Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/horizontalmergerOOfish H331 I 16 .11415 working paper department of economics HORIZONTAL MERGERS AND ANTITRUST POLICY Franklir M. Fisher i No. 439 February 1987 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 ]S86 HORIZONTAL MERGERS AND ANTITRUST POLICY Franklin No. 439 M. Fisher February 1987 Draft January 1987 BQBIZ0NT£L_MEBG£BS_MO_MTITByST_PQl,ICY Franklin M. Fisher Massachusetts Institute of Technology antitrust policy years now, some For mergers has been evolving. horizontal towards It is plain to me that some sort change was earnestly needed; of whether the changes that have taken place or those that are now proposed by the Reagan Administration are the appropriate ones is not quite so clear. the In years folowing Bxown_Shge. ciously intertwined. Section 7 These were: kets or "submarkets" with "the economic often some ; second, that the definition of mar- (whatever they are) is readily accomplished, The "market", product lines and had even small a a hardly ultimate grocery store acqui- Los Angeles was ruled illegal even though the had only 7.5% of retail grocery business, chains and 3,800 stores in operation, said to be difficult.) competitive, of even if it was obvious that the merger by itself case in this line was Vc;D_ls_Grocery 3 where grocery over- fraction (Perhaps the firms and be firms could not materially affect competition. in mar- serious result was that mergers could successfully challenged if the merging in their sition monopoly thwart high-fashion shoe market") substituting for analysis. were lapped 2 to that parlance of businessmen ("the Chicago drug-store the ket", the older view first, of the Clayton Act was designed power "in its incipiency" perni- two views became efficiency merged there were and entry 150 could Since there certainly can be pro- reasons for mergers, 2009824 there are clear social costs to having an over-stringent policy. doctrine. there is the language of level, one At to lessen competition or to tend to substantially monopoly." (It is for this reason that the More fundamentally, tion.") standard, a reduce 7 a pro- competi- there are substantive reasons these are reasons for not and create administration to change the language to "substantially poses such Section which speaks in terms of mergers the effect of which "may itself be serious reasons for the "incipiency" to be sure, There are, for changing the language. In the case of single-firm monopolies, we have had, at least since the ALCOA case non-competitive a , legal doctrine that permits us to attack market structures even if the firm involved wrongful in 'itself but has deliberately nothing done 4 achieve the market structure in question. There is no doctrine Hence, in the case of tight oligopoly. has acted to parallel even where we are sure that the structure of the market is highly conducive conscious likely parallelism, to succeed no antitrust attack on that structure is even be attempted) (or explicitly Only . implicitly collusive acts can be successfully attacked, a win that by the Government will leave in place the very makes . occur again. to it likely that similar anticompetitive or and even structure events will 7 Of course, it will sometimes be the case that no structural remedy for tight oligopoly is possible. Just as there are natu- ral monopolies, there are natural oligopolies, inevitability of a monopoly-like structure is defense under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, (or and, just as the ought to be) a so the inevitability of oligopoly structure ought to be tight a structurally-oriented anti-oligopoly act. a defense under a But at present that is not an issue, because such an act does not exist. The closest thing that we do have to such an act is Where 7. merger or a series of mergers will result in a Section oligopoly structure. us "inevitability" structure can be most easily examined by weighing the that of pro- anticompetitive effects of the merger in the context of and pre-merger situation. is the move to a tight oligopoly be halted at a time when the can tight a with its present language permits What is more, to prevent it. structure 7 Section Finally, since, as generally far easier to enjoin divestiture afterward, a the practical matter, it merger than to order complex a there is something to be said for dealing with structural oligopoly "in its incipiency" by dealing with the mergers that will create it. There which are, however, problems here. Consider the case in tight oligopoly structure will be a series of mergers if they are not stopped. dealing with because in other hand, itself innocent and even it may stop a merger pro-competitive of a line of mergers that may never happen. if di- On the one hand, if antitrust attack simply the Court or the Justice Department envisages it as forerunner a In such a situation, begins with the first merger in the series, is through the problem through merger policy rather than rectly runs certain risks. which attained antitrust attack waits for later anticompetitive effect seems certain, mergers one can regard the cipants in those merger as being treated unfairly. On the the when parti- Further, such a policy can provide an incentive to merge while the merging structural anti-oligopoly policy, A good. by contrast, — involve all the participants in the oligopoly those involved in As direction the first problem of — rather than only as defendants. has erred like them would together be anticompetitive. gers the in mergers attacking particular - would the Kantian categorical imperative shows that many because the incipiency doctrine too far. of — merger policy turned out, has it single transaction a mer- This carries On the other hand, the attempt administration to change the language of the is Section 7 to "substantial reduction in competition" will lead to the require a second problem • — otherwise attacking only later mergers in an symmetric series. There is no solution for this in the realm of merger policy. The problem arises substitute for because we attempt to make structural policy towards oligopoly. a policy merger It is at o best an imperfect substitute. pursuit The of presupposes however, structures when any structural policy that we we see them. direct structural policy, can oligopoly, towards recognize anti-competitive That would be a requisite and it is crucial for the more indirect approach embodied in merger policy. that requisite is not easy to meet, a necessarily Unfortunately, and there is a temptation to avoid difficult analysis in favor of easily measured, rect standards. of but incor- While some progress has recently been made, this problem pervades all aspects of merger policy. The market area in which some progress has been made is definition, that of in which the Department of Justices' s Guider lines 9 have focussed on the right sort of things. definition is an artificial problem created by anti- Market the For any other purpose of economic litigation. trust analysis, binary question of whether particular firms or products or "out" of a given "in" market is a antitrust cases, that question is not results a whose those The proposition that flexible wrap- papers substitute for cellophane at ping in constraints the firms and products put on the power of actions are being examined. Even useful one if substantive What matters are turn on the answer. other that meaningless one. are a high cellophane price but not at lower ones already contains a good deal of information concerning the ability of monopoly a sole supplier of cellophane to charge There is nothing to gain and much to lose by the Procrustean device of summarizing that information either in the prices. that flexible wrapping papers and cellophane statement "in" the same market or in are (the Supreme Court's position in Cellppbaog) the statement that they are not (the position many of commentators) Such Procrustean activity, however, has historically been of overwhelming definition importance in antitrust cases. being used as information, merger market device for summarizing and organizing has become the principal issue. To return Nestle's of Stouffers in the mid-1970s to know that analysis that case was not helped by a debate over whether there is 1 "market" consisting of high-priced, frozen, non-ethnic entrees. If to one need know little about the facts of cases, acquisition in it a Instead of market definition is to be at all useful in a 11 antitrust cases, it must be the beginning, rather than the end of analysis. Market definition ought properly to define the universe of dis- course within which analysis will take place. that This means the "market" should include those firms and products necessary to of the pricing and product understanding the behavior the in An alternative way of putting this is to say that the "market". must include those firms and services that act to "market" con- strain the activities of the firm or firms that are the object of That such constraints may not all be equally powerful attention. points merely to the facts that analysis does not end when market has been defined and that simple-minded measures of or concentration, definition, the power like simple-minded binary treatments of market unlikely to be adequate. return to this Department of Justice (DOJ) Mg£ggr_GuidgliD£s (in both are I 12 U T below. The the 1982 and 1984) versions, are firms that could, aside above if they colluded, profitably raise prices five Putting the current levels for a year. a moment, for major step in the direction of DOJ defines a "market" as the minimum collection of sanity here. percent a this is plainly the right details approach. If prices cannot be so raised, then supply or demand substitutability puts important included. be constraints on the power of those To leave those constraints out of the "market" to have much of the action take place off stage. already would The Guider lines implicit focus on constraints as the principal question to be asked in market definition is absolutely right. It is less clear that the specific details of liDgsJ. approach are correct. the Guide;: Is five percent the correct thres- amount hold amount to use for price rises? of time? Is one year the correct Should the five percent be applied to current price levels or to something else? begin with the third of these questions, I since the answer to it has implications for the answers to the first two. The use of current levels as the base for the test is consistent with the view that merger policy is a preventive, designed to keep matters from getting worse. that merger policy is a substitute for view if one takes the On the other hand, structural policy a to- wards oligopoly, then one may want to use competitive rather than current levels as the base. duopoly in which prices have already been raised to Consider an already percent of the level at which product (flexible Guidelines a tight fairly within five competitively-produced substitute wrapping papers) can compete. present The since the market would let the duopoly merge, have to include the producers of the substitute. would Since conscious parallelism may not always be easy to maintain, permitting such merger last. may (A make permanent a situation that otherwise might a not similar statement applies where there are more than two firms in the original oligopoly.) Further, since the merger of the two duopolists is not "economically inevitable" or solely the result of "superior skill, the foresight, and industry," 13 there is possible anomaly that the Guidelines used in the administra- tion of the supposedly more stringent Clayton Act, would permit merger leading to a monopoly that could then be a successfully challenged under Section Two of the Sherman Act. On the other hand, while the use of current price levels implies an acceptance cf existing power and behavior, competitive levels has its own problems. what competitive prices would be, just prices used as the base, were the use of It is not easy to know in practice. there would be danger serious a such If that DOJ would simply look at profits or profits-sales ratios a mechanical attempt to compute competitive prices. be This would both because profits play an important mistake, a role competitive industries and are not absent save in long-run librium, accounting because and measures of profits knowing 14 what competitive price levels are is more apparent decide whether than market participants can raise prices above competitive levels is precisely the kind of analysis required do sensible job of market definition by considering the a straints on behavior. to con- It is not particularly different in kind the qualitative analysis now required by the use of current from levels as the base. to in The kind of qualitative analysis required real in this context. to the or the difficulty however, in equi- profits-sales ratio do not tell one what one wants to know. If that danger can be avoided, in Only if detailed quantitative analysis were performed would the exact location of be levels matter, and such competitive analysis is typically not price practical anyway. As the question of whether five percent this suggests, the correct figure for the test may not be very five The important. percent figure does serve to focus attention on the sort of effects serves is that will be considered important, only to give a but beyond spurious impression of precision analysis that is generally imprecise. that it to an On the other hand, quanti- tative analysis need not always be impossible, point so there is some in considering whether five percent is a reasonable figure to use. The answer here depends on the costs and benefits By using a high figure, one allows mergers to slip by that lead to elevated prices and welfare loss. using low figure, one runs the risk of prohibiting mergers that a ther, may On the other hand, by relatively harmless and may have efficiency are involved. reasons. Fur- bears the cost of administrative or judicial proceed- one ings in order to stop a fairly small harm. Since it is impossi- ble to decide where to draw the line without a detailed analysis of the likely welfare losses and gains in each case, five percent seems to me to be however, price I sensible administrative rule. a As indicated, would apply it to competitive rather than to current levels, which suggests a more stringent rule for already non-competitive industries than DOJ now uses. take a different view on the use of one year as the I criterion for the test. which entry short a not a me Together with two years as the time will be considered, this seems to me to imply time horizon and too restrictive the power involved in Self-correction within that time seems to test. particularly about, to raise prices by five percent everybody if colludes does not imply that prices will in fact be so raised. would market be inclined to use definition and too is to make the problem not worth bothering since in Two years a particularly long time compared to the time litigating a merger. time a longer time, perhaps two four years for ease of years entry. I for Again, it is hard to be sure. however, Since market definition is the threshold event for analysis, a more stringent rule may be appro- priate in deciding whether to investigate further than in deci- Certainly, a more stringent ding whether to challenge a merger. rule is appropriate in that circumstance than in setting a stan- dard for judicial decisions. This brings me to an important point. between deciding cases to investigate or oppose, what — difference a guidelines as to and deciding on a judicial Arbitrary rules are inevitable and may even be useful standard. in on guidelines for triage There is the first context. Department They are a menace in the The second. of Justice has not always recognized the difference, particularly when it comes to the use of concentration measures. principal reason for such unwise concentration on The what to be the non-question of market definition is that things ought "in" the market will be counted in measures such as market shares or concentration indices which, answers give simple it is vainly hoped, to questions of market power or the likelihood of competitive activity. Things "out" of the market, anti- on the other hand, play a much more minor role, often coming in, if at all, in terms of The makeweight reference to ease of or barriers to a problem is that the use of such indices does not entry. fact in produce correct results. The fact is that the analysis of oligopoly does not yield useful results relating structure to conduct and performance. know in a general way what the features are that make parallelism firms, more or less likely conscious (number and size distribution of complexity of the product, 10 We etc.). Unfortunately, such is nowhere near precise enough to substitute knowledge study of specific situations. while it is clear In particular, conscious parallelism is more likely the smaller the number that of the for firms, whether is not true that we have any serious idea it danger point is reached at four firms the rather than five or, indeed, what the function in question lokks like. while likely the more concentrated is the market, reason for Hirschman it seems clear picking Index (HHI) Simi- that conscious parallelism is larly, out particular levels as danger points. there is of more sound no Herfindahl- the Indeed, to as while the HHI itself seems a reasonable way to measure concentration, there is neither theory nor reliable econometric evidence showing that the HHI is a sufficient statistic for the effects of concentration on non-competitive behavior. It would 15 therefore be a great mistake if courts were to adopt the practice of judging mergers by gress) or even primarily at pre- and post-merger HHI only with market shares in monopoly cases, crudest Con- (or looking levels. As the HHI provides only the of indications as to what we want to know. Any serious merger case must ask specifically about the possibility of collusion. This means an investigation of the particular situa- involved tion tacit including not necessarily (but limited to) a serious analysis of ease of entry. Such strictures, however, do not apply to the use of the HHI for administrative purposes as in the DOJ Guidelines. mited resources and finite time, decide somehow the antitrust authorities what cases to investigate and then 11 With pursue. li- must If decision is net itself to require that In that circumstance, readily. investiga- rules must be used that can be applied some then tion, full-dress a fairly the use of the HHI to trigger or turn off investigation appears warranted. Since would only use the HHI in this way, such to treat foreign competition recede in how as I exist quotas or are likely, questions importance. then the availability If foreign of capacity does not put the same constraint on post-merger anticom- petitive behavior than would the same capaicity domestic hands. independent in would calculate the HHI both including foreign I production beyond the quota level and excluding it. a difference, "right" mistake in then there is something to analyze and investigate There is no point in wasting time arguing which one is further. the If it makes computation'. As with market definition, it deci- a that foreign competition is either the same as domestic sion not present at all. point a to suppress the fact that foreign competition may matter different way from domestic competition by forcing a is of a or Calculation of the HHI ought not to be the merger analysis, but only a signal for further investigation. Are the levels currently used in the Guidelines, the How can one know? Plainly, a very post-merger HHI makes it most unlikely that anticompetitive ones to use as such signals? low behavior will merger (or can) result from the merger. Plainly also, that raises the HHI by a very large amount and leaves very high is one that requires investigation. low" right and "very high" mean? it But what do "very Is the 1800 cut-off the right To know this with much certainty would be to know what we 12 a one? empha- do not know tically — exactly how the HHI relates to non-compe- titive behavior One can get a little farther than this, however. of The danger setting the trigger levels of the HHI too high is that mergers will slip through. competitive them setting with beset effects been dangers of too low is that the antitrust authorities will be One of the many cases of high HHIs with claims experience in this regard under the What has . Guidelines? that the call for DOJ to consider other suspect offsetting of (and may lose such cases if they go to trial) the anti- things I besides concentration suggests that the trigger levels are set low rather than particularly because my experience suggests that DOJ high, has a strong tendency towards too narrow a market definition. This is not necessarily a bad thing. setting such levels is to trigger investigation, better to waste resources on an investigation of shown to purpose of it may well be If the a be harmless than to fail to investigate merger that is a that merger will turn out to be harmful. Unfortunately, there are other costs to Mergers are sometimes delicate creatures, litigation can be extremely expensive. Guidelines levels. mergers. used by low trigger levels. and antitrust The HHI levels set in the such can therefore act to deter mergers that involve Setting the levels low can deter socially useful This is particularly likely if the trigger levels the authorities not as signals to investigate signals to oppose. is a natural, Alas, this is likely to be the case. if distressing are but as There tendency for the Antitrust Division 13 to become fascinated with its own Guidelines, and to focus on the HHI levels mentioned therein as though failure to pass the tests of the Guidelines were proof that tive rather than merely being analysis further Unfortunately, merger was anticompeti- signal for further analysis. (but not necessarily) primary The a a the only the investigation of is item barriers such in entry. to this is generally recognized in principle, while there is mass confusion over what it involves in practice. analytic use of the term "barriers to entry" The can from working." only be entry a must as "Barriers to entry prevent the competitive part of the sentence: process comes Similarly: competitive result." there "Where entry is easy, Accordingly, be something that interferes with must be something that allows incumbent firms, barrier a to competition. if they It collude, to charge non-competitive prices and earn supra-normal profits. follows It not everything that that makes difficult or uninviting is necessarily a barrier to mere built mies or necessity of building a of scale can be) creating a The entry. already plant when incumbents have theirs is not such a barrier appear entry (although associated econo- Neither is the necessity of advertising . reputation automatically a barrier. long-run the phenomenon involved must give incumbents advantage, permitting them to earn supra-normal profits on rier, whole bar- To be a a the process of getting into the market and continuing to without inducing others to enter and bid those profits away. This Antitrust is not an easy Division concept to apply in practice, does not have a good track record recent example will serve to illustrate the point. 14 1 act, 17 and here. the A In the recent was Northwest-Republic airline merger witness for Northwest) a market. , which (in DOJ took quite a narrow view of the addition to the position discussed in footnote In I 16, above, DOJ argued that air passenger traffic on routes out of the merged airline's Minneapolis hub, peted could only be effectively com- Minneapolis. by another airline also having a hub at for This is not a compelling position. What keeps an airline with a hub at Denver from competing on equal terms with one at Minneapofor traffic between the two cities? lis with hub at Dallas, a say, Why cannot an airline and already serving cities between and Minneapolis simply extend its flights to compete Dallas between Minneapolis and those other cities? traffic these questions entry and assume aside in order to concentrate arguendo that a on But I barriers hub at Minneapolis would for put to be necessary to compete with the merged airline. There were structing such gate a hub. facilities. already no obvious barriers to another Landing slots were not Further, of problem, nor were since both Northwest had hubs at Minneapolis, economies a con- airline's Republic and it could not be the case scale made the possession of such a hub that natural a monopoly. Why then did the DOJ claim that there were barriers to entry and go on to oppose the merger? Division, It is not an said the attractive to build a and other airlines a hub. between will not hub there in the presence of the East and West Coast cities, it Antitrust attractive place to have is too far North to be an efficient connecting point major find Minneapolis Because, 15 large number of flights "controlled" by the west. Indeed, DOJ conducted an informal survey of other airlines post-merger told them that they would not regard hubbing at who North- Minneapolis as an attractive post-merger proposition. This position misunderstands the proper analysis of barriers issue should have been whether The entry. to other find hubbing at Minneapolis attractive if the would ppstrmerger Whether Northwest sought to raise prises and reduce output. not airlines would find Minneapolis attractive other aggressively Northwest post-merger airlines competing by with the offering the service previously flown by the two merger partners and doing pre-merger price was irrelevant. the at Even or so obviously more was the issue of whether Minneapolis is inherently an irrelevant The geographical position of Minneapolis is not attractive hub. something that gives incumbents an advantage over entrants. Having said this, I cannot forbear adding that DOJ factually wrong about the attractiveness of Minneapolis as In fact, jection great because the earth is sphere, a hub. the usual Mercator pro- of North America gives a quite misleading picture. circle and that, The pass quite together with prevailing winds routes from East to West Coast cities close to Minneapolis, traffic patterns makes it the second most attractive hub for and flights, such DOJ a was ' s hearing position a few minutes worse than Chicago. Shockingly, on this indisputable matter persisted after in the case. At discussions following those the hearings, higher-ups in the Division made the same argument about Minneapolis's wrong. position and were quite surprised to learn that they The symbolism is clear. I 16 were fear that, at least as regards the the Department of barriers to entry, analysis Justice of still believes that the earth is flat. This is defined Particularly if markets are to be narrowly pity. a would put great weight on it in considering Having said this, I must go en to caution against permit the HHI to serve as more than produce a useful quantitative index of ease of entry. the antitrust authorities quantitative need so also we know too little to be able premature attempts in this regard. on not rough signal of the may change as the science progresses, this for a of measure Just as the state of our knowledge does for further investigation, to attempts important question by the creation of some summary ease of entry. I prospective merger. a avoid what ought to be a thoughtful and detailed analysis this of set the analysis of entry is absolutely crucial. relatively low, to investigation HHI levels that trigger further and standards is well to it There is While temptation great a (and perhaps the courts) as a substitute for avoid real focus to analysis. Economists ought not to offer such temptation unless the delivery soundly backs up the promise. Another example drawn from the Northwest-Republic illustrative here. likely to enter a Correctly observing that airlines are service, for example, other origins at Kansas City) lihood of constructed entry is more given city-pair route if they have traffic that feed into that route (more likely to enter Kansas lis case City-Minneapo- if they can collect passengers , DOJ introduced called the "feed ratio." as follows for a given city pair, 17 a from measure of like- That measure A and B. was Assume first that there is only one incumbent airline and one potential The "feed ratio" is the ratio of the sum of the poten- entrant. entrant's emplanements at A and B divided by the sum of the tial incumbent's emplanements at the two cities. than one incumbent-entrant pair, the "feed ratio" is taken to be the maximum over all such pairs of this ratio DOJ argued least at first) (at Where there is more that the fact of emplanements. that the "feed was relatively low for a number of routes involved in the ratio" merger showed that entry was difficult. This is, of course, nonsense. lis city pair, those airline. be flying on by definition, must, between incumbent an Other passengers emplanng at those cities are certainly Of what possible' relevance to a decision somewhere else. going Passengers wishing to fly for example. cities Consider the Boston-Minneapo- by Delta to enter Boston-Minneapolis service is the fact that my wife, who has no reason to travel to Minneapolis, sometimes flies from Boston to Cincinnati to visit her parents? It predict is entry and not surprising that the chief actual DOJ eventually admitted that it was not an entry for What is disturbing is that DOJ made it forward. I . putting That lure should always be resisted. After the decision to investigate on the basis of the HHI, a proposed merger has been ease of entry is the that should be investigated first. the witness predictor. fair production of a phenomenon That is so, first because of intrinsic importance of the role of potential entry (or lack thereof) to believe this was because of the powerful lure of spurious measurability taken fails thus not surprising that the "feed ratio" and, second, because 18 a the finding that entry is easy Where entry is not easy or the issue in should be dispositive. doubt, further investigation must be undertaken as to the likely effects the proposed merger on of competition and, those if effects are found to be negative, on any offsetting efficiencies. gone beyond an analysis of entry to an Having merely first as a threshold matter. would I those other factors as tie breakers. use concentration One of not One analyzes then analyzes because it may dispose of the question if the answer comes entry out bearing on effects on competition, factors other analysis particular way. a have But one must not forget that we do not good enough theory of oligopoly to be able to infer anti- a competitive results from structure in any precise way. Instead, analysis should always bear in mind that the question merger at issue is the likelihood, or at least the ease, of anticompetitive The complexity of the product, the extent to which an behavior. effective many agreement would require implicit tacit negotiated price, transaction prices instead of collusion single a list the ease with which cheating on a tacit agreement can be detected, analysis and similar matters are properly these once subjects appears that concentration will be it entry difficult. high for and It is not unnatural that the burden of proof in matters will devolve onto the participants in the such on prospec- tive merger, but that is not to say that such matters should only come into play in otherwise doubtful cases. The burden of proof as to cost savings or other efficiencies here I whould also be on the proponents of would require a very high standard. 19 a offsetting merger, but That is because such claims are easily made and, I often too easily believed. think, Two examples will illustrate this. General Motors and Toyota proposed When assemble small car in California, a joint venture a one would have thought considerations would have prevented it. antitrust that Here the two largest automobile manufacturers in the world were combining produce a provide an obvious prices. Even question by prices, The price of that vehicle vehicle. reference point for the very to a particular sion approved the joint venture. argument that the venture the likely setting average other of would realize efficiencies, Japanese Presumably, GM would then be able to use those secrets in other plants. is far from clear that the by secrets all. at hardly It to be learned, labor relations and took a joint venture to learn about those. the extent that there were production "secrets" to it seemed unlikely that GM would learn very much from assembly Finally, to be at least, management were believed to be the source of efficien- Moreover, an The Japanese system of Japanese so-called were not believed by Ford officials, inventory cies. The 19 accepted efficiency argument the FTC was more than superficial. "secrets" to because It did so principally automobile manufacture more efficient than American. It car Yet the Federal Trade Commis- GM would learn from Toyota the secrets that made since to other of use of a particular average seemed likely facilitate conscious parallelism. of was to though GM and Toyota proposed to set the price in reference the to plant when the engines were produced in Japan. GM already had relations with other Japanese automobile manufacturers 20 All by in all, the FTC appears to have been too easily swayed the difficulties of the American automobile industry and success of the Japanese. It accepted fairly superficial promises of efficiencies to be gained and approved an arrangement to be anticompetitive. result of Ford, a One need only contemplate similar application for example, for to the likely likely the joint venture by GM and realize the tremendous weight that the a efficiency argument was given. My second example relates once again to airlines. Here, the Department of Transportation (DOT) has approved a whole series of mergers. On the whole, I regard those approvals as warranted. The entire process of airline deregulation rests on the view that city-pair and "markets" are contestable. other facilities are available number large of airlines) , So long as landing (or can there is a be purchased slots from strong presumption mergers of domestic airlines cannot result in much market That presumption, however, where entry is in fact difficult, does not extend to DOT's that power. situations automatically and it does not extend to acquisitions involving foreign routes. a In particular, approval of United Airlines acquisition of Pan American's Pacific Division is open to very serious question. 20 . Entry Asia is service plays ding . into air transportation between the United States and far from easy. This is particularly true between Japan and the United States, a and as regards that service vital role both because of Japan's importance as partner and because of its geographic position. tion does not apply to that service, 21 and, indeed, a tra- Deregulathe Japanese historically reluctant to been have there Further, are considerable permit expanded restrictions on service. the use of Tokyo's Narita airport. Before the acquisition, quite concentrated would permit percent The 2542 in 1984) the number four carrier service (United) with , about Lines and Northwest) each had Air a bit more 7 carrier Numbers one and which had about 19 percent. was acquisition The . the market to combine with the number three of (Pan American) (Japan (an HHI of mainland Japan-U.S. than two 30%. acquisition (in terms of 1984 figures) caused an increase in the HHI from 2542 to 2812, DOJ's Guidelines. well beyond the trigger levels set in 21 Before the acquisition, there was substantial price competition in particular, United, acquisition, traffic it Apollo computer reservation system, be the only airline providing both After attract could first by manipulating competing on price, without United seemed likely that actively had gateway. to increase traffic through its Seattle sought the various kinds. .of its and second, because it would a really extensive route structure in the United States (acquired during regulation) and large system of routes connecting at the Tokyo hub — a latter the being Pan American's legacy from regulation. There service is meant no doubt that the provision a real benefit to pasengers. regarded this as an efficiency. of such DOT very integrated properly What is not so clear is whether that efficiency should have justified the acquisition. Had have the acquisition not been approved, either sold its Pacific Division to a 22 Pan American different would domestic airline not already serving Japan or else would have continued to (The Pacific Division was operate it itself. before the profitable, Pan American had announced acquisition, Pacific service for the summer of 1985.) expanded and, plans for In the latter Pan American would certainly have continued its program to case, expand its domestic route structure. quisition would have not forbidding the ac- Hence, prevented service integrated from developing American was not the only airline that would have deve- Pan loped such integrated service. developed its own Tokyo hub, domestic route system. largely sion, gradually which had was also striving to expand its (After the transfer of the Pacific Diviof the need to catch up with because acquisition United, Northwest, ' post- the Northwest strove to expand quickly by acqui- ring Republic.) United itself could have expanded. Most important, was already creating a rival hub at Seoul. into Japan was difficult, States Further, while entry it was not impossible, and the United government could have made expansion by United object of negotiations with Japan. This was United a a primary very real possibi- lity, because the Spring of 1985 saw an agreement between the two countries to open as many as three new routes. United could have been given those routes. In short, absent the acquisition, there might well have been three companies competing to provide acquisition service. that number to no more than two. reduced connection, DOT took integrated a In The this very limited view of its responsibilities, 23 for refusing, to connect the award of the new example, with the outcome of the case. with would It appears to have been impressed post-acquisition irrelevant argument that the the be stronger competitor than a routes United pre-acquisition the Pan American. because of efficiency considerations if the efficiencies involved could be obtained in a this suggests, As I would not approve mergers Further, less restrictive way. I would hesitate to efficiencies as an excuse for permitting merger if those efficiencies are unlikely to be passed on to customers. In use the such Pacific Division case, for example, a the benefits of inte- grated service could have been achieved while maintaining compe- tition. That would have ensured that the travelling public would benefitted from those efficiencies without paying more have for The approval of the acqui- them in the form of increased prices. sition created the efficiencies but also made it very likely that all benefits would be captured by United itself. am, I payments concerned obtained who sensible of the argument ought not to matter to economists, be only of course, outweigh with the question but hard to evaluate. achievable mergers, nally, whether In practice, however, I of not would otherwise Efficiency arguments are easy to The same efficiencies will often be in less restrictive ways, on the other hand, a should efficiencies mergers for efficiency reasons if they seemed likely to be anticompetitive. make, so that one deadweight loss and not with the question captures the savings. approve of transfer that have a particularly if one waits; way of being permanent. policy of approving anticompetitive mergers for 24 Fieffi- reasons is likely to promote a dissipation ciency resources of into rent seeking. All of this, however, supposes that been has a proper merger analysis carried out and the proposed merger found to be competitive. I would certainly accept evidence of showing that the merged enterprise will be as tor. efficiencies tougher competi- merger analysis continues to be dominated by the If surement a anti- of concentration, I weight would put considerable a showing as offsetting the really crude presumption such meaon resul- ting from market definition and the HHI. To sum up then, I think the DOJ Guidelines are roughly right properly interpreted. if however, Such proper interpretation, requires the use of market definition and the HHI only as signalling the necessity of serious analysis. done, then pre-merger screening can serve an important useful purpose, pre- venting If that is lengthy litigation to force the disgorgement of already digested assets. On the other hand, there has been a tendency for the Guide;: lines to substitute for analysis, with DOJ focussing on issues of market definition and concentration measures. the present In rious in a (and likely future) That is state of our a mistake. knowledge, analysis of market power and oligopoly cannot be se- subsumed few spuriously precise measurements. The Reagan administration has generally been very permissive in its merger policies. viewed as HHI a To an extent, that permissiveness may be correction to the tendency of DOJ staff to substitute measurement for economics, 25 but that is only true if one thinks fact, opposed of different mergers as substitutes for each mergers by standards, have sometimes been wrongly blocked (or at DOJ) because of unthinking application of and sometimes wrongly approved because of find efficiency excuses (a The a least Guideline a wish to United-Pan two mistakes do not compensate for each and neither approach is In wish that may be greatest where compe- tition with foreigners is involved as in GM-Toyota or American). other. substitute for sound analysis. 26 other, FpptDOtes BrpWD_Shpe_CpmpaDy v 1. "incipiency" doctrine goes back The 2. discussion of the original Clayton Act. 63rd Cong., 2nd Sess. 698, used when Section 81st Cong., Court 7 (1950), 294 at 317, United_States 4. 148 F. 2d 416 (1945) Whether 5. understood is and J.J. 384 U.S. , 270 (1966). , . that standard is always wisely applied or McGowan, See F.M. well Fisher, J.E. Green- Fplded^_Spindled^_and_Mutilatedi_Ecpr Mass.: (Cambridge, MIT Press, . This 6. have may be the reason that the attempted (decided 1981) antitrust authorities to invent a doctrine of "shared monopoly." In_the_Matter_pf_Kellpgg_Company^_et_al J , FTC Docket No. See 8883 . Consideration of the absence of any serious remedy in the 7. second Co.., and by the Brpwn_Shpe A2umiDum_CpmpaDy_pf_Americaj._et_alj v. different matter. a 1775, 346), as well as in later opinions. npmic_Analysis_and_y_.S_._yj_.IBM 1983) (Senate Report No. United_gtates v. VpD_[s_GrpC£ry_Cp J 3. Congressional The same language was 4-5), pp. to (See Senate Report No. (1914), p. 1.) was amended in 1950 2nd Sess. (370 U.S. wood, UDited_States, 370 U.S. 294 (1962). * Amer ican_Tpbaccp case 328 U.S. 781 (1946)) (Unj.ted_§ tates v. or of the Ameiican_Tpbaccp history of litigation investigations in the blem. no position on whether structural remedies I take cement industry will illustrate have been effective in these industries. 27 the and prowould policy towards oligopoly that (unlike the case tural tural Section a single all in them- There is no escape from this problem. it in terms of merger policy either does not solve else makes it worse in the sense or of it penalizing for acts that might later be taken by others. firms itself in penalized because of actions (also not wrong Attacking at individual firms doing nothing wrong taken by others. selves) struc- of cases where all the acts are under the control of 2 firm) be will of course, be considered an objection to a struc- It may, 8. two It is well to remember that such objections have less force when considering civil, rather than criminal cases. United States Department of Justice, Merger_Guidelines 9. Federal Register, Vol. 49 (1984), 26,284. United_States v. 10. U.S. 377 E.. Ij_duPpnt_de_Nemours_and_Cpmpany See G.W. Stocking and W.F. Mueller, (1956). , 353 "The Cello- Case and the New Competition," American_Ecgnomic_Reyiew 45 phane (March 1955), pp. 29-63; Policy (Cambridge, Mass.: and 102; Posner, R.A. C. Kaysen and D.F. Turner, Antitrust Harvard University Press, 1959), p. Antitr^st_Lawi_AD_Econpmic_Perspectiye (Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, 1976), pp. 127128. 11. the It may or may not have been a coincidence that, after acquisition was challenged by the Federal Trade Conmmission, Stouffers began someone tasting "What is it? a series of television commercials that a featured Stouffer's product and saying something It tastes like lasagna, but it isn't lasagna." case was eventually settled. 28 like The 12. For more detailed discussion of these issues in a context of Sherman Act, Section Chapter Greenwood, op_._cit_ ! , 13. F. 295 Amer.ica.t _et_al.1 PP.±_cit.., of 3. 148 F. , 2d 416 On these matters, Chapter 7, (1945) at 430. see Fisher, McGowan, and Greenwood, F.M. Fisher and J.J. McGowan, "On the Misuse Accounting Rates of Return to Infer Monopoly Profits," Amgiir Fisher, Vol. "On the Misuse of the Profits-Sales Ratio to Infer Mono- Massachussetts Institute Power," 15. (March 1983), pp. 82-97, and F. M. 73 Paper 364 (Revised April 1986) Working . The HHI is defined as the sum of squares of the venient decimal points). of Technology of of the individual firms multiplied by 10,000 HHI 110 , at 341; Dnited_3tate v. AlumiDum_CpmpaDy_Pf (1953) can_Ecpnpmic_Reyiew, poly cases, see Fisher, McGowan, and UDited_States v. United_Shpe_Machine£y_CprppiatipD Supp. 14. 2 the shares (to eliminate incon- Before the multiplication by 10,000, an 1/n can be thought of as the level of concentration measured) that would occur if there were n (so identically-sized firms in the market. Studies attempting to relate profit levels to HHI values are not reliable competitive Fisher, guides to the influence of concentration behavior. pp_._cit... See Fisher and McGowan, on non- op J._cit J and Even on their own terms, such studies are not so successful as to warrant basing merger policy on them. 16. In the Northwest-Republic airline merger Acguisitipn_Case, Department of Transportation (NWArRepublic Docket 43754 (1986)), DOJ insisted that one-stop or connecting airline service was not in the same market as non-stop service. 29 In so doing, it based arguments on the undeniable fact that its travelers all non-stop service to one-stop or connecting service if the prefer flights leave at the same time and have the same price. argument takes definition. a very limited view of substitution market and In fact, people take one-stop or connecting flights in preference to non-stop flights if they get something That Such an something lower price. cally sells for can be time-of-day convenience or it can A large box of a thereby. a be a particular breakfast cereal typi- higher price than does a small box. not put them in different markets, and, in fact, That does the prices of the different types of flights tend to move together. For an extended discussion of these matters, 17. see C. C. n vori lin, Weizsacker, Heidelberg, Barr iers_tp_Entryi_A_Theoretical_Treatment New York: Springer-Verlag , 1980) (Ber- and Chapter 6 of Fisher, McGowan, and Greenwood, pp_._c.it_.. lpc__cit_. 19. see Fisher, For an older one, 18. McGowan, and Greenwood, . [CITE NEEDED]. I was retained by counsel for Ford who eventually decided not to bring suit to oppose the joint venture. 20. Pacj,fic_DiyisipD_Transf ex_Case, Department of Transpor- tation Docket 43065 (1985). I was a witness for Northwest Air- lines which opposed the acquisition. My views on the matter are set forth at length in F. M. Fisher, "Pan American to United: The Pacific Division Transfer Case," Massachusetts Institute of Tech- nology Working Paper 420 (May, 1986) 21. . It is worth remarking that the testimony offered by DOJ in opposition to the acquisition was focussed very heavily on the 30 HHI and the QuideliDSg. this. They purporting HHIs had United and Pan American were ready fcr had previously prepared a study for use in rebuttal to show the not very surprising fact little effect on fares. that The result was city-pair largely divert argument from the more substantial questions at issue. 31 to 361 UQ75 Date Due JE26W) IY 1 OEC o '90 ^ 1990 dec o 1 ress Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 TOBO OD5 130 b43