Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/financialfrictioOOIore 6 DEWEY Y\0- OT' 4> Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series FINANCIAL FRICTIONS INVESTMENT AND TOBIN'S q Guido Lorenzoni Karl Walentin Working Paper 07-1 April 25, 2007 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 021 42 This paper can be downloaded without char ge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://ssrn.com/abstract=983421 Financial Frictions, Investment and Tobin's Guido Lorenzonit Karl Walentin* MIT and NBER Sveriges Riksbank q* April 25, 2007 Abstract We develop a model of investment with financial constraints and use it to investigate q. A firm is financed partly by insiders, who investors. When their wealth is scarce, insiders the relation between investment and Tobin's control its assets, and partly by outside earn a rate of return higher than the market rate of return, on invested by two capital. This rent forces: is i.e., they receive a quasi- rent priced into the value of the firm, so Tobin's q is driven changes in the value of invested capital, and changes in the value of the insiders' future rents per unit of capital. This weakens the correlation between q and investment, relative to the frictionlcss benchmark. We present a calibrated version of the model, which, due to this effect, generates realistic correlations between investment, q, and cash flow. Keywords: Financial constraints, investment, Tobin's JEL codes: E22, E30, E44, q, limited enforcement. G30. *We thank for useful comments Andrew Abel, Daron Acemoglu, Joao Ejarquc, Mark Gertler, Veronica Hubert Kcmpf, Sydney Ludvigson, Martin Schneider, and seminar participants at New York University, MIT, University of Oslo, EEA Meetings (Amsterdam), Minneapolis FED, Sveriges Riksbank, Uppsala University, Norges Bank, SED Meetings (Vancouver), NBER Summer Institute 2006, and CEPRBank of Finland conference on Credit and the Macroeconomy. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Executive Board of Sveriges Riksbank. Guerricri, ^E-mail: glorenzo@mit.edu. E-mail: karl.walentin@riksbank.se. Introduction 1 The standard model the investment rate should be entirely explained by changes in Tobin's generally been rejected in empirical studies, which of current profitability have a strong predictive Tobin's many This has been taken by q. movements of investment with convex adjustment costs predicts that This prediction has q. show that cash flow and other measures power for investment, after controlling for authors as prima facie evidence of the presence of financial constraints at the firm level. and Ejarque (2003) have challenged in Gomes In recent papers, this interpretation. (2001) and Cooper They compute dynamic general equilibrium models with financial frictions, calibrate them, and look at the relation between Their results show that, even in the Tobin's q and investment in the simulated series. presence of financial frictions, Tobin's q explains most of the variability in investment, still and cash flow does not provide any additional explanatory power. This seems to echo a concern raised by Chirinko (1993): "Even though market financial frictions impinge on the firm, q is looking variable capturing the ramifications of these constraints on decisions. Not only does In this paper frictions does so, amount we analyze this issue which can be interpreted The shareholder. he is some or all financial by building a model of investment with financial as the entrepreneur, the For each firm there an is manager, or the controlling insider has the ability to partially divert the assets of the firm and, if he punished by losing control of the firm. This imposes an upper bound on the of outside finance that the insider is able to raise. In this framework, to fully characterize the optimal long-term financial contract, of the state-contingent claims issued by the firm. and to derive the analytical result between average q, is we are able total value This gives a measure of Tobin's q and allows us to study the joint equilibrium dynamics of investment, Our main the firm's 1 caused by limited enforcement of financial contracts. "insider," all q reflect profitable opportunities in physical investment but, depending on circumstances, q capitalizes the impact of constraints as well." a forward- q, and cash flows. that the financial constraint introduces a positive wedge which corresponds to Tobin's q in our model, and marginal q, which determines investment decisions. This wedge reflects the tension between the future profitability of investment and the availability of internal funds in the short run. quantitative side, we use a calibrated version of the model to show that this On wedge the varies over time, breaking the one-to-one correspondence between investment and q which holds in the frictionless we can obtain model. When we realistic coefficients run standard investment regressions on simulated data on q and cash flow. Therefore, financial frictions to reconcile models of firms' investment with the data. 'Chirinko (1993) p. 1903. do help Aside from the enforcement Hayashi (1982) model. friction, In particular, it our model on the equilibrium behavior of investment and costs, the coefficient of q in The main q. way the In the difference Ejarque (2003) benchmark model with quadratic The presence by a factor of 6 and gives a large positive between our approach and that is identical to the inverse of of the financial friction reduces coefficient in Gomes the modeling of the financial constraint. is and constant effect of the financial friction investment regressions the constant in front of the quadratic term. this coefficient virtually identical to the classic features convex adjustment costs returns to scale. This allows us to identify in a clean adjustment is on cash flow. (2001) and Cooper and They introduce a constraint on the flow of outside finance that can be issued each period. Here instead, we explicitly model a contractual imperfection and solve for the optimal long-term contract. This adds a state variable to the problem, namely the stock of existing liabilities of the firm, thus generating slow-moving dynamics in the gap between internal funds and the desired level of investment. As we investment and Our paper shall see, these (2004)). 2 for the empirical disconnect between q. macroeconomic implica- related to the large theoretical literature on the is tions of financial frictions (e.g., Holmstrom and dynamics account Bernanke and Gertler (1989), Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997), Tirole (1997), Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), Cooley, Marimon and Quadrini In particular, our model provides a tractable framework that introduces long- term, state-contingent financial contracts, into a standard general equilibrium model with adjustment costs. The form of limited enforcement we adopt, and the recursive characteri- zation of the optimal contract, are related to the approach in Albuquerque and (2004). By exploiting constant returns to scale, we Hopenhayn are able to simplify the analysis of the optimal contract, which takes a linear form, making aggregation straightforward. In this sense, the rich model retains the simplicity dynamics of net worth, profits of a representative agent model, while allowing for and investment. Following Fazzari, Hubbard and Petersen (1988) there has been a large empirical lit- erature exploring the relation between investment and asset prices using firm level data. The great majority of these papers have found small coefficients on Tobin's q and positive and significant coefficients condition of a firm. on cash flow, or other variables describing the current financial This result has been ascribed to measurement error in caused by non-fundamental stock market movements. the explanatory power of is q, 3 Measurement and cash flow would then appear as a good predictor of future 2 4 profits. Gilchrist error q, possibly would reduce significant, given that and Himmelberg (1995) show that this it is See Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (2000) for a survey. E.g. Gilchrist and Himmelberg (1995), Gilchrist and Himmelberg (1998). See Hubbard (1998) for a survey. 4 The debate is open whether non-fundamental movements Chirinko and Shaller (2001), Gilchrist, Himmelberg and in q Huberman should affect investment or not. (2005) and Panageas (2005). See insufficient to explain the failure of q theory in investment regressions. 5 They replace the value of q obtained by financial market prices with a measure of "fundamental q" (which employs current cash flow as a predictor of future flow retains its profits), and they show that current cash independent explanatory power. The evidence in this literature provides the model (Section starting motivation for our exercise. In an extension of the 4) we introduce firm-level heterogeneity and further explore the connection between our model and panel data evidence. The idea of looking at the statistical implications of a simulated model to understand the empirical correlation between investment and q goes back to Sargent (1980). Recently, Gomes (2001), Cooper and Ejarque (2001, 2003) and Abel and Eberly (2004, 2005) have followed this route, introducing both financial frictions and decreasing returns and market power to match the existing empirical evidence. This literature concludes that decreasing returns and market power help to generate realistic correlations, while financial frictions do In this paper not. we show way one models the the that the second conclusion between our approach and these papers, emphasized reflect in On financial constraint. is unwarranted, and depends on the other hand, there are some parallels in particular with the "growth options" mechanism Abel and Eberly (2005). Both approaches imply that movements in q can changes in future rents that are unrelated to current investment. In our paper these rents are not due to market power, but to the scarcity of entrepreneurial wealth, which evolves endogenously. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the model, the derivation of the optimal contract, and the equilibrium analysis. Section 3 contains the calibration and simulation results. In Section 4 we extend the model to allow for firm-level heterogeneity. Section 5 concludes. All proofs not in the text are in the appendix. The Model 2 The environment 2.1 Consider an economy populated by two groups of agents of equal mass, consumers and entrepreneurs. Consumers are infinitely lived and have a fixed they supply inelastically on the labor market at the wage and have a discount of death 7. factor Each period, a j3 c Entrepreneurs have . Ie m the 'first period of also risk neutral, life, j3 - is of labor Iq, Consumers are which risk neutral with a constant probability replaced by an equal mass of newly with no capital and have a labor endowment life which gives them an with a discount factor t finite lives, fraction 7 of entrepreneurs born entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurs begin w endowment E < j3 initial c The . wealth wtlE- last Entrepreneurs are assumption, together with the See Erickson and Whited (2000) and Bond and Cummins (2001) for a contrarian view. See evidence in favor of the financial frictions interpretation. Rauh (2006) for recent See Schiantarelli and Georgoutsos (1990) for an early study of q theory market power. in a model where firms have assumption of finitely lived entrepreneurs, is We state with a binding financial constraint. + lh = lc to-scale technology is is, 1- Starting in their second period of lt needed to ensure the existence of a steady normalize total labor supply to one, that A F (kt, h), where t entrepreneurs have access to the constant-returns- life, the stock of capital installed in period kt is The productivity labor hired on the labor market. p.d.f. n We (et). Investment in new capital dG (kt+i, k°) /dkt+i = 1 G G (fci+i, k°) is and equal across entrepreneurs and where an et is mean normalize the unconditional units of capital ready for production in period adjustment cost function is — 1, of i.i.d. A t to shock drawn 1. subject to convex adjustment costs. In order to have k t +\ is used capital needs to employ t — T (At-i,et), follows the stationary stochastic process At from the discrete A t = if fct+i where entrepreneurs can buy and k°. sell + an entrepreneur with k° units of 1, units of the consumption convex in 7 t fct+i, There homogeneous is good at date of degree one, and t. The satisfies a competitive market for used capital, capital at the price q°, after production has taken place. This allows individual entrepreneurs to choose k° ^ However, market clearing kt- in the used capital market requires that the aggregate value of k° across entrepreneurs equals the aggregate value of An kt, denoted by entrepreneur born at date to K t 8 . finances his current and future investment by issuing a long-term financial contract, specifying a sequence of state-contingent transfers (which can be positive or negative) from the entrepreneur to the outside investors, {dt}^Z tQ t = to, his budget constraint form it + G (k t+l ,k°) + into capital ready for use in to + 1- + G (fct+x, k°t + ) < wt l E - dt . to acquire used capital and trans- Furthermore, he can increase his consumption and investment by borrowing from consumers, remaining periods, the budget constraint q°k° consume and uses his initial wealth to cf In period is cf The entrepreneur . i.e., choosing a negative value for dt . In the is q° (k° t - kt ) < A F t (k u k) -w t lt - dt . uses current revenues, net of labor costs and financial payments, to finance consumption He and investment. At the beginning of each period t, the entrepreneur learns whether that his last period of activity. Therefore, in the last period, consumes the all the capital k t and receipts, setting = A F (kt cf 7 he liquidates is t To keep notation compact G(k +i,kf) t , h) -w t lt + q°h - df includes both the direct cost of investment and the adjustment See (14) below, for the explicit functional form used in the quantitative part. 8 To simplify notation we do not introduce indexes for individual entrepreneurs, although the value of will be different across entrepreneurs born at different dates r <t. costs. kt From then on, the payments are set to zero. dt The entrepreneur Financial contracts are subject to limited enforcement. and can, firm's assets k t he does so, run away, diverting a fraction in each period, he re-enters the financial market as if for a defaulting entrepreneur is — 9) of them. he was a young entrepreneur, with wealth given by the value of the diverted assets, and zero punishment {1 controls the liabilities. That is, If initial the only the loss of a fraction 9 of the firm's assets. 9 Aside from limited enforcement no other imperfections are present, in particular, financial contracts are allowed to be fully state-contingent. Recursive competitive equilibrium 2.2 We our attention on recursive equilibria where the economy's dynamics are fully will focus characterized by the vector of aggregate state variables X = the aggregate capital stock and Bt denotes the aggregate to be defined in a moment. t (At,Kt,B liabilities of t ), where K is t the entrepreneurs, In the equilibria considered, consumers always have positive consumption. Therefore, the market discount factor and the net present value of the liabilities of is equal to their discount factor, (3 C , an individual entrepreneur can be written as IE* s=0 The variable A B t equal to the economy-wide aggregate of these is recursive competitive equilibrium is liabilities. defined by law of motions for the endogenous state variables: and by two maps, w (Xt) of the entrepreneurs. K = K(Xt-i)\ B t = B (*,_!, et), q° {Xt), which give the market prices as a function of the (ii) The quadruple K.,B,w(.) and q° () forms a recursive competitive the entrepreneurs' optimal behavior is consistent with the law of motions the labor and used capital market clear. In the next two subsections, we characterize entrepreneurs' decisions, and then aggregate and check market clearing. first We (i) if: and B, and t Given these four objects, we can derive the optimal individual behavior current state. equilibrium and K use Xt to denote in a r,/C, compact way the law = of H (Xt-i,e motion t) for , Xt derived from the laws of motion and B. Here, we just take this as an institutional assumption. For a microfoundation, we could assume that defaulting entrepreneurs are indistinguishable from young entrepreneurs. dressing a number of informational issues, which However, this would require adwould considerably complicate the analysis. Optima] financial contracts 2.3 Let us consider the optimization problem of the individual entrepreneur. first Exploiting the assumption of constant returns to scale, we will show that the individual problem This property linear. We will greatly simplify aggregation. describe the problem in recursive form, dropping time subscripts. Consider a contin- uing entrepreneur, in state Let V (k, b, X) denote X, who controls a firm with capital k expected his end-of-period utility, and outstanding computed after liabilities b. production takes place and assuming that the entrepreneur chooses not to default in the current period. entrepreneur takes as given the law of motion for the aggregate state functions w c Lemma 1 E+ G (k\ k°) + q° (X) k° < AF allows us to rewrite it where q m (X) is unit of capital, q m (X)k' new the shadow price of the on the - w (X) + q°{X)k- I) l w (X) <R(X)k-d, capital and q° (X), any that satisfy the following conditions for k', (1) R (X) and lemma m (X)k' = k' and mm{G(k',k )+q°(X)k be discussed A or q° (X). The variable q m (X) is m R{X) show that q m (X) and R (X) k, }, exploits the assumption of constant returns to and the (gross) return per (X) and q°{X)k. are independent of the current and future capital stocks, k and k' w (X) is there are two functions q R{X)k = max {AF{k, I) -w{X)l} + This d. installed capital k. Given the prices q (jfe, as E 1 The and the pricing constraint takes the form c Lemma X (X) and q° (X). The budget prices is and only depend on the , equal to marginal q in our model, and will in detail below. continuing entrepreneur can satisfy his existing by promising future repayments. Let the realization of the aggregate shock b' (e') e', if liabilities b either denote next-period tomorrow is by repaying now liabilities, contingent on not a terminal date, and let b' L (e') denote the same in the event of termination. Then, the entrepreneur faces the constraint b where the expectation is The entrepreneur has that, if = d + Pc ((1 -7 ) E[6' (e')] taken with respect to + iWl ( > 2) e'. to ensure that his future promised the entrepreneur defaults, his (01) liabilities repayments are are set to zero credible. Recall and he has access to a fraction {1 — repayments 9) of b' (e') the capital. Therefore, if tomorrow is a continuation date, his promised have to satisfy the no-default condition , V(k\b'{e'),X')>V((l-9)k ,0,X') for all e' Throughout . X' stands this section, H (X, for R (X the entrepreneur can either liquidate his firm, getting or default and get — (1 6) R (X 1 ) tomorrow If e'). (3) 1 is the final period, k\ and repay his ) liabilities, Therefore, the no-default condition in the final period k'. takes the form R (X') k' for all e'. which again needs to hold We are now ready to write the V{k,b,.X) = - b'L (e') > (1 - 9) Bellman equation max c E R (X') k', (4) for the entrepreneur: + /3 E (1 - 7 )E \V (k',b' U') +P El E[R(X')k -b L (1), Notice that, except for constraint k and 6, and in the choice variables c the value function is (3), all , (3) (2), and + , l s.t. ,X')1 (P) (e')} (4). constraints are linear in the individual states k', b' (.) and b' L Let us (.). make the conjecture that and takes the form linear V{k,b,X) =<j>{X){R{X)k-b), for some comes positive, state-contingent function (f)(X). linear as well, and can be rewritten This is Then, the no-default condition (3) be- as < 9R b' (e') (5) (A") (3') k'. a form of "collateral constraint," which implies that an entrepreneur can only pledge R(X')k. 10 a fraction 9 of the future gross returns constraints in the literature (e.g., in The crucial difference with similar Kiyotaki and Moore (1997)), is the fact that we allow for fully state-contingent securities. Before stating Proposition and q° {.) problem (3') is is and on the law well defined always binding. and of 3, we impose some restrictions on the equilibrium prices w (.) motion H. These conditions ensure that the entrepreneur's deliver a simple optimal contract In subsection 2.4 we where the collateral constraint will verify that these conditions are met in equilibrium. Suppose the law of motion H admits an ergodic distribution 'Constraint (4) immediately gives an analogous inequality for b'L . for the aggregate state X, Assume that equilibrium with support X. hold for each prices are such that the following inequalities X eX: /3 6f3 E E[R{X')] c E[R(X')] > q m (X), (a) < m g (X), (b) (1- 1 )(1-6)E[R(X')} [C) q™(X)-9(3 c E[R(X')} ^ Condition (a) implies that the expected rate of return on capital E [R (X')] /q m (X) greater is than the entrepreneur's discount factor, so a continuing entrepreneur prefers investment to consumption. Condition (b) implies that "pledgeable" returns are insufficient to finance the purchase of one unit of capital, investment cannot be i.e., funds. This condition ensures that investment the entrepreneur's utility is is finite. fully financed with outside Finally, condition (c) ensures that bounded. Before introducing one last condition, we need to define a function (j>, which summarizes information about current and future prices. Lemma 2 When conditions (a)-(c) hold, there exists a unique function <j> : X— > [l,oo) that satisfies the following recursive definition 9{ ' This function satisfies A <p p E (l-e)E[( 1 + (l- 1 )<l>(X'))R(X')] m {X)-e/3 E[R{X')} q c (X) > 1 for all [> ' IeX, further condition on equilibrium prices is then: cj>(X)>^(X') (d) Pc for all IgX and all investment. Namely, X' it — H (X,e'). Condition (d) ensures that implies that they always prefer to invest in physical capital today rather than buying a state-contingent security that pays in The function </> entrepreneurs never delay defined in Lemma The next proposition shows that some future state. 2 will play a central role in the rest of the analysis. substituting <f>{X) on the right-hand side of (5), gives us the value function for the entrepreneur (justifying our slight abuse of notation). Define the net worth of the entrepreneur n(k,b,X) = R(X)k-b, which represents the difference between the liquidation value of the firm and the value of its liabilities. Equation (5) implies that expected utility 8 is a linear function of net worth and its <f> (X) represents the marginal value of entrepreneurial net worth. will go back to interpretation in subsection 2.5. Proposition 3 Suppose q° We (.) the aggregate law of are such that (a)-(d) hold, where V (k, b,X) takes the form and (5) c E <f> H motion and defined as in is the equilibrium prices Lemma 2. and Then, the value function the entrepreneur's optimal policy = w (.) is 0, R(X)k-b [ q^(X)-ep c E[R(X')Y = b'(e') The L (e')=6R(X')k'. b' (8) entrepreneur's problem can be analyzed under weaker versions of conditions. (a)-(d). However, as we shall see in a moment, these conditions are appropriate for studying small stochastic fluctuations around a steady state where the financial constraint 2.4 ' is binding. Aggregation Having characterized optimal individual behavior, we now aggregate and impose market and on the used clearing on the labor market To help the reading capital market. of the dynamics, we now revert to using time subscripts. Each period, a fraction WtlE- Their net worth is 7 of entrepreneurs begins life with zero capital and labor income simply equal to their labor income. Moreover, a fraction — Rth — bt- The of continuing entrepreneurs has net worth equal to n% (1 — 7) aggregate net worth of the entrepreneurial sector, excluding entrepreneurs in the last period of activity, is then given by N t = (l- Using the optimal individual rules gregate states Kt and B 7) (7) (R and t K - Bt ) + jw t E l t (8), we . get the following dynamics for the ag- t Kt+1 ~ Bt+ i {1 - {R 7) t K -B t q?-ep c E = p c 6Rt+ iKt+1 and qt = ~ l t m l l9j } (10) dF{K — dl u A + 7w E . in the used capital Wt ) ' t Finally, the following conditions ensure that the prices clearing in the labor market t [Rt+1 u>t and q° are consistent with market market l) ' ^ dG(Kt+1 ,Kt) dK ^ > ' {U > t To clarify the role of condition (12), notice that all continuing entrepreneurs . choose the same ratio k°/kt+i, and this ratio must q°+dG (kt+i, k°) /dk° = satisfy the first-order condition 0. Market clearing on the used capital market requires that continuing entrepreneurs acquire all K /Kt+ the existing capital stock, so Summing up, t we have found a equal to k°/kt+\. This gives us condition (12). recursive equilibrium the pricing rules for wt and q° satisfy are satisfied. is i and (9) to (12), The next proposition shows if the laws of motion if and K, B and they are such that conditions (a)-(d) that an equilibrium with these properties exists under some parametric assumptions. Let the production function and the adjustment cost function be: A F{ku t = A lt ) G(kt+l ,k = t) t k?l\- kt+1 a (13) , -(l-6)kt + ^ kt+1 ~ kt) (14) . To construct a recursive equilibrium, we consider a deterministic version omy (i.e., an economy where A t is constant and equal to state as a reference point. Let [A, A\ be the support of 1), A t of the same econ- and use the deterministic steady in the stochastic economy. Proposition 4 Consider an economy with Cobb-Douglas technology and quadratic ment costs. pendix). Suppose the economy's parameters satisfy conditions (A) and (B) Then there is a scalar A > such -0 that, if A—A < A adjust- (in the ap- there exists a recursive competitive equilibrium with aggregate dynamics described by (9)-(10). The conditions (A) and (B) presented in the Appendix ensure that the cally stable deterministic steady state economy has a lo- with binding financial constraints. These parametric restrictions are satisfied in all the calibrations considered below. Finally, as a useful which arises when 9 — benchmark, 1. let us briefly characterize the frictionless equilibrium In the frictionless benchmark, equilibrium dynamics are fully characterized by the condition <?r The definitions of q™ and Rt are the and so are the equilibrium conditions entrepreneurs consume their wealth in all future periods. Investment is = p c ®t same (11) w^e m (is) [Rt+i] as those given in the constrained economy, and (12) for wt the Average q and marginal life /?£ < 0q and consume zero by consumers, which explains why the consumers' discount factor appears in the equilibrium condition 2.5 Given that q°. period of their first entirely financed and (15). q Having characterized equilibrium dynamics, we can now derive the appropriate expressions for Tobin's q and for marginal q. Marginal q problem as the shadow value of new is immediately derived from the entrepreneur's capital, q^ 10 1 . The definition of q™ in Lemma 1 and the equilibrium condition (12) can be used to obtain q? This is t between the investment rate and the shadow price of new To derive Tobin's is, t dK,t+i the standard result in economies with convex adjustment costs: there relation that dG{K +i/K ,l) = the sum we g, is a one-to-one capital. need to obtain the financial value of a representative firm, first of the value of the claims on the firm's future revenue, held by insiders all (entrepreneurs) and outsiders (consumers). For firms in the last period of activity this value is zero. For continuing firms, this gives us the expression = V(k Pt We t subtract the current payments to outsiders, firm. + bt-d ,bt,Xt) t (16) . to obtain the end-of-period value of the dt, Recall that continuing entrepreneurs receive zero payments in the optimal contract (except in the final date), so there is no need to subtract current payments to insiders. Dividing the financial value of the firm by the total capital invested we obtain our definition of average q _ Pt Qt In the recursive equilibrium described above, liquidating firms both pt and kt+i are The next proposition shows marginal q and average q, qt is zero, so qt is the same for all continuing firms. For not defined for those firms. that the financial constraint introduces a wedge between and that the wedge is determined by </> , t the marginal value of entrepreneurial wealth. Proposition 5 In same for all the recursive equilibrium described in Proposition 4, continuing firms and equal, the ratio qt/q™ is is increasing in greater than marginal (f> t q, qt > q"'• average q is the Everything else . Proof. Substituting the value function in the value of the firm (16), and rearranging gives Pt = (<p t - 1) (Rth - bt) + Rth - a\. (17) Using the entrepreneur's budget constraint, constant returns to scale librium properties of q° and g[™, gives Rth-dt = G(k t+l ,k°) + dG{k dG\ t+u dk t+l — for It fc k° t ) q° k°-t k+1 + t+l 11 dG(h + uk?) dkt+1 K + qt kt G, and the equi- Substituting in (17) and rearranging gives It = — Notice that (7) implies that (Rtkt > 4> t 1 and bt < < Rth 9 Rtkt / , (d>t - — Rt kt s .. 1) b* + k bt)/kt+\ €m equal across continuing firms. Given that is the stated results follow from this expression. Notice that in the frictionless benchmark investment - we have to the bt — Rth, . (18) which immediately implies Hayashi (1982) model: average q is = qt is fully financed by consumers and down q™. In this case, the model boils identical to marginal q and a sufficient statistic is for investment. It is useful to in provide some explanation for the wedge between average q and marginal q the constrained economy. First, notice that this wedge the discount factors of entrepreneurs and consumers. In fact, present value of the entrepreneur's payoffs {cf+ A not due to the difference in is if we evaluated the expected using the discount factor /3 C instead of P E we would get a quantity greater than V (kt,bt,Xt) and the measured wedge would be 11 larger. The fundamental reason why the wedge is positive is that t > 1, the marginal , <f> value of entrepreneurial wealth on the right-hand side of To clarify the of wealth. (18) Suppose he uses consumes Rt+i/q™. is than one. If 4> t was equal to 1, mechanism, consider an entrepreneur who begins and consumes the receipts is larger The then the first term would be zero and the wedge would disappear. life this wealth to start a firm financed only at date so the entrepreneur can install which is t + 1. The (shadow) 1/q™ units of capital. (a). with inside funds price of a unit of capital In period value of the firm for the entrepreneur greater than one, by condition with one dollar + t is 1 is q™, he receives and then fi^Et [Rt+i] llT In short, the value of a unit of installed capital and larger inside the firm than outside the firm, this explains why q theory does not hold. This discrepancy does not open an arbitrage opportunity, because the agents that can take advantage of this opportunity (the entrepreneurs) are against a financial constraint. This thought experiment captures the basic intuition behind Proposition To go one 5. step further, notice that the entrepreneur can do better than following the strategy described above. In particular, he can use borrowed funds on top of his funds, and he can re-invest the revenues made at £ + 1, rather than consume. The borrowing allows the entrepreneur to earn an expected leveraged return, between 11 For the quantitative results presented in Section 3, of q (discounting the entrepreneur's claims at the rate j3 12 we c also t own ability of and t+1, experimented with this alternative definition E ), with minimal effects on the results. instead of . equal to 12 (1 - 6) E [Rt+1 J (q? t ] - ep c Bt Iterating expression (6) forward shows that returns discounted at the rate fi (p t [Rt+i]) > Et [Rt+ i] lq?- a geometric cumulate of future leveraged is into account the fact that, as long as the en- E taking , trepreneur remains active, he can reinvest the returns made in his firm. Therefore, when borrowing and reinvestment are taken into account, one dollar of wealth allows the entrepreneur to obtain a value of receiving q™kt+i is — 1 <j> > t /3 EE [Rt+i] Jq™ t from outside investors > At the same time, the entrepreneur 1. (recall that he only has funds). Therefore, the value of the claims issued to outsiders which must equal q™kt+i — an entrepreneur with one dollar to invest can start a firm valued clusion, is m larger than the value of invested capital, g t fc( 1 dollar of + i, given that <f> t at > (f> t 1. internal In con- + q™kt+\ — 1, 1. Quantitative Implications 3 we examine the quantitative implications In this section, behavior of investment, Tobin's q, and cash flow of the model looking a simulated economy. in at the joint First, we give a basic quantitative characterization of the economy's response to a productivity shock. Second, we ask whether the wedge between marginal q and average q in our model helps to explain the empirical failure of q theory in investment regressions. Baseline calibration 3.1 The production in (13) and function (14). is Cobb-Douglas and adjustment costs are quadratic, The productivity process is given by A — t e at , as specified where a t follows the autoregressive process at with tt a Gaussian, "Notice that, from i.i.d. (7), — 9) Rt+ikt+i- m - 1 To prove the In t + 1 j3 c > (E t [Rt+i]) f} E it 2 is et , and simplify to obtain > 6q?E t [Rt +1 ] . theoretical analysis can be extended to the case where bounded, we set A t = A whenever e at < A and bounds A and A are immaterial for the results. At + the capital stock kt+i which can be invested by an the entrepreneur has to repay 8R t+ ik t+ i and can keep inequality, rearrange inequality follows from (a) and The t 8j3 c ^i t \Rt+{\) is l//(<ji 6/3 c The pa -i shock. 13 entrepreneur with one dollar of wealth. (1 = A =A 13 t tt is a continuous variable. whenever e°' > A. As long To ensure that as a\ is small the Pc 0.97 He 0.96 a 0.33 5 0.05 t 8.5 P 0.75 9 0.3 7 0.06 Ie 0.2 Table The year, so Baseline calibration. 1. baseline parameters for our calibration are reported in Table we set /3 C The close to that of the consumers. match basic values of £ and p are chosen to The the Compustat dataset. (CFK) 0.51 rate, r(.) a values for a and <5 are statistics, obtained from 14 r CFK is features of firm-level data on cash flow and investment. In particular, we consider the following where The time period to give an interest rate of 3%. For the discount factor of the entrepreneurs, we choose a value smaller but standard. 1. [CFK) a (IK) a 0.061 0.128 denotes cash flow per unit of capital invested, IK denotes the (yearly) coefficient of serial correlation, and denotes the investment <r(.) the standard devia- We calibrate p so that our simulated series replicate the autocorrelation of cash flow r(CFK) = 0.51. In our baseline calibration this gives us p — 0.75. We set £ to match the ratio between cash flow volatility and investment volatility, a {IK) /a (CFK) = 0.48. Given all the other parameters, this gives us £ — 8.5. tion. Finally, the parameters (1988) report that we choose 9 = 0.3. 30% and Ie are chosen as follows. Fazzari, of manufacturing investment The parameters 7 and 2%, as of 7 and Ie and found Hubbard and Petersen financed externally. Based on this, is Ie are chosen to obtain an outside finance Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (2000). of in 9, 7, that, as long as the finance We premium experimented with different values premium remains at 2%, the specific choice of these two parameters has minimal effects on our results. Impulse responses 3.2 In the model, the net investment rate of the representative firm IK = h+i (1 - S)k is t t H 14 We use the same data from Compustat as Gilchrist U.S. stock market listed firms from 1978 to 1989. We each variable. The moments reported in a (IK) /a (CFK)) is a ratio of such means. statistics separately for Any ratio used (e.g. and Himmclberg (1995). The sample consists of 428 use the code of Joao Ejarque to calculate firm-specific 14 this paper are the means across all firms. . 0.05 IK 0.5 \ - \^\^ ^^^^__ " - marginal q — - 1 1 1 10 20 15 CFK Figure and the ratio 1: Responses of investment, 1 and cash flow to a technology shock. of cash flow to the firm's capital stock CFK Figure q, plots the responses of IKt, t = qt, A F(k t t ,l t -w h t and CFKt, following a positive technology shock. All variables are expressed in terms of deviations All three variables in Figure 1 increase financial frictions. ) is from on impact, their steady-state values. as in the standard However, the dynamics of average q are now jointly determined by marginal q and by the wedge qt/q™. Marginal q moves one q initially rises with investment, but at its model without some point (3 for one with investment. Average periods after the shock) it falls below steady-state value, while investment continues to be above the steady state for several more periods (up to period 6 periods after the shock). As marginal q is reverting towards steady state the wedge remains large, thus pushing average q below the steady state. slow- moving dynamics of the wedge are responsible average q and investment. 15 for its The breaking the synchronicity between 4> E[R]/q -0.05 Figure 2: In Proposition to cj) t , 5, Responses of <j> and expected returns we argued that the cf> t to the is its dynamics of of <j) t , <j> t steady-state value. closely related to the slow adjustment of To understand the response is The top panel same technology shock, showing that the shock, and then slowly reverts to wedge ratio of average q to marginal q the marginal value of entrepreneurial net worth. response of to a technology shock. recall (f> t positively related of Figure 2 plots the decreases on impact following The slow adjustment in the . from the discussion in subsection 2.5 that the are closely related to those of the rate of return <p t is E t [Rt+i] /q™, since (f> t a forward-looking measure which cumulates the discounted returns on entrepreneurial investment in all The dynamics future periods. of </> t reflect the fact that the rate of return on entrepreneurial investment drops following a positive technology shock, as shown the bottom panel of Figure 2. 15 Two opposite forces are at work here. persistent nature of the shock, future productivity increases and this raises First, in due to the expected returns per unit of capital, Rt+i- This tends to increase the marginal value of entrepreneurial wealth. At the same time, entrepreneurs' net worth increases because flow. of the current increase in cash This leads to an increase in Kt+i, which reduces Rt+i, due to decreasing returns to capital, and increases g m due to adjustment ( , costs. These effects tend to reduce the marginal value of entrepreneurial wealth. In the case considered, the second channel dominates and the net effect 15 is a reduction in Since the market rate of return premium" E t [/?t+i] /q™ — E is t [i?t+i] /q™ and in <p t . As we will see in subsection 3.5, this constant and equal to 1//3 C this also implies that the "outside finance , l//3c decreases following a positive shock. 16 depends of the type of shock considered, and can be reversed result with greater persistence. For now, what matters the one-to-one correspondence between IK and t if we consider shocks that the dynamic response of is <fi t breaks qt- Investment regressions 3.3 We now turn to investment regressions, and ask whether our model can replicate the on cients q and cash flow observed To do in the data. so, we generate simulated time coeffi- series from our calibrated model and run the standard investment regression IKt The 2. ao +a 1 frictions (9 = points, we model are presented coefficients coefficient frictions, in the first row of Table obtained by Gilchrist and Himmelberg (1995). latter are representative of the orders of Absent financial (19) t.. report the coefficients that arise in the model without financial and the empirical 1) + a2 CFKt + e qt regression coefficients for the simulated As reference The = q is magnitude obtained in empirical studies. a sufficient statistic for investment, so the model gives a on cash flow equal to In this case, the coefficient on q zero. which, given the calibration above is is equal to l/£, equal to 0.118, a value substantially higher than those obtained in empirical regressions. Adding financial frictions helps both to obtain a positive coefficient on cash flow and a smaller coefficient on reported in Figure between it and qt, 1 help us to understand why. q. The impulse response functions Financial frictions weaken the relation while investment and cash flow remain closely related, due to the effect of cash flow on entrepreneurial net worth. Model with a\ ai financial friction 0.018 0.444 model 0.118 0.000 0.033 (0.016) 0.242 (0.038) Frictionless Gilchrist Table Third 2. and Himmelberg (1995) Investment regressions. line: Standard errors Notice that under the simple relation between q AR1 and investment in parenthesis. structure for productivity used here, a sizeable corpresent. is still Running a simple univariate regression of investment on q gives a coefficient of 0.13, not too far and an R of 0.5. once cash flow matically. the R 2 To is This is frictionless coefficient, not surprising, given that only one shock added to the independent see this, notice that the R 2 is less than 1 is present. variables, the explanatory power of q of the bivariate regression is of a univariate regression of investment explanatory power of q from the on cash flow alone is virtually falls 1, dra- while 0.995. So the additional percent of investment volatility. 17 However, The values of R just reported are clearly unrealistic and are a product of the simple one-shock structure used. Furthermore, idiosyncratic uncertainty and measurement error we do not attempt are absent from the exercise. For these reasons, 16 empirical coefficients for q and cash flow. model can help generate calibration of the to exactly replicate the Instead, our point here 3.4 To for idiosyncratic uncertainty is that a reasonable both q and cash realistic coefficients for introducing a time-varying wedge between marginal q and average model that allows is q. An flow, by extension of the discussed below. Sensitivity we experiment with verify the robustness of our result, tions, in a different parameter configura- neighborhood of the parameters introduced above. Table 3 shows the of the investment regression for a sample of these alternative specifications. basic result holds under a large set of possible parametrizations. coefficients Note that our Moreover, a number of interesting comparative statics patterns emerge. Baseline a\ 0-2 0.018 0.44 9 = 0.2 0.012 0.50 61 = 0.4 0.025 0.39 a= 0.2 0.022 0.45 a= 0.4 0.017 0.44 4 0.022 0.67 0.015 0.35 0.017 0.44 0.019 0.45 0.023 0.36 0.011 0.57 £ = £ = 12 E = 0.1 l l = 0.3 = 0.6 = 0.9 E ,0 p Table 3. First, notice that increasing 9 brings the Sensitivity analysis. economy reduces the wedge between marginal q and average coefficient closer to the frictionless (which determines the coefficient 16 coefficient on cash flow By changing initial A This accounts for the increase in the on cash flow when we increase all 9. How- parameter changes that bring the wealth of the entrepreneurs) both the coefficient on q and the increase. 17 This is consistent with the general point raised by the model parameters, in particular increasing 6 and similar result benchmark and benchmark. In particular, notice that when we increase Ie and Himmelberg (1995). emerges if we decrease 7. coefficients in Gilchrist 17 q. comparative static result does not apply to ever, this economy on q and the decrease of the closer to the frictionless 18 £, it is possible to Kaplan match exactly the and Zingales (1997), who note that the not necessarily a good measure of how coefficient on cash flow in investment regressions tight the financial constraint is is. Increasing £ reduces the response of investment to the productivity shock and decreases the coefficients of both q and cash flow. technology shock, The cash flow. To further clarify compare the in the persistence of the tends to lower the coefficient on q and to increase the coefficient on effect of changing p is analyzed in detail in the following subsection. Current and future changes 3.5 to p, an increase Finally, in productivity what determines the wedge between marginal and average shocks with different persistence. effect of q, it is useful Figure 3 plots the impulse- response functions of average q and marginal q for two different values of the autocorrelation coefficient, p. They can be compared we In panel (a) of Figure 3 case, the effect of the to the middle panel in Figure 1. plot the effect of a very persistent shock (p shock on future returns dominates the effect = 0.98). In this on current cash flow. Entrepreneurial investment becomes very profitable while entrepreneurs' internal funds are The wedge only catching up gradually. the financial constraint — shock {p 0). increases in the short-run, reflecting the fact that In panel (b) initially tighter. is This shock has the opposite effect are higher, while future total factor productivity equilibrium rate of return adjustment move in costs. E f The wedge [i?t+i] falls, is we temporary plot the effect of a on the wedge on impact: internal funds unchanged. As investment increases, the IqT ^& ^ s due to decreasing returns to capital and convex and this effect is so strong that average q and marginal q opposite directions. Marginal q increases, due to the increase in investment, while average q falls reflecting The two the lowered expected profitability of entrepreneurial investment. plots in Figure 3 show that the wedge between marginal and average q captures the tension between the future profitability of investment and the current availability of funds to the entrepreneur. They also suggest that the observed volatility of q the types of shocks hitting the economy. of q to the volatility of the investment rate, comparison, the value of the ratio a (q) we report the In Table 4 a{q)/a{IK), ja {IK) for depends on ratio of the volatility For for different values of p. Compustat firms is equal to 27. 18 In the frictionless benchmark, the ratio between asset price volatility and investment volatility is equal to £, which we are keeping constant the presence of the financial friction tends to higher values of p, asset price volatility volatility of q doubles data. compared is at 8.5. For values of p lower dampen amplified. asset price volatility. For example, to frictionless case, although it is still than 0.89 However, when p — for 0.98 the smaller than in the Highly persistent shocks to productivity help to obtain more volatile asset prices, by generating variations in the long run expected return on entrepreneurial role of shocks to future productivity in emphasized in Abel and Eberly (2005), capital. The magnifying asset price volatility has recently been in the context of See footnote 14 for calculation method. 19 a model with no financial frictions, . a\erage q marginal q -0.5 20 10 40 30 60 50 70 80 100 90 (b) - 0.1 marginal q \ \ n -A_10 Figure Panel 3: (a): 20 15 Responses of q and qm to a technology shock p = 0.98. Panel (b): p = 0. for different degrees of persistence. but with decreasing returns and market power. This exercise suggests that a model with constant returns and financial frictions can lead to similar conclusions. shock considered here in future productivity. productivity, is left is The explicit treatment of pure "news shocks," only affecting future work (Walentin i a(q)./a(IK) a (IK) /a In Table 4 we {CFK) (2007)). 0.25 .50 0.75 0.98 0.967 8.5 8.5 8.5 8.5 8.5 18 1.9 2.3 3.4 5.5 16.5 27 0.19 0.24 0.33 0.48 0.73 0.48 p 4. Shock persistence and the volatility of q. also report the effects of different values of p vestment a (IK) /a (CFK). High values of p tend to increase the relative to the volatility of cash flow. a (IK) I a (CFK) — When on the volatility of in- volatility of we increase p we can investment re-calibrate £ to keep 0.48 (as in the baseline calibration above) and this leads to a further increase in the volatility of q. In particular, setting p the empirical values of both a (IK) /a ble 4). highly persistent a combination of a change in current productivity and a change to future Table The (CFK) and a — 0.967 and £ (q) ja (IK) = 18, allows us to match column of Ta- (see the last Although the model does well on these dimensions, the required adjustment costs 20 seems very high and for cash flow. A an excessive degree of this parametrization delivers relatively easy fix serial correlation would be to introduce a combination of both temporary shocks and shocks to long-run productivity. This would allow the model to deliver correlation, while at the same time having current investment. Again, this extension richer set of shocks is left movements with in q that are uncorrelated better developed in a model that allows for a is to future work. Firm-level Heterogeneity 4 So and larger less serial far, we have focused on an economy where all firms have the same productivity, and only aggregate productivity shocks are present. This, together with the assumption of constant returns to scale, implies that the investment rate, identical across firms. The advantage and cash flow (normalized by q, of this approach is that makes it assets) are easy to compare it our results to the classic Hayashi (1982) model. At the same time, this approach has on the relation between q and investment limitations, given that the evidence based on panel data. Therefore, it is useful to consider variations of the is its largely model that allow for cross-sectional heterogeneity. An immediate extension is to allow for multiple sectors. capital are immobile across sectors, which w run, then and to the aggregate may be q° are sector-specific prices dynamics studied above. If we assume that labor and a reasonable approximation in the short and each dynamics are analogous sector's Therefore, under this interpretation, all the In this section, we pursue an results presented so far apply to the multiple sector case. alternative extension, by introducing productivity differences across firms. Let Ajj denote the productivity of firm j. from a given distribution process Aj it simple, we =T (Ajj-i,€j The t t) From then with e^t receive an is drawn from the is discrete p.d.f. 1 it (e^j). To keep matters always identical to the ex-ante distribution for each individual details of this extension are presented in the wage and equal to than random draw Ajj on, individual productivity follows the stationary Appendix B. Given the absence of aggregate uncertainty, aggregate capital and so initial abstract from aggregate uncertainty and assume that the realized cross-sectional distribution of the shocks firm. <J>. Newborn entrepreneurs and is 1. w and the price of used capital q°. to simplify the problem, as it The assumption constant in this economy This also implies that q m However, as long as the financial constraint different across firms. is is of constant returns to scale implies that the investment rate, Tobin's flow-to-assets ratio are independent of the individual firm's assets kj )t variables are now functions of the firm's productivity Aj t t _ [l-9)Rht -\ l-0/3 c E[J?jit+1 |A,-, 21 t] - q, constant is greater still helps and the cash- However, these three and are given by the following three equations, ht is binding, average q ' qht = pE {i-e)m [( 7 + - (1 7) </> jlt+ i) CFK = R J)t where the return per unit of (j>j t , are The now Rj capital, firm-specific variables. three expressions above for t , jit - + Wc® [Rj,t+i\A jt t] , q°, and the marginal value of entrepreneurial wealth, 19 IKj t, t between current and future changes Rj*+Mj,t] Qj,t, and CFKjj, emphasize once more the tension On in productivity discussed in subsection 3.5. the one hand, current returns, captured by Rj tt affect positively both the investment rate and cash , but have no flow, effect on q, future returns, captured by effects on current cash which [.Rj^+ilA^t], affect positively IE On a purely forward-looking variable. is q, but have no flows. To study the implications of the model for investment regressions, we construct simulated model described and run the investment regression time-series from the the other hand, investment and In Table 5 (19). we report the regression coefficients obtained from the simulated series, using the parameters as in Section 3. Model with .., - Table Once more, financial friction ai <Z2 0.116 1.023 Investment regression. Firm-specific shocks. 5. financial frictions introduce a strong correlation between cash flow and and a?, are now larger than in the corresponding line of Table 2 than their empirical counterpart. This is not surprising, given that firms in- Notice that both vestment, so that cash flow has a positive coefficient in the regression. coefficients a\ same now and larger face essentially zero adjustment costs. In this model, adjustment costs are only due to aggregate changes in the capital stock, and with no aggregate uncertainty such changes are absent. 20 Another implication of the absence of adjustment costs a (IK) J a data. 21 (CFK) is that investment is too volatile. The ratio equal to 1.34 in the simulated series, more than twice as large as in the In our model firms to trade is we have homogeneous essentially capital with firm-specific shocks clearly both to reduce investment assumed "external adjustment on the used capital market. calls for fully by allowing developed model the introduction of "internal adjustment costs," volatility at the firm level cients in investment regressions. A costs," and to obtain more However, with internal adjustment costs we realistic coeffi- lose analytical tractability, as optimal investment rules are, in general, non-linear. I9 Both Rj jt and jt are functions only of A,,t, so the distributions of Rj,t+i and <t>j +i conditional on can be obtained from the law of motion A~,t+i = T (Aj t,tj,t+\)20 The parameter £ is accordingly irrelevant for this version of the model. 21 Notice also that the frictionless model is not a very useful benchmark in this case, as it gives very extreme and unrealistic results. Absent financial frictions all the capital stock in the economy would go, each period, to the single firm with the highest expected return on capital, while q would be constant and <j) :t Aj,t equal to : 1. 22 Conclusions 5 we have developed a In this paper, frictions tractable framework to study the effect of financial on the joint dynamics of investment and of the value of the The model shows firm. that, in the presence of financial frictions, q reflects future quasi-rents that will go to the This introduces a wedge between average and marginal insider. is determined by the tension between current and future q. The that the growth of is and this raises the future The paper its capital stock is A profitability. future productivity and low internal funds today will display a higher this size of this wedge firm with high The reason q. for constrained relative to expected productivity, marginal product of capital. focuses on the implications of the model between invest- for the correlation ment, q and cash flow. In particular, we show that a model with financial frictions can help between q and investment, and the fact that cash flow appears with a positive coefficient in standard investment regressions. However, the to replicate the observed low correlation model has a number of additional testable predictions on the response of investment and asset prices to different types of shocks (shocks with different persistence, shocks affecting current/future productivity), as discussed in Section market power and decreasing returns 3.5. As we noticed, recent models with at the firm level also display rich ing shocks with different temporal patterns. dynamics follow- Empirical work documenting the conditional behavior of investment and q following these shocks, would provide an important testing ground for both classes of models. Throughout the paper, we have maintained Hayashi's (1982) assumption of constant returns to scale both in the production function and in adjustment costs. advantages. First, it greatly simplifies aggregation. Second, it This has two allows us to focus on the "pure" effect of the financial friction on investment regressions. Models with decreasing returns at the firm level can produce deviations from q theory for independent reasons, so it is useful, at this stage, to separate those effects financial contracts. At the same time, from the effects this choice leaves aside a due to imperfections number of interesting issues, which seem especially relevant when one introduces firm-level heterogeneity, Section in as we did in 4. Finally, in the steady state. It is paper we have focused on the case of small stochastic deviations from the possible to extend the to potentially interesting model phenomena. In to allow for "large" shocks, opening the door particular, with large shocks a model where firms hold precautionary reserves, in order to buy i.e., it is possible to have choose to reduce investment today financial securities as insurance against future shocks. This where equilibrium behavior will be very sensitive to the time the firm. 23 is another area profile of the shocks hitting ' . Appendix A. Proofs Proof of Lemma 1 Consider the problem minG(/c',fc )+g°/c = Suppose k° any = k° k', k k (q°) we can Therefore, optimal is for a given q° and m completing the proof of the first (X) = G(n(q = r)(w,q°,A) - (u\ q°, A)) tj is equal to (G (k (q°) , 1) + q°) k' optimal is + q°(X), part of the lemma. In a similar way, consider the problem any k, I wt] (w, q°, A) + to scale imply that, given {AF (1, optimum {X)),l) max AF(k, I Constant returns to scale imply that, given 1. set q and suppose = k' a solution to problem (20) and the (q°) k' is (20) . R (X) = AF (1, V (w (X) q°k, (21) = a given triple w, q°,A and k for = -wl + I) rj{w,q°,A)k is 1. Constant returns a solution to (21) and the optimum is q°) k. Setting q° , (X) , - w (X) .4)) r, (w (X) q° (X) , , .4) + q° (X) completes the proof. Proof of Let B Lemma 2 be the space of bounded functions T ^ (x) = Pe (1 , Let us first and P E check that T<p 6 < Pc g) ] [ B if </> </> : X— [1, » oo). Define the - 6) for any (1 showing that T<p(X) S B, so the map is well defined. Notice that conditions (a)-(b) 4> B £ - > 1. (X) < M for all Next, we show that ity of T is X 1. we have Assumption (c) P E (l-9)E [R (H (X, e'))] q™ (X) - 90 C E[R(H (X,e<))} e X, then l } T0 (X) < Mj (1 - 7) for 1 1 all -7 X g X, completing the argument. T satisfies Blackwell's sufficient conditions for a contraction. easily established. ' implies that p E (l-8)E[R(H(X,e'))} g- (X) - 80 C E [R (H (X, £'))]" if cp as follows [( (H (X, e'))) R (H (X, e'))} 7) ~ ™(X)-60 c E[R(H(X,e'))] E [(7 + q so » imply that This implies that (1 : 7 + (1 - 7) <P (H (X, e'))) R (H (X, e'))} m (X)-e/3 c E[R(H(X,e'))} q E (l-8)0 E E[R(H(X,e'))} > q™(X)-ej3 c E[R(H(X,e>))} E map T B — B To check that it satisfies 24 The monotonic- the discounting property notice that if <j> — + <(> then a, - T4> (X) = T4> (X) where the inequality follows from assumption exists and a qm{x) _ g0cE[R{H{Xtel))] (22) immediately shows that <f){X) for all 1 T Since (c). > < Pb°, a contraction a unique fixed point is X. Proof of Proposition 3 Let is 4> be defined as V (k, b, X) — Lemma in 4>{X) (R{X) k We 2. — proceed by guessing and verifying that the value function no-default condition can be rewritten in the form max B + c c B ,k',b'(.),b'L (.) E -7 (1 ) c + qm E = b T n Therefore, (3'). (H (e') \4> {X, that, under (R (H (X, e')) this conjecture, the we can rewrite problem (P) - e')) k' b' (e'))l as + '—f +(3 E -f s.t. we have shown In the text, b). {X) + (3 C d J2*(z')lK(H(X,e'))k'-b'L < R (X) k-d, k' ( (1 -7 Y; n ) (e')} (A) (e') b' (e') +7 £> (e') b'L (e') (/i) , J (0 < 6R {H (X, e')) ** b' b' L (e') E > c fc' where, in parenthesis, > e', (y <eR(H(X,e'))k'foialle'\ 0, (e') tt (e')) [y L (e')Tr(e')) (r c ) 0, (r fc ) we report the Lagrange multiplier associated to each constraint. ers of the no-default constraints are normalized for this for all by the probabilities it The (e'). - A + tc = 0, EM -7 [( 7+ (1 ) 0') R'} - \q m (X) + 9E [(j/ + A (£') + A£ c (1- 7 7T (e') -P E (1 - 7) -^ S 77r (£') + \0cyn (O - u L (e') w (e') = ^ ) (£') u L )R'\ n 1 (e ) + = first-order conditions J?' and 0' are shorthand for R (H (X, e')) and <p (H (X, e')). We want E c ,k',b' and b'L in the statement of the proposition are optimal. It that they satisfy the problem's constraints. = A— 1 > 0, Tfc = 0, and v{t') ,vl (e') To show that they > for all e' . m q which, by construction, is equal to <fr {X)- tc {X) + Setting t> + (1-7)0')^] ep c E\R'} Then we have = 4> {X) 25 - 1 > o, = 0, 0, to show that the values is immediate to check are optimal condition gives us (l-fl)/? E E[( 7 r fc 0, where rc multipli- problem are 1 for The = we need to show that the second first-order which follows from Lemma v 2, (0 = which follows from condition (1 function <t){X) we obtain > 1 - P E (H 7) (P c 4> (X) <t> (X, > e'))) 0, and (d), vL which follows from - = (l-j)(P c <t>(X)-0 E )>O, (e') and (3 — b) (X) (R (X) k C > j3 E Substituting the optimal values in the objective . confirming our initial guess. Proof of Proposition 4 The proof economy, two split in is in the second, steps. we In the first step, we construct an equilibrium derive the steady state of the deterministic of the stochastic economy. Conditions (A) (B) will be introduced in the course of the argument. First, Applying the envelope theorem to problems (20) and (21) fact that, in equilibrium, the ratio k°/k' and using condition we obtain the (12), ,? - Rt = equal to 1. (see the proof of following expressions for ^M Lemma g™ and R t 1 in each period (recall We model). is 1), using the equal to l/K t , : e0{ (23) , OK-t + 1 At t 8G(Kt+1 ,K 8K ,l) —dK t t) (24) • t (Deterministic steady state) Consider a deterministic model where in the stochastic and derive a useful preliminary result. equal to Kt/Kt+i, and the ratio l/k is 0F(K Step we that 1 is will derive the unconditional t is constant and of the stochastic process for a steady state of this deterministic model and use reference point for the stochastic case. Let the superscript S = 1 state the equilibrium conditions (12) mean A and ,s (23) give q° it A t as a denotes steady-state values. In steady m S and q s = 1. The law of motion — ' for the capital stock (9) gives the steady-state condition (1 and - 90 C R S ) Ks = (1 -7 (1 ) - 6) R S K S + ~tw s l E (25) , (24) gives , Rs = Substituting (26) in (25) ^^ dF (K s , 1) + 1-5. we obtain K s =~\f a(0|gc + (l-7)(l-g)) + 7(l-tt)M l-(90 c + (l--y)(l-e))(l-6) J and substituting back (26) in (26) we get Rs = a (A' 5 )"" 1 26 +1-5. ^ (27) ] [ ' We make the following assumption on the model parameters '• The l-(flg c + (l-7)(l-fl))(l-*) + " a(6(3 c + (1 - 7) (1 - 0)) + 7 (1 - a)l B 1-5 )>1. (A) following three inequalities follow from assumption (A): s The (these correspond to assumptions (a)-(c) in Proposition 3). To diately. (0 C 6 + (1 first inequality follows imme- show that the second inequality holds notice that assumption (A) implies that - - 7) (1 0)) (1 Rearranging equation - (25), given that 5) is positive, j3 E (I - - 9) Rs > S) < Then, 1. (27) gives us K s 1 — > 0. one can then show that 1 - (3 C 6R S - (1 - 7) (1 0, which implies both the second and the third inequalities. In steady state, the recursive definition of (1-8)13^ s 1 - ep c R k3 Rearranging Step 2. this equation (X), <fi shows that > <p (7 +(1-7)/). Condition (d) holds immediately, given that 1. (Stability) Substituting (11), (24) and the lagged version of following second-order stochastic difference equation for /i (1 t+1 ~~ - 7)\n (1 - —m dG(K t o\ ( A dF(K,,l)' 0) (A t gK ; - K + 1 ,K7) - t takes the form (6), K Q' v jKt+'yAt dG(K, + i,K )\ t g^' ' . . dF(K ",l), 1 t t ' (3 C . we obtain the l — E ~j l + 1 X) 1 made > 9L dC(K- + 2 ,K a K^- 9F(K, + ,1) 00 h \( A op c K t [[At+i gKt+1 ln7\f E < t Linearizing this equation (under the functional assumptions — \nK s = second order equation for kt (10) into (9), (3 in the text) JJ we get the following , /C( + Otikt+l + = Q2^( + 2 0, where qo ai q2 = ^ + a(l-a)(-/l E -(l- 1 )(l-e)){K s = -e-l + /3ei? S -^(? + = pec a-1 ) Q'(l-Q)(A- s ) Q"1 + (R s -0(l-l)(l'e), )+(l-7)(l-^)e, Pro\aded that a\ it is possible to show that the steady state - a a2 > Ks is saddle-path stable. Then, given sufficiently small shocks we can construct a stochastic steady state where gives us an ergodic distribution (B) for the state vector 27 K t varies in a neighborhood of X, with bounded support. We Ks . This, can then establish the continuity of the function in [<p, 0]. with respect to the parameters <j> A—A hold in the stochastic steady state. Finally, 4> (X) X This guarantees that condition B. The model with Let w (d) (X) is bounded can be set so as to ensure that the bounds for C > 0e$. also satisfied. is firm-level heterogeneity and q° denote the constant values return per unit of capital is now for the wage and the price where 77 t t, The the labor to capital ratio. is = max c B ,k',b'(.),b' {.) L c B is subject to + /3 E . c = (gross) d (1 - j)E[V now (fc',6' (e') ,T{A,e'))} + (e')} <R {A) k - d, 7 )E[6'( e ')]+7E[(/L b'(e') < 9R(T(A,e'))k', (e') < 6R(T(Ae'))k'. L , „.. E +k' + /3 c ((l- b' } characterized by the Bellman equation: +P El E[R(r(A,e'))k'-b'L 6 The state variables for an individual entrepreneur are and Ajj. The entrepreneur's problem V(k,b,A) of used capital. defined as: R (Ajj) = max {Ajlt F (l,r?) - wr] + q The <fi satisfy /3 kj,t,bj and show that Since (a)-(c) hold in the deterministic steady state, a continuity argument shows that they (e')]), no-default constraints have been expressed as linear constraints, proceeding as we did in Propo- sition 3. Now the marginal value of entrepreneurial wealth, A and we j have 0[ is a function of the individual productivity , E , , (i-P|(7 + (i-7)»(r(i,f')p(r(A, f '))] l-ep c E[R(T(A, £ '))] ' The analogues <fi, to conditions (a)-(d) are now P E E[R(r(A,e'))\ > 1, ep c E[R(T(A,e'))} < 1, (i- 7 )(i-fl)E[fl(r(A, e '))] l-O0 c E{R(T(A,e'))) and <P(A)>^4>(T(A,e')). Pc Under these conditions the optimal individual policy can be derived 28 as in Proposition 3, and we obtain the following law of motion for the individual capital stock k A newborn entrepreneur has $ and the law of motion T , e'), l-ep c E[R(T(A,e'))] wealth wis- Putting together these conditions, the distribution initial (A, (i-e).R(A) = allows us to completely characterize the joint dynamics of k and A. Then, under appropriate assumptions, that the wage rate w is we obtain an ergodic = [q{A)k}dJ{A,k) where rj {A) is joint distribution J (A, k) and check consistent with the market clearing condition 1, the optimal labor to capital ratio for a firm with productivity A. Proceeding as Pj,t Substitute for dj t t, we can in subsection 2.5, = <t>j,t ( define the financial value of a continuing firm R3,tkJlt - using the budget constraint dj } t b ht) = + bjtt Rj,tkj t t - — dj, t j: . kj,t+i, and the law of motion for the capital stock kj t+1 = - ep c E [2WMW > i (Rj ' ht " ht) ' to obtain P] < - {*" + 1 - 90 c E[Ru+1 \Au}) ht] " " Kt) [ Dividing both sides by k Jtt +i and using the recursive property of for <f>^ t gives the following expression Tobin's q q ht = P E (l-9)E [( 7 + (1 - 7 ) <t>jt i+i) Rj,t+i \Ajtt ] + 9j3 c E [R ht+l \A 3 A For the investment rate notice that which gives the expression in the text. For cash flow notice that 29 Aj t F (kj it , I Jt ) — wljj = Rj,t^j,t ~ References [1] Abel, A. and Effects [2] C. Eberly, 2004, J. "Q Theory Without Adjustment Costs and Cash Flow Without Financing Constraints," mimeo, Wharton. Abel, A. and C. Eberly, 2005, "Investment, Valuation and J. Growth Options," mimeo, Wharton. [3] Albuquerque, R. and H. A. Hopenhayn, 2004, "Optimal Lending Contracts and Firm Dynamics," Review of Economic Studies, 71 [4] American Economic Review, 79 Bernanke, B., M. Gertler and titative Business [6] Bond S. and A S. Gilchrist, pp. 14-31. 2000, "The Financial Accelerator in a quan- Cummins, 2001, "Noisy Share J. Carlstrom, C. and T. tuations: (1), Cycle Framework," Handbook of Macroeconomics, North Holland. Institute for Fiscal Studies [7] pp. 285-315. Bernanke, B., M. Gertler, 1989, "Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations," [5] (2), WP S. Fuerst, Prices and the Q model of Investment," 01/22. 1997, "Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluc- Computable General Equilibrium Analysis," American Economic Review, Vol. 87, pp. 893-910. [8] Chirinko, R., 1993, "Business Fixed Investment Spending: Modeling Strategies, and Policy Implications," Journal of Economic Literature pirical Results, Em- Vol. 31, pp. 1875-1911. [9] Chirinko, R. and H. Shaller, 2001, "Business Fixed Investment and "Bubbles": The Japanese Case," American Economic Review, pp. 663-680 [10] Cooley, T., R. Marimon and V. Quadrini, 2004 , "Aggregate Consequences of Limited Contract Enforceability," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 112, pp. 817-847. [11] Cooper, R. and Ejarque, 2001, NBER imperfections," [12] J. Cooper, R. and J. Market power vs. capital market Ejarque, 2003, "Financial frictions and investment: requiem in q" Vol. 6, pp. 710-728. Erickson, T. and T. Whited, 2000, "Measurement error and the relationship between investment and [14] q: working paper 8182. Review of Economic Dynamics, [13] "Exhuming Fazzari, S., G. g," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 108, pp. 1027-1057. Hubbard and B. Petersen, 1988, "Financing constraints and corporate investment," Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 30 1, pp. 141-195. [15] and C. Himmelberg, 1995, "Evidence on the Gilchrist, S. role of cash flow for invest- ment," Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 36, pp. 541-572. [16] Gilchrist, NBER S. and C. Himmelberg, 1998, "Investment, Fundamentals and Finance," Macro Annual, B. Bernanke and J. Rotemberg eds., the MIT Press, Cambridge, pp. 223-274. [17] Gilchrist, S., C. Himmelberg and G. Huberman, 2005, "Do Stock Price Bubbles Influ- ence Corporate Investment?" Journal of Monetary Economics. [18] Gomes, J., 2001, "Financing Investment," American Economic Review, Vol. 91, pp. 1263-1285. [19] Hayashi, F., 1982, "Tobin's marginal q, and average q: a neoclassical interpretation," Econometrica, Vol. 50, pp. 215-224. [20] [21] Holmstrom, B. and Loanable Funds, and Tirole, 1997. "Financial Intermediation, The Real Sector," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, pp. 663-691. Hubbard, G., 1998, "Capital-Market Imperfections nomic [22] J. and Investment," Journal of Eco- Literature, Vol. 36, pp. 193-225. Kaplan, S. and Zingales, L. 1997, "Do Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities Provide Useful Measures of Finance Constraints?" Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, pp. 169-215. [23] Kiyotaki, N. and Moore, 1997, "Credit Cycles," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. J. 105, pp. 211-248. [24] Panageas, S. 2005, "The Neoclassical q Theory of Investment in Speculative Markets," mimeo, Wharton. [25] Rauh, J. D., 2006, "Investment and Financing Constraints: Evidence from the Funding of Corporate Pension Plans," Journal of Finance, 61 (1), pp. 33-71. [26] Sargent, T., 1980, " 'Tobin's q' and the Rate of Investment in General Equilibrium," Carnegie- Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 12, pp. 107-154. [27] Schiantarelli, F. and G. Georgoutsos, 1990, "Monopolistic Competition and the Q Theory of Investment," European Economic Review, 34:5 (July 1990), 1061-1078. [28] Walentin, K., 2007, "Expectation Driven Business Cycles with Limited Enforcement," mimeo, Sveriges Riksbank. 31 3521 55