Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/jointdesignofuneOOblan 0EW IB31 M415 c OH* jOO > Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series The Joint Design of Unemployment Insurance and Employment Protection. A First Pass. Olivier Blanchard Jean Tirole Working Paper 04-15 April 1,2004 Revised: November 11, 2005 RoomE52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, 02142 MA This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection http://ssrn.com/abstract=527882 at 2 LIBRARY The unemployment insurance and employment joint design of A protection. first pass.* Jean Tirole Olivier Blanchard^ November 11, * 2005 Abstract Unemployment insurance and employment protection studied in isolation. In this paper, on we argue are typically discussed that they are tightly linked, and we and focus their joint optimal design. We start our analysis with a simple neutral firms, and random shocks benchmark, with to productivity. risk averse workers, risk unemployment insurance comes with employment protection taxes; indeed, optimality requires that layoff taxes be equal to We we show In this benchmark, — in the form of unemployment that layoff benefits. then explore the implications of four broad categories of deviations: limits on insurance, limits on layoff taxes, ex-post of firms or workers. scope for insurance We wage bargaining, and ex-ante heterogeneity show how the design must be modified may be more in each case. limited than in the benchmark; so employment protection. The general principle remains however, may The the scope for namely the need to look at unemployment insurance and employment protection together, rather than in isolation. *We are grateful to Daron Acemoglu, Suman Basu, Larry Katz, Tsyvinski for helpful comments. T MIT and NBER. 'IDEI and GREMAQ (UMR 5604 CNRS), Toulouse, and MIT. Javier Ortega, John Hassler, and Aleh Introduction Unemployment insurance and employment In this paper, in isolation. protection are typically discussed and studied we argue that they are tightly linked, and we focus on their optimal joint design. We start our analysis in Section 1 with a simple The productivity entrepreneurs run firms and are risk neutral. is random. If productivity is benchmark. Workers are risk averse; of any worker-firm low enough, the worker and the firm may separate, in match which case the worker becomes unemployed. In this benchmark, a simple employment to achieve the benefits so as to insure workers, to internalize the cost of benchmark shows the ployment protection unemployment The same allocation their workers; for the state to pay un- layoff taxes so as to lead firms efficient layoff decision. Thus, the as layoff taxes. This common The level delivers second, which follows from the is is between unemployment insurance and em- further characteristics: benefits: The and to levy tight conceptual relation —defined efficiency. optimum unemployment and take an The optimum has two to way first, is first is both that layoff taxes are equal full insurance and production that state intervention is not needed. achieved by having firms voluntarily pay severance payments to in effect, severance payments act both as unemployment insurance and layoff taxes. This leads us to examine, in Sections 2 to 5, how these conclusions are affected by the introduction of four empirically-relevant deviations from the benchmark, from limits on unemployment insurance, wage bargaining, and we ask two questions: to limits on the ability of firms to pay layoff taxes, to ex-post to ex-ante heterogeneity of either workers or firms. The first is unemployment insurance and how In each case, the distortion affects the optimal combination of layoff taxes. The second is whether state intervention is required. We find that, in general, efficiency and unemployment and insurance require different levels of layoff taxes benefits, with the difference being financed through payroll taxes — positive or negative. The fact that layoff taxes are in general not equal to that individual firms can no longer implement the erance payments). A pooling firms which lay workers off or insurance agency unemployment optimum on is and from firms that do their benefits also implies own (i.e. through sev- needed to receive payments both from not, and to distribute unemployment benefits to laid off workers. We show that, in some cases, this role can be by a private filled agency, with voluntary participation by firms, but that in others, participation must be compulsory, implying a clear role for the state. We also show, in Section 6, that, while, in can be provided through a combination of severance payments by some cases, insurance firms and unemployment benefits by the agency, exclusivity in the provision of insurance, lest the in other cases, the agency must require outcome be suboptimal. Our framework Before we start, we want to emphasize the limits of our analysis. As a static, one-period, model. is such, it represents a substantial step back from recent dynamic models of either unemployment insurance or employment protection. two reasons. employment First, we want to focus protection, which on the joint design of makes things more We do so for unemployment insurance and difficult. Second, we want to explore a large number of labor market imperfections, starting from as simple a benchmark as feasible. of We believe that the conclusions we draw from our model, about the unemployment insurance and employment and payroll taxes in response to various state, are quite general Section A 1 7, what we articulation protection, about the relative use of layoff market imperfections, and about the role of the and can help design better systems. In that context, we draw, see as our main conclusions and our intended in extensions. benchmark Assumptions 1.1 Tastes and technology are as follows: • The economy is composed of a continuum least) 1 of entrepreneurs, • and the of mass of workers, a continuum of mass If a firm is Productivity created, a worker is which is is hired, the same for all and the productivity of the match Realizations are iid across firms; there firm, but not the worker (or is off, a [0, 1]. is The then revealed. firm can either who then becomes unemployed. no aggregate for that is entrepreneurs. given by y from cdf G(y), with density g(y) on keep the worker and produce, or lay the worker The (at state. Entrepreneurs are risk neutral. Each entrepreneur can start and run a firm. There fixed cost of creating a firm, /, • 1 risk. matter third parties such as an insurance company or the state) observes y. • Workers are if unemployed risk averse, utility function £/(.). given by U(b) (so is The optimal 1.2 with 1 b is Absent unemployment the wage equivalent of being unemployed). allocation Let y be the threshold level of productivity below which workers are laid payment are laid benefits, utility to the workers who remain employed, and \i off. Let w be the be the payment to the workers who off. The optimal allocation maximizes expected worker utility subject to the economy's 2 resource constraint: max Vw = + M + (l - G(y)U(b G(y))U{w) ) subject to: V= -G(y)fi + I y dG(y) - (1 - G(y))w = I ly Prom the first-order conditions, it follows that: y* Given y*, the levels of Condition (1) (2) is efficient for firms to unemployed (we 1 [i* laid-off b are determined an insurance condition: is whether employed or Condition w* and = (2) by the resource constraint. Workers achieve the same level of utility, and unemployed. an efficiency condition: From the point of view of total output, it is produce so long as productivity exceeds the wage equivalent of being shall call b the production-efficient threshold level). This assumption is maintained throughout the paper, except in Section 4 which introduces ex-post bargaining, and in which both the worker and the firm observe the realization of y. 2 We derive the optimal allocation ignoring the assumption that y show below that this optimal allocation can indeed be implemented. is observed only by the firm. We shall Implementation 1.3 Any provision of insurance by the firm (a severance payment) can be duplicated by the unemployment state through benefits in this economy. At best, severance redundant; in some circumstances (those envisioned in Section must actually be ruled out in order to now • Stage benefits • The 1. until we discuss we assume away severance payments. the following implementation of the optimal benchmark state chooses a payroll tax rate r, a layoff tax rate /, offer contracts to workers. and, implicitly (since y the worker allocation: and unemployment Contracts are characterized, explicitly, by a wage w, not contractable), a threshold productivity level y below which is off. firms face the all 3. laid is workers are Stage 6, they Entrepreneurs decide whether to start firms and pay the fixed cost. 2. They • shall see that fi. Stage As we implement the optimal allocation. So, alternative implementation schemes in Section Consider 2), payments are same cost and distribution of productivity, in equilibrium, all initially hired. The productivity of each job is realized. Firms decide whether to keep or dismiss workers. To show how the optimal allocation can be implemented, At Stage such that the firm and paying 3, the cutoff y w+r in is is we work backwards in time. between keeping the worker indifferent wage and payroll tax and dismissing the worker and paying layoff tax /: y If y state. > If the firm keeps the worker, produces y, y = w + r-f. < y, the firm lays the worker off, y, (3) pays w to the worker, and r to the pays / to the state; the state pays /i to the worker. At Stage 2, firms' Vf wage offer w satisfies = -G(y)f + J ly the free entry condition: y dG{y) - (1 - G(y))(w + t)=I. (4) Consider now the problem faced by the government in choosing taxes and unemploy- ment benefits at Stage Condition 1. = efficient layoff decision y* b, implies that to induce firms to take the production- (3) the following condition must hold: w + r-f = Because optimal insurance further requires that f-r = The net fiscal cost to between (5) w = b+ fj,, the state's policy must satisfy: (6) ti. the firm of laying off a worker must be equal to the benefits paid to the worker the layoff b. by the state. and the payroll tax Note that rates: unemployment this condition implies a positive relation For given unemployment benefits, the higher the payroll tax, the higher the layoff tax needed to induce the firm to take the productionefficient decision. The government budget constraint implies a second relation between taxes and benefits: VG = -G(y)( f,-f) + (l-G(y))T = (7) This constraint implies a negative relation between the layoff and the payroll tax rates: For given unemployment benefits, the higher the payroll tax, the lower the layoff tax required to balance the budget. Combining the two conditions gives: f The layoff tax to zero. must be equal The payment to = unemployment of layoff taxes equal to internalize the cost of insurance provided We summarize our Proposition insured (b + = w*), being unemployed (y* = (8) benefits, and the payroll tax rate unemployment and the threshold productivity b). makes firms equal fully 1. benchmark, the optimal allocation = benefits is by the state to the unemployed. results in Proposition 1. In the n* t fi, is is such that workers are fuJly equal to the wage equivalent of Implementation taxes f = n* . achieved through unemployment benefits equal to n* is Payroll taxes are equal to zero. defined as the ratio of layoff taxes to , and layoff Put another way, the contribution unemployment rate, benefits, is equal to one. Limits on Insurance 2 In our benchmark, workers could be and were fully insured. In practice, there are various reasons why this may not be feasible. Workers may employed, or to search when unemployed. Or there with becoming unemployed. require incentives not to shirk may be when a non-pecuniary loss associated We explore the implications of this last assumption, and return to a discussion of other potential reasons later. Assume if that the utility of workers unemployed, so B> is is now given by U(c) if employed, and by U(c) —B the utility cost of being unemployed. All other assumptions are the same as in the benchmark. 2.1 The optimal The optimal allocation allocation is the solution to: 3 max Vw = G(y)(U{b + /x) - B) + (1 - G(y))U(w), subject to the resource constraint: V= -G(y)n + I[y dG(y) - (1 - G(y))w = I. Jy Prom the first-order conditions, it follows that: w* Given y*, the levels of w* and /i* = b + /i*. are determined (9) by condition that the resource constraint holds with equality. In deriving the optimal allocation, we again ignore the constraint that y Again, we show below that this allocation can be implemented. is only observed by the firm. Condition (9) shows that marginal ployment. Because B> utility is equalized across however, this implies that utility Condition (10) shows that the threshold production-efficient level b. employment and unem- lower is when unemployed. level of productivity, y*, is lower than the A Implementation 2.2 Assume, as before, that the state a wage to workers, and, offer allocation is At Stage first finally, chooses taxes and benefits, the firms then enter and productivity is To describe how the optimal realized. implemented, we again work backwards in time. 5 3, the threshold productivity below which the firm lays a worker off is still given by: y At Stage 2, =w+T- (3) f. the wage must satisfy the free entry condition: VF = -G(y)f + f Jy y dG(y) - (1 - G(y))(w +r)=I. Consider thus the problem faced by the government ment benefits at Stage 1. Prom equations (3) take the socially-optimal layoff decision y* = and b hold: f- T =n+ The net fiscal cost to (10), choosing taxes and unemploy- in it follows that, to induce firms to — B/U'(w), the following condition must B U'{w) the firm of laying off a worker must exceed the unemployment benefits paid to the worker by an amount which depends on the cost of becoming unemployed. The other condition on taxes and benefits comes from the government budget con- straint: -G(y)(fi-f) 4 + (l-G(y))r = This overemployment result should be familiar from the "implicit contract literature" Baily (1974), Azariadis (1975), Akerlof and Miyazaki (1980)): substitute for 5 0. The (in particular lower layoff rate serves as a partial unemployment insurance. We continue to assume that severance payments are equal to zero. In this case, the assumption is not innocuous: Allowing for both unemployment benefits and severance payments would lead to a co-insurance problem and a suboptimal allocation. We discuss the issue in Section 6. Combining these two conditions f The gives: (11) U'{wj must exceed unemployment layoff tax T<0 = (*+-£- benefits, implying, for budget balance, a negative payroll tax. We summarize our Proposition 2. results in Proposition 2. In the presence of limits to insurance, the threshold productivity in the (i) socially efficient allocation is lower than the wage equivalent of being unemployed (y* < b): The lower incidence of unemployment partly compensates for the limits on insurance when unemployed. Unemployment (ii) benefits, u., must be financed by a combination of > ji) and of negative payroll now be greater than one. exceed these benefits (f contribution rate must < 0). Put another way, the Implications and discussion 2.3 • taxes, (V layoff taxes which The main result in Proposition 2 is that, in the presence of limits to insurance, layoff taxes must exceed unemployment benefits one. The — the contribution rate must be greater than higher the utility cost of unemployment, the lower the layoff rate, the larger the layoff taxes. This implies that, with respect to variations in B, unemployment insurance' and em- ployment protection are therefore substitutes: The lower the feasible level of insurance, the higher the implied level of employment protection. Higher employment protection however is a poor substitute for insurance, as it leads to distortions in the layoff decision. unemployment insurance reforms which reduce interpreting B as a result of the and (better insurance) • The second result is need for B Thus, (we shall give an example below, when search incentives) have both favorable direct indirect (lower layoff taxes and lower distortions) effects. that payments by firms in case of layoffs must be larger than payments to the laid-off workers. This obviously could not be achieved by severance payments, which imply equal payments by firms and payments to workers, and requires the presence of a third party. 6 This is We have taken this third party to be the state, collecting layoff taxes and an example of the genera] proposition (for example Holmstrom (1982)) that, when both incen- and paying unemployment (negative) payroll taxes, is needed what Formally, benefits to workers. a pooling or insurance agency, collecting payments from firms that is layoff, paying unemployment benefits to workers, and distributing the difference to the remaining firms. In this case, firms who join are better The agency may off. therefore be private and participation voluntary. • We formalized limits to insurance as coming from a non-financial cost of being unem- The ployed. limits may come instead from incentives. Consider for example a modification of the benchmark based on shirking. Once hired, but before productivity is B brings private benefits revealed, the worker decides whether to shirk or not. Shirking but results in zero productivity and thus a Shirking layoff. is unobservable. Thus, to prevent shirking, the following condition must hold: {l-G{y)){U{w)-U{b + y))>B. The expected utility gain some value B. The from being employed relative to being identical to those above, except for the replacement of An tive constraints are likely to lead search effort, (1 are then — G(y))B/U'(w) in comes from the need to motivate the unemployed to While we cannot formally analyze difference in utility B/U'(w) by 7 alternative rationalization search. unemployed must exceed optimum and the implementation characterization of the the relevant equations. (12) this case in our one-period however to results similar to those model, search incen- we have between unemployment and employment has to be yielding a constraint of the form (U(w) — U(b + fi) > would however require a dynamic model, and we cannot provide it derived. sufficient to B). A full The induce treatment here. Shallow pockets 3 In our benchmark, firms were risk neutral and had deep pockets. These assumptions are again too strong. Even in the absence of aggregate risk, the owners of many firms, especially small ones, are not fully diversified, and thus are likely to act as tives and insurance considerations are present, there company or the state. Under the more general assumption that is if they were risk averse. typically a need for a "budget breaker" , such as an insurance shirking does not yield zero productivity but instead shifts the distribution of y from G(-) to H(-), with G(-) stochastically dominating H(-), results are In the absence of further restrictions, it is not necessarily the case that / is greater than jj,. 10 less clear cut. And, even if entrepreneurs are risk neutral, information problems in financial markets are on the funds available to likely to lead to restrictions firms. In this section, we focus on the implications of limited funds. We assume that each entrepreneur with assets I starts + f, the free cash flow available to the firm after investment. While point, the exogeneity of / obviously too stark, and is we where / it is discuss a > is therefore a convenient starting number of extensions below. 3.1 The optimal allocation The government budget payments by the firm constraint (7), the threshold condition (3), and the condition that in case of layoff to give the following constraint on cannot exceed free cash flow y, w (/</), can be combined 8 9 and /j: G(y)fi-(l-G(y))(y-w)<fTherefore, the optimal allocation max VW = is the solution G(y)U(b to: + n) + {l- G(y))U(w), subject to the resource constraint: V= and the additional -G(y)/i + f y dG(y) - (1 - G(y))w = /, constraint: G(y)n-(1-G(y))(y - w) < f. One may wonder whether allowing for job creation subsidies/taxes in addition to payroll and layoff taxes might alleviate the shallow pocket constraint, and improve the allocation. This is not the case. Subsidies, even if allowed in the government budget constraint, would not appear in the equation below. 9 This constraint is derived as follows. First rewrite the threshold condition as t = y-w + f and replace r in the government budget constraint to get -G(y){fi - f) + (1 - G{y))(y - w 4- /) = 0: For a given y-w, the lower /, the lower is /i. Reorganize and use / < / 11 to get the equation in the text. , Prom the first-order conditions, it follows that the worker still 10 receives full insurance : w * = b + n*. Furthermore, the second constraint if binding (that is benefits in the optimal allocation derived in Section 1) By limiting payments by firms is, if / is less than unemployment : in case of layoff, the shallow pocket constraint prevents the state from achieving the production-efficient threshold, and the layoff rate than the production-efficient /, the larger w*, and fi* (fi* — level. The /), the higher y*, is tighter the shallow pocket constraint and so, the larger the layoff rate. are determined by (13), the full insurance condition, The now higher — the lower levels of y* and the condition that the resource constraint holds with equality. The optimal allocation offers full insurance to workers. still But limited funds lead to a higher threshold productivity, and thus a higher layoff rate than in the benchmark. Implementation 3.2 If the shallow-pocket constraint unemployment benefits ji" , is binding, the state chooses the layoff tax / - ;w-/»o. cm benefits exceed layoff taxes, payroll taxes The threshold productivity chosen by w > To b see + p.. Given Gte i 10 /• the government budget constraint then implies: As unemployment = firms is must be positive. therefore given by: why the presence of shallow pockets does not prevent full insurance, consider an allocation where and an equal increase in payments by firms Now, consider a decrease in the wage of Aui < to the state. This change affects neither the threshold condition nor the firm's profit. Use these increased payments to increase unemployment benefits by —[(1 — G(y))/G(y)] Aw. Together, these changes imply a change in utility of [-(1 - G(y))U'(w) + (1 - G(y))U'(b + fj.)](-Aw) > 0. Thus, welfare can be improved until workers are fully insured. 12 This is the same expression as in (13), and The the optimal allocation. so, layoff and payroll taxes indeed implement shows that we can think derivation of the shallow pocket constraint as affecting the threshold productivity level directly (through the limit on the layoff tax) and indirectly (through the need tax and the higher payroll tax reduce the We of layoff for firms, layoff and thus lead to a level. fi*. summarize the Proposition results in Proposition 3. presence of shallow pockets, workers remain fully insured (w* 3. In the = The threshold productivity is higher than the wage equivalent of being unemployed b-\-u*). > both the lower the same argument as before, the resource constraint implies that workers receive the optimal w* and (y fiscal cost than the production-efficient layoff rate higher By for positive payroll taxes); b), leading to a higher layoff rate than in the benchmark. This allocation can be implemented by the government choosing unemployment benefits u* t and financing them partly through , > 0. layoff taxes f, and partly through payroll taxes, Put another way, the implementation implies now a contribution rate smaller than one. As before, implementation can be achieved fG(y*) from firms that layoff by a pooling agency, receiving contributions and contributions r(l — G(y*) from those that do not, and paying unemployment benefits G(y*)j±* to laid-off workers. join, and the agency may therefore be Firms have an incentive to private. Discussion 3.3 Two extensions of this analysis of shallow pockets are explored more formally in a com- panion paper (Blanchard-Tirole 2005). Here a short is summary of the conclusions of that paper: (a) Endogenization of limited pocket-depth. There are at least two reasons shallow pockets. The first reason they can. This arises when, government policy the state cannot is is may in contrast to the set after rather commit and that they maintained assumption of than before firms sets (t, /, (j.) why firms have not want to have deep pockets even after firms invest. if this paper, the Suppose, for example, that have invested and hired workers, but before they learn the productivity of the match. In this case, firms will obviously choose to be "judgment proof, i.e. to have no assets left in 13 case of layoff, so / = 0. The threshold is = b + fJ.*/[l — then given by: y* layoff rate, reflects two G{y*). The high threshold, one coming from zero distortions, and by implication, the high layoff taxes and the other from positive payroll taxes. Second, firms income. When may have limited access to external finance due to a dearth of pledgeable the entrepreneurs enjoy a rent cannot appropriate the in the benchmark. We R > in case of continuation, investors more surplus from continuation, which leads to full find however that, should in this case, the state than layoffs still make the "investor-entrepreneur coalition" fully accountable for the cost of layoffs, so the optimal contribution rate remains equal to one. (b) Multi-activity firms. A concern often expressed by policy makers firm can pay the layoff taxes, companion paper, may have it to collect the fully collectable If it did collect the amount full shows that the state amount, the marginal excessive incentives for the firm to shut 4 one the The and implication in general does not want (/ in the notation of this section) in case of partial layoff tax be equal to zero (as the state cannot collect more than in if to close otherwise healthy activities. in a two-activity context, investigates the possibility of such "spillovers" or "snowball" effects. It layoffs. that, even is down entirely /.) on further layoffs would This would in turn provide when having low productivity only activity. Ex-post wage bargaining Our benchmark embodied the assumption that wages were hiring. set ex-ante, i.e. at the time of This had the implication that, by offering unemployment insurance to workers, a firm could not only offer a lower wage, but actually lower its risk averse expected labor costs. To some extent however, there is always some room the case, a firm which has to pay a layoff tax position vis-a-vis that worker; a worker off is in of a stronger position. unemployment benefits The if it who for ex-post bargaining. lays a worker off will receive is in a unemployment layoff tax, the severance When this is weaker bargaining benefits if laid payments, and the provision both lead to higher, not lower, wages, and thus increase labor costs. In this section, we therefore modify our earlier assumption about wage setting, ex-post wage bargaining instead, and characterize the optimal allocation and 14 its assume imple- In order to avoid the complexities attached mentation under ex-post wage bargaining. we assume, to bargaining under incomplete information, the firm and the worker observe productivity ex post. in this section only, that both Thus "ex-post wage bargaining" includes the assumption of symmetric information between worker and firm ex post. A 4.1 The formalization of wage bargaining following formalization captures the effects of benefits and taxes on ex-post wage determination in a simple way: Assume wage setting now takes place after productivity of a two-stage game. In stage either accept the offer or turn by the worker with probability realized, down. turns down, the wage it by the firm with probability or /?, If it Under the assumption that the firm chooses the threshold to maximize profit ex-post, in stage 2, the highest the wage offered by the worker, and therefore the wage accept, wage in stage 2 is given by (3{y worker will make the highest and is equal to y offered — r offer by the — + f. firm, is The firm can is set in stage 2, either — /3. will accept, lowest equal to + /) + (1 — (3){b + /i). The level of productivity so as wage the firm r 1 the outcome is the worker makes a wage offer to the firm. 1, it is b + and therefore wage the worker fi. will Thus, the expected This implies that, acceptable by the (risk neutral) firm, i.e. in stage 1, the an offer of w(y)-=P(y-r+f) + {l-0)(b + n). The higher the layoff tax, or the lower the payroll tax, or the higher the unemployment benefits, the higher The threshold is the wage. value for productivity, y, is given by the condition that w(y) +T—y = f. Using the expression for the wage and rearranging: y Note that the threshold of / see, = fi, t = would is = b+l_l + T-f. (14) privately efficient. Just as in the benchmark, the combination deliver the production-efficient threshold, y other considerations are now = b. But, as we shall relevant. Expression (14) allows us to rewrite the wage schedule w(y) = (b + fj,)+P(y-y). 15 as: (15) The wage paid to the marginal worker, the worker in a job with productivity equal to the threshold level, unemployment equal to is benefits + (b wage equivalent the fj,), unemployed plus of being and severance payments. The wage then increases with /? times the difference between productivity and threshold productivity. 4.2 The optimal The optimal allocation same problem allocation solves the ditional constraint that the wage as in the benchmark, subject to the ad- no longer a decision variable, but is is instead given by equation (15): max G(y) U(b + n) + [ U(w(y)) dG(y), subject to the resource constraint: -G{y)n+ J (y-w(y))dG(y)=I, and the wage relation w(y) =b+ + P(y n Under pure ex-post wage bargaining, the scope surance to workers is extremely limited: An -y). unemployment for increase in change the slope of the income schedule, increasing employment y benefits. in the worker's The Put differently, the only all b+ is utility if = y] 1 (J- . employed, and expected value of marginal So long as marginal so y* is /3 utility is the location of the kink is if P(l-G(?)) G(y*)U'(b E[U'\y b. The *n > y*} (16) EU' - G{y*)) + n) + J-\ is the expected value of marginal U'{w{y)) dG{y) is the unconditional utility. strictly positive, and workers strictly risk averse, then the expected utility, and layoff rate exceeds the production-efficient level. Setting y* =b employed greater than follows: implicitly defined by: U'(w(y))dG(y))/{\ E U' = benefits does not wages by an amount equal to un- degree of freedom g(F) > unemployment income schedule. The solution can be characterized as threshold level of productivity where E[U'\y benefits to provide in- is less than the unconditional expected marginal 16 = Our formalization shows that it is optimal to choose a threshold higher than the production-efficient level so as to decrease income (and / fi) would achieve production risk averse the workers, or the stronger the workers in bargaining, The more uncertainty. the higher the threshold Given y, efficiency. and level, 11 so the higher the layoff rate. and by implication the wage schedule w(y) are determined by the resource fj, constraint above. Implementation through payroll and 4.3 Replacing y from (16) first relation in the expression for the threshold decision of firms, (14), gives between / and /-r relation is = A* -P (1-G(y«)) E[U'\y 7=^ given, as before, efficient level. namely By unity. shortfall of the 11 clear is This is is now in left fi and so, /—r < must be (i. (7). As the Together with a contribution rate below higher than the production- is its benchmark value, positive, in order to finance the unemployment insurance system. of getting more intuition and reorganize to read: + n) + f Jy ((b for the The optimal threshold + /j) + P(y - y)) dG{y) is to combine the < G(y)b + / first and the second y dG{y) Jy side gives the value of total workers' the economy. < negative, from above: The optimal threshold implication, payroll taxes G{y){b The (17) achieved by lowering the contribution rate from One way constraints, y* by the budget constraint, equation the government budget constraint, this implies / The reason > EU' ) second term on the right side of equation (17) one. the r: g{y The other layoff taxes income (the sum of wages, reservation wages, and benefits) income in the economy. The two are the same, as right side gives the value of total free entry implies zero profit income. Suppose, counterfactually, that changes in y do not affect total income, and so do not affect total workers' Then, changes in y change the shape of the income profile without affecting the total workers' income. income. An increase in y implies that the same, but the income schedule = more workers receive (fi + b). The overall workers' income remains Indeed, the best value of y from the point of insurance workers receive the same income. is flatter. is where all The assumption that changes in y do not affect total income is, however, clearly incorrect. Starting from y = b, small changes in y do not affect total income; this implies that, as it decreases risk, at least a small increase in y is desirable; this explains why the optimal y exceeds b. But, as y increases, the output loss increases, and total income decreases. For y = 1 for example, total income is just b and so fi must be equal to zero. This implies that the optimal value of y is greater than 6, but less than one. y 1, 17 Note that for /3 = 0, i.e. if workers have no bargaining power, then we obtain the same characterization as in the benchmark: / the wage schedule now is = fi and =w— /j, increasing in productivity, it b. As becomes (3 positive, and can be shown that the equations above imply: df i That is, < du Tp <0 both the unemployment benefit and the more bargaining power, and the - layoff tax decrease as the workers acquire layoff tax falls faster, leading to a decreasing contribution rate. We summarize our When wages Proposition 4. worker same is the results as follows: as for the unemployed workers, and workers with higher productivity These outcomes are independent of the receive a higher wage. is are set through ex-post bargaining, utility for the marginal state's policy choices. optimal to induce a threshold higher than the production-efficient choice decreases the uncertainty faced by workers at some level: (y* > b) . It This cost in efficiency. This optimal allocation can in turn be implemented through a combination of layoff taxes, payroll taxes, ployment benefits, and unemployment Layoff taxes must be benefits. with payroll taxes used to make up less than unem- the difference; equivalently, the contribution rate must be less than one. Heterogeneity 5 We have assumed so far that clearly are not. Firms all workers and assets. firms were ex-ante identical. In reality, they differ in the distribution of the distribution of productivity and relative Workers all productivity shocks demand (or, more generally, shocks) they face, and in their initial also differ in the distribution of productivity. We study in this section the implications of heterogeneity in productivity, both on the firm and on the worker side, both observed and unobserved. 5.1 A Heterogeneity of firms worry often expressed by policy makers than others, a layoff tax will penalize is that, if them more, and 18 some this firms have higher layoff rates may be undesirable. To explore this idea, suppose there are two types of firms, "strong" and "weak", which The productivity differ in their productivity distributions. of "strong firms" is drawn from 12 cumulative distribution Gh(-) and that of "weak firms" from distribution Gl(-)- distribution function of strong firms stochastically dominates that of Gh(v) < Gl{v)- The in (0, 1), fraction of strong firms is equal to Let us start with the assumption that this heterogeneity unable to is weak The firms: for all y p. unobserved, so the state is the two types of firms apart. Let us also start with the assumption that the tell state sets a uniform policy (t, /, We /i). return to these two assumptions below. Note that given the distribution assumptions and uniform taxation, strong firms have We higher expected profits than weak firms. fixed. By Thus, at the creation margin, the both types may contrast, assume that the number of strong firms free entry condition lay workers off, is relevant for so the destruction margin is weak is firms only. relevant for both types of firms. The fact that the free entry condition difficult to follow now. We is relevant only for weak firms we have the optimal allocation/implementation approach makes it more followed until take instead the more "pedestrian" route of solving the optimization problem of the state given firms' behavior. We assume that the state maximizes the welfare of workers. Allowing the state to also put some weight on the positive rents earned by the owners of strong firms would not alter the results. The problem state's optimization max [ P G H (y) + (1 is given by: - p)G L (y)\ U(b + p.) {T,f,p.,w,y} + [p(l - G H (y)) + (1 - P )(l - GL {y))\ U(w), subject to the free-entry condition for weak firms -G L (y)f+ I (y-w-T)dG L (y)=I, the government budget constraint -[pG H (y) + (l-p)G L (y)}(p-f) + [p(l-G H "We assume fb ydGi(y) > I m + (l-p)(l-G L (y))}r that the weak firms are not too unproductive. : Weak firms have positive NPV = 0, Namely we assume that 6Gl(&) + for the production-efficient threshold. 19 and the threshold productivity condition, which y The the same for weak and strong firms: is =w+r- f. solution can then be characterized as follows: • The • The threshold state fully insures workers: w = b+ fi. level of productivity is given by: {P9H(y) By + G H {y)) - P (G L (y) = b+ y (l-p)9L(y))' the definition of weak and strong firms, Gi(y) threshold level This solution benefits, so is is higher than the efficient in turn > Gh(jj)- So, unless p = 0, the level. implemented by choosing layoff taxes lower than unemployment through a contribution rate lower than unity. The difference is financed through payroll taxes. The firms intuition for why the contribution rate may lay workers off and so the is destruction margin applies to creation margin corresponds to the welfare by allowing for than one is less weak firms only. The some cross-subsidy from strong the rents of strong firms to wages. Because the state is to as follows: all firms. Both types of By contrast, the state can then improve workers' weak firms —transferring some of unable to assess the firms' strength, the cross-subsidy operates through the contribution rate: Weak firms lay workers off more than strong firms and so benefit more from a contribution rate smaller than unity. Can the state do better by offering menus and shows that while offering a menu improves acteristics of the uniform with a contribution rate If heterogeneity apart, the state can It is still is policy, for weak Appendix 1 the solution carries the main char- namely cross-subsidization observable, do even letting firms self select? efficiency, of weak firms by strong firms, firms below one. i.e. if the state is able to tell weak and strong better. Characterizing the optimal policy optimal to subsidize weak firms. is firms straightforward: This can now be done however by offering a 20 job creation subsidy to the weak firms, while setting the net contribution rate equal to 1 for both types of firms. This achieves the desired redistribution from strong to weak (Note that both layoff and firms, while avoiding distortions at the destruction margin. payroll taxes must be higher than in the benchmark, as the extra revenue finance job creation subsidies to weak The firms. unemployment payroll tax remains however equal to between the difference benefits, so there is needed to layoff tax is and the no distortion at the destruction margin.) We can summarize our results as follows: Proposition 5. Suppose that there are two types of Strong "strong" or "weak". firms: weak firms Gl(-), and Gl(u) > Gjj(y) firms have productivity distribution Gh(-), for all y in (0,1). if optimal policy is to fully insure workers (w = the state relies on a uniform policy, then the and If this heterogeneity is unobserved, the efficient level (y > b), If the state offers a and implement menu b + fi), instead, then the optimal the following properties: Workers are fully insured. rate of unity, and choose the efficient threshold. below one, and the threshold exceeds the the same, cross-subsidization of Whether the state offers to set If heterogeneity is separates the firms and has Weak firms face a net contribution rate The underlying mechanism remains weak firms through the use of a lower contribution menus or a unit contribution menu than one. less Strong firms face a net contribution efficient level. not, small enough, to not have them operate at and choose a threshold level higher than through a contribution rate it it is all optimal, if rate. the proportion of weak firms is —at the cost of some ex-ante unemployment— rate. observed by the state, then the optimal policy subsidy to weak firms, choose the efficient is to offer a job creation threshold for productivity, and implement it through a unit net contribution rate for both types of firms. 5.2 Heterogeneity of workers Another frequently expressed worry others, and that a layoff tax these workers worse To explore is that may make some workers firms are more reluctant more likely to be than laid-off to hire them, and thus make off. this idea, we set up a case very similar to that of are two types of workers, "high-ability" and 21 firms. "low-ability" workers. We assume there High-ability workers A . have a productivity distribution given by Gh(.), low-ability workers a distribution given by > Gn(y) Gl{-), with Gl{v) is equal to We for all y in (0, l). 13 The fraction of workers with high ability p. assume that firms know the workers' abilities. Proceeding in parallel with the earlier case of heterogeneity in firms, we workers' abilities, and that chooses a uniform policy We it start by assuming both that the state does not know the (r, /,//). can simplify the set-up of the optimization problem, by noting that workers of each type will be fully insured, and that, because high-ability workers are more valuable to they will be paid more, both when employed and when unemployed. firms, Suppose therefore that low-ability workers receive employed, and are fully insured, so when employed, and p + A w = b + p. w when employed, and p when un- High-ability workers will then receive when unemployed (so w+A=b+p+ A), where A w+ is the additional expected profit brought about to the firm by a high-ability worker. Noting that A does not affect the layoff decision, so the threshold productivity types of workers, A= Payment who is when paid it follows that [G L (y) - GH A {y)} f is is the same for both given by: + J Jy [y - (b + p) - r) [dG H (y) - dG L (y)] A can be achieved by wage-indexed unemployment benefits, so a worker w + A receives p + A (and the firm pays correspondingly higher layoff taxes of laying a high-ability worker off). With this characterization of wage setting, and assuming that the utilitarian social welfare function, the optimal policy max {(1 is the solution - p)U{b + (j,)+pU{b + ti state maximizes a to: + A)}, {t,/,M,5} subject to the free entry condition -G L (y)f+ I [y-(b + iJ.)-T}dG L (y)=I, Jy 13 We assume that the low productivity workers are not too unproductive. Namely we assume that ydGL{y) > I- Under observed heterogeneity, the low-ability workers are sufficiently productive justify investment by firms. bGL^b) to + J* 22 and the government budget constraint - [(1 where A The G L (y) + pG H (y)} p) (/ - p) + P) [1 " Gl (v)} +P[l-G H (y)]] r = 0, and y have been defined above. solution has the following form: • If the proportion of low-ability workers is - [(1 is high enough, then the threshold for productivity given by: p(l + V [(1 - - p)g L (y) Note that Gi{y) - Gh(V) on the right is positive, This solution rest of is is positive, and so f/p > 1; No job is small enough, however, then The unity, with the not optimal to created for them, and they receive unemployment = is given by: b. implemented by relying on a gross contribution rate greater than one: and a net contribution rate equal turn given by r level. it is is y is A). So the fraction higher than the efficient is for sure. In this case, threshold productivity This solution +b+ benefits being financed by payroll taxes. facilitate their employability. p U'(p implemented by using a contribution rate below • If the fraction of low-ability workers benefits + b) - U'(p is and the optimal threshold in turn unemployment - G H {y)\ [U'(p + b) - U'(p + b + A)} + P9h(v)} 1(1 - pW(p + b) + P U'(p + b + A)Y p){G L (y) = [(1 — to one: f — t = p. The payroll tax rate is in p)j p\ p. intuition for these results is as follows. When both types of workers are employed, the use of a contribution rate below one reduces the cost to firms of hiring a low-ability worker. This in turn leads to a higher relative wage for low-ability workers, and therefore reduces inequality, but at some cost in efficiency. is very low, it is more efficient to If the proportion of low-ability workers have them not work, and then to choose tax rates so as to have efficient separations for high-ability workers. Because unemployment benefits taxes, the solution requires having for low-ability workers exceed corresponding layoff both a positive payroll tax and a correspondingly higher 23 layoff tax on high-ability workers. This increases revenues while maintaining a net bution rate equal to one. Note that the logic of the results under firm and worker heterogeneity workers (firms) are more likely to be laid of the externality of the layoff on the What if UI fund The aimed aimed at firms that It is at firms that a net contribution rate below one. similar: Weak Both types straightforward to announce they have announce they have hired a low-ability option has a net contribution rate equal to one. first is and an incomplete internalization benefits the creation margin. state then offers two options, one hired a high-ability worker, one worker. off (to lay off), the state can offer menus and firms then self-select? show that the contri- 14 The second option has of workers are fully insured. Thus, just as in the uniform case, heterogeneity leads to lower layoff taxes, but in this case only for low-ability workers. What happens differences if between workers are observable? apart high-ability from low-ability workers tell or disabled —then the optimal policy — is solution combines job creation subsidies summarize our Proposition ability". G L (-), 6. if they hire a low-ability worker. The net when differences are only partly observable, the and a net contribution rate below one. results in the following proposition: Suppose that there are two types of workers: "high- ability" and "low- High-ability workers have productivity distribution £?#(•), low-ability workers and G L (y) > G H (y) If this heterogeneity is optimal policy is for all y in (0, 1). unobserved and the state to fully insure workers (w the efficient level (y The workers are in bad health if set equal to one for both types, and the destruction margin undistorted for both types. In general, We example the state can to offer a job creation subsidy (or, equivalently, is uniformly lower payroll and layoff taxes) to firms contribution rate can then be for When > b), and implement relies on a uniform policy, then the = b it through a contribution rate + fi), choose a threshold level higher than less than one. lower layoff tax leads in effect to a transfer from high-ability workers to low-ability workers. If the state offers a menu instead, then the optimal menu separates workers and has the following properties: Workers are fully insured. Firms hiring high-ability workers face L4 This result is Cahuc and and payroll tax rates. related to the result in also leads to higher layoff Jolivet (2003) 24 where the need to finance a public good a net contribution rate of unity, and choose the efficient threshold. Firms hiring low-ability workers face a net contribution rate below one, and the threshold exceeds the The underlying mechanism remains the same, through the use of a lower contribution Whether or not the low-ability workers is state is efficient level. cross-subsidization of low-ability workers rate. allowed to use menus, it is optimal, if the proportion of small enough, to leave them unemployed, and use a unit contribution rate for the remaining, high-ability workers. If heterogeneity is observed by the state, then the optimal policy creation subsidy to low-ability workers, and implement it and choose an efficient is to offer a job threshold for productivity, through a unit contribution rate. Mixing unemployment benefits and severance pay 6 We We have assumed throughout that the state was the sole provider of insurance to workers. saw how, even under was able to implement the optimal assumption however raises two issues relative to the scope location. This provision of insurance. for the state. this assumption, the state The As we have first is for private-sector whether a private third-party insurer can substitute seen, the answer firms or across workers, are absent, al- i.e. is yes as long as redistributive concerns, across except in section 5. The second issue is whether the third party insurer, whether the state or a private insurance company, needs to de- mand exclusivity and prohibit the firm from offering supplemental insurance in the form of severance pay. A recurrent theme of the insurance literature is that the insurer must be wary of the externality imposed by supplemental insurance contracts (Pauly (1974)). For this reason, insurance companies often demand exclusivity and managerial compensation contracts pre- vent executives from undoing their incentives through insider trading or derivatives contracts with financial institutions. In the context of this paper, the state's provision of insurance to workers raises the question of welfare-reducing supplemental insurance. Let us it first note that allowing severance pay does not reduce (nor, of course, does increase) welfare suggests, when the state already provides full insurance to workers. and analysis confirms, that the firm does not want to undo the full Intuition insurance pro- vided by the state by overinsuring the worker (severance pay) or underinsuring her (asking the worker to return some of the unemployment benefits, assuming this were feasible). Thus, the analysis of Sections 1 (benchmark), 3 (shallow pockets) and 5 (firm or worker 25 heterogeneity) is immune to the introduction of severance pay. The co-insurance problem may insured, that Section 4, is in Sections 2 (incomplete insurance) though, the firm is when therefore arise only new wage is imperfectly and 4 (ex post wage bargaining). In unable to exchange a bit more insurance against a lower wage. Indeed, severance pay increases the wage one-for-one; pay, the the worker if /j,p denotes the severance function, w(y), can be written as: w{y) = P (y - r + f + nF + (1 - 0) = w(y)+/j, F + n + ii F (b ) ) . The threshold f + fip', that is, value for productivity, independent of severance pay. Put no externality on the state (as it Thus, the analysis of Section 4 The only is is fi differently, the introduction of severance . immune also Vw = And to the introduction of severance pay. utility of workers is -G(y)(f is therefore optimal and allow firms see this, return to stage 2 is w and a severance given by: + n)-B) + (l- G(y)(U(b +fiF the free entry condition VF = To 2). benchmark, contracts which specify both a wage The expected pay exerts doesn't change y) and only serves to increase labor costs. that of incomplete insurance (Section fip +t — y = = b + + r-f case in which co-insurance reduces welfare and exclusivity to offer, as in the payment, given by the condition that w(y) the threshold y is y, is G(y))U(w), given by: + »f) + V dG(y) I - (1 - G(y))(w +t) = I. Jy Now, starting from fip w = b + fi, = 0, and assuming the economy consider the effects of a small increase in fip. is at the optimal allocation, so From the two equations above, it follows that dVw = Firms therefore have an incentive to allocation. The reason why is 9{ y - 1 Bdixp > -n G(y) offer 0. more insurance than required in the optimal that increasing fip has two effects on the expected utility of 26 workers. First, it wedge between marginal creates a starting from the optimal allocation, this effect reduces the probability of a is equal to When U{w) — U(b This is +B = B, this up however, they firms increase unemployment + /j) because the layoff; is utility when employed and unemployed; of second order. loss in utility effect is of first The other is that it from becoming unemployed order and dominates the first. decrease layoffs, and given that layoff taxes exceed benefits paid by the state, they impose a negative externality on the state. why, in the end, letting firms freely choose severance payments leads to a suboptimal allocation. Proposition 7. In the incomplete insurance extension of Section pay severance payments in addition to the unemployment 2, allowing the firm to benefits paid by the state leads to oversinsurance, an unemployment insurance deficit and suboptimal welfare. By contrast, severance pay has no impact on welfare in the benchmark and in the other extensions. 7 We Extensions and Conclusions are very much aware however of the limits of our analysis. model, there are a number of issues An important issue not as triggered taken up here b, The first is and depend very much y), work If we think of layoffs and quits as triggered by reservation wage —which we do not have actions by firms to induce workers they layoffs. in each case The by workers The second off instead (shirking). to mislabel quits issues in that of quits versus layoffs. explicitly in our of the layoff tax as applying only in case of layoffs, this raises quit instead (harassment), and actions them is or to the disutility of we think sets of issues. to lay to be explored. Let us mention two. by productivity shocks (shocks to shocks (shocks to model), and still Even within our one-period is would to induce firms they two like to lay off to would like to quit actions by firms and workers together incentives to harass, shirk, or cooperatively misreport, on the contribution rate. We have informally explored these Blanchard and Tirole (2003b), but a formal treatment remains to be given. Another issue is the role of judges, who, in and are often ultimately the logic of our argument many European in charge of deciding is that this is whether countries, play a central role, layoffs are justified or not. Clearly, better accomplished through a combination of layoff taxes and severance payments, with the decision then being left to the firm. But our look at the implications of imperfections, from shallow pockets to heterogeneity, also suggests the 27 — desirability of adapting layoff taxes to particular situations. This can in principle be done through offering menus, or allowing taxes to be conditional on observable characteristics by leaving some discretion to judges. of firms, or when judges do in fact and more informed have the information, the It remains to be shown however ability, and the if and incentives, to take better decisions. Then, and obviously so, there are dynamic issues we could not consider at all in our one- period model. Dynamic models of the labor market with risk aversion and imperfections are notoriously hard to solve. The only model we know which derives optimal institutions defined as the optimal combination of payroll taxes, layoff taxes, job creation subsidies or and unemployment taxes, However, it benefits —was developed by Mortensen assumes risk neutrality and so cannot deal interaction between insurance and efficiency. in and Pissarides (2003). a convincing way with the (A model by Alvarez and Veracierto [1998] has risk averse workers, self-insurance as well as state-provided insurance, payroll and layoff taxes, and severance payments. While of these instruments, it The first is is effects of changes in some model as We essential: the role and the implications of self insurance by workers (in terms of the here, the role question shows (numerically) the does not give a characterization of optimal taxes and benefits.) see two extensions of our model it the role, and implications if any, of of the endogeneity of b). In this context, an important mandatory individual unemployment accounts such as are being considered or introduced in a number of Latin American countries. (Three papers All three allow for self-insurance, provide a useful starting point here. role of state-provided insurance in the presence of other imperfections. Imrohoroglu (1992), moral hazard in search limits the scope and look In at the Hansen and for state-provided insurance. In Acemoglu and Shimer (1999, 2000), state-provided insurance affects search, which in turn affects match quality.) The second is the role of experience rating systems, such as the US system, as ways of implementing the collection of layoff taxes. This requires a careful look not only at the dynamic problem of the firm, but at the exact nature of the financial constraints that it faces. We feel, nevertheless, that as it stands, the paper can be helpful in thinking about reform about employment protection in Europe (the origin of the paper was indeed a request to define the contours of employment protection reform in France; our conclusions are presented in Blanchard and Tirole [2003a,b]): 28 The basic conclusion from the nanced through layoff taxes odds with reality in is benchmark that unemployment straightforward conceptually. It is benefits should be fi- however very much at Europe. All European unemployment insurance systems are financed through payroll rather than layoff taxes; other things equal, both lead to too high a layoff rate. The lack of layoff taxes is counterbalanced however, in many countries, by heavy judicial intervention. This suggests that a shift from judicial intervention to higher layoff taxes firms may be desirable, reducing uncertainty and channeling layoff costs into on unemployment benefits. The to insurance, higher layoff also very relevant. this —that in the presence of limits taxes and a contribution rate larger than one are — basic conclusion from considering limits to insurance comes justified Employment protection is at the cost of production efficiency. This suggests the unemployment insurance which allow search. Recent reforms, for better insurance while if importance of reforms of still which make unemployment benefits more search and acceptance of jobs is then a partial substitute for insurance, but providing incentives to explicitly conditional available, go in that direction. If successful, they on can bring not only better insurance, but also lower employment protection and lower production inefficiencies. The final broad insight is that layoff and payroll tax schedules should be tailored to the economic environment in which firms operate. Lower layoff taxes and higher payroll taxes are called for in industries, countries, or periods in which firms have shallow pockets. Similarly, and less unobserved firm or worker heterogeneity suggests relying more on payroll taxes, on layoff taxes in the financing of unemployment benefits. 29 References [1] Acemoglu, ical [2] D., Economy, Acemoglu, D., and R. Shimer, (1999), "Efficient Unemployment Insurance", Journal of Polit- 107-5, October, 893-928. and R. Shimer, (2000), "Productivity Gains from Unemployment Insurance", European Economic Review, 44-7, June, 1195-1224. [3] Akcrlof, G., the [4] Wage and H. Miyazaki (1980) "The Implicit Contract Theory of Unemployment Meets Bill Argument," Review of Economic Studies, Alvarez, F., and M. Veracierto 48: 321-338. (1998), "Search, Self-Insurance and Job Security provisions," working paper WP98-2, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. [5] Azariadis, C. (1975) "Implicit Contracts and ical [6] Economy, Baily, Underemployment Equilibria," Journal of Polit- 83: 1183-1202. M.(1974) "Wages and Employment under Uncertain Demand," Review of Economic Studies, 41: 37-50. [7] Blanchard, O., and J. Tirole (2003a), "Redesigning the Employment Protection System," De Economist, 152: 1-20. [8] (2003b), "Licenciements et Institutions dAnalyse Economique. La Documentation [9] (2005), du Marche du Travail," Rapport pour le Conseil Frangaise, pp. 7-50. "Layoff Taxes and Shallow Pocket Firms," mimeo, MIT and University of Toulouse. [10] Cahuc, P. islation?", [11] and G. Jolivet, (2003), mimeo Paris "Do We Need More Stringent Employment Protection Leg- I. Hansen, G. and A. Imrohoroglu, (1992) "The Role of Unemployment Insurance in an Economy with Liquidity Constraints and Moral Hazard", Journal of Political Economy, 100-1, February, 118-142. [12] Holmstrom, B. (1982) "Moral Hazard in Teams," Bell Journal of Economics, 13-2: 324-340. 30 [13] Mortensen, D., and C. Pissarides (2003) "Taxes, Subsidies and Equilibrium Labor Market Outcomes" Enterprise, [14] Pauly, M. , Designing Inclusion: Edmund (1974) S. Phelps Tools to Raise (ed), Low-End Pay and Employment in Private Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. "Overinsurance and Public Provision of Insurance: The Roles Hazard and Adverse Selection", Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88(1): 44-62. 31 of Moral — Appendix Policy 1: Suppose the state offers menus under an option (tx, firm heterogeneity fL ) targeted at strong firms, rather than the single option (r, /). olds, payroll is and now indexed by the type layoff taxes are identical to the problem above, except that the y is - [w weak at firms and another (r#, /#) With obvious notation change of firm), the optimization (thresh- problem last constraint, + t - f] = 0, replaced by the constraints: yL - [w + tl - fL yn ~[w + th - fH = =0, ] \ 0, and the incentive compatibility constraint that the strong firms do not want to masquerade as weak ones is given by: -G H (Vh) fu+ It is (y-w-TH dG H (y) > -G H (vl) !l + I (y -w- tl ) dG H {y). useful at this point to define the net contribution rate as the ratio of the layoff tax minus the payroll tax to unemployment as the net contribution rate here f ) is not the layoff tax is benefits, (fi — Ti)/fii, i equal to one, the layoff decision = H,L. Note is efficient: that, so long What matters but the difference between the layoff tax and the payroll itself, tax. The solution can then be characterized as follows: w=b+ • The • Strong firms face a net contribution rate equal to one, and so choose the state still fully insures workers: /j,. efficient threshold: yH • Weak = b = and fH - th firms face a net contribution rate below one, than the /J- and so choose a threshold higher efficient level: G l {Vl) -G H {y~L) t^— VL=b + p -— 1 PWLiVL) , . r 32 and f,L , -TL <. fi. ^28/4 02 7 IAB 2 4 2UG5 Date Due 3 9080 02618 0643