iiiii$iiiii3i H.I.T. LIBRARIES - DEV^Y Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/measurementerrorOOpisc ® working paper department of economics massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 MEASUREMENT ERROR AND EARNINGS DYNAMICS: Some Estimates from the PSID Validation Study Jorn-Stef f en Pischke Dec. 93 94-1 APR 5 1994 Measurement Error and Earnings Dynamics: Some Estimates From the PSID Validation Study Jorn-Steffen Pischke Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Cambridge, MA 02139-4307 November 1992 Revised: December 1993 Measurement Error and Earnings Dynamics: Some Estimates From the PSID Validation Study Jbrn-Steffen Pischke ABSTRACT Previous empirical work on measurement error in survey earnings data has shown that the variance of the measurement error is roughly constant over time, and it is it is negatively correlated with true earnings, autocorrelated with previous measurement errors. where the measurement error stems from underreporting of white noise component. The model implies that there will be some fits This paper proposes a simple model transitory earnings fluctuations and a well to data from the PSID Validation Study. While it bias in estimates of variances and autocovariances these biases are of the same magnitude so that autocorrelations will be estimated roughly correctly. Keywords: Panel estimator. data, reporting error, income, covariance structure model, minimum distance INTRODUCTION 1. It is widely recognized that measurement error survey data and that errors-in-variables can lead is a pervasive phenomenon to inconsistent estimates in models. In a linear regression context, attenuation bias"can be cured available. if in microeconomic many econometric suitable instruments are Empirical studies trying to identify, for example, earnings or consumption processes typically have to ignore metric structure (e.g. measurement error altogether or assume that it follows a particular para- uncorrelated white noise). Absent any direct knowledge about the properties of the measurement error process such assumptions are invariably necessary for identification. This paper tries to establish some simple relationships between measurement error and the dynamics of true earnings. Systematic research on response error plays an important role in other social sciences (see Sudman and Bradburn 1974) but little work has been undertaken properties of reporting error in earnings data. The few to assess the magnitude and studies that have tried to obtain validation common variables to assess the extent of measurement error directly make assumptions highly questionable. The earlier studies have usually obtained two inde- in this area the identifying pendent observations on the same variable. Both these records were potentially error ridden. The study by Mellow and Sider (1983) employee-employer responses results of separate little to for the insight on the direct nature of the was undertaken by They obtained an example of two variables. measurement as the team claims They used matched Such studies can be instructive but yield error. researchers at the Institute for Social Research at the University of Michigan. payroll records at a cooperating firm and simultaneously administered the Panel PSID to approach. trying to obtain accurate validation records for typical labor market variables Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) questionnaire known this Current Population Survey (CPS) questions and compared the wage regressions The first study is Validation Study). have obtained very Due to the to careful covered employees (the study is therefore checking of the firm records the research reliable validation information. Their results are reported in Duncan and Hill (1985) and Duncan and Mathiowetz (1985). This study has an optimistic message: % more than 80 results was of the variability of earnings measurement that the CPS sets, like the occasions for the purpose to assess used a match between the CPS by the CPS is typical regressors assumptions of the classical errors-in-variables-model. have been matched to administrative records at various Samuhel, and Triest (1986) Little, hot deck procedure to impute missing earnings values. Bound and Krueger (1991) measurement It is more it is CPS and Social Security Administration records to study the The CPS-SSA match has error. various advantages compared to the representative of the whole population and contains a two period panel referring to 1976 and 1977. may many more The disadvantage be erroneous as well and these earnings are top coded maximum. Bound and Krueger CPS, seems correlated with many part of their to assess the error introduced Security earnings surement The unfortunate and Internal Revenue Service records properties of Moreover, to actual signal. survey data quality. David, analyzed a similar match between the PSIDVS. due error in earnings in earnings equations, thus violating the Census data is error, constructed pointed out two new findings with the observations. is that at the Social Security CPS-SSA match. by subtracting social security earnings from earnings reported negatively correlated with true earnings, a measurement error. Secondly, measurement error phenomenon they Social refer to as mean Meain the reverting significantly positively autocorrelated in is two adjacent periods. Both features defy the classical measurement error model and seriously complicate the estimation of earnings dynamics. These findings were corroborated on a second wave of the PSID Validation Study by Bound, Brown, Duncan and Rogers (1989, in press). The second wave was collected four years later through Bound et al. a similar survey at the same firm. in also find mean reversion and a positive autocorrelation measurement error extending over a four year period. framework that the to summarize the impact of impact of measurement error None of these studies shed measurement error be small. to correct estimates of earnings in analyses of the intertemporal allocation measurement error have and Card 1989) or consumption a regression context and conclude on the question of how households or individuals over time. Generally, very structure of the in in the level of earnings is likely to direct light dynamics as they are often used In addition, they develop a nice theoretical (e.g. to be made restrictive in studies at least on the dynamic of life cycle labor supply Hall and Mishkin 1982). how measurement error relates to earnings over time. assumptions of resources by I use the Abowd this we need to know PSID Validation Study To improve on In this paper (e.g. to address this issue. The fact that survey earnings are only available for limits. Fortunately, the dataset contains validation earnings for up to six two years imposes some years thus providing a lot of information on the true earnings process. I sample. begin in section 2 with a description of the data set and some I also revisit the basic findings of and show that they largely hold up in my sample. by about the et al. (in press) Section 3 presents a dynamic model for both results provides underreport transitory earnings fluctuations. Quantitatively, this error, the bulk is explained statistics Bound and Krueger (1991) and Bound measurement error and earnings. The estimation measurement summary is some evidence that individuals only a small fraction of the total component. The following a classical white noise section discusses the impact of these results for the study of earnings dynamics, in particular the estimation of permanent and transitory components of earnings. Section 5 concludes. 2. DATA AND BASIC FACTS ABOUT MEASUREMENT ERROR For the PSID Validation Study a survey questionnaire analogous but shorter firm. was administered to a number of employees At the same time, payroll records for these at to the one used for the PSID an unnamed Detroit area manufacturing employees were obtained from the firm. The producers stress the cooperation of the firm involved which allowed an error free transcription of the company records. The PSIDVS consists of two waves. In the first wave, 387 employees were interviewed A second survey 1983. This survey included questions about annual earnings in 1981 and 1982. was conducted in 1987 which included questions about earnings for every year from 1981 these years are provided as well. Validation earnings for all made many to reinterview as participants part of the panel. the 1987 survey so that a total of 275 of the original 1983 Additional hourly workers were interviewed in 492 interviews could be coded for that year. Thus, both survey years consist of a cross section larger than the overlap that creates the panel. Since on measurement error for earnings with a one year cross sections and the panel. to 1986. For the 1987 wave an attempt was of the original participants as possible. became eventually in recall I will refer to I will concentrate them as the 1986 and 1982 1 Before proceeding I eliminated observations that contained assigned values or zeros in the reported or validation earnings in the relevant years. also eliminated four I more observations because the coded validation earnings seem questionable and they deviate significantly from the rest of the sample. Bound work with et al. (in press) also a sample where they remove some outliers and question the validity of two of the 1986 validation values. Details on the omitted observations are given in the Appendix. asserting that in levels measurement error 1 income variables thus error. and 2 provide some basic sample section, respectively. take logs of the I proportional. All of the qualitative results hold up for earnings is and additive measurement Tables is In line with the literature, Most striking about the statistics for the sample is panel dataset and the 1986 cross the high tenure, 19 years on average. This of course due to the sampling design, only employees continuously with the firm between 1981 and 1987 became part of the sample. The sample general. is therefore also older than the labor force in Sample members are relatively well educated, the proportion of women is very low. About half of the panel are salaried employees. Earnings in this sample are higher than in representative cross sections. Remarkably, validation and reported earnings do not differ much in either mean or variance. This implies that "measurement error," calculated as the difference between reported and validation earnings, has a mean quite large, on the other hand. close zero. Its skewness ranges from indicating only small asymmetries but fat of the distribution can be found in I will use this definition of The standard tails in deviation of the measurement error -1.3 to 1.4 the distribution of the et necessitates some within period al. (in press). measurement Bound and Krueger (1991) and Bound measurement error Identification of the restrictions the survey and validation variables. Given moments error. to Plots This implies that made by Duncan and Hill (1985) of the survey measurement error on the joint distribution of the measurement error that some gross 1 et al. (in press). in the analysis that follows. validation earnings are measured correctly, an assumption also and Bound and the kurtosis from 8 is in outliers in the validation variables have been eliminated the assumption of correct validation earnings seems as good as any other. Simple cross section regressions of the log measurement error so defined on demographics did not reveal any particular pattern and the explanatory results are therefore not reported here. power of these regressions is low. These Bound and Krueger (1991) They found the that established two important findings using the measurement error is two observations one year apart measurement error and Bound et al. positively correlated over time. about 0.40. Secondly, there is true earnings in their data set. (1989) on the PSIDVS. Bound et for the error four years apart. from the PSIDVS I will show al. This is The CPS-SSA match. autocorrelation between a negative correlation between has been confirmed by latter finding also found a positive but smaller autocorrelation that these findings largely hold data. In revisiting the earlier results I will up on the samples I drew pay particular attention to the distinction between a recession year (1982) and a boom year (1986). Table 3 reports the basic results. The (m), true earnings (y), and reported earnings % and 25 stable <Ty /<£ columns report first The variance of measurement (x). The variance of of the variance of earnings. error is between 15 measurement error seems much more between 1982 and 1986 than the variance of earnings. This implies that the reliability ratio measurement error model in a regression context, , which plays a crucial will be higher in recessions. also stressed by Bound role for the classical However, this is entirely related to the variance of the signal, a finding et al. (1989). The last two columns report the regression (b my ) the measurement error the variances of and on reported earnings (b^). Bound coefficients of measurement error on true earnings et al. (in press) show that these regression coefficients take the role of the reliability ratio for calculating the bias introduced by general models; the reader similar to theirs. is measurement error in more referred to their paper for the algebraic details. The negative correlation between measurement error and for the recession year 1982 than for the boom year 1986. For the panel My results are roughly true earnings hourly workers and the correlation is stronger this coefficient is actually estimated to be positive in 1986. However, a negative and significant coefficient 1986 cross section. This difference stems partly from the is is found for the fact that the cross section contains more strongly negative for hourly workers. more For the 1986 cross section the coefficients are -0.170 (0.056) for hourly workers and 0.019 (0.035) for salaried employees. For the panel the 1986 coefficients are -0.064 (0.067) for hourly workers and 0.020 (0.043) for the salaried group. The coefficient for the hourly workers differs to quite a substantial degree between the cross section and the panel sample. For 1982 the panel coefficients are -0.105 (0.056) for hourly workers and -0.029 (0.052) for salaried employees. holds up within the subgroups: the correlation workers have always a lower correlation. is more negative in Thus the general pattern 1982 for both of them. Hourly The correlation between same pattern: is it the higher measurement error and survey earnings boom. the in cov(m,x) = cov(m,y) + var(m) This has Since the variance of . follow to m is positive but by definition rather stable the is shows the since two covariance terms have to follow the same relationship over time. Table 3 reports results for the basic samples as well as for subsamples true earnings to be above 9 (about $8, 100) fulfilled that restriction. of the sample that this in each year. For the 1986 cross section There are a few observations with very low earnings may strongly influence the estimates involving mainly reduces the estimate of the variance of y and x estimates very much. All the results hold up The data set. is slightly lower than what Bound y. in the earlier years As can be seen from error is et al. (in press) found. AR( 1) Taking the Bound and Krueger (1991) estimate of 0.40 0.094 (0.065) Let me summarize the three structure of the recessions. 2) is is measurement is roughly constant over time, stronger for hourly workers. autocorrelated over time, the correlation Since the is error. possibility is that combined with an AR(1). Measurement error is weakly negatively correlated with stronger in recessions and in the panel for the first order autocorrelation as a main findings about measurement error variance of the measurement error the table, They pointed out already benchmark, the fourth order autocorrelation would be 0.026. One alternative there exists a person specific fixed effect in misreporting observations samples as well. measurement that this correlation is too high to be compatible with an all 1982 but changes none of the other in in the restricted correlation between the 1986 and 1982 This that restrict the log of 3) it may at this stage: 1) The be slightly higher in true earnings, the correlation Measurement error is positively declining slowly over time. PSIDVS only contains two observations on measurement error I cannot distinguish between different hypothesis on the correlation of the measurement error over time. However, dataset contains relatively rich information on true earnings. cations 1) and 2) reported above. In the next section, between the dynamic structure of true earnings I I will therefore focus the on the impli- use a simple model to capture the relationship and measurement error. 3. In A DYNAMIC MODEL FOR EARNINGS AND MEASUREMENT ERROR many applications it is useful to decompose earnings into a permanent and a transitory component. Different events are associated with these components. Promotions or job high paying industry lead to permanent changes induce temporary variations. Obviously, the more important events it is in people's lives. in loss in a earnings while overtime or temporary layoffs the changes in According to permanent earnings that are related to Sudman and Bradburn (1974) events of greater importance ("salience") are recalled better by survey respondents. This behavioral suggests that respondents underreport transitory earnings changes. Such a model with the findings reported above since transitory income fluctuations tend A simple statistical formulation of such a model composed of a permanent (random walk) component and V„ Z;« In the estimation Some it is I chose + Z„-i be larger in recessions. Let annual earnings be a transitory (white noise) component, i.e. Tla (1) £,, to let the transitory random walk component var(e The process = + Z it as follows. also consistent not possible to identify time varying variances for both shocks for each period. restriction is necessary; the variance of the = is to is model for it ) = a;, is var{y\ measurement error is m„ = shock have time varying variances while constant over time. it ) = aj„ cov(e,„ri li ) = (2) given by ari,, + ]i, + %„ var%) = (^ var((i,) = a; Measurement error consists of three components. The shock, we expect a < . The second component is first is (3) correlated with the transitory income a person fixed effect in the measurement error unrelated to earnings. Recall that this will yield results that are consistent with the autocorrelation in measurement error found by Bound and Krueger (1991). Given the limitations of the datasetat hand no richer structure of the dynamics of the measurement error can be is just an arbitrarily chosen alternative measurementerror is white noise. earnings at model to In this simple identified; the fixed effect The the autocorrelation. introduced by varying it is the model measurement error is not related to permanent useful to difference the earnings equation initial conditions = ( 1 ) to eliminate heterogeneity person effects in the earnings process). (i.e. Ay,, + e„ t]„ - ri,., (4) The resulting model for earnings and measurement error defined in equations the following (2), (3), and (4) implies moment conditions var(Ay lt cov(Ay, / var{m lt ) ) = <TE + 0^.+ ,A.v,,_ = l ( _ + <s\ ) = -acr,_, = aj restrict the it helps to put sample so some (5) ; All other sample covariances are restricted to be zero. model. However, + aj = acr, cov(Ay,,,m,,_,) cov(m, p m, oj,., = -c^,., ) ara], cflv(Ay,„/?7,.,) I component of all. For the estimation that last This is structure on the data and that the log of true earnings is admittedly a very simple minded it fits above 9. amazingly well. But recall Including observations with smaller earnings often led to results that were strongly influenced by a single or a few observations, especially in the estimates of the earnings process. I fit the moment conditions in (5) to the data by matrix of earnings changes (for 1982 then imposing the restrictions using a Abowd and Card to No estimating the unrestricted covariance 1986) and measurement errors (for 1982 and 1986) and minimum 1989). This strategy has a Likelihood estimation. first distance estimator (see Chamberlain 1984 and number of advantages compared distributional assumptions are necessary. to, say, The estimation Maximum is therefore robust to the departures from normality typically observed in actual data. Simple specification tests are available, allowing a general assessment of the Given 1985). can be traced that the first stage unrestricted covariance matrix is available, failures of the to their sources relatively easily. estimates are asymptotically efficient. putationally simpler than small set of Newey of the model (Chamberlain 1984 and fit moments The minimum If model optimal weights are chosen the second stage samples the two stage procedure Finally, in large com- is MLE because the nonlinear maximization has to be performed only on a rather than the entire dataset. distance estimator for a sample of size 7" is given by 6 T = argmin{c T - f(b))'WT (cT - f(b)) where cT WT is F = is a vector of r sample covariances,/(b) is a function of the parameters of interest, and a positive semi-definite weighting matrix that possibly depends on the data. df{b)ldb , the jacobian of the moment conditions. If the weighting matrix the matrix of sampling covariances of the estimates of the sample certain optimality characteristics and tribution with degrees of is T times freedom equal moment the inverse of the fourth to r - the variances The problem tends to is the inverse of then the estimator has minimized has a % their be worse the The results Instead, I like this. This results from the correlation sampling variances, which are calculated from the same fatter the tails of the empirical distribution (see Altonji and I experimented is split sampling variances are calculated from different portions of the were extremely imprecise and highly dependent on the particular sample data. split used. use a weighting matrix with the optimal weights on the main diagonal and zeros elsewhere. This corresponds to weighted nonlinear least squares on the sample moments. condition receives a weight that moments -dis- minimum distance estimator tends to underfit with the independently weighted estimator suggested by Altonji and Segal where the sample their 2 matrix of earnings changes and measurement errors. Segal 1993). In the sample the kurtosis of log wage changes ranges from 10 to 27. and the moments and Define rank(F). In this case the optimal weighting matrix on the main diagonal of a covariance model between the second moments and moments the quadratic form being In empirical applications the optimally weighted data (6) is allowed for. The asymptotic is inversely proportional to This estimator seems to yield its accuracy but no dependence between very reasonable estimates. distribution of the estimator in (6) is Each moment ^f{S T -b) -> N(0,(F'WFy F'W\r WF'(F'WF)) l V = Newey (1985) has shown that an asymptotic % T(c T The sample the at a generalized inverse of estimation results are given hand there is no evidence correct, it may model is can be formed for -statistic this model as - f(B T)YQr(cT - f(S T )) ~ X l rank{F) PT = is (7) E(cc') 2 Qt = where Qj l - FT (FT 'WT FT )' FT'WT l I QT in (8) . Table 4. The specification test reveals that in the small model does not that the just reflect on the observations purged of gross outliers. WV fit the data. This low power of the The estimate of a is may not mean that with a sample of only 231 test about -0.25, meaning that individuals underreport transitory earnings by 25 %. Unlike most of the variances in the model, this coefficient is not very well determined. error is The standard deviation of the white noise quite large, around 0. 10 in both years. There periods. This means is due to the this variance differs across % in 1982 and 5 % in 1986. More also seem quite sensible. than 80 They imply % of the variation in earnings changes is due to the transitory component. shocks are measurement % of the white noise component. The estimates for the earnings process and 90 no evidence that in that the underreporting of transitory earnings accounts only for a small part of the total variance in measurement error, 9 variance is component much more important the standard deviation is in the recession about twice as large years 1982-83 than in the in the recession. that between 75 Transitory earnings boom years 1985-86, This explains part of the stronger negative correlation between earnings and measurement error in a recession year like 1982 compared to a boom year like 1986. This is the second major fact about measurement error from the previous section. Table 5 reports the actual covariance matrix used fitted covariance matrix from the model. These in the estimation and table 6 displays the tables provide useful information on the short- comings of the model. The model explains most of the variances and autocovariances of the earnings 10 process well; it overpredicts the autocovariances between 1983/84 and 1984/85. This stems from the fact that a large value for the variance of the transitory earnings the earnings variances in 1983 and 1984. This This deviation may be due to at the same boom because is fit permanent component is nonstationary not everybody benefits from an upswing predicts three non-zero covariances between earnings and cov(Ay i82 ,m ia2 ), cov(Ay ia3 ,m lS2 ), cov{Ay i86 ,m l36 ) there necessary to time. The model ( is the only parameter entering the autocovariance. is the fact that the variance of the as well and high during the early years of a component one other non-zero covariance and measurement error in 1986. relation exists with earnings in that the It fits all ). later years up is to 1986. While significant, a % -test for the joint hypothesis that all seven covariances p- value of 0.43. and the 1986 measurement error may just well. rather peculiar since 2 be zero are indeed zero has a them very error However, model misses, between earnings changes This correlation of -0.21 any of the three of measurement in 1982 no similar cor- this single correlation is cov(A y„ _,, m„) which should Thus, the correlation between 1982 earnings changes be due to sampling variation. The model has a number of other implications. Many sample members had negative transitory earnings shocks in 1982 due to the recession. Thus, the measurement error should be positive on average for that year. According to table 1 this is indeed the case but the mean of the measurement error is very small (and not statistically different from zero). An alternative test for the model can a linear regression where would result in a r\ u downward is be designed by considering equation (3) as the basis for replaced by current earnings. Obviously, inconsistent estimate of a if the model was true this since earnings contains both a temporary and a permanent component. However, a consistent estimate could be obtained by instrumenting earnings with a variable that movements is just related with transitory earnings in earnings. For the sample at hand, relatively stable manufacturing workers, changes in annual hours will satisfy this criterion relatively well. changes in changes but not with permanent Between 1981 and 1982 much of these changes are due to temporary layoffs and unemployment while between 1985 and 1986 most will be due to variation in overtime. size significantly. However, hours are only available for hourly workers, cutting the sample Table 7 displays the results of regressing the measurement error on earnings using hours as an instrument for the panel sample as well as the larger cross sectional samples. coefficient estimates are similar to the ones obtained from the structural 11 The model above except for — . the estimate for the 1986 cross section. This yields a point estimate of -0.54, indicating that for this group one half of transitory earnings movements may go unreported. some of the It should be kept in mind that difference in these estimates will be due to sampling variance. We would like to assess again how much the underreporting of transitory income, Obviously, the standard R 2 i.e. of the variance of the measurement error we defined as explained total will notestimate this quantity since the variance oftheregressor, earnings, exceeds estimator for the explained variance available under the null that the is model due to 2 oro ,/^ like an estimate for the quantity sum of squares divided by is sum of squares a2 A consistent , . is true. given It is by «, . R- = — covjm^y,,) oc/v var[m This quantity variation in is (9) it ) reported at the bottom of table 7. measurement error is due For the panel sample only 7 This to underreporting. is surement error component. better. This will be true more In a if the still from other factors representative sample the like the higher. Since this is likely to 4. One in white noise mea- is component in earnings true. IMPLICATIONS FOR THE ESTIMATION OF EARNINGS DYNAMICS of the motivations for this paper is to We want to estimate the variances of the to the transitory i.e. to three earnings are due to mobility between firms and separations assess to what degree measurement error biases estimates of the parameters in a dynamic model of earnings. again. two variance of the white noise component of the measurement error many movements be is model might actually perform the same in the population as in the sample while the variance of the transitory is of the again similar to the finding above using the structural estimates. In the cross section samples the explained variance times as large but the major contribution comes % component, r\ it The only . data are only available on xu Axu = . + (1 in (1) innovation to the permanent component, e„ data available are contaminated by Instead of the true £„ Consider the simple model model +oc)(r|„-ri„- 12 1 ) + in (4) kn ~ measurement , and error, we have S* -i ( 10 ) The moment conditions are var(Axu ) = <Te + +a) (1 2 (aj, + aj,_ 1 ) + oj + a|_, = -(l+a)o5,_, - cov(Ax,,Ax,_,) crj,., (11) The estimates of the variance of true earnings will be confounded by two bias terms of opposite sign. First, the variance will be underestimated a< because On . the other hand, the white noise term in measurement error % introduces an additional positive variance component. Similar biases t and 9 summarize these biases for 1982 and 1986 using arise for the first autocovariance. Tables 8 the estimates The first 2 ((1 from Table + oc) - column l)(c^, 4. reports the bias due to underreporting of transitory income, + o^,_,) measurement error. Column . use 2o| I , assuming periods. Recall that this variance this component has substantial changes (column transitory component. This to the white noise component that the variance of the noise is the variance, in the is due given by same in in the two adjacent only estimated for the survey years 1982 and 1986. Notice that is However, the 4). (2) gives the bias it is same order of magnitude much lower because total bias is as the variance of earnings of the underreporting of the especially true for the recession year 1982 because of the large variance of the transitory component. The first panel uses actual period t and period t-1 estimates of the variances in the transitory earnings shock. This creates an asymmetry with the white noise error component. panel in the table uses only period the same in t-1. t The reliability in 1982 because Bound and Krueger(1991) found reliability ratio is very accurate as the the entire total is changes to of course was around is for 1976-77. variance in much , around one economy while my changes this in the bias due underreporting of the transitory to the highest variance year. ratio for 1982, i.e. the ratio of variance of true earnings of survey earnings changes oi/ci, where the estimates for both variables and assumes the variances were This yields more extreme values component especially half. The This picture Bound measurement is is is changes much mind in much bleaker for the that this PSID the 0.65 that boom The variance than in the year 1986 comparison larger since their data is not come from in within plant earnings et al. (in press) report the variance in the to the variance somewhat higher than One should keep Bound and Krueger be about three times as high individual effects of the 0.8. data just cover one plant. lower. The second of reported earnings PSIDVS. The white noise and error are presumably comparable in the population and the 13 single plant use here. Hence, there will be error in a representative sample. population, mean two sources of reduction variance of First, the out that the strong business cycle pattern present in the plant level the PSIDVS it computed by using period t column 4 is the For the data. first same in the reliability worth pointing is not present in in the population. autocovariance biases can only be innovation variances and assuming that the variances were the same during the two previous years. line of PSIDVS is data PSID. Thus, the differences between 1982 and 1986 should be much lower Return to the analysis of the the is Secondly, the Furthermore, is larger. from measurement a will rise, so if reversion will be stronger in a representative sample. be higher because the variance of the signal ratio will r|„ in the biases This yields the results given in table 9. one between 1983 and 1982. The biases The covariance in the first in the first autocovariance show a very similar business cycle pattern as the variance. Table 10 presents some a permanent effect which is ( aE and results for the decomposition of the variance of earnings changes into an a transitory effect . These are based on the second panel consistent with the assumptions for the autocovariances in table The present the estimates for the standard deviations of the innovations. The validation earnings from table 4 are given below in parentheses. identified from the autocovariance. Given from the variance. For 1982 the its for earnings: the first order autocorrelation estimated. As estimate, the permanent results are not is less than -0.5. to the total variance of earnings error was purely white noise. the variance of the permanent The would therefore be relative contributions is and (3) estimates based on the transitory component component can be is identified For 1986 both components are over- changes relatively good news is given in a similar in column (4). It can be way. This would not be true the variance of the transitory component component would be estimated accurately. Then only would be overstated while This (2) compatible with a random walk plus noise model seen that the measurement error biases both components measurement Columns a measure of the relative importance of the two components the contribution of permanent innovations if 8. in table 9 affected. for the estimation of earnings dynamics: the negative correlation of measurement error with transitory earnings attenuates the role of white noise measurement error. The low reliability ratios for this sample should not be seen too pessimistically. The sample exhibits much less variation in the true variables than typical labor many different jobs, industries, and regions. decomposition is market datasets that include people in Furthermore, the estimated permanent/transitory roughly correct since the biases in the estimated variances and autocovariances are of about equal magnitude. This result will only carry over to a 14 more representative sample as ) long as the transitory earnings variance does not in further rise too reducing the impact of measurement error. much. A small rise will actually be helpful If the transitory variance becomes sufficiently large the bias due to the underreporting feature will dominate the bias due to the white noise error component. This would imply that the importance of the transitory component might even be understated in a permanent/transitory decomposition. 5. CONCLUDING COMMENTS This paper analyzes the structure of measurement error of the true earnings process. The PSID Validation Study in earnings in relation to the dynamics a fairly unique data set that allows such is an investigation. But the data also have important limitations. The small number of observations in the data set make it hard to statistically discriminate between opposing hypotheses. Furthermore, only two observations on survey earnings are available and these are not from adjacent years. Finally, the data come from a single plant and importantly, the variance in the responses is may therefore not be very representative. Most also limited by this fact. The results obtained here are qualitatively similar to the findings of Bound and Krueger ( 199 1 on the CPS-SSA match file. The PSIDVSdataexhibitmeanrevertingmeasurementerrorin earnings, i.e. the measurement lation is weaker than error in is negatively correlated with validation earnings. However, this corre- Bound and Krueger. The results differ year mainly because the variance of the earnings process properties of the measurement error changes less cyclical than manufacturing To characterize the data using a measurement boom and a a recession different in these states while the the extend that the this finding will not easily carry find a positive autocorrelation in the I little. is between over economy as a whole to a larger population. I is also error over four years. model where individuals underreport the transitory component of earnings. This seems like a sensible behavioral hypothesis since permanent income changes are often associated with more important events and should therefore be remembered better. This part of the measurement error implies that the transitory component in earnings will be underestimated in a model of earnings dynamics. However, the white noise component in measurement error more than offsets this effect. This implies that the permanence in earnings changes somewhat if inferences are made on the basis of data with 15 measurement may error. It be understated would be wrong, however, to attribute the entire transitory better rule of thumb is probably component of earnings changes to treat the to measurement error. A estimated transitory/permanent decompositions of earnings as correct. Overall, the model fits the data well when estimated identified using an instrumental variables strategy. sistent with the stylized facts about Some of survey and validation records would be necessary component of earnings On model are not features of the fully con- in misreporting. A more extensive panel to investigate this aspect in the data. In representative samples, earnings dynamics also do not also exhibit richer dynamics. model or when measurement error. The correlation of measurement errors over time cannot be fully accounted for by a person fixed effect as well. If the transitory as a covariance structure fit is itself the other hand, this the random walk serially correlated may also call for a plus white noise more model measurement error will more elaborate model of misreporting. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I thank David Card, Francois Laisney, and participants Mannheim Labor Lunches for helpful comments at the Princeton and University of as well as an Associate Editor for valuable suggestions. 16 and two referees APPENDIX: OMITTED OBSERVATIONS Here I provide some information on the four observations which Each observation was omitted because that the record is actually erroneous but that these records any may I should by on the basis of the available information there is a possibility sample however, that the decision rather arbitrarily, no particular cutoffs in the their 1987-ID. PSIDVS wave has individual in the 1987 The mean be coded incorrectly. Since the four observations have a large influence on stress, Each individual omitted from the sample. the validation record is questionable. This does not (least squares) statistics calculated with the analysis. I to I find saver to exclude them from the it exclude these particular observations is taken were used. that is part of the 1983 wave has a 1983-ID, similarly, each a 1987-ID. All four outliers are part of the panel. identify I them four omitted observations have the IDs 20, 127, 191, and 307. Information about validation and reported earnings is displayed in table Al for these individuals. The ques- tionable records are highlighted. Observation 20 is an hourly worker with 26 years of tenure earning an hourly each year from 1982 to 1986. In 1981 he only worked 64 hours. $10 in that someone keeps working The other them. They all It seems inconceivable for less than a dollar an hour even for such a short time. three observations are salaried employees, no hours information is available for have 16 or more years of education and between 12 and 18 years of tenure. In each case the highlighted earnings reflect a significant drop in normal earnings levels. report earnings wage of about much in line with earnings in the other years. It would not remember earnings changes of such a magnitude seems peculiar after The respondents that the respondents one or two years. There are no other college educated employees in the sample that had earnings changes even approaching the same magnitude. 17 REFERENCES Abowd, and Card, D. (1989), "On the Covariance Structure of Earnings and Hours Changes," J. Econometrica, 57, 41 1-445. Altonji, Brown, C, Duncan, G. J., in GMM Estimation of Covariance working paper. Department of Economics, Northwestern University. Structures," Bound, "Small Sample Bias G. and Segal, L. (1993), J. J., and Rodgers, W. L. (1989), "Measurement Error sectional and Longitudinal Labor Market Surveys: Results from Two in Cross- Validation Studies," Working Paper No. 2885, National Bureau of Economic Research "Evidence on the Validity of Cross-Sectional and Longitudinal Labor Market (in press), Data," Journal of Labor Economics. Bound, J. and Krueger, A. B. (1991), "The Extent of Measurement Error Do Two Wrongs Make Data: David, M., Intriligator, Little, R. J. in Handbook of Econometrics J. and A., Samuhel, Hill, surement Error Duncan, G. J. in (Vol. 2), eds. Z. Griliches Amsterdam: North Holland, 1247-1318. M. E., and Triest, R. E. (1986), "Alternative Methods for CPS Income Imputation," Journal of the American Duncan, G. Longitudinal Earnings a Right?" Journal of Labor Economics, 9, 1-24. Chamberlain, G. (1984), "Panel Data," and M. D. in Statistical Association, 81, 29-41. D. H. (1985), "An Investigation of the Extent and Consequences of Mea- Labor-economic Survey Data," Journal of Labor Economics, and Mathiowetz, N. A. (1985), A 3, 508-532. Validation Study of Economic Survey Data, Ann Arbor, MI: Institute for Social Research. Hall, R. E. and Mishkin, F. S. (1982), "The Sensitivity of Consumption to Transitory Income: Estimates from Panel Data on Households," Econometrica, 50, 461-481. Mellow, W. and Sider, H. (1983), "Accuracy of Response Implications," Journal of Labor Economics, 1, in Labor Market Surveys: Evidence and 33 1-344. Newey, W. K. (1985), "Generalized Method of Moments Specification Testing," Journal of Econometrics, 29, 229-256. Sudman, S. and Bradburn, N. M. (1974), Response Effects Chicago, IL: Aldine Publishing Compnay. 18 in Surveys. A Review and Synthesis, Table 1. Sample Statistics: Panel Minimum Maximum 0.29 8.71 10.96 10.28 0.30 8.58 11.00 Measurement Error 82 0.01 0.12 -0.48 0.62 Validation Earnings 86 10.47 0.21 9.76 11.02 Survey Earnings 86 10.47 0.24 9.62 10.97 Measurement Error 86 -0.00 0.11 -0.63 0.27 Highest Grade 13.0 1.94 8 17 Tenure 18.9 7.4 8 40 Age 40.3 8.1 29 63 Female 0.10 0.30 1 Salaried 0.50 0.50 1 Variable Mean Validation Earnings 82 10.27 Survey Earnings 82 Note: Number of observations is Std. 234. 19 Dev. Table 2. Sample Statistics: 1986 Cross Section Variable Mean Validation Earnings 86 10.46 Survey Earnings 86 Minimum Maximum 0.21 9.74 11.02 10.46 0.23 9.62 11.08 Measurement Error 86 -0.00 0.12 -0.63 0.55 Highest Grade 12.58 2.07 4 17 Tenure 20.30 8.03 8 43 Age 41.67 8.67 27 63 Female 0.08 0.27 1 Salaried 0.33 0.47 1 Note: Number of observations is Std. 437. 20 Dev. Table Data 3. Basic Facts About Measurement Error in Earnings set Panel 1986 Panel 1986 (y > 9) Cross Sect. 1986 Panel 1982 Panel 1982 (y > 9) Cross Sect. 1982 Cross Sect. 1982 nobs var(m) var(y) var(;t) Ky b„ix 234 0.0110 0.0441 0.0557 0.007 0.203 (0.037) (0.032) 0.006 0.201 (0.037) (0.032) -0.068 0.207 (0.036) (0.026) 231 437 234 231 352 351 0.0110 0.0446 0.0440 0.0137 0.0135 0.0860 0.0697 0.0135 0.0142 0.0739 0.0670 0.0142 0.0562 0.0517 0.0875 0.0697 0.0735 0.0654 (y>9) Note: Heteroskedasticity consistent standard errors 21 in parentheses. -0.070 0.086 (0.038) (0.026) -0.097 0.097 (0.042) (0.031) -0.099 0.094 (0.035) (0.023) -0.118 0.096 (0.034) (0.025) Table 4. Minimum Parameter Estimate Std. Err. *n8i 0.106 0.027 0.139 0.022 0.132 0.021 >Tl84 0.120 0.033 >Tl85 0.073 0.021 J 0.089 0.025 J J 2 X Distance Estimates for Earnings Changes and Measurement Error Tl82 n83 tl86 Parameter Std. Err. 0.042 0.055 0.105 0.011 0.096 0.010 a, 0.034 0.013 a -0.258 0.123 ^82 23.870 [17] -Statistic [dof] 0.123 p-value Note: Panel data, number of observations Estimate is 23 1. 22 Table 5. Estimated Covariance Matrix of Earnings and Measurement Error Ay«2 Ayiu Ay,w Ay«5 Ay i86 fn-,82 "li86 tym 0.0322 -0.54 -0.05 -0.18 0.09 -0.21 -0.21 Ay«i -0.0193 0.0399 -0.45 0.17 0.07 0.22 0.08 Ay,« -0.0018 -0.0163 0.0335 -0.43 -0.06 0.05 0.01 Ay«5 -0.0049 0.0051 -0.0121 0.0239 -0.30 0.09 0.00 Ayi85 0.0019 0.0016 -0.0012 -0.0055 0.0141 -0.05 -0.18 ™\82 -0.0044 0.0051 0.0011 0.0016 -0.0007 0.0135 0.10 ™i86 -0.0039 0.0016 0.0001 0.0000 -0.0023 0.0012 0.0110 Note: Covariances are below the diagonal, correlations above the diagonal 23 Table 6. Fitted Covariance Matrix Ay lS2 Ay aj Ay lS4 Ay iS5 Ay i86 mm m,i86 Ay i82 0.0322 -0.55 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.24 0.00 Ayi83 -0.0192 0.0383 -0.48 0.00 0.00 0.22 0.00 Ayi84 0.0000 -0.0173 0.0334 -0.54 0.00 0.00 0.00 Ay l85 0.0000 0.0000 -0.0144 0.0214 -0.30 0.00 0.00 Ayi86 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 -0.0053 0.0149 0.00 -0.16 m i82 -0.0050 0.0050 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0135 0.10 m i86 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 -0.0020 0.0012 0.0110 Note: Covariances are below the diagonal, correlations above the diagonal 24 Table 7. Regression of Measurement Error on Earnings Using Hours Changes as Instruments 1986 Panel Coefficient R2 no. of obs. 1982 Panel R 1982 Cross Section Section -0.31 -0.15 -0.23 -0.54 (0.20) (0.12) (0.93) (0.17) 0.07 0.07 0.14 0.23 114 114 168 292 Note: Heteroskedasticity consistent standard errors the reported 1986 Cross 2 . 25 in parentheses. See text for the definition of Table Year 8. The Biases in Estimated Variances of Earnings Underrep. of White noise trans, earnings Error (1) (2) Total Bias (l) + var(Av„) Reliability Ratio (2) (3) (4) (5) Actual Innovation Variances 1982 -0.0137 0.0221 0.0084 0.0322 0.79 1986 -0.0060 0.0184 0.0124 0.0141 0.53 Period t Innovation Variances 1982 -0.0174 0.0221 0.0047 0.0322 0.87 1986 -0.0071 0.0184 0.0113 0.0141 0.56 26 Table Year 9. The Biases in the Estimated First Order Autocovariance of Earnings Underrep. of trans, earnings White noise Total Bias (D + EiTor cov(Ay ,Ayt-i) t Reliability Ratio (2) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) 1982 0.0087 -0.0110 -0.0023 -0.0193 0.89 1986 0.0036 -0.0092 -0.0056 -0.0055 0.50 27 Table Year 10. Implied Estimates of the Innovation Variances Gix, Oa <** Contrib. of Perm. Comp. 1982 1986 (1) (2) (3) 0.19 0.15 ... (0.18) (0.14) (0.04) 0.16 0.11 0.06 (0.12) (0.09) (0.04) Note: Estimates from Table 4 in parentheses. 28 (4) (5.5 12.6 %) % (12.5%) Table Al. Earnings for Observations Omitted form the Final Sample ID Record 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 20 Validation 62 24204 17525 20379 33020 32224 Reported 83 2400 24000 Reported 87 4000 24000 23000 30000 32000 32000 Validation 29379 51951 55720 57258 57045 54195 Reported 83 52000 52000 Reported 87 50000 50000 55000 55000 55000 60000 Validation 5237 30653 37565 41557 40803 45327 Reported 83 26500 36000 Reported 87 45000 51000 52000 55000 62000 63500 Validation 40730 39691 44020 48307 52063 11076 Reported 87 40000 42000 43000 49000 51000 55000 127 191 307 29 026 MIT LIBRARIES 3 iQBO oaa3Eaib o