 1—1 ( Ln ID Ln rsi in CTl in 1^ CO Ln o "i_ o en in OD in 1-H r\i I-H rM rH T-4 tH I-H rH CTl QJ -M ra U (U u c T^ O o q; rM o in en en cn I-H T-H o rsl I-H i-H 1-H 1-H o i-t T-H 1-H 1-H 1-H Ln en rM en cn en 00 sT 1-H rsl Ln CTl m m Ln o o o o o Ln Ln 00 Ln in Ln 1^ Ln Ln Ln rM Ln in in Ln uo in en Ln o o o o rn Ln Ln Ln Ln Ln in Ln r^ rsi fNJ rsi rsi 1^ rM iH tH in CO T-i T-t 00 tH r~^ T-i dl o dl (6 dl QJ m rM o o o o o rsi rM in rM rsi ro en en CO I-H I-H I-H T-H rsj ID o m Ln ^3- CO iH 'i_ 0) Q- X LU a TO X jO in ro ro m Ln Ln Ln Ln Ln o o o o o vn o rM Ln cn ro ro o o o o o o o Ln Ln Ln 1-H o O O O o o 00 1-H rsl 1-H rsl rsl rM rsl LO Ln ^H 1-H 1-H rH LO rM ro Ln ro ro J-J ID U ,— 5 p t ITJ , Ln Q- u if > -D ^ 2 O O rM 1-H 1-H 1-H tH 1-H Ln o ro 00 in ro rM ro Ln ro in cn Ln 1-H rsl in Ln Ln q TO n r (D o a: -:1 >-i en c > t= ( t5 d: fD U CD UJ '^ X Dl r I) i_ U m T—t 00 CO t^ rsl A <r in ro in in Ln in rM Ln Ln Ln rsl Ln 00 vn T-H rsl in 1^ in rsl ro 1^ ro o o rv en 00 rsl 1-H rsj I-H cn Ln Ln o o o o O ro in cn t~^ o ro Ln Ln Ln Ln Ln CM ro Ln CD U in Ln Ln in ro in d) u r Ln 1-H rM ro rN in ro L. ro > o Q in LO o rsl CD Ln ro rM rsl rsl rsl rM ro ro rsl rsl rM rsl rsl in o tv a: ij L. rsi o o rM 1-H 1-H rN 1-H iH 1—4 cn 00 rsl ro CO en o m in rsl 1-H Ln 1-H o O o O o 1^ in ro O cn Ln in in ID in o o o o o en rsl 1-H rM rM in ro I-H rsl O o o o O 5: r en o 00 rM i-H o O rsl 1-H (D "5 o CJ S O cn _aj fNJ ) i_ ro tn OJ en .E o Ln ro o CO o o o o CO m vn vn o o o o o (.'J U rM 1-H ct: .E vn vn (J LU l-'J Qi 00 o en o 1-H 1-H O 1-H Ln 00 Ln o Ln I-H 1-H I-H 1-H 1-H 1-H rN CTl Ln ro ro ro rsl Ln Ln rM I-H cn sT 1-H OJ Ln ro I-H I-H ro rsl in ro 1-H 1-H 1-H 1-H ro ro cn rM in CO rM en o Ln in CO o o o o o o Ln Ln Ln OD 00 r^ 1^ o Ln 1^ in in in CO uo r^ in in 00 in > OJ rsl in Ln rsl vn rM Ln O O Ln ro Ln in 00 in ro |\ CO r^ rsl ro Ln sT cn CO in 00 1-H 1-H 1-H 1-H 1-H Ln ro ro ro cn PM CO CO O en vn rsl o o o o 6 ro Ln n vn in o o o o o d Ln r^ o 1-H I-H 1.0 ro cn m CO in in m in o o o o o Ln Ln ro rM o Ln n in in 1-H rsl ro rsl d cn rN en rM CO rM rsl r^ rsl rsl Ln rM CM u o o o o ro Ln rsl rsl in in en Ln en Ln 00 Ln 03 Ln cn Ln 1^ Ln l\ Ln rsj rM ro rM "drsl rsl rsl o d d a: o >fD in en 1- C OJ Q. < O a. LU ^ 4 in I-H o o o o in rM in ro rsl ro 00 00 rsl Ln o in cn Ln o in 1^ Ln Ln in Ln in Ln cn CO "3- 1-H 1-H 1-H d d d in in n rsl ro rsl ro 00 ro in PM in ro rM ro 00 ro vn in in 1-H rsl vn ro rsl ro Appendix Table 3a. Quantile JMP Decompositions of Hourly Earnings Inequality into Price and May/ORG CPS 1973 - 2003: Model Using Quartic in Potential Experience (100 X log point changes) ^ Quantity Connponents 1973 Total - 1988 1988 Quan- Btwn Within titles Prices Prices Total - 2003 1973 Quan- Btwn Within titles Prices Prices Total - 2003 Quan- Btwn Within titles Prices Prices A. Males Order: Quantities, 90-10 90-50 50-10 21.9 11.3 10.6 90-10 90-50 50-10 21.9 Between B's, Within B's 7.0 -3.7 11.0 4.9 0.7 7.1 3.1 -2.8 4.1 -0.2 -6.8 30.0 22.3 7.7 23.3 17.4 3.6 2.3 0.8 5.9 1.0 Order. Within B's, Between B's, Quantities -2.4 7.5 8.1 5.5 5.1 30.0 0.0 15.7 6.2 8.1 0.5 -0.5 9.6 1.3 6.1 5.0 13.6 11.3 0.8 -0.9 8.6 3.7 10.6 1.7 5.0 3.9 2.6 8.8 17.4 3.9 0.8 5.5 4.6 22.3 1.2 4.7 -0.5 -7.0 7.7 7.6 12.9 4.5 8.2 -4.4 Order: Quantities, Between B's, Witiiin B's 12.5 9.9 4.8 5.1 0.0 35.0 8.4 14.8 11.7 3.1 7.9 10.0 5.3 6,9 1.7 12.0 12.4 10.6 3.2 8.5 9.3 8.8 3.8 1.3 11.0 -2.8 B. Females 90-10 90-50 50-10 25.1 12.3 12.8 1.8 -0.5 10.8 5.7 7.1 8.8 1.1 3.3 4.5 2.3 5.1 5.5 1.1 3.7 1.8 -4.5 90-10 90-50 50-10 25.1 12.3 3.5 8.5 13.1 9.9 9.0 3.4 -2.6 1.2 4.2 6.9 8.8 2.6 3.2 3.1 12.8 2.3 4.3 6.2 1.1 6.5 0.3 -5.7 Order: Witiiin Source data: May/ORG CPS 1973 procedure. 3.1 - B's, Between 21.1 13.9 B's, Quantities 35.0 21.1 13.9 2003. See text for details of quantile decomposition Appendix Table 3b. Quantile JMP Decompositions of Hourly Earnings Inequality into Price and Quantity Components, March CPS 1975 - 2003: Model Using Quartic in Potential Experience (100 X log point changes) 1975 Total - 1988 1988 Quan- Btwn Within tities Prices Prices Total - 2003 1975 Quan- Btwn Within titles Prices Prices A. Total - 2003 Quan- Btwn Within tities Prices Prices 10.0 Males Order: Quantities, Between B's, Within B's 90-10 90-50 50-10 17.5 8.3 90-10 90-50 50-10 -1.0 9.8 8.7 10.3 2.6 3.7 4.0 16.2 5.9 2.1 12.9 -0.5 3.5 9.9 27.8 21.2 1.6 1.9 11.8 7.6 9.2 0.3 -1.3 3.9 6.6 -2.6 3.1 0.2 -5.9 6.6 -0.2 4.4 2.5 17.5 -0.3 8.2 6.6 8.3 -0.8 4.8 1.4 11.4 8.2 11.7 9.2 0.5 3.4 5.2 3.3 -1.9 13.1 Order: Within B's, Between B's, Quantities 9.6 10.3 23 4.8 3.0 27.8 -0.2 4.4 12.9 4.4 8.7 21.2 -5.7 -2.6 5.2 2.7 0.4 6.6 B. Females Order: Quantities, Between B's, Wittiin B's 90-10 90-50 50-10 18.6 9.5 2.3 7.7 8.6 13.5 1.9 5.7 5.9 0.3 3.8 5.4 8.4 -1.4 3.8 6.1 9.1 2.0 3.9 3.2 5.1 3.3 2.0 -0.2 90-10 90-50 50-10 18.6 1.0 6.6 11.0 9.5 -0.7 3.9 9.1 1.7 2.6 Order: Within Source data: March CPS 1976 procedure. - B's, 9.8 Between B's, 32.2 17.9 14.2 5.6 13.5 0.9 8.1 8.9 4.6 5.4 4.3 10.0 10.3 11.8 1.6 7.5 8.8 8.4 2.8 3.0 Quantities 5.7 4.9 3.0 6.3 13.5 8.4 0.5 4.0 3.9 4.7 5.1 5.2 0.9 -0.9 32.2 17.9 14.2 2004. See text for details of quantile decomposition 1 -''^ Li '^ r 33 MAR 2 4 2006 Date Due MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02527 9669