Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/disorganizationOOblan u .M415 |/io.%-30 ® working paper department of economics DISORGANIZATION Olivier Blanchard + Michael KMWvcf" 96-30 October, 1996 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 DISORGANIZATION Olivier Blanchard » ^ctaxel Ktev*t 96-30 October, 1996 Disorganization Michael Kremer Olivier Blanchard * Department of Economics, MIT, Cambridge, mer@mit.edu) Greif, . 02138. (blanchar@mit.edu) and (kre- We thank Susan Athey, Abhijit Banerjee, Simon Commander, Bill Easterly, Avner Dani Kaufmann, Gian-Maria Andrei Shleifer MA * for discussions for research assistance. Milesi-Ferreti, and comments. We Wolfgang Pesendorfer, Julio Rotemberg and thank Maciej Dudek and Andrei Sarychev Michael Kremer thanks the Research Department of the International Monetary Fund, where some of the initial work for this paper was conducted. Disorganization Abstract Under central planning, many firms relied on a single supplier for inputs. Transition has led to decentralized bargaining ers. be Under incomplete contracts inefficient, many of their between suppliers and buy- or asymmetric information, such bargaining can and the mechanisms that mitigate this problem in the West can only play a limited role in transition. For example, the scope for long-term relations to reduce opportunistic behavior to disappear or disorganization, change most of is limited existing firms are expected their suppliers in the future. and a sharp decrease that disorganization has played a than in Central Europe. when many in output. The more important The result has been empirical evidence suggests role in the former Soviet Union Disorganization Figures 1 and 2 show the evolution of official measures of GDP The two of the former Soviet Union, since 1989. in the countries figures give a striking picture, that of an extremely large decline in output. In 10 out of the 15 countries, for 1996 is expected to stand at The evolution unreported still of these activities. official less than half its 1989 measures GDP level. reflects in large part a shift to unofficial, But studies which attempt to adjust for unofficial activity conclude that there has been a large decline in output. For example, a recent study, by Kaufmann and Kaliberda [1995], puts the actual decline in GDP from 1989 to 1994 for the set of countries of the former Soviet Union at 35%, compared to a reported decline of about 50%. x This large decline in output presents an obvious challenge ory. Given the myriad price and trade for neo-classical the- distortions present under the Soviet system, these countries surely operated far inside their production frontier before transition. With the removal of these distortions, one would have expected operate closer to the frontier, and thus output to increase. expected that the development of new tier out, activities would And them to one would have production fron- shift the leading to further increases in output over time. This clearly is not what has happened. In this paper, we explore one explanation lieve has played 1. an important role. for the decline of output, The best word to describe it is which we be- disorganization. Estimates for a number of other studies are given and discussed in European Bank for Recon- struction and Development [1996], Annex 11-1. CO CJ mo cd a LD CD CD o L_ ZD CO 3) L_ a CO CD CD m CO CO =) a CD as CD CD >CD Q CJ o cz o CD CO o > UJ CD -r O — co CD o CO o CO O o O CD CD cq o CD [_ ZJ en |8ASH co LO o CO o o o CM CO o > o GO i_ CD LD O, O CD 00 CJ 00 oo ZJ Q_ CD ^CD n — a CD a, CD cd >CD Q_ Q CD O cz I I CD CD I mCKM(ESj-)UJO m3<»-o;S<muj CD C\J C\J CO CD CD O CD CD CD CO CD CD |9A9-| O CM CO CD CO CD Disorganization goes as follows: Its logic • Central planning was characterized by a complex set of highly specific relations between "specific" if firms. (Following there is standard usage, we shall call a relation a joint surplus to the parties from dealing with each other rather than taking their next best alternative.) There were typically fewer firms in each industry than in the West. 2 For or knew firms • many of only one supplier from which to buy. For had or Specificity knew of only one buyer to opens room for bargaining. complete contracts, the whom many had of their goods, 3 Under asymmetric information or result of bargaining set of highly specific relations to sell. inputs, firms may be can thus lead to a inefficient. in- A complex poor aggegate outcome, with large effects on total production. • Through various institutions and arrangements, economies develop ways of limiting the adverse effects of specificity: Under central planning, the main instrument was the coercive power of the central planner to enforce production In the West, for some goods, there eliminating specificity altogether. verse effects of specificity is and delivery of goods. are And many alternative buyers for other goods, the 2. scope for ad- between firms. Transition eliminated the central planner, and thus the main instrument One reason is that, in the create incentives for entry of 3. sellers, reduced by arrangements ranging from vertical integration, to contracts, to long-term relations • and The buyer was transition. West, (non natural) monopolies and associated monopoly rents new firms. There was no such mechanism under central planning. often a centralized trade organization, which disappeared altogether during Disorganization used to limit the adverse effects of specificity under the previous regime. But the mechanisms which West could not operate exist in the right away. New buyers and sellers cannot be created overnight. The role of contracts is reduced when many firms are close to bankruptcy. At the same time, transition has created the anticipation that change many suppliers, thus shortening horizons state firms will disappear or and the scope for long-term re- lations to avoid the adverse effects of specificity. • The result has been the breakdown of many economic between the republics of the former Soviet Union has than seems consistent with tion, many crucial workers/managers, turing it and and raw who may have been survival. Cannibalization of fallen by far more materials. Firms lose their only machines Trade Despite price liberaliza- efficient reallocation. firms report shortages of inputs relations. is hope for restruc- widespread, even when appears that machines would be more productive in their original use. This general disorganization has played an important role in explaining the decline in output. Our paper • is organized as follows: In sections 1 to 3, we show through three examples how specificity, together with either incompleteness of contracts or asymmetric information, can lead to large output losses. We show how the effects depend both on the degree of specificity in the relations between firms, and on the complexity of the production process. portunities can lead We show also how to a collapse of the emergence of new private op- production in the state sector, and to a sharp reduction in total output. • In section 4, we argue that the mechanisms used in the West to deal with Disorganization specificity take time to transition. that it makes a In section • We develop and have therefore played a limited role in also discuss the policy implications of our theory, — limited —case and argue for gradualism. taking measures of reported "shortages" of inputs by firms as 5, indicators of disorganization, we show that disorganization appears to have played an important role in the former Soviet Union, but a more limited one in Central Europe. Before starting, Our analysis is it may be useful to do some product differentiation. based on standard ideas in microeconomics, from asymmetric in- formation, to hold-up problems under incomplete contracts, to the breakdown of cooperation in repeated games as the horizon shortens or as alternative opportunities arise. 4 The potential importance of specificity for has been emphasized recently by Caballero and tion is Hammour macroeconomics [1996]. Our contribu- to point to the potential importance of these problems in the context of transition. Our analysis Most explanations tion. form, may complements other explanations of the decline and for new start from the need private firms to emerge. reflect efficient reorganization capital, as firms try 4. On this last topic, see for tion within households, development. for state firms to decline Some for example). In contrast, Newman trans- in information look for the right jobs. (Atkeson example Wells and Maher [1995] and Banerjee and and argue that the output decline and unmeasured investment new techniques and workers and Kehoe [1992], Shimer [1995] in output in transi- for we see the evidence breakdowns of coopera- [1993] for an example in the context of Disorganization as reflecting in large part inefficient disorganization. reallocation with some remaining Other explanations combine distortion, explaining the decline in output as a second-best outcome. Perhaps the most widely accepted explanation argues that efficient reallocation would have implied a decrease in real wages of some workers inconsistent with either actual wage determination or political concerns about income distribution; as a result of these contraints, employment and output have decreased (see Blanchard [1996]). Soviet Union as showing that there theories are related to ours. The We more is first, read the evidence from the former at work, namely disorganization. Two developed by Murphy et phasizes the adverse effects of partial price liberalization. al. [1992], em- The second, developed by Shleifer and Vishny [1993], focuses on the role of corruption, and emphasizes the adverse effects of rent extraction by government the relations as 1 we go officials. out along. A chain of production This and the next two sections develop three examples, ing different mechanisms through which in output during transition. • We shall point A good is The first is produced according of production. Each firms three aimed at captur- can lead also the simplest. It step of production We is to a large decline goes as follows: to a Leontief technology (A point of semantics here. firm specificities all and requires n carried out by a different state shall use "state" firms to denote the which existed under central planning and produced under the plan, whether or not they have been privatized since the beginning of We steps shall use "private" firms to transition. denote the firms which have been created . Disorganization One since transition.) one unit of the One may leads, after the n steps, to good. Intermediate goods have a value of zero. final price of the final good unit of the primary good is The normalized to one. replace "production" by "distribution" here: an interpretation with a Soviet Union flavor is good having that of a to travel through n provinces/republics, to go from the primary producer to the final distributor. • The supplier of the primary good has to One can a c. for the input equal think of c as a private opportunity, perhaps the production of much simpler good, production; c an alternative use may avoiding the division of labor implicit in the chain of therefore be much lower than 1. (It is straightforward to introduce similar private opportunities for the intermediate producers along the chain of production. But the point is made more simply by ignoring this possibility.) Each buyer along the chain knows only the • central planning, and bargaining problems. vice-versa. We The end supplier it was paired with under of central planning thus leaves assume that there is Nash bargaining at n each step of production, with equal division of the surplus from the match. The characterization of the solution is straightforward and is obtained by working backward from the last The value stage of production. of the surplus in the last bargaining problem, between the final producer and the next-to-last intermediate producer is equal to 1 (by assumption, the good is useless before the final stage) Thus, the next-to-last intermediate producer receives the first The intermediate producer receives (l/2) n surplus to be divided between the plier of the primary good is first equal to (l/2) (1/2). Solving recursively, . intermediate producer and the supn — c. If c < (l/2) n , the surplus is Disorganization positive and production takes place along the chain. If > instead c (1/2)", the primary producer prefers to take up his private opportunity. Thus, the appearance of even mediocre private opportunities will lead to the collapse of production in may be the state sector: the decrease in total output example (what matters here is as large as — (l/2) n 1 in our not the absolute level of private opportunities, but their level relative to opportunities in the state sector.) The more complex the structure of production (the higher n), the smaller the private opportunities needed to trigger the collapse of the state sector. Avoiding the adverse effects of specificity in a problem faced by firms in the sufficiently specific that firms one buyer. We West complex structures of production as well. Even can only get them from one shall discuss in The source many goods supplier, or sell are them to Section 4 below the mechanisms which alleviate the adverse effects of specificity in the West, and role in transition. in the West, is why they have played a limited But a few points are worth making here already. of the inefficiency and of the collapse of output in our example a hold-up problem: each intermediate producer must produce its is intermediate good before bargaining with the next producer along the chain. Once he has produced the intermediate good and has no alternative use value The is for it, his reservation equal to zero. inefficiency would therefore disappear if all the producers could sign an en- forceable contract before production took place. In this case, production take place so long as c was less than ceive 1 — specificity, c of the output. which gives The source rise to 1, and the producers of the problem the bargaining problems, is as a would whole would re- thus the combination of and incomplete contracts. 8 Disorganization The assumption of incomplete contracts seems quite former Soviet Union. ment is The legal system reasonable in the case of the in construction. Contract enforce- is still notoriously weak. Firms often have few valuable assets, making punish them for deviating Another natural solution it hard to from the contract. is vertical integration. In our tegration (which effectively reduces the from n to a smaller number) , number example, even partial of bargaining problems alleviates the problem, and full vertical in- down integra- tion (where one decision-maker decides whether or not to produce) eliminates it. Even short of vertical integration, long-term relations also alleviate the problem. If they are may be ing it willing to pay their supplier more likely that engaged 2 in a long-term relation, producers more than the price we derived above, mak- production takes place in the chain. As we shall argue in Section 4 however, the nature of transition vertical integration between producers can and for is such that it reduces the scope for long-term relations to induce such behavior. A state firm and its suppliers. I In our second example, the source of inefficiency is not incomplete contracts but asymmetric information: • • A state firm needs n inputs in order to produce. the firm can produce n Each input is for his input, If all inputs are available, units of output. Otherwise, output is equal to zero. supplied by one supplier. Each supplier has an alternative use with value c, distributed uniformly the distribution function, so that F(0) pendent across suppliers. = on and F(c) [0,c]. = 1. Let F(.) denote Draws are inde- Disorganization We can again think of c as a private sector alternative, production or sale of the input to a foreign buyer. known, but the specific realization of each c is The such as small scale distribution of c is private information to each can be thought of as indicating the degree of development of the supplier, c private sector, which we assume is very low pre-transition, and increasing over time thereafter. The • state firm maximizes expected each supplier (given the symmetry to price is the same for of suppliers, production takes place in the state firm. Otherwise, all tion of c and all all suppliers). If the price suppliers use their and n. own Given price first to profit term if it does private opportunity. private, and total production as a func- p, expected profit is = is given by: (F(p)) n (l-p)n the probability that production takes place. The second is equal production takes place. Maximizing with respect to p yields the profit maximizing price: p the exceeds the reservation prices We must first solve for the profit-maximizing price set by the state ir The built in the assumptions, the p We can now characterize expected state, The take-it or leave-it price not, firm. announces a profit. It firm never pays maximum = min(c , — — n + -) I more than the maximum alternative opportunity, alternative opportunity exceeds (n/(n + 1)), c. But, if the firm does not Disorganization increase its 10 price. Increasing the price would increase the probability that pro- duction takes place, but would decrease expected Given this price, Y expected state production, Y = s , is , is , ( equal n — — -) n + lc 1 nmin(l Yp Expected private production, s profit. to: n ) equal to the probability that state production does not take place, times the conditional expected sum of alternative opportu- on nities (conditional at least offered by the state firm) . one private alternative being Yp can be written as: n nr ^ = ^(0,1-^1) Expected total larger than the price production is \ n+1 ) in turn equal to Y = Y + Yp s The best way to see the behavior, for what these equations imply n '.== 4, figure, would be the outcome to look at Figure 3, it is useful to if the for values of c keep the monopsonist was efficient fully for inputs (all plots three ranging from 0.4 to 2.4. benchmark in mind (which informed about the alternative opportunities of each supplier and thus was fully discriminating, or markets which of expected state, private and total production normalized by the number of inputs, n) To interpret the is if there were which revealed these alternative opportunities). So long as c II CNJ Z3 CL Z3 o o ~o o a o cu o > a> O o J2> en a; o CU o_ X CD o > o ao O CO CD cu 3 en o fl Z' I OL 80 9'0 *'0 3 - 0"0 1 Disorganization was 1 than one, production would always take place in the state less increased above one, would sometimes be it efficient production would increase. Eventually, as c became very would take place in the private with linearly sector, As c not to produce in the state expected production in the state sector would decrease, but sector: sector. total expected most production large, with expected total production increasing c. In contrast with the efficient outcome, increases in private opportunities lead initially to such a large decrease in state production that the net decrease in total production. Total production starts declining (n/(n tion + still 1)) = .8. For c equal to the efficient is divided by the a production level of only 0.75. that total production is It is number a c exceeds outcome would be that produc- of inputs). its The actual (1 outcome in is pre-transition level. in the state sector increases the size of the decline in We can think of n as an index of the complexity of the production process. Figure 4 shows the effects of alternative values of n The is not before c has reached a value of about 2.0 again equal to Complexity of production total when only takes place in the state firm, with total production equal to n the figure, as output output. 1, effect on the evolution of expected production (again normalized by the number of inputs) as a function of larger n, the higher the price that the state firm offers: for c large so that the minimum condition does not bind, p = n/(n + 1). c. enough Thus, the higher n, the higher the value of c required to trigger the collapse of the state sector. But, also the higher n, the smaller the probability that production takes place in the state firm for c total > n/(n + 1), and thus the greater the production as c increases. As n approaches state firm infinity, initial collapse of the price offered by the approaches one, and state production collapses as soon as c increases CO CD _3 O > O CD CNI CD "O o Z3 o o o o O CD o CD Q. X CD > CO CD CD CD CD o ZJ LZ >'L £1 0*1 11 60 9*0 }nd}no |d;o; pe^Dadx^ S'L L0 9*0 Disorganization 12 above one: the probability that at least greater than one goes to one. Thus, as one supplier will n approaches have a realization of c infinity, the path of state production (normalized by the number of inputs) approaches one c/2 (the expected value of private production) for c 1, output falls by fifty > 1. for c < and 1, When c increases above percent. Putting our results in words: Pre-transition, suppliers have such poor alternative opportunities that the state firm can offer a price at which there alternative than to supply. suppliers now have more As transition starts, is no better and alternatives improve, some attractive opportunities. They start asking the firm for more. Not knowing which suppliers are bluffing and which are not, the firm has no choice other than to offer a given price and take the risk of not getting the inputs. The result is an initial decrease in total production as opportunities improve. Let us take two sets of issues at this point: (1) This example is closely related to the analysis by effects of partial price liberalization. In their held fixed while others are left free Murphy et al. [1992] of the model, the fact that some prices are can also lead to an inefficient diversion of output from state to private firms (Young [1996] argues that a similar perverse mechanism is relevant in China) occur even under section 5) in a full . Our argument price liberalization. that the The presence same perverse effects of reported shortages (see number of former republics a number of years after nearly complete price liberalization suggests that there liberalization. is The quite different. is indeed more at work than partial price implications of the two models for policy are also potentially The Murphy et price liberalization. In our case, al. [1992] model implies the desirability of even under full price liberalization, output full may 13 Disorganization be lower during transition than (2) it was under central planning. We have assumed that the sellers had private information, and that the seller set the price. What is essential here is that there be private information, some bargaining power. Suppose the uninformed party have for and that example that the firm has private information about the value of final production, but that, now, suppliers tunities, sum make price offers to the firm. and choose the Assume that they have maximize price so as to of the prices charged by suppliers is their no private oppor- expected revenue. It is probability increases in the tion process, the more pliers. likely is on output. There is also easy to state production to collapse, show that that this is even in the absence closely related to results on the adverse We have assumed that the price setters were sup- But, absent the rule of law, they to operate the firm. It is much and that, number of suppliers: the more complex the produc- 5 of private opportunities. This result effects of corruption positive. is show straightforward to in this case, the probability that suppliers collectively ask for too production does not take place the higher than the actual value of final production, production does not take place. final If may be government officials selling permits therefore a close parallel between our argument that decentralized bargaining between firms has led to a decline in output, and the ar- gument made by Shleifer 5. More for example uniformly on formally, the prices set by assume that all common 1/(71+1). Now consider other suppliers as price is = (n political decentralization has inputs are supplied, output if all [0, 1]. chooses a price equal to pi that the and Vishny [1993] that — equal to p p_,-. is equal to ne, with the problem facing supplier Supplier i maximizes (1 — (p_,- n/(n + 1), Denote the sum of + Vi)l n p_,)/2. In the symmetric equilibrium = i. e distributed p_,- = ) Pi< ar| d (n — ^ us l)p,-, so and the state firm produces with probability . Disorganization 14 led to competition among rent extractors, with large adverse effects 3 A state firm and its suppliers. 11 The third example shows how coordination failures, is more natural and complexity can combine specificity here, is again Leontief in n inputs. Because the interpreta- we think of the n The suppliers as the n crucial workers in between the firm. But this is previous model in the timing of decisions. In the previous model, is to create and a collapse of output. In this model, technology tion on output. 6 not essential. essential difference duction did not take place, suppliers could still this if and the state pro- take up their private opportunity. Here, suppliers have to decide whether or not to take their private opportunity before they know whether production is taking place in the state firm. This dif- ference in timing introduces problems of coordination between workers, which we now examine. The model is as follows: A state firm needs n workers in order to produce efficiently. Assume that its • technology is Leontief in those workers (who are therefore the workers are difficult to replace; we can think of who the other workers as having been solved out of the production function) If all workers stay, the firm produces n units of output, equivalently output per worker. 6. If is given by unit of one or more workers leave, the firm can hire replace- Empirical evidence on the number and the today 1 Kaufmann and Kaliberda size [1995]. of bribes needed to run a business in Ukraine 15 Disorganization merits; replacements are or however less productive. If the firm more replacements, output per worker Thus n measures 7 (which was 1. the complexity of the production process. implicitly put equal to zero in the first measure of the < equal to 7 is has to hire one The parameter example) is an inverse specificity of existing workers. Each worker has an alternative opportunity given by c, distributed uniformly • on [0, c]. Draws known, but the are independent across workers. specific realization of each c The distribution of c private information. is is We can think of cas representing the opportunities open to the most qualified workers after transition, from opening their own business, to working for foreign consulting firms, and so on. 7 The wage • paid is equal for workers all from the assumption (this follows that alternative opportunities are private information, and the symmetry in production), and is equal to output per worker. This assumption simplifies the analysis, and is reasonable in the case of many former state firms, but the analysis would be qualitatively similar as long as wages increased with other workers' participation. Workers must decide whether • they know to take the decisions of other workers, the wage per worker in the state firm. so that their decision 7. An is is If all We their private opportunity before and thus the level of assume that they are output and risk neutral, based on the expected wage. alternative interpretation of this ferent costs of effort. worker up workers put model effort, is as a model of output per worker shirking, is one. If where workers have some do dif- not, output per equal to 7 instead. Under that interpretation, one may interpret the model as applying to all workers. 1 Disorganization Thus, wage, tive, 16 workers decide to if all is equal to one. If output per worker, and therefore the stay, one or more workers take up their private alterna- some replacement workers must be hired, and output per worker and the wage are equal to 7. It is form: Stay c*, problem facing each worker has the following clear that the solution to the if c less is than some threshold c*, otherwise leave. To characterize think of the decision problem facing one worker. his alternative opportunity, Given that, he will by symmetry, the (n to c*, the probability that they receive — all 1) Suppose he decides instead to c. n_1 + (1 - (F(c*)) stay n-1 is The )7. stay. other workers also have a threshold equal given by (F(c*)) per worker, and thus the wage he can expect to receive to (F(c*)) he leaves and takes up If if n_1 . he threshold level c* Expected output stays, is is thus equal such that he must be indifferent between leaving or staying, so that: n— » c* = 7 + min(l,(-) c )(l- 7 ) (3-1) Expected output per worker, and thus the expected wage, are given io 8. Note the different exponents alternative opportunity from what the n of the as n is — 1 = + min(l, in (3.1) and (3.2), when choosing whether other workers will do. wage and depends on what large. 7 all fy (n — )(l-7) 1) versus n. to stay or not, The expected wage n workers do. in turn by: J (3-2) Each worker knows his own and thus the uncertainty comes is the unconditional expectation The difference between c* and w goes to zero 7 Disorganization The solution of c. 1 These three cases equation on the (3.1) vertical axis against c* = represented by a 45-degree which • initially is 5, and 7 line. convex, turning The = right flat at c* workers decide to stay, depending on the value which The axis. The figure is left-hand-side of the equation hand = both sides of plots on the horizontal .2. For low alternative opportunities, there initial types, are represented in Figure 5, drawn assuming values of n is can be one of three to equation (3.1) side is represented by a curve 1. is only one equilibrium, in which all leading to a level of output per worker equal to one. In Figure 5, the only equilibrium corresponding to the case where c at point • = .3 is A. For intermediate alternative opportunities, there are two equilibria (the equilibrium in-between all is unstable using standard arguments) one in which , workers stay and output per worker ers are likely to leave, where c*, and is one, and one in which most work- in turn expected output per worker, are close to 7. In Figure c* is 1. 5, for At c equal to A and B. At A, the two equilibria are at points B, c* (and the expected probability that at least • .7, one worker wage from will leave For higher alternative opportunities — for c (3.2)) is is very close to .2: the very high. > 1 — there is a unique, low activity, equilibrium. In Figure 5, for c = 1.1, the only equilibrium is at point B, the expected wage, are both equal to a value close to state sector We want is .2: very unlikely. to emphasize two separate aspects of these results: where c*, and production in the lo O CD O > CD > oo d O CD CO *. d <-> * CD Z3 ^_ -Q ^3- d Z5 CT UJ LO CD CNI d ZS o o I 01 80 90 *D V0 Z'O O'O 18 Disorganization (1) is The first is some the existence, over not due to private information. To see an alternative opportunity equal 7 and c, to a range, of multiple equilibria. This result this, note that even known value there are two equilibria, one in which (the efficient outcome) and one , in which all c, all when workers have then, for values of c between workers stay in the state firm workers take up their alternative opportunity. Is one equilibrium more likely to prevail? The arguments here the one hand, the equilibrium with high production is one of pure coordination, so if worker ravel. if each worker believes that there will irrationally refuse to participate, As n becomes large, tionally refuse to participate can lead is is better for some all of them. probability that On the some other then the high-equilibrium can unwill irra- to the rational collapse of output. fact that which require the contribution of many is The game even a small probability that one worker This aspect of the model captures the suppliers) imply Pareto superior. On the workers can talk beforehand, they should be able to coordinate on the equilibria which other hand, is are standard. specific complex coordination problems. the potential presence of multiple equilibria. complex production processes, workers (or/and many specific A reflection of these problems The argument was first made by Bryant [1983] in the context of Western Economies. But the prevalence of specific relations (and we shall argue in the next section, the lack of mechanisms designed to handle such coordination problems) makes tries in transition. Some firms it more relevant may disappear simply because for coun- they are expected to, either by their suppliers or their essential workers. (2) The second aspect derives from the combination between private informa- Disorganization tion 19 and interactions between decisions given the timing of decisions. It is the rapid collapse of state output as soon as the probability that at least one private wage under efficient production alternative exceeds the positive. For example, for the case value of private opportunities if is where = c in the state firm 1.1 in Figure 5 (so that the only equal to .55, compared to workers stay) the probability that 1 becomes expected in the state firm workers stay in the state firm all initial nearly equal to zero, and expected production per worker in the state firm close to .2, collapses, note that as chance that a worker is will leave. soon as c The wage is greater than one, there is a that remaining workers can expect to thus reduced in proportion to the probability that at least one worker reduction in the expected wage prompts more workers to will leave. In turn, this leave, very a highly inefficient outcome. To see why output receive is is and so on. The effect of higher values of between the workers' decisions. For example, worker in the state firm equal to .92 is if n— 2, n is to magnify the interactions for c = but falls 1.01, expected output per to .21 when n=3. 9 This aspect of the model appears to capture a number of aspects of transition. It captures the idea that crucial managers large payoffs from turning stay around long enough. 9. To see the it If may leave a firm, despite potentially around, because they are not sure that others we will return to an interpretation of the model with sup- role of timing decisions, these results can be compared to those which obtain when workers decide whether or not to take their private opportunity after having observed the decisions of others. In that case, the probability that (l/c) n , and expected output per worker expected output per worker in in the firm the state firm is all is workers stay equal to 7 equal to .98 if in the state firm + (l/c)"(l — 7). n=2, and .97 if n=3. is For c equal to = 1.01, 20 Disorganization pliers rather than workers, the model is consistent with anecdotal evidence that suppliers are often very reluctant to supply state firms, because of the difficulties of getting paid. If they are not paid on delivery but only producing and selling pliers become if the firm succeeds in production, then, just like workers in our example, sup- its residual claimants, (this raises the issue of why state firms do not pay their suppliers on delivery. More on this in the next section.) The probability that one of them will not supply leads all of them to be leary of supplying, leading to collapse of the state firm. 4 Managing specificity We have shown through three examples how specificity and complexity may have combined to lead to a large decrease of output during transition. But these exam- ples raise a general issue. If anything, the production structure in the more complex than it is in the East. West is even Why aren't problems arising from specificity as severe in the West? We have already hinted (1) First, in buyers and the West, at some of the answers: many goods are many sellers. And traded in thick markets, markets with while for many intermediate many goods, firms deal with only one supplier, there are likely to be other potential suppliers, and shifting suppliers may be difficult but not impossible. For many goods however, just not enough suppliers or buyers in the economy to start with; thick markets cannot be created overnight. There are new firms must be created, a process which takes time. Opening the economy to foreign trade 21 Disorganization increases the potential number of buyers and sellers can clearly help here. In- deed, one of the arguments for imposing convertibility and low in 1990 was indeed monopoly power of domestic to limit the tariffs in Poland firms by increasing competition, an argument closely related to ours (Sachs [1993]). (2) Second, there is more scope handle problems created by speci- for contracts to ficity. The potential role of contracts in solving or alleviating problems of specificity clearest in our tracts before first example. In that model, if production takes place, then they achieve an efficient outcome. Total output is producers can sign binding conavoid hold-up problems, and will not decline will when private oppor- tunities improve. There question however that the scope is little lems such as hold-ups is more limited in the East. Russian legal system have been pointed out by del [1994]): Contract enforcement is weak for contracts to alleviate The many prob- deficiencies of the current (for example Greif and Kan- our example, producers have an (in incentive ex-post to renege and offer a lower price to their suppliers. Contract enforcement is therefore crucial) Firms have few assets . thus less to lose from breaking a contract. This last which can be seized, and aspect takes us to the next point. (3) Most state liquid assets, The on "cash" (more firms in transition are short and limited access precisely have limited to credit.) potential role of cash in reducing problems in our third example. Consider the case coming from specificity where there are two which existing workers stay and productivity is high, and one in is clearest equilibria, one in which they leave, 22 Disorganization forcing the firm to hire less efficient replacements. A commitment by the firm to pay each existing worker a wage of one, independently of what the other workers do, will lead all workers to stay, and will sustain the efficient equilibrium, at no cost to the firm. Thus, firms with "deep pockets" can alleviate some of the problems arising from specificity. 10 But state firms in the former Soviet Union typically do not have such deep pockets: wages access to credit, and many typically exhaust most of revenues, firms have limited are close to bankruptcy. have no easy way of convincing Under these conditions, they workers to stay or their suppliers to supply. their This argument points to the role of foreign direct investment: foreign firms typically have deep pockets. They can pay suppliers on delivery; they can credibly promise to pay their workers even if things go wrong. They can therefore avoid the problems of coordination faced by state firms. (4) While state firms were often more vertically integrated than in the West, the type of vertical integration needed to alleviate problems of specificity during transition is different from what it was in the past. The reason to vertically integrate under central planning was the imperfect ability of the central planner to enforce timely delivery of some inputs, leading firms to protect themselves against such disruptions. Sachs [1993] gives the example of an industrial firm installing pigpens to raise pigs and insure the delivery of food to their workers in the face of food shortages. The type of vertical integration needed in transition, lO.See Holmstrom [1982] for a related point. as well as later on, is likely to 23 Disorganization be different. It is most needed for those inputs with a high degree of specificity, and thus a large potential for serious bargaining problems. Pigpens are not the answer anymore: markets in agricultural goods have eliminated the problem. But the problem may now be a planning but is now which was easy specific engine part, available from only one to get under central firm, raising issues of specificity and bargaining. Thus, the existing structure of vertical integration can only play a limited role in And creating new transition. vertically integrated structures of has sharp limits and takes time. production interlock. The arguments here When suppliers have integrates with the buyer? Second, are standard. First, chains of more than one if vertical time not in the determination of input prices, but of the purchase price of firms. If n — 1 which supplier we saw become now of the firms in our integrate, the remaining hold-out firm has buyer, integration is to be achieved through the purchase of existing firms, the bargaining problems this production both an incentive to relevant, in the determination first example hold out vertically for a large part of the rents, and thus a high purchase price. Thus, no firm will want to be the first to be vertically integrated. This suggests to proceed through the development of new the development of (5) Fifth, new much of vertical integration needs activities within the firm. This, like firms, takes time. but we think most important, the very nature of (any) transition that there is is such limited scope for long-term relations in solving problems arising from specificity. In stable economic regimes, such as under central planning in the Soviet in the past or in Union Western market economies today, long-term relations can play 24 Disorganization an important role in reducing inefficiencies arising from specificity, who decide take for example our third model, and assume that workers a private opportunity cannot work . logical reasons (they have to move will use a much workers will The and higher expected production is is still low, there and relies then workers will c*, for if it is up the optimal private opportu- More formally, they deciding whether to result will be a higher probability that workers overall. In that context, the value of c* will depend crucially firm Then, think twice about leaving. higher threshold, a higher value of take up a private opportunity. stay, state firm. to take either for techno- to another city) or because punishment from the point of view of the nities are temporary, may be this, (one can again for the state firm in the future replace "workers" by "suppliers" in what follows) This lb see on the same workers on the probability that the in the future. If this probability behave opportunistically, in a way close to that charac- terized in the previous section. But by the nature of transition, this probability indeed likely to disappear, well as and many be low in transition: Transition implies that that, even if they survive, they will have to many is state firms will change operations as of their suppliers. In a neo-classical benchmark, if it took time for new more productive firms to were arise following transition, state firms would continue producing replaced by new, more efficient firms. The argument we have just developed sug- gests that the mere anticipation that more efficient private firms will eventually appear can lead to a reduction in productivity in the state firms. plain why the pre-official transition period in the Soviet ized by increasing disorganization until they It may also ex- Union was character- and decreasing output, as the shortening of horizons led to more opportunistic behavior on the part of firms. There is indeed 25 Disorganization some evidence that the degree to which state firms felt they had to satisfy the plan decreased in the Soviet Union with the increased likelihood of reform in the mid-1980s. n This line of argument may explain also some of the difference between the experiences of China and Eastern Europe during transition. China's lower level of industrial development, and its explicit policy of decentralizing industry to small factories implies that problems of specificity were less in the et al. [1996]). control meant bargaining. place (Qian the ability of the Chinese government to maintain political that centralized allocation was not fully replaced by decentralized And China's commitment may have lengthened necessary, relations And first many between firms and firms in the face of new to maintain state firms, using subsidies if horizons, allowing for a larger role of long-term their suppliers, and thus avoiding the collapse of state private opportunities. This last point naturally takes us to a discussion of the policy implications of our theory. implications. (6) Policy Suppose that in a neo-classical benchmark on so far) time. , absent subsidies, many state firms The argument we have developed specificity are 11. This taken into account, argument can (i.e this absent the effects we have focused can be expected to disappear over implies that, once the implications of may well lead to the immediate collapse also explain the opposition of industry to laws requiring firms to provide workers advance notification of plant shut-downs and why some firms decide simply to pay their workers severance pay rather than providing notice. Ellickson [1989] notes that at the time of the collapse of the nineteenth century whaling industry, the among whalers began to break down. norms of cooperation that had evolved 26 Disorganization of those firms. Shorter horizons cally, may lead suppliers to behave more opportunisti- leading to the collapse of state production. By the same argument, a mitment by the government to subsidize state firms for com- some time may avoid their immediate collapse. 12 Should a government commit and thus avoid a to subsidizing state firms, lapse of state production at the beginning of transition? This will col- depend on the expected path of private opportunities, on the time path of c in our example. efficient private firms (firms in the state firms) are with values of c equal to or greater than productivity expected to develop quickly, then a commitment to main- taining state firms for a long time accept the fall is in initial output, in likely to exchange be overly for (if enough c is higher production soon is after. If expected to take more that state production dominates private production for a long time) justified to commit immediate collapse There are to subsidize state firms for in the face of any point in the future. A some we have not taken is the beginning. is a positive probability, standard: with certainty at some future point into account be high enough probability will lead suppliers to increase the government must be such that there The argument it and avoid as affecting the probability that the state firm will threshold at which they take up their private opportunities. Technically, the survives forever. time, , mediocre private opportunities. clearly other implications of subsidies 12.Think of subsidies by the government alive at better to expected to be high enough to create problems of bargaining, but low may then be their may be costly. It however, the development of an efficient private sector time If if it however were known that in time, things commitment of the small, that the state firm a firm was going to disappear would unravel, and the firm would collapse at 27 Disorganization here: subsidies may reduce to be financed, firms. And the incentives of state firms to adjust. Subsidies have and through the tax channel, slow the growth of new private in the end, political economy considerations may conclusion that the only way to stop subsidies is to stop well them still lead to the But our at once. theory provides at least one respectable argument in favor of gradualism. the emergence of efficient private firms is the government to subsidize state firms for ate collapse, and avoid likely to When be slow, a commitment by some time may avoid their immedi- a large inefficient decline in output at the beginning of transition. 5 Empirical Evidence As we went along, we attempt to give we gave anecdotal evidence of disorganization. In this section, more formal evidence about the ganization, both over time and across countries relative importance of disor- in transition. To do so, we rely on measures of reported shortages of raw materials and intermediate products by firms. Two remarks What firms are in order here mean when also not clear they report "shortages" whether the breakdowns ples should be called shortages. in supply", while there are are, admittedly unclear. which occur breakdowns shortages. Thus, we And in our three it is exam- however, no measures of "breakdowns measures of reported shortages. that firms facing proxy There in supply is in supply as in And it is plausible our examples would report them as are reasonably confident that reported shortages are a decent for disorganization. 28 Disorganization We focus on shortages rather than some of the other implications of our examples because most alternative theories of the output decline do not naturally predict shortages. 13 There one exception: shortages may is price liberalization, along the lines of however, prices have now been Murphy et reflect the effects of partial al. [1992]. In most republics mostly liberalized, so that partial price liberaliza- tion probably plays a limited role in explaining shortages at this point. We 14 read the available evidence as suggesting that disorganization has played a limited role in the major Central European countries, some role in Russia and the Baltics, and a major role in the other republics. (1) in a Since 1992/93, the number OECD has carried out a survey of firms in manufacturing of Central European and Baltic countries, asking limiting production in manufacturing. come from roughly The important. Table 1. strength of these data identical surveys. Unfortunately, they period of transition, where disorganization The evidence from is these surveys them about likely to is is factors that they do not cover the early have been summarized relatively in table more 1: Percentage of firms experiencing shortages of materials. 13. Phenomena such Rutkowski [1996] as wage compression in state firms for Poland, Kollo [1996] for compared to private firms (for example Hungary), the collapse of inter-republican trade, cannibalization of machines, "spontaneous privatization" and the carving up of firms, are also consistent with our story. The problem including efficient reorganization. ization of tion on that they are also consistent with other explanations, The volume machines or of firms may be 14. For a survey of progress is efficient, of trade may well have been too high. Cannibal- and so on. price liberalization as of 1995, see and Development [1996). European Bank for Reconstruc- , 29 Disorganization min percent max percent 1996-1 value Czech Republic 93-1 96-1 3 9 5 Hungary 92-1 96-1 6 11 5 Poland 93-3 96-1 3 6 5 Bulgaria 93-1 96-1 15 33 25 Romania 92-1 96-1 8 39 15 Latvia 93-1 96-1 21 32 21 Lithuania 93-3 96-1 13 43 17 Source: OECD Short term indicators, 2/1996. Business survey annex. In the three major Central European countries, shortages of materials have played a very limited role since 1992-1993. The numbers are tained from similar surveys of firms in Western Europe. Blanchard [1994] show that, even in comparable Numbers from Berg and 1990 in Poland (the disruptions were not an important part of the story. to those ob- first year of transition) The proportion of firms citing "supply and employment shortages" as a limiting factor in production was 62% in October 1989, 37% in January 1990 (the month of the "big bang"), but down to 10% by April 1990. The evidence from those Central European countries which are doing less well suggests a larger role for disorganization. In Bulgaria and Romania, two of the countries with the largest drop in output, supply shortages played an important role more than two years the Baltic states. after the beginning of transition. The same is true of 30 Disorganization (2) Table 2 gives corresponding numbers for Russia, since 1991 (from a sample of about 500 industrial firms, with a response rate of 30-40% over time). Table 2. Proportion of firms in industry mentioning the following constraints as limits to production. Russia, 1991-1995 Insufficient Shortages of Shortages of Shortages of Demand Materials Financial Resources Labor 1991 4 82 18 28 1992 51 46 45 8 1993 41 23 62 6 1994 48 19 64 5 1995 47 22 64 8 ; Source: Russian Economic Barometer, 1996 The most striking number is the proportion of firms experiencing shortages of materials in 1991. This however is (which took place in January 1992). 1992, and are still the 15 last year before success. lost to full directly to disorganization, is the stoppages of production, by reason. series are given in table 3. would be interesting pre-1991. in high by standards of market economies. proportion of work time in firms 15. It price liberalization The numbers however remained high Another piece of evidence, which speaks more The time full The to find out how the proportion of firms experiencing shortages evolved survey used above starts in 1991. We have searched for earlier ones, so far without Disorganization 31 Table 3. Percentage of working hours lost due to full stoppage ofproduction, reasons for Russia, 1992-1995. it. By reason Percentage of hours lost Lack of demand Lack of materials Other 1992 10 59 40 1 1993 10 50 39 11 1994 18 53 35 13 1995 7 37 53 10 Source: Goskomstat Rossii, various issues. 1992 age over 4 quarters. 1994 of the first and is the average of May is August only. 1993 is the aver- and October. 1995 is the average two quarters. Lack of materials appears to be the main factor in explaining work stoppages during the period 1992-1995. (3) Shortages of materials appear to play still a more important publics of the former Soviet Union. Table 4 gives republic. The numbers role in the re- some numbers are from a survey of firms by the ILO and for the Kyrgyz are for 1993, thus a year after price liberalization in the Kyrgyz republic, and one year after the collapse of trade between the Kyrgyz republic and the other republics of the former Soviet Union. (1993 a month on average trade, and this — . is High may account however a period of very high inflation for is inflation —23% typically associated with disruptions in some of the shortages reported by firms.) 32 Disorganization Table 4- Main business problems of firms 1993 in industry. Kyrgyz republic, Shortages of materials Low demand Other factors Food processing 57 13 30 Textiles 36 17 47 Non 26 32 42 Fabricated metals 31 22 47 Wood and 63 16 21 43 21 36 metallic minerals paper Other Source: Windell et These numbers al. [1995] Proportion of firms, in percent. are in sharp contrast to those for, say Poland or Hungary. Short- ages of materials seem to being playing a central role. evidence from the other republics. So far, We are now collecting more the evidence appears consistent with that in Table 4. The shortages in Table 4 seem to reflect mainly internal disorganization, rather than the collapse of trade between republics. The same survey gives industry the proportion of materials coming from domestic sources. The for each and non-domestic correlation across sectors between the proportion of firms citing shortages and the share of materials coming from non-domestic sources is roughly equal to zero. Can one explain the differences between Central Europe and the former Soviet Union? Our discussion suggests may well have been higher in a number of potential explanations. many of the republics of the Soviet Specificities Union than in, 33 Disorganization say, Poland or the Czech Republic, leading to a larger collapse of both intra- and inter-republican trade. Distance from the West, and the scope 6 role. These are however speculations at this point. Conclusions Transition was conceptualized in a recent World movement "From Plan port [1996] as a a trade, problems of specificity, may also have for foreign firms to alleviate played an important and thus the volume of more accurate, stitutions to if less succinct, Market and Market title to Bank World Development Re- Market." If our argument is right, then would have been "From Plan and Plan Institutions." Transition may cause In- the existing organization of production to collapse, leading to a large decline in output until new institutions The evidence can be created. suggests that disorganization has played a limited role in Central Europe, a more important one in the Baltics and Russia, and an even more important one in the other Republics. Put another way, disorganization appears to have played a more important role in countries where the output decline has been the largest. While political economy and other considerations may sion that the only provides way some support emergence of new to stop subsidies is to stop for gradualist policies in efficient private firms for subsidizing state firms for some time is them at once, our analysis dealing with state firms. likely to at the well lead to the conclu- be slow, there may beginning of transition. If the be a case 34 Disorganization References Atkeson, A. and Kehoe, Banerjee, A. and E, 1992, Social insurance Newman, A., 1993, and transition, mimeo. Occupational choice and the process of development, Journal of Political Economy 101(2). Berg, A. and Blanchard, O, 1994, 1991, pp. 51-92, in K. Froot and J. The Stabilization and transition transition in Eastern Europe, Sachs eds, Volume NBER and University of Chicago The economics of transition Blanchard, O., 1996, in Poland; 19901, O Blanchard, Press, Chicago. in Eastern Europe, Oxford University Press, Oxford, Clarendon lectures, forthcoming. Bryant, J., 1983, A simple Journal of Economics Quarterly 525-528. Hammour, Caballero, R. and mimeo, June 3, rational expectations Keynes-type model, M., 1996, The macroeconomics of specificity, MIT Ellickson, R., 1989, A hypothesis the whaling industry, of wealth-maximizing norms: Evidence from Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 5(1), mimeo LSE. European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1996, Transition report, 1995. Greif, A. and Kandel, E., 1994, Contract enforcement institutions: historical perspective and current status in Russia. Holmstrom, B., 1982, Moral hazard in teams, 13, 324-340, Bell Journal of 35 Disorganization Economics. Kaufmartn, D. and Kaliberda, A., 1995, Integrating the unofficial economy into the dynamics of post-socialist economies; a framework of analysis and evi- dence, mimeo, World Bank. Kollo, 1996, J., market Murphy, omy; Employment, wage transition, mimeo, Budapest. K., Shleifer, A., pitfalls setting in three stages of Hungary's labour and Vishny, R., 1992, The transition to a market econ- of partial reform, Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(3), 889- 906. Qian, Y, Roland, G., and Xu, G, 1996, Coordinating changes in M-form and U-form organizations, mimeo, Stanford Rutkowski, nomic Sachs, J., J., 1996, High skills transition in Poland, 1993, Poland's jump pay off: University. the changing wage structure during eco- Economics of transition 4-1, 89-1 to the market economy, MIT 12. Press, Cambridge, Mass. Shimer, R., 1995, Microfoundations of the optimal speed of transition, mimeo, MIT. Shleifer, A. and Vishny, Wells, R. R., 1993, Corruption, 108(3), 599-618. and Maher, M., 1995, Time and surplus allocation within marriage, Stanford Graduate School of Business Windell, QJE J., Anker, R., and WP 1372. Sziraczki, G., 1995, Kyrgyzstan: Enterprise restructur- MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 01428 2807 36 Disorganization ing and labour shedding in a papers 5, free fall economy, 1991-1994, ILO labour market 1995. Young, A., 1996, Transition in China, mimeo, Boston University. ^232 118