Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/comparativeadvan00kraa2 DEWEY \4f 1 Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Massachusetts Institute of Comparative Advantage and the Cross-Section ot Business Cycles Aart Kraay, The World Bank Jaume Ventura, MIT Working Paper 98-09Revised January 2001 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf7abstract id-=1 371 75 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY OCT l 6 2001 LIBRARIES *\ Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Massachusetts Institute of Comparative Advantage and the Cross-Section of Business Cycles Aart Kraay, The World Bank Jaume Ventura, MIT Working Paper 98-09Revised January 2001 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf7abstract id-=1 371 75 Comparative Advantage and the Cross-section of Business Cycles Aart Kraay Jaume Ventura The World Bank M.I.T. December 2000 Business cycles are both less volatile and more synchronized with the world cycle in rich countries than in poor ones. develop two alternative explanations based on the idea that comparative advantage causes rich countries to Abstract : We specialize in industries that use new technologies operated by skilled workers, while industries that use traditional technologies operated by poor countries specialize in unskilled workers. Since new technologies are difficult to imitate, the industries of rich countries enjoy more market power and face more inelastic product demands than those of poor countries. Since skilled workers are less likely to exit employment as a result of changes in economic conditions, industries in rich countries face more inelastic labour supplies than those of poor countries. We show that either asymmetry in industry characteristics can generate cross-country differences in business cycles that resemble those we observe in the data. We are grateful to Daron Acemoglu and Fabrizio Perri for useful comments. are the authors' and do not necessarily reflect those of The World Bank. The views expressed here , Business cycles are not the is in the top panel of Figure income growth against the countries. We we , level of (log) downwards. A second difference bottom panel 1 refer to this relationship more synchronized 1 we , and poor countries. A is plot the is in rich countries than countries and years. Why cycle in rich more in poor ones? Part political and same in In the question, set of countries. it We refer to slopes upwards. Table of the 1 sub-samples of to the production of agricultural minerals. Table shows fraction of the variation in the of the variation in the a answer must be with the world that poor open or more and they also have a higher share economy devoted that, in more synchronized policy instability, they are less distant from the geographical center, much slopes 1 countries than 1 poor ones. that these facts apply within different are business cycles less volatile and countries exhibit in it income growth are income growth, excluding the country shows in per capita income growth rates as the comovement graph and note that self-explanatory, countries than graph and note that that fluctuations in per capita against the level of (log) per capita income for the which difference standard deviation of per capita volatility plot the correlation of with world average per capita this relationship in rich first per capita income for a large sample of as the with the world cycle of Figure in rich income growth are smaller that fluctuations in per capita poor ones, same statistical volatility of comovement of their products and the extraction of sense, these factors explain a substantial income growth, although they do not explain of income growth. More important for our purposes, the strong relationship between income and the properties of business cycles reported in Table 1 is still present after we control for these variables. In short, there must be other factors behind the strong patterns depicted differences in political instability, in remoteness and the importance Figure 1 beyond of natural resources. With the exception that the comovement graph seems to be driven by differences between rich and poor countries and not within each group. Acemoglu and Zilibotti (1997) also present the volatility graph. They provide an explanation for it based on the observation that rich countries have more diversified production structures. We are unaware of any previous reference to the comovement graph. . In this why business countries than paper, we develop two cycles are less volatile and more synchronized poor ones. Both explanations in advantage causes rich non-competing explanations alternative but countries to specialize rely with the world on the idea that in rich comparative new industries that require in for technologies operated by skilled workers, while poor countries specialize in industries that require traditional technologies operated by unskilled workers. This pattern of specialization opens up the business possibility that cross-country differences in cycles are the result of asymmetries between these types of industries. In particular, both of the explanations advanced here predict that industries that use traditional technologies operated by unskilled workers shocks. Ceteris paribus, these industries will will be more sensitive not only be more to country-specific volatile but also less synchronized with the world cycle since the relative importance of global shocks To lower. is the extent that the business cycles of countries reflect those of their industries, differences in industrial structure could potentially explain the patterns in Figure 1 One explanation of idea that firms using why industries react differently to shocks new technologies face more those using traditional technologies. for technical New inelastic product technologies are reasons and also because of them monopoly power imitate in based on the demands difficult to imitate than quickly legal patents. This difficulty confers a cost advantage on technological leaders that shelters them from gives is potential entrants and world markets. Traditional technologies are easier to because enough time has passed since their adoption and also because patents have expired or have been circumvented. This implies that incumbent firms face tough competition from potential entrants and enjoy in little or no monopoly power world markets. The price-elasticity of product demand affects how industries react to shocks. Consider, for instance, the effects of country-specific shocks that encourage production in all industries. In industries that monopoly power and face fluctuations in inelastic demands use new technologies, firms have for their products. supply lead to opposing changes industry income. In industries that use in As a result, prices that tend to stabilize traditional technologies, firms face stiff demands competition from abroad and therefore face elastic supply have result, fluctuations in is more volatile. competition be is To the little extent that this important, incomes or no effect asymmetry on in of industries that less sensitive to country-specific for their products. their prices As a and industry income the degree of product-market use new technologies are shocks than those likely to use of industries that traditional technologies. Another explanation for why industries react differently to shocks the idea that the supply of unskilled workers workers. more A first reason for attractive to unskilled ones. Changes labour in abandon the labour workers. is this A second employment The is that elastic than the supply of skilled non-market workers whose market wage demand might induce reason for the asymmetry in more some is activities are relatively lower than that of skilled unskilled workers to enter or in minimum wage. Changes and out of skilled labour supply across in labour demand unemployment, but are not of might force likely to affect in all of unskilled is elastic, workers. in on the employment how industries that asymmetry in and shocks than those that is inelastic, make the industry of industries that use To study these hypotheses we demand. Since industry likely to skilled is is in supply in income more same shocks have income the elasticity of labour supply use unskilled workers are shocks that use them, fluctuations of skilled workers. In industries that fluctuations in supply are not magnified extent that this raise the labour employment Since the supply of skilled workers effects the these shocks lead to large fluctuations In industries that are therefore magnified by increases no and therefore industries the supply of unskilled workers volatile. some workers. industries react to shocks. Consider again the effects of country-specific encourage production categories skill wage-elasticity of the labour supply also has implications for employment based on force, but are not likely to affect the participation of skilled the imposition of a unskilled workers asymmetry is is little or use them, less volatile. To the important, incomes of be more sensitive to country-specific workers construct a stylized world equilibrium model of the cross-section of business cycles. Inspired by the work of Davis (1995), we consider in section one a world which differences in Heckscher-Ohlin and industry technologies a la in both factor endowments a Ricardo combine to determine a country's comparative advantage and, therefore, the patterns of specialization trade. To generate business productivity fluctuations that In we section two, asymmetries in we economy in to the sort of Figure calibrate the 1 demand seems to respectively; Using available microeconomic estimates of the key . model and and We explore these we (ii) find that: (i) The asymmetry The model in exhibits slightly less on the slopes elasticity in the labour supply. results further in variation in monetary policy and business cycles. model Once these exhibits roughly the percent of the variation in of the volatility sections three and four. extend the model to allow for monetary shocks that have face cash-in-advance constraints. in volatility the elasticity of product effect have a quantitatively stronger comovement graphs, than the show how and/or labour supply can be used to than two-thirds and one-third of the observed cross-country variation comovement, and have been emphasized by Kydland and Prescott (1982). 2 the elasticity of product we subject this world characterize the cross-section of business cycles and explain the evidence parameters, cycles, la In and demand and section three, real effects since firms We use the model to study how cross-country financial development affect the cross-section of factors are considered, the calibrated version of the same cross-country variation comovement as the data. In in volatility section four, and about 40 we show that the two industry asymmetries emphasized here lead to quite different implications for the cyclical behavior of the terms of trade. data, the picture that appears Namely, the asymmetry important than the 2 in is clear When we confront these implications with the and confirms our earlier calibration result. the product-demand elasticity asymmetry in seems quantitatively more the labour-supply elasticity. open-economy real business cycle models that shocks are transmitted across countries. See Baxter (1995) and Backus, Kehoe and Kydland (1995) for two alternative surveys of this research. We differ from this literature in two respects. Instead of emphasizing the aspects in which business cycles are similar across countries, we focus on those aspects in which they are different. Instead of focusing primarily on the implications of international lending, risk sharing and factor movements for the transmission of business cycles, we emphasize the role of commodity trade. Our research studies how is related to the large literature on productivity The main theme of this paper is that the properties of business cycles differ across countries because they have different industrial structures. There are determinants of the industrial structure of a country. most important we five of such determinants, of business cycles. "iceberg" transport costs reductions industrial structure If and the cross-section One should different In this in in into of the business cycles that of business cycles is flat. in production. As a As transport costs result, industrial structures of Trade section, we and Business Cycles present a stylized model of the world economy. Countries skilled workers are objective is to cross-country variation cross-country variation income of a country also is, the determine to same its industrial develop a formal framework that allows us to think about in industrial in structure, and therefore income, translates the properties of the business cycle. We consider a world with a continuum good and two continuums and also tend richer, industries that use these factors intensively. That Our same countries have the all therefore expect globalization to lead to business cycles that are characteristics that determine the structure. (modeled here as parametric which a country has comparative advantage have better technologies and more specialize how section across countries. A Model that ability to trade. In transport costs are high enough, increase and so does their share diverge. globalization changes the nature decline, the prices of products . a country's We introduce trade frictions in the form of and study how transport costs) in countries experience. 1 is, perhaps the explore further the connection between international trade, industrial structure and the nature more that We focus here on many of intermediates mass of countries with indexed by ze[0,1], which one; one we final refer to as the a- and (3-industries; and two factors of production, skilled and unskilled workers. There is free trade emphasize the in role of intermediates, but commodity trade, we do we not allow trade in the final good. To rule out trade in financial instruments. To problem simplify the further, we also rule out investment. Jointly, these assumptions imply that countries do not save. Countries differ in their and unskilled workers by a country is, 5 is \i is a measure the fraction of the population that technology are stable, so that in time-invariant joint distribution. productivity index n level of skills and consumers by ie [1 ,») following expected and Ejufc(i) \i and 5 are constant. the value of non-market and assume =1-i _x F(i) that this index with X>0. , is is be Let F((i,5) their who differ in their activities. We wage. We index distributed according to this A consumer with index i maximizes the utility: WVe-.dt utility function; c(i) is an indicator function that takes value r(|i,5,7i) (H,5,7t)-country. skilled of We generate business cycles by allowing the wage as any well-behaved otherwise. Let constraint an index is '; v U(.) is l(i) is and n their personal opportunity cost of work, or reservation Pareto distribution: where defined is the technology of the populated by a continuum of consumers is think of this reservation o is skilled, each country to fluctuate randomly. Each country (1) how advanced of and of skilled We assume that workers cannot migrate and that cross-country productivity. differences endowments their level of productivity. In particular, where triplet (n,5,7t), technologies, their and w(fx,8,7t) 1 if be the wages consumption the simply p F • c(i) = w • l(i) for unskilled good consumer works and of skilled Also define p F (n,8,7t) as the price of the of the final and final unskilled workers in a good. The budget workers and p F • c(i) = r • l(i) for ones. The consumer works unskilled) if and only exceeds a reservation wage if the applicable real 1 of i" 8 . Let s(u.,5,7t) and wage (skilled or u(n,5,Tt) be the measure of skilled and Under the assumption unskilled workers that are employed. and reservation wages are independent, we have distribution of skills f - that the that \ if r < pF if r > pF vPf, (2) (1-5) u (3) = 'w^ 1-5 If if w < pF if w > pF K^J \ wage the real of any type of worker is supply of this type exhibits a wage-elasticity of dispersion of reservation wages. If the entire labour force of this type This elasticity depends only on the X. wage the real is less than one, the aggregate labour of any type of worker reaches one, employed and the aggregate labour supply this type of workers becomes real wage workers exceeds one, vertical. Throughout, —> we consider equilibria x for skilled 1 , wage while the real in for which the for unskilled Pf workers is less than one, —w < 1 . That is, all countries operate in the vertical region Pf of their supply of skilled workers and the elastic region of workers. This assumption generates an asymmetry aggregate labour supply across workers and X>0 for unskilled skill ones. in As X-^0, this This combine intermediates is the case countries, i.e. in 5«1. equilibrium if to produce the skilled (unskilled) final supply of unskilled the wage-elasticity of the categories. This elasticity is zero for skilled asymmetry disappears. Each country contains many competitive firms firms their in the final good according workers are sufficiently goods sector. These to this cost function: scarce (abundant) in all . V "1 1-e JPa(zr dz B(p a (z),p p (z)) = (4) 1-v "1 M) 1 Jp P _0 The between between any two in for the final product industries varieties within some workers Since there are always demand -e is is one, while the elasticity of an industry is 9, with 6>1 that participate in the labour force, the always strong enough Our assumptions on technology imply equilibrium. dz .0 elasticity of substitution substitution (z) to generate positive production that firms in the final good sector spend a fraction v of their revenues on a-products and a fraction 1-v on products. Moreover, the ratio of spending on any two a-products z and z' is (3- given by 1-e 1-e Pa(z) ; and the spending on any two (3-products z and ratio of Pp(z) z' is P.(z') Pp(z') where p a (z) and p (z) denote the price respectively. Define P n and P p as the of variety z of the a- and (3-products, ideal price indices for the a- and (3-industry, i.e. 1 1-e Pa = 1 Jp a (z) numeraire 1 and PR = -dz 1 Jp p (z) -e -dz ; and define the following rule: v (5) -9 = P« -Pp" v Since firms in the final goods sector are competitive, they set price equals cost. This implies that: (6) p F =1 Since of the final all good intermediates are traded and the law of one price applies, the price is the same in all countries. In this world 10 economy, purchasing power is parity applies. not traded is An implication of this that the is assumption that the industries. The sophisticated production processes that require skilled workers. a different technology that is owned by one variety of a-products, the firm that As mentioned, the owns firm only. owned by a domestic advanced the technology We can of a country technology and market structure demand for any variety of in the a-product It unit of any in is not under which the technology n as a natural indicator of how follows from our assumptions on the final is 0. variety requires n fluctuates randomly and interpret is. Each the technology requires e" units of skilled productivity index firm. a-industry uses To produce one the control of the firms. Let n be the measure of a-products is good not binding. Each country also contains two intermediate labour. final goods sector As a that the elasticity of result, all firms in the a-industry face downward-sloping demand curves and behave monopolistically. Their optimal pricing policy is a markup over unit cost. Let pjz) be the price of the variety z of the a- to set industry. Symmetry ensures all the firms located in a (|i,8,7i)-country set the same price for their varieties of a-products, p a (ja,8,7r): pa = (7) As re" 6-1 usual, the The markup depends on the (3-industry uses elasticity of traditional technologies that demand for their products. are available to countries and can be operated by both skilled and unskilled workers. unit of any variety have assumed of (3-products firms require that in equilibrium skilled the same technologies, they competitively. They all face flat all firms individual set price equal to cost. Let p 11 firms in all To produce one e " units of labour of any kind. Since wages exceed unskilled workers produce (3-products. Since all in unskilled wages, only the (3-industry have access to demand curves and behave (z) we be the price of the variety z of the (3-industry. Symmetry ensures set the same (8) p p =w-.e-" With all firms the P-industry of a (n,5,7r.)-country in varieties of (3-products, p^n,S,n): this formulation, this ; all demand. This of product As 0^co price for that we have elasticity is introduced an asymmetry in the a-industry and the price-elasticity infinity in productivity shocks. The index % component, We n-Y\. Each is of the sum of refer to changes these components 2 instantaneous variance equal to r\a and on and assume [-n,7i] characteristics. this distribution is Under the assumption components are independent across distribution of 71-n is time invariant. has been defined as an index average productivity. The instantaneous is therefore Jr) variation in whether it 5 . (1-r|)rj 4 that is an independent Brownian domestic productivity See Harrison This is and % >0, 0<r|<1 and distributed in these country-specific we have that the cross-sectional refer to this distribution regulates the n as G(7i-n). While n serves as an index of world volatility of the domestic shocks. between domestic shocks, dn, and foreign shocks, dn, The parameter comes from dn drift components be uniformly domestic productivity, of The parameter a correlation respectively, with changes countries, We n as independent of other country ti is therefore regulates the extent to which the due to global or country-specific or d(7i-n). Figure 2 under three alternative assumptions regarding 4 2 distribution of country-specific initial in a global component, n, and a country- motion reflected on the interval [-1,1] with changes that have zero a>0. Let the the (3-industry. asymmetry disappears. Business cycles arise as n fluctuates randomly. specific in components, shows possible sample paths of i.e. n t|. (1990), Chapter 5. true except when either n or n are at their respective boundaries. These are rare events since the dates at which they occur constitute a set of measure zero 12 in the time line. A competitive equilibrium of the world and quantities such prices In world the a-industry, different products demands country, for the — P.W (sum , of must equal the and is unique. command different prices. The ratio of supplies ratio of se' is . (n',d',n')- Using this se and the condition plus Equation (2) 1 va and markets a-products of a (^,5,7i)-country and a all) of prices. Pa(z') Pa optimally that a competitive equilibrium exists We prove this by constructing the set of equilibrium sequence consists of a consumers and firms behave that Our assumptions ensure clear. economy definition of Pa we find that: n-n H ^9 (9) = *¥„ IW — e-1 1 where 8 (n-n) 9 dF-dG and G(n-n) are its time-invariant, own ¥a x a constant. Since each country is many skilled with relatively high productivity (high 7i-n) producing a small produce large quantities prices. As In is a "large" depends varieties of a-products, the price of these varieties negatively on the quantity produced. Countries with |i) F(u.,8) J v. producer of Since the distribution functions of each the (5-industry varieties of (3-products all products command in Equation (4). Pp (10) 13 8) of varieties (low and as a result, disappears and p (z)—>p a face low . ra the would not be produced. But given the technology described number variety of the a-products 9^>°°, the dispersion in their prices workers (high same price. Otherwise, low-price this is not Therefore, it a possible equilibrium follows that: n Finally, we compute the ratio of world spending the relative price of both industries. in To do equate this, v the a- and (3-industries, , to the ratio of the value 1-v s-e"dFdG ffp a ^jPpue of their productions, . n Using Equations (2)-(3) and dFdG (5)-(10), we j then find that: \~ 1 v % 1-v Wn f (11) P where yp —-— 1+X.-V 1+Xv •e* = JJ(1-5)-e (1+X)(n_n) dFdG , and is constant. If X>0, high productivity is associated with high relative prices for a-products as the world supply of (3-products is high relative to that of a-products. This increase is due to increases in employment of unskilled in the relative supply of (3-products workers. As A.-^0, the relative prices of both industries are unaffected by the level of productivity. What be the income and the share x(n,5,Tr) y = are the patterns of trade \ / (p a s • + p p u} e" and x = • d — technologies (high n) and more and x. We therefore them in s o v, respectively. and i.e. 71 . Not surprisingly, countries with better capital (high 5) number goods, all production of a-products and import almost final Let y(n,§,7i) • human final economy? of the a-industry in a (n,5,7i)-country, infinitesimal the production of production of world refer to countries with high each country produces an of • in this have high values values of x as of varieties of y Since rich countries. a-products and uses countries export almost all for both of the a-products all used all of their in the domestic goods. As a share of income, these exports and imports are x and To balance their trade, countries with countries with x>v import them. As a share of 14 x<v export (3-products and income, these exports and imports are v-x and x-v, respectively. Therefore, usual, this trade can be decomposed interindustry trade, x-v I The factor proportions. proportions. The the share of trade | . The former consists of trade and in 2. trade among poor The Cross-section In to the in little and a stylized manner three broad empirical a large volume of intraindustry trade between rich and poor countries. Business Cycles economy described the world same of As products with different factor later consists of trade in model therefore captures (c) max[v,x]. products that have similar in rich countries, (b) substantial interindustry trade countries, is into intraindustry trade, min[v,x], regularities regarding the patterns of trade: (a) among income in in the previous section, countries are subject Any type of country-specific and global shocks to productivity. difference the properties of their business cycles must be ultimately attributed to differences in their technology and factor proportions. This is clearly a simplification. In the real world countries experience different types of shocks and also differ beyond technology and factor proportions. With ask: How much potentially The first answer is to the between one and two of a mind, thirds of is ways in this (n.,5,7t)-country as a 1), linear we dlny-E[dlny] = x- — section all we the variation. to obtain an expression obtain the Ito's that lemma (demeaned) growth combination of country-specific and 1 + (1-x)-(1 + X) d(7t-n)+ +x 1+X-v 15 go Perhaps global shocks: (12) that business cycles could shocks that countries experience. Applying the definition of y and using Equations (2)-(1 income in in of the previous section? step towards answering this question income growth rate of caveat observed cross-country variation be explained by the simple model surprisingly, the links of the this in dn to Equation (12) provides a complete characterization of the business cycles experienced by a measured by (u.,5,7i)-country as a function as of the country's industrial structure, Equation (12) shows that poor countries are more sensitive to x. 3dlny country-specific shocks, is i.e. decreasing in x. Equation (12) also ad(Ti-n) dn=o shows that all countries are equally sensitive to global shocks, x. Why are We next discuss the intuition poor countries more sensitive X-^0 and 9^°° so that the a-and > specific increase in productivity to country-specific = 1 if In this case, a one percent country- has no effects on employment or product and 6^^. A.-^0 shocks? Assume (3-industry face both perfectly inelastic factor production and income also increase by one percent. This 3dlny d(;t-n)=o behind these results. supplies and perfectly elastic product demands. result, is adn independent of that i.e positive, is If A, is prices. As a why a country-specific increase in ad(Ti-n) dn=o productivity of one percent leads an increase to industry and, as a result, production in employment of A. percent in the (3- and income increase by more than one percent. This employment response magnifies the expansionary effects of increased productivity in the (3-industry. 3dlny countries, As a = i.e. 1 + result, (1 — x) - the shock has stronger effects A, if 8—>°°. If 6 is finite, in poor a country-specific 3d(7t-n) dn=o increase in productivity of one percent leads to a 0" 1 percent decrease in prices in the a-industries. This price response counteracts the expansionary effects of increased productivity in the a-industry. Consequently, the shock has weaker effects Bdlny countries, = i.e. — x 1 if X=0. If X>0 and 9 the employment and price responses combine to country-specific shocks, =x i.e. dd(Ti-n) dn=o 16 is finite, make poor —1 9 + (1 - x) we have in rich that both countries react (1 + X) is more decreasing to in x. Why are all on the assumption countries equally responsive to global shocks? This result rests that the elasticity of substitution one. Consider a global increase in productivity. On between a- and (3-products the one hand, production is of p- products expands relative to the production of a-products as more unskilled workers are employed. Ceteris paribus, this would increase the share of world income that goes and hence poor to the p-industry, the increase in relative countries, after a positive global shock. But supply lowers the relative price of p-products. This reduces the share of world income that goes to the P-industry, and hence poor countries, after a positive global shock. The assumption of a Cobb-Douglas technology production of the world spending in in final good implies two effects cancel and the share of the a- and P-industries remains constant over the cycle. Therefore, our framework differences in industrial countries react to global shocks. We are ready to use the from Equation (12) structure do not generate differences in how 6 model dlnY as the world average growth to interpret the rate, i.e. evidence dlnY = jj dlny in dFdG Figure . 1 Then, Define . it follows that: 1 dlnY-E[dlnY] = (13) that these for the 1 +X dn + A-v Since the law of large numbers eliminates the country-specific component of shocks in the aggregate, the world countries that belong to 6 economy exhibits milder cycles that any of the 7 it. is special, it is not difficult to grasp what would happen if we the elasticity of substitution between industries were higher than one, poor countries would While the Cobb-Douglas formulation relaxed it. If be more sensitive shocks than as the share of world income that goes to the |3and decreases after a negative one. If the elasticity of substitution were less than one, the opposite would be true. 7 Once again, this result rests on the Cobb-Douglas assumption. If the elasticity of substitution between a- and |3-products were higher than one, the very rich countries might exhibit business cycles that are to global rich countries industry increases after a positive global shock milder than those of the world. 17 Let V(n,8,7i) denote the standard deviation of country, and let CQx,5,7c) denote the correlation of its income growth we find shocks, in Figure 1 (14) x o-. ^+x ' .^I + (1-x)-(1 + X) C= 1 x (1"T1) + + 1-v .®^ + (1-x)-(1 + X) Figure 3 plots the parameter values. Except volatility graph downward intuition is clear: As a 1 + •(1-71) (3-industry. This makes in sloping +A + X-v the limiting case Tl is in of x, for where both X=0 and and the comovement graph asymmetries result of and labour supply, the a-industry + X-v and comovement graphs as functions volatility different is ^ f\ 1 The and to the volatility that: -\ (15) (u.,5,7t)- Using Equations (12)-(13) and the properties of the . -i2 V= a income growth with world average income growth. These are the theoretical analogs comovement graphs of is upward 0=<~, the sloping. the elasticity of product-demand less sensitive to country-specific the a-industry less volatile and shocks than the more synchronized with the world cycle than the (3-industry. Since countries inherit the cyclical properties of their industries, the incomes of rich countries are also less volatile with the world cycle than those of poor countries. is and more synchronized The magnitude of these differences more pronounced as X increases and/or 6 decreases. A simple inspection of Equations (14) and (15) reveals that there exist various combinations of parameters capable of generating approximately the data patterns displayed in Figure 1 and Table 1 . In this evidence that motivated the paper. But impose more values that range for x. discipline seem by sense, the model this is With these choices at this, hand, we we 18 able to replicate the a very undemanding restricting the analysis to reasonable. To do is combinations criterion. of One can parameter next choose values for a, r\, v and a then examine how the cross-section of business cycles varies with X and Needless 9. strong conclusions from a calibration exercise As noted above, also differ that and of countries industries, the large cross-section of countries To determine The model Since this share so that caution we in around 60 percent bound The model for x. poor countries, and that GDP is around 20 percent 0.1 in x, we use income the richest countries in in choose v=0.2 and use generalizing to in in in countries our sample, also predicts that v is for x. The choice in problem by choosing a and and comovement of 8 parameters. This model's ability to comovement The of income growth means capita of volatility rj and r\ around 6.5), In particular, choices for more We level of volatility for the typical rich country, given the rest of our can only tell us about the in volatility and panel of Table 2 reports the results of this calibration exercise, in Figure 3. The around 9.5) and the poorest country a and r| row reports the predicted first and comovement between the based on the regressions A and is we income growth. in volatility of the share of and cross-country match the observed match observed cross-country differences top-left GDP to that this calibration exercise and selected cases are shown difference r| we use our sample, correlation of productivity growth for this large cross-section of countries. this is x. these countries x<v. Since the share problematic, since there are no reliable estimates of the circumvent shall data on trade in rich the poorest countries as a lower bound we this exercise. predicts that the share of exports is when order study here. Despite these caveats, income of exports in is in the relevant range of variation for 0.6 as a reasonable upper exports factor proportions. Moreover, X and 9 are based on non-representative see that some useful insights can be gained from shares. draw a model as stylized as ours. like this in go beyond technology and available estimates of the key parameters samples to the real world countries experience different types of shocks and in ways in one should be cautious to say, with controls richest country (with log per (with log per capita in Table 1 . GDP of The remaining rows are chosen to ensure that V=0.04 and C=0.4, for x=0.5, v=0.2 and the given 9. 19 report the difference poorest (x=0.1 ) in volatility and comovement between the countries that the model predicts for different values of X These values encompass existing and richest (x=0.6) and 0. microeconomic estimates. Available industry estimates of the elasticity of export demand range from 2 10 (see Trefler and Lai to (1999), Feenstra, (1994)), while available estimates for the labour supply elasticity of unskilled workers range from 0.3 to 0.35 table also reports the values for Table 2 shows can account rich that, a and r\ (See Juhn, Murphy and Topel (1991)). The that result from the calibration procedure. using values for 8 and X of 9=2 and A.=0.35, the model between for nearly two-thirds of the cross-country difference in volatility and poor countries (-0.016 versus cross-country differences in -0.026), and slightly less comovement (0.129 versus than one-third of the 0.382). These values for the parameters are within the range suggested by existing microeconomic studies. industry asymmetries are predicted differences These values. results assumed in volatility to be even stronger, say 9=1 and comovement are closer such a stylized model as ours. Moreover, we shall see in in the and X=0.7, the to their predicted seem encouraging. The two hypotheses account for a sizeable fraction of cross-country differences .2 If put forward here can business cycles even in the next section that a simple extension of the model that allows for monetary shocks and cross-country differences in the degree of financial development can move the theoretical predictions closer to the data. A second demand seems result in Table 2 quantitatively is that the asymmetry in the elasticity of product more important than the asymmetry in the labour supply. Within the range of parameter values considered changes to have in is in Table 2, 9 have strong effects on the slope of the two graphs, while changes little consider the elasticity of or no effect. To the extent that this range of parameter values in we the relevant one, this calibration exercise suggests that the asymmetry asymmetries hypothesis of in the elasticity of product why business point in section four demands constitutes the cycles are different across countries. where we attempt to distinguish examining terms of trade data. 20 more promising We X return to this between hypotheses by in 3. Monetary Shocks and Financial Development Our simple account for calibration exercise tells almost two-thirds of the cross-country differences one-third of the cross-country variation model that the is surely too stylized to made our modelling choices were model fit. Now that the by adding to in comovement. One it is maximize reaction to this finding and cross-country we choose this extension highlights are both narrow this gap, but variation in to follow this route and realistic We now allow countries to differ also and their monetary where k (|j.,5,7:,k,i), interest rate policy. is Each country is interesting in their financial constraint. 9 In particular, firms a fraction k of therefore we We assume that k wage bill limit in Christiano, i development is not the only in their own have to right. of financial is development \i, that firms face a cash-in-advance credit markets. which credit markets are so efficient that As . in order to pay The parameter k k^O cash is a discussion of related models. 21 the We allow for an 8 and k. before production starts, with 0<k<1 for i is constant over time and re- use cash or domestic currency Eichenbaum and Evans (1997) that fluctuate randomly. money by assuming measures how underdeveloped are reach the See their that by therefore defined by a quintuplet, additional source of business cycles by letting motivate the use of of closer to a measure of the degree of financial development, and on domestic currency. is intuitions because the elements degree define F(^,5,k) as the time-invariant joint distribution of We move where we show helps to significantly narrow the gap between model and data. This to most all, and the clearly stated time to build on the stylized model and way and nearly theoretical transparency rather than details. This is the goal of this section, introducing monetary shocks in volatility, be confronted with the data. After main mechanisms have been behind them developed, reality us that the two industry asymmetries can in all countries, never used. This is the case we have studied so far. In those countries where k>0, firms borrow cash from the government and repay the cash plus completed and output sold to consumers. is Monetary policy consists distributing the in proceeds random. 10 variance § in n. 2 a lump-sum fashion we assume In particular, motion on the in interval [i,T ], on cash and then of setting the interest rate money and business the literature on interest after production is with among consumers. As we assume cycles, that the interest rate changes is have zero that that monetary Let the initial distribution of interest rates be uniform policy is a reflecting Brownian drift, instantaneous and are independent across countries and also independent , customary is in [t,T ] of changes and independent of the distribution of other country characteristics. Hence, the cross-sectional distribution of The i, H(i), does not change over introduction of world equilibrium in money time. leads only to minor changes in Equation (5) sector do not pay wages, their pricing decision cash-in-advance constraints affect the firms (8) have to in in addition to labour costs. be replaced by: (16) pa =— -r-e-™ e-1 (17) pp =w-e" 10 the description of section one. Equations (2)-(3) describing the labour-supply decision and the numeraire rule face financing costs in adequate still apply. Since firms is still in given by Equation the (6). final The the a- and (3-industries since they As a result, the pricing equations now (7)- 11 one takes the view that monetary policy has objectives other than the inflation tax is used to finance a public good, shocks to the marginal value of this public good are translated into shocks to the rate of money growth. Alternatively, if a country is committed to maintaining a fixed parity, shocks to foreign investors' confidence in the country are translated into shocks to the nominal interest rate, as the monetary authorities use the latter to manage the exchange rate. This simplification is if stabilizing the cycle. For instance, 11 if We are using the following approximation here: Ki=ln(1+Ki). 22 Note that changes the interest rate affect the financing costs of firms and in are therefore formally equivalent to supply shocks such as changes payroll taxes. Formally, this of earlier arguments shows prices are still is that Equations (9)-(1 valid provided which converges to the A the only change required. we T re-define Y describing the set of equilibrium 1 ) dFdGdH, J||(1-5)e the limiting case in B straightforward extension (1+A)(7t " n) " Kl = p earlier definition of production or in in which k-^0 in all countries. Financing costs are not a direct cost for the country as a whole but only a transfer from firms to consumers via the government. Consequently, income and the \ / share of the a-industry are still respectively. Now more human capital (high 5) defined as y = rich countries been simple: A for weaker labour demand The and x = u) e u. and S lead k). is is to a high value of x. This as rich. , n), is why have However, we have now that x. The intuition is associated with higher financing costs and therefore a for all types of workers. translated fully into low size of the a-industry p -s-e" — Remember that, k leads to both higher income and a lower value for high value of k weak demand • systems (low financial referring to countries with high values for x a low value + pp s are those that have better technologies (high and better ceteris paribus, a high value for \p a is in In the market for skilled workers, this wages and has no effects in employment. therefore not affected by cash-in-advance constraints. In the market for unskilled workers, this wages and employment. The weak demand latter implies is a smaller translated into both lower (3-industry. continue to refer to countries with higher values of x as rich. Despite That is, it this, seems we to shall us reasonable to assume that technology and factor proportions are more important determinants of a country's industrial structure than the degree of financial development. We are ready to determine how interest-rate the cross-section of business cycles. Applying 23 Ito's shocks affect income growth and lemma to the definition of y, we find this expression for the (demeaned) growth rate of income for the (|n,5,7t,K,i)- country: dlny-E[dlny] (18) x = .®-l + (1-x)-(1 + X) d(7t-n)+ 1+ J \ + Xv dn-(1-x)A-K-di Equation (18), which generalizes Equation (12), describes the business cycles as a function of a (|j,,S,7i,K,i)-country of its industrial structure. The first two terms describe the reaction of the country to productivity shocks and have been discussed at length. shocks. The term third In particular, is new and shows how shows it countries that are poor is and have a low degree decreasing shocks have larger effects that interest-rate 3dlny 9di the country reacts to interest-rate in x of financial and increasing in in development. That k (holding constant is, x). d(rc-n)=o dn=o An increase in the interest rate raises financing costs industries. This increase is larger in countries with low development (high interest-rate in Just because of shocks than supply of labour workers k). is rich countries. inelastic and the passed to is degrees the a- and (3- of financial poor countries are more sensitive to But there is more. In the a-industry, the additional financing costs are fully the form of lower wages. Production industry, the supply of labour partially this, in is passed therefore not affected. In to the f3- and the additional financing costs are only elastic wages. Employment and production therefore decline. In the aggregate, production and income decline after a positive interest-rate shock. But the asymmetry stronger in in the labour supply elasticity poor countries that have larger is important, this reaction should be (3-industries. reason why poor countries are more sensitive if This provides a second to interest-rate shocks than rich countries. The introduction of interest-rate country-specific shocks have stronger shocks provides two additional reasons why effects 24 in poor countries: one also works through their industrial structure and another financial a consequence of their lack of is development. Both of these considerations reinforce the results of the To see previous model. this, re-define dlnY = f | applies since monetary shocks are country-specific eliminates their effects in dFdGdH. fdlny and the law the aggregate. Then, rewrite the Equation (13) of large volatility still numbers and comovement graphs as follows: f V= (19) a x-iLl + (1-x).(1 + A.) 2 (1-T1) 1 + ^ +x \ 1 12 2 +r-K^-(i-xr-A.' Tl + X-v 1+X C= (20) + X-v 1 a . (1-tl) + show that, ceteris paribus, volatile which and 2 •Tl 1 These equations are ^ 1+X ' x .8_1 +(1 _x).(1+X) 2 + X-v ,,-2 j natural generalizations of Equations (14)-(15). countries with low financial development less correlated with the world. industrial structure affects the will They be both more They also show the new channel through business cycles of countries. With these additional forces present, the model closer to the observed cross-country variation is in volatility now able to come much and comovement using values for 9 and X that are consistent with available microeconomic studies. This shown of in the bottom panel of Table 2, where shocks to monetary policy sample and k=0.5 now we in is 0.1 and in we assume is that the standard deviation that k=1 in the poorest countries in our the richest countries. For 9=2 and X=0.35, the extended model delivers cross-country differences estimated t2 „\2 I* +r-K^-(1-Xr-X' Table 1 in volatility that are nearly identical to the (-0.024 versus -0.026), and cross-country differences comovement are now 40 percent Looking further down the table, of those we can we observe further in reality improve the fit ones in (0.165 versus 0.382). of the model in the comovement dimension by considering more extreme parameter values. However, this is achieved at the cost of over-predicting cross-country differences in volatility. 25 We could try to further narrow the gap between theory and considering additional extensions to the model. But so far are sufficient to establish that the potential to explain at least countries. This 4. is in part cycles are different in rich and poor our simple objective here. From the standpoint in think that the results obtained two hypotheses considered here have the why business The Cyclical Behavior developed we data by of the of the Terms evidence reported in of Trade Table 1 and the theory the previous sections, the two industry asymmetries studied here are observationally equivalent. However, using microeconomic estimates for 9 and X as additional evidence to calibrate the model, elasticity of product we found demand seems a more promising cycles are different across countries than the supply. section, In this that the we show that these asymmetry explanation of asymmetry in in the why business the elasticity of the labour two asymmetries have different implications for the cyclical properties of the terms of trade, and then confronting these implications with the data. The evidence on the cyclical behavior of the terms trade is of consistent with the results of our calibration exercise. Namely, a strong asymmetry in the elasticity of product demand helps the model provide a more accurate description of the terms of trade data than a strong asymmetry elasticity of in the the labour supply. We first derive the stochastic process for the terms of trade. Let T((i,5,7t,k,i) denote the terms of trade of a (|a,5,7r,K,i)-country. that the (detrended) growth rate 12 in Using Equations the terms of trade decompose income growth is equal to: (9)-(1 1), we find 12 into the growth rates of production and the terms of trade. growth rate) measures income growth that is due to changes in production, holding constant prices. The growth rate of the terms of trade measures income growth that is due to changes in prices, holding constant production. We follow usual convention and define the terms of trade of a country as the ideal price index of production relative to the ideal price index of expenditure. The growth rate of the terms of trade is equal to the share of exports in income times the growth rate of their price minus the share of imports in income times the growth rate of their price. It is possible to The growth rate of production (or GDP 26 dlnT-E[dlnT] = --d(7i-n)+ (21) v (X 9 1 ^ -dn + A-V Equation (21) describes the cyclical behavior of the terms of trade as a function of the country's industrial structure. shocks to productivity affect negatively the It shows that positive country-specific terms of trade, and adlnT absolute value) the richer the country, is is i.e. this effect is larger (in negative and ad(Tt-n) dn=o decreasing in x. Equation (21) also shows that positive global shocks to productivity worsen the terms ~\f-i I— of trade of poor countries and improve those of rich countries, i.e. T is adn negative if x<v and positive if x>v. Finally, Equation (21 ) shows that d(n-n)=0 interest-rate shocks have no effects on the terms behind these results of trade. We discuss the intuition in turn. Country-specific shocks to productivity have no effect on import prices because countries are small. But they do affect export prices. Consider a positive country-specific shock to productivity. In the a-industry, firms react to the shock by producing more of each variety they know increase in the production of each variety how is to produce. Since this set large. varieties are imperfect substitutes, the increase country's a-products. In the P-industry, firms react to the (or shock by spreading by forcing some do this). production lowers the price of the to among a As a small, the Since domestic and foreign know how their production firms abroad to in is result, produce large all varieties. number the increase in They of varieties the production of each variety is infinitesimally small products are not affected. In the aggregate, the terms of trade worsen as a result of the shock. But terms of trade if the asymmetry in the elasticity of product should deteriorate more Global shocks influence all and the prices in rich of the country's p- demand is important, the countries. countries equally and, consequently, they do not affect the prices of different varieties of a- and P-products 27 relative to their corresponding industry aggregates. Consider a positive global shock to productivity. We saw earlier that this shock lowers the price of products (See Equation (11)). The reason in productivity leads to a direct increase elasticity of the labour supply employment (3-products. of unskilled is in is all simple: (3-products relative to both industries, the increase In production. But important, the increase workers and leads As the world supply a- all in the asymmetry if in the productivity raises to a further increase in the production of of (3-products increases relative to that of a-products, their relative price declines. This is why the terms of trade of net exporters of |3- products, x<v, deteriorate, while the terms of trade of net importers of p-products, x>v, improve. Finally, effects country Equation (21) states that country-specific interest-rate shocks have no on the terms is small. But they interst-rate shocks do not affect the prices of These shocks do of trade. do not affect export prices either. relative to the industry shocks affect the production of (3-products. change their prices in the makes cyclical behavior of the affect the terms comovement graphs result, they do not aggregate. Interest-rate in the p-industry cannot do not how affect the terms of trade. the two industry asymmetries shape the of trade. In the absence of asymmetries in the elasticity only country-specific shocks affect the terms of trade. the absence of asymmetries shocks clear terms A—>0, of the labour supply, As a earlier, face of perfect competition from firms abroad. Therefore, country-specific monetary shocks ) However, firms because the As discussed affect the production of a-products. domestic varieties Equation (21 not affect import prices in the elasticity of product of trade. for the demand, This has implications for the terms of trade. Let 8-^°=, only global volatility VT (fi,5,Tr,K,i) denote and the standard deviation of the (detrended) growth of terms of trade of a (|a,8,7t,K,i)-country, C J (\i,5,n) denote (13), (21) and the properties its correlation with world In and let average income growth. Using Equations of the shocks, we 28 find that: V T =a-. (22) (x-v)-A + (1-il) Tl CT (23) = "l V? + X-v + 'ix-v)X^ •Tl fl-<1-1> To understand the extreme cases. Both are comovement graphs values. is Assume first the asymmetry VT = — a in 1 + X-v behind these formulae, intuition illustrated in Figure 4, terms of the that the only of trade and C T = prices is . is it demand, volatility graph i.e. differ and parameter across countries A=0. Then, upward is volatility x, for different reason why business cycles The useful to consider two which plots the as functions of the elasticity of product •y/l-'n • + A.v 1 V sloping. Since all the G volatility in of trade are more due changes to in the domestic varieties of a-products, the terms volatile in rich countries The comovement graph of the a-industry is large. zero. While the terms of trade is flat at country-specific shocks, world where the share income responds only respond only to shocks. As a result to global both variables are uncorrelated. Assume countries VT is the lx-v|-X = J ! 1 next that the only reason asymmetry i— cr-AH an d in + A.v 1-1 [ all if x < v if x >v . i 1 the volatility in aggregate industry prices, the terms share cycles are different across the elasticity of the labour supply, T C = a minimum when x=v. Since why business The of trade are more of interindustry trade in overall trade is large, very rich and very poor countries whose is due i.e. is to changes Then, like in | x-v | is large. a V, with the volatile in countries factor proportions most from world averages. The comovement graph 0^><». graph looks volatility prices i.e. where the These are the and technology differ the a step function with a single step at x=v. Since global shocks drive both the world cycle and the terms of trade, these variables are perfectly correlated. If the country 29 is a net exporter of a-products, this correlation is positive. correlation The is If the country a net exporter of (3-products, is negative. volatility and comovement graphs for the combination of these two extreme cases, as shown looks like while the v. a V that has. been shifted to the right of comovement graph slopes upwards The extreme cases are terms of trade are in Figure 4. The source of differences with flat tails elasticity of the is business cycles. The more important comovement graph. the slope of the comovement is is graph because they is asymmetries as a the volatility The more important labour supply, the closer volatility and a steep slope around useful not only to build intuition, but also product demand, the higher the slope of the the slope of the higher in general a in x=v and rotated counter-clockwise, point to a criterion to determine the relative importance of the two elasticity of this asymmetry in graph and the the asymmetry the volatility graph to a V-shape in the flatter the and the graph. Before going to the data however, note that there is an alternative interpretation of these patterns within our theory. Independently of the values for and A., the larger the slope of the r|=0, is the country-specific volatility graph and the V T = — a and C T = component flatter Also, the . productivity shocks, the closer is the the slope of the more important volatility graph , the slope of the of productivity for the terms country-specific of the of trade of -,- T a and C = + A. v • volatility as providing evidence on the and global components If of is [-1 if X < V [1 if x >v and comovement relative importance of the shocks, instead of the relative importance two industry asymmetries. Figure 5 plots the empirical analogs of the terms of trade comovement graphs. in component a V-shape and the higher ! Therefore, one could also interpret the shape of the comovement graph. the global Ix-vl-X comovement graph .|fn=1,V T =J 1 graphs to is shocks, the higher Figure 1 In volatility and contrast with the very clear unconditional patterns apparent for the volatility and comovement 30 of income growth, in Figure 5 we see and comovement that the volatility significantly correlated with of fluctuations in the income. However, the the introduction, there in of trade and comovement a significant positive partial correlation comovement and income remains the third column of Table 3 the asymmetry in function, respectively). median we is We do this by interacting income. from zero. dummy this, we and a step sample no evidence find in two at the of the non-linearity when we the sample at different points (not reported for brevity). In light of graph and a flat as evidence in the discussion above, this pattern of an upward sloping comovement graph for the terms of trade could favour of the relative importance of asymmetries product demand, or as evidence in volatility be interpreted either in the elasticity of favour of the unimportance of global shocks. However, there are good reasons to prefer the former interpretation over the Consider for example the calibrations comovement of correlation productivity shocks, Jr\ in income growth, that cross-country correlations story, Table 2. In was necessary it in in , and so the evidence on terms to assume ranged from 0.25 productivity product demand over Finally we observe country differences in the that the volatility in the terms of trade of the same to 0.40. This suggests to us of the and comovement should be asymmetry in the elasticity of the elasticity of the labour supply. model is able to replicate the observed cross- and comovement reasonable parameter values. The that the cross-country shocks are an important part of trade volatility the asymmetry latter. order to replicate the observed interpreted as favouring the relative importance of the for when both the intercept and the variable that divides the When we do In and important, the volatility non-linear functions of income (V-shaped on income with a level of insignificantly different predicted by this version of the theory. Moreover, our results do not change split we between take seriously the prediction of the theory that the labour supply elasticity comovement graphs are coefficient the second column of Table 3 the terms of trade and income, while the partial correlation between volatility of terms is of trade are not of volatility sources find that, controlling for other potential discussed in terms right of the terms of trade fairly well panel of Table 2 reports the results for calibration exercised discussed previously 31 in the context of the volatility and comovement of income growth. For a value find that the theory predicts cross-country differences in when 0.012 and 0.010 respectively. This the elasticity of unskilled labour supply compares favourably the regression with controls in no cross-country differences X=0, but it somewhat terms Table in we of 9=2, of trade volatility of is A.=0 or X=0.35 with the predicted difference of 0.009 from Regarding comovement, the theory predicts 3. terms of trade comovement whatsoever whenever overpredicts cross-country differences in comovement when in both physical and X=0.35. 5. Trade Integration The postwar period has seen a policy barriers to international trade paper is in substantial reduction goods. Remember that As transport costs decline, the prices of products country has comparative advantage increase and the share As a industries increases. argument result, industrial structures diverge. one should expect that is we add transport costs to the We generalize the model transport costs t>1 at the destination . If implies that domestic model and confirm by assuming that trade x units of output are and the and shipped from rest "melt" in transit. We re-define P a pa (z) and p p D (z) be the c.i.f. and P p as the production of these A natural conclusion of In this this intuition. is subject to "iceberg" origin, only in one unit arrives of transport costs ideal price indices of the a- and keep the numeraire The domestic 32 and the a- and (^-industries, or domestic price of variety z the (|i,5,n;,K,i)-country, respectively. its which a international product prices might differ. Define p o (z) industries using international prices, D in business cycles. in The presence p p (z) as the f.o.b. or international price of variety z respectively. of this that reductions in transport costs (globalization?) should increase cross-country differences section, in theme depends on that the nature of business cycles that a country experiences industrial structure. this the main in rule in and (3- Equation (5). Let the a- and (3-industries price of imported varieties is in D p a (z)=xp a (z) and p p (z)=rp p (z), while that of exported varieties D p p (z)=p p (z). If some there are D follows: p a (z)<p a (z)<x-p a (z) case varieties that are not traded, their price D and p p (z)<p (z)<xp E, converge and the model international prices one here. As t-»1 and k->0 of the p a (z)=p a (z) and is As (z). t-»1, domestic bounded as and fJ of section three obtains in all is model countries, the as a special of section one obtains. The introduction of transport costs leads to The maximization problem of the world equilibrium. and Equations some changes of the goods sector of the firms in the final D (24) consumer (2)-(3) describing the labour-supply decision relevant prices for firms are the domestic ones. First, p F =(Pa v -(P ) D in Equation (6) are we must not affected valid. now But the replace the pricing rule ) D ideal price indices of the a- Given the cost function produce the domestic varieties all is by the following one: and (3-industries using domestic prices. Consider next the pricing decisions of firms almost still the description D 1v p where Pa and P 3 are the industries. in of their production in (4) and the the a- and in fact that foreign firms of a-products, firms in the a-industry and the domestic price is (3- cannot always export the international one, i.e. D p a (z)=p a (z). Therefore, Equation (7) describing the pricing behavior of domestic producers of a-products still applies. We must however replace Equation (8) by the following: (25) pf=w-e-" To complete equilibrium prices. that Equation (9) in A the description of the model, we need to compute the straightforward extension of the arguments is still valid as description in set of section two shows of the relative prices of different varieties the a-industry. However, finding the prices of (3-products 33 in different countries and l the international relative price of the a- and p-products appendix provides a detailed derivation intuition behind them and In equilibrium, is quite involved. these prices. Here of we simply discuss the their implications. poor countries export P-products to rich countries. In income countries, P-products are not traded. The appendix shows classify countries into these three groups as 0i,5,7T,K,i)eM yP iff U/ 1 ^ ^ 9 iff 1 x" -^-'"-n) -^-' c- t -(1-5) v ' . a Te < e e-1 ^ v ' 9 5 e ~i^7 K i)eX ^v< Y T iff I p 2=1 where ¥a x is defined as before and W. generalizes the previous one. is time-invariant in An is "n) (,I lT^ K < T ^» -(1-5) 8-1 1 I c1 c Av t-" (jx,5,7t we can e-i -8 e 9 1 (h,8,71,k,i)eN that middle- follows: 2 (26) The ^ t" 9 Xv ' S9 -^7-'"- n) c l^- K " -(1-5) a new constant that depends on x and important characteristic of this classification an important sense: the fraction of countries of is that each type that belongs to each group does not vary with the world cycle. The appendix shows that international relative prices, but we can we must still use Equation (1 1 ) as a description of replace Equation (10) by the following one: 34 it if (|a,5,Tl,K,l)G X if (u,5,7t,K,i)e N if (|^,5,7i;,k,i)g M 1 9-1 1 ^•^•5 Pp 1+A-v e -(n-n) IE! ^« 9 -x" Xv ki 1+Xv 1+Xv (27) (1-5) Unlike the previous models, purchasing power parity no longer applies. see this, note that the price of the final good is now To given by: 1-v (28) pF =x v 'PP y V J To understand an this equation, remember infinitesimal part of the total expenditure ideal basket of a-products the numaraire rule in countries purchasing is x-P a Equation power . The in that domestic oc-products constitute a-products, so that the price of the price of (3-products however pp . Finally, use Since the prices of (3-products vary across (5). no longer applies and the cost parity D is of living is higher in countries that import (3-products. Consistent with existing evidence on the cost of living, the theory predicts these countries to be the rich ones. 13 We are ready to characterize the cross-section of business cycles in this extended model. Now income and the share of a-products are d prices. That find that the / is, y = (p„ • s + p° \ • u)- (demeaned) growth e n and x = rate of d — income measured -s- e" . is still Applying Ito's in domestic lemma to y, we given by Equation (18). Consequently, Equations (19) and (20) relating the properties of business cycles to a country's industrial structure The assumption to the same that the final transport cost still good is hold. And Equations nontraded is still x. 35 (22)-(23) describing the cyclical not binding, provided that the latter is subject properties of the terms of trade also apply. So, what are the effects of transport costs on the cross-section and, as a result, of business cycles? Transport costs reduce the volume of trade the cross-sectional dispersion in x. To see this, we compute the cross-section of shares: e-1 1 Yp-n e -5 e _ tl 1-v (29) V]i°-5 v 1-v The x -x- is if (|j.,8,7i,K,i)e N -(X+9 _1 if (^,5,7l,K,l)€ M )(7t-n)-AKi °=1 Ta e t- , Xv -(1-8) high enough, trade the greater are the differences mean in (3-products disappears becomes in industrial 14 flat. i.e. the a-products and x=v The lower in rich in production remains constant. But changes in rich Lower transport countries and the [3-products in relative employment and production. The lower are transport production of (3-products countries. which a country has poor ones. Higher relative prices imply higher industry shares if in all the transport costs, structures of countries. higher relative prices of those products comparative advantage, even l)eX ((li8| (1-6) 8 cross-section of business cycles costs ^ jf 1-V 1-x If HV , AV - ( x + 9-).(.-n)-x.K, e for those products, prices also affect costs, the lower countries and the higher is in in is poor ones. these two channels, increased trade integration magnifies differences in the 15 Through the industrial structures of countries. An interesting result that follows from this discussion affects differently the business cycles of rich If the elasticity of substitution would there still is vary and there would no trade in is that trade integration and poor countries. In rich countries, between a- and (3-products were different than one, industrial structures still be some differences in business cycles across countries even if ^-products. 15 These increases in employment could come from increased participation or reduced unemployment, as is the case in the model presented here. Or they could come from employment in other industries, as it would be the case if we changed our assumptions and allowed both industries to use both types of workers. 36 trade integration increases the share of a-industries and to country-specific shocks. This leads to more synchronized makes them business cycles that are less less sensitive volatile and with the world cycle. In poor countries, trade integration increases makes them more the share of (3-products and This leads to business cycles that are more sensitive to country-specific shocks. volatile and less synchronized with the world. The welfare consequences to assess. the As absence of trade integration for usual, there are the standard welfare effects that would occur it also might change the among products and therefore re-distribute income that there are also welfare effects that business cycles. accumulation. As a consumers are integration as 6. Remember risk result, in rich volatility relative price of a- is even and [3- come from changes trade equal to consumption. To in in the nature of assets and capital the extent that countries welfare improves as a result of trade declines. The opposite is true in poor countries. 16 Concluding Remarks This paper started with the observation that business cycles are different rich in countries. But the theory here we have assumed away income averse, income that difficult Trade integration increases efficiency and of fluctuations in productivity. raise welfare everywhere. But shows a given country are and poor countries. In particular fluctuations in per capita growth are less volatile and more synchronized with the world cycle in rich countries than in poor ones. explored the possibility that these patterns might be due to differences structure. Comparative advantage leads use new technologies operated by face inelastic product rich skilled demands and in countries to specialize workers. in We in industrial industries that We argued that these industries labour supplies. Under these conditions the 16 If there were some trade in assets, it is not clear whether the welfare effects of trade integration would be always positive in rich countries and negative in poor ones. On the one hand, volatility increases in poor countries and this lowers the value of their assets. On the other hand, comovement with the world declines in poor countries and this increases the value of their assets. 37 income effects of country-specific supply generate reductions in prices shocks tend and only small increases advantage also leads poor countries demands and use traditional We argued that these industries face shocks tend to be large, since they generate little on prices and large effects on employment. Our model employment. Comparative labour supplies. Under these conditions, the income effects of country-specific supply effects in be moderate, since they to specialize in industries that technologies operated by unskilled workers. elastic product to to been contribution has study their implications. to A frame these hypotheses and provide a formal simple calibration using available microeconomic estimates of the key parameters suggests that these hypotheses have the potential to account for observed cross-country differences that cross-industry differences in product-demand important than cross-industry differences for observed cross-country differences quite flexible and allows us examined how differences to in in in business cycles. Also, elasticities are quantitatively more labour-supply elasticities in we find in accounting business cycles. The model turns out to be analyze a number of related issues. For instance, financial development affect the way we countries react to shocks, the implications of the theory for the cyclical behavior of the terms of trade, and the effects of globalization on the nature The next step however should be of business cycles. empirical. The theory developed here provides a rich set of testable hypotheses relating the industrial structure of countries with the properties of their business cycles. preliminary. These hypotheses are promising, They should be thoroughly confronted 38 with the data. but still . References Acemoglu, D. and F. Zilibotti (1997) "Was Prometheus Unbound by Chance? Diversification and Growth," Journal of Political Economy 1 05: 709-751 Risk, Backus, D.K., P.J. Kehoe and F.E. Kydland (1995), "International Business Cycles: Theory and Evidence" in T.F.Cooley (ed.) Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, Princeton University Press. Baxter, M. (1995), "International Trade and Business Cycles" in G.M. Grossman and Handbook of International Economics, Volume 3, North-Holland. K. Rogoff (eds.) Banks, A. (1979), Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive, Center for Social Analysis, State University of New York, Binghamton. Eichenbaum and C. Evans (1997), "Sticky Price and Limited Models of Money: A Comparison," mimeo. Christiano, L, M. Participation Davis, D. (1995), "Intraindustry Trade: A Heckscher-Ohlin-Ricardo Approach," Journal of International Economics 39: 201 -226 "New Product Varieties and the Measurement American Economic Review 84: 157-77. Feenstra, R. (1994), Prices," of International J. and D. Romer (1999). "Does Trade Cause Growth?". American Economic Review. 89(3):379-399. Frankel, Harrison, J.M. (1990), Brownian Motion and Stochastic Flow Systems, Krieger. C, K.M. Murphy and R.H. Topel (1991), "Why Has the Natural Rate of Unemployment Increase Over Time?" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Juhn, Vol.2, pp.75-143. Kydland, F.E. and E.C. Prescott (1992),"Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations," Econometrica, 50: 1345-1370. and H. Lai (1999). "The Gains from Trade: Standard Errors With the Monopolistic Competition Model". Manuscript, University of Toronto. Trefler, D. 39 CES Appendix 1 Data Description : Our sample consists of 76 countries which for we have complete annual data over the period 1960-1997 required to construct income growth and terms of trade We growth. measure per capita income growth as the sum growth plus growth of real the terms of trade. Data on real per capita in per capita GDP GDP growth are drawn from the Penn World Tables and are extended through 1997 using per capita GDP growth constant local currency units from the World Bank World in Development We construct growth Indicators. the terms of trade as the growth in in the local currency national accounts deflator for exports multiplied by the share of GDP in current prices adjusted for differences less the growth in the local currency national account deflator for imports multiplied exports in by the share of imports purchasing power in parity. GDP in in purchasing power current prices adjusting for differences trade volatility in Data on import and export deflators and current price trade shares are from the World Bank World Development Indicators, and factors are from the parity, Penn World Tables. Prior to PPP conversion computing income and terms of and comovement, we discard 33 country-year observations constituting about 1 percent of the sample where measured growth in the terms of trade exceeds 20 percent. Each of these cases occurs during episodes of very high where growth inflation in very noisy signal of true The oil movements is a dummy variable all other countries This variable is in one the World if the country the World variable Bank World Development we of classified a weighted average of countries' distances Romer to their bilateral trade. (1999). Data on revolutions coups are taken from the Banks (1979) dataset. The standard deviation computed as the standard deviation is Bank World Development where the weights are proportional taken from Frankel and extreme and provides a from the following sources. Primary taking the value is is import and export prices. exporter or a commodity exporter Indicators. Trade-weighted distance from in control variables are obtained product exporter as an the import and export deflators growth rates of the Indicators. GDP and of inflation is deflator taken from To avoid extreme outliers in this discard 204 country-year observations constituting seven percent of the 40 sample where inflation exceeds 100 percent per year computing the standard prior to deviation of inflation. The data are Appendix 2: section in five. *F p we compute the world equilibrium =JJJ P P p , V model x~ Xv (1 - 8) e (1+X) {n ~ n) - K p p =Pp, Tpis constant over time. This D If p p =P p and k—>0 in all corresponding constant of the real model general model of section for *F l • • dF dG dH • • J, of section four. problem the model with transport Define the following object: D If in nV +Xv f (A1) upon request. Equilibrium Prices with Transport Costs appendix, In this costs available from the authors in is the case studied countries, ¥. section two. in the monetary simplifies to the We show next that in the the world equilibrium can be computed as a fixed-point five, . p First, we derive a relationship that ensures that international prices clear world markets, for a given set of domestic prices. Equating the the a- and (3-industries, ratio of world spending in v , to the ratio of the value of their productions, 1-v fffp a I se' dFdGdH we find that Equation (11) is still valid, provided we use the JjJpp-u-e'-dF-dG-dH 1+X-v definition of Y p write Equation in Equation (A1). Define Z (1 1) as follows: 41 e An . Then, we can re- (A2) Yo=Ta -Z ( where *F„ e H — — e e-1 1 -5 e e-1, 9 N _. (n-ri) dFdG e as , in the text. This equations defines J v a linear relationship between Tp and Z that has a simple economic interpretation: — Pb Taking as given the set of domestic prices (remember that the distribution of is PP implicit in T p ), P — P Equation (A1) describes the international prices (remember that P implicit in Z) that equilibrate Second, we world markets. derive a relationship that ensures that domestic prices clear domestic markets, for given international prices. To do in assume first P-products are nontraded goods. Then, equating the (|a,S,7i,K,i)-country spending this, the a- and (3-industries, v , to the ratio of the income that in the ratio of of both 1-v D industries, 1 p -s-e' ^ p°-u-e* , we find that: 110-1 (A3) ^= Z- " .9 -(1-5) V, Xv»V " This domestic price of p-products holds exceeds the price at which domestic does not exceed the price at (3-firms which firms in in can the equilibrium sell if and only if: (i) it P-products abroad; and (ii) it goods sector can purchase final P- products abroad. These conditions define three sets of countries: X(Z), N(Z), M(Z). 1 We say that (n,8,7t,K,i)e M(Z) if and only if z • —— Xv t" 42 9-1 1 IT/ fl C A+O fi -(1-8) e 1+Xv A 1+Xv *' < 1 . We is . 1 also say that N(Z) (u.,5,:n:,K,i)e if and only if <z 1 e-1 1 .„e .5 xj/e 1 a T" _A±^. (Tt _ n )-^. K1 e ItAv Xv 1 8-1 X+8~' Finally, (n,8,7i,K,i)eX(Z) and only if T if ^<z- ^1 t-' the membership of membership of the different the membership of with Z. M(Z) i+av non-increasing is G(n-n) and groups varies only with The membership Z depending on With e _ Kl i+xv . ,. Define -(1-5) distribution functions F((j.,5,k), the in - a group as the fraction of countries of each type that belongs to each group. Since the decreasing X , , (7l-n) 5 tA " v < X 1+Xv -(1-5) 1 ' 1+Xv in H(i) are constant, Z. In particular, Z and the membership of N(Z) could increase, we have of X(Z) is that non- decrease or stay constant the distribution of country characteristics. we can hand, this notation at write the relative prices of (3-products that as a function of Z as follows: _1+Xv vpe '9 T 2 (A4) .5 u u e9 .X 11 . . *+8 6 M- ct -X-v M(Z) if (|i,5,7i,K,i)e if (n,5,7t,K,l)6N(Z) if (n J 8,7i,K,i)eM(Z) 6-1 2 1 1+i-v , c * „, n-n) ki 1+Xv 1+Xv (1-§) Equation (A4) also has a simple economic interpretation: Taking as given international prices, this equation describes the set of domestic markets. Substituting Equation (A4) Y p = - 8) e {UX)in ' n) - K ' • JJJ(1 • into Equation (A1) dF dG dH + • • X(Z) e-1 1 1 (A5) +wyZ^[L Q -6 v e-1 v dFdG + e~ N(Z) +t • JJJ(1 - 6) e (1+x >("-n)-K -i dF dG dH . . M(Z) 43 domestic prices that equilibrate we find: . Equation (A5) defines a function Yp = Tp(Z) that * Y decreasing and bounded: lim lim ^= x - • constant T y = f f|(i p x| • e (1+X) (n- n) - Kl is + • continuous and non- e WH»*)-™ dF • • • dG dH • and > - obtained by crossing (A2) and (A5). That is, the refer to in the text is implicitly defined by: - 5) e < 1+A H«-n)-K • . dF dG dH + . . Ie VV " 19 jjl V X e ! ! (A6) 5) dF dG dH < • equilibrium we that JjJ(1 ' 5) JJJ(1 The world - = p is ' - 59 " -l (n -n) e6 dFdG + N|^ +T ' JlfC _8 > • e (1+M(It - nhKl • dF dG dH • • M It is unique. In degree of straightforward to the text, show we assume smoothness that this is an equilibrium the case. This is exists. But it equivalent to imposing enough to the distribution functions F(|li,8,k), G{n-Yl) 44 might not be and H(i). . — CO t o LJJ c o T3 O .^ Q_ CO := EiS c o TO O 3 CO > o cz CO o _ CD <? O c _ CQ ' =5 .c g S *co TTi co — ^ CD oi f; .3 * c > o I CD cd O CO CD ^ .^J - oc — -Q r- co >CD co > ^§2?£ E 0) > o £ o 11Jf £» § »2 c £ o £1 o> <- fc -5 -2 sP £§.£ CO ,_ CD S E E O o > LU o CO E CO > £ .2 o z> CO Q- u O *c5 CO O CO CO fc CD CD > "O co 1= CO CD "a JC0 CD ® £ > O CO i_ lD c TO i: o iii r° g-o Z ^ «50)O o £ m "D TD CO c .t CO cq oj CO "O m co co 55 o *-L. O ^- "aj co CO o o c O _ CL*; .y c-" co en O _ 3 CO x 5 CD CJ u5 CD =§ C CD E O -o CD O ~ a> Cl O g - o .9O CO^ Q. cd - -a — ^" oio — c*O yCD a> O co _ C CD CD <*> CD CD > c£ co z> >_ cCO "O o cd cd B o t: o o o o *~ CD ,g> co oj — o> Old] f~ -C co t: CD co co o o D_ > "o .2 CO E JZ 3 O ~ E 2Z Q. _ C ^ is o >> CO c CO CO CO m ° c "CO CD §-£ ° CO IX n . > £ O °-5 CD co 'J= CD co O >CD ro a_c _ o (0 > "B - a> CD^8 0) _o >. I 8 CO o ac u, !"§ ffl c C CO CO -f- ffl . ' s o cm ti; *- == >r £1o CL Q. Q_ "co Q_ Q O co a. CO U tr 0. D- a. 75 LU Q_ CD o X o O "O nj 3 o a. & o. m o ^ co JS ir CD ^^ > 5 CO .t; £ ! o - o -» CO £ ® S tr o CO sUJ o o CD o F Q. oo CD CO ct -° <-> & ro E? O ZJ CO ? = CO CD 3 -O CO E or z 3 S 5 i o CD o o u o o o = o CD C C C C • co Q. CO CO CO CO r Table 2: Calibrations Cross-Country Differences in Volatility and Comovement Terms Volatility ComovemRnt Volatility Growth Comovement -0.026 0.382 0.009 0.037 Income Growth of Trade Empirical Point Estimate Theoretical, Basic e Model X CO cxt oo 0.35 0.7 2 2 2 0.35 0.7 1.2 1.2 1.2 0.35 0.7 a Vn 0.04 0.40 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.03 0.38 -0.005 0.047 0.001 2.000 0.37 -0.009 0.078 0.002 2.000 0.05 0.31 -0.011 0.098 0.012 0.000 0.04 0.30 -0.016 0.129 0.010 0.343 0.04 0.31 -0.019 0.149 0.009 0.623 0.06 0.25 -0.025 0.186 0.026 0.000 0.05 0.25 -0.027 0.200 0.020 0.171 0.04 0.26 -0.028 0.208 0.016 0.330 0.03 Theoretical, Monetary Model with K (x)= =i.i-x,4> =0.1 e CO 0.04 0.40 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 =o 0.35 0.03 0.38 -0.015 0.108 0.001 2.000 oo 0.7 0.03 0.37 -0.038 0.189 0.002 2.000 0.05 0.31 -0.011 0.098 0.012 0.000 2 2 0.35 0.04 0.30 -0.024 0.165 0.010 0.343 2 0.7 0.04 0.31 -0.045 0.219 0.009 0.623 0.06 0.25 -0.025 0.186 0.026 0.000 1.2 1.2 0.35 0.05 0.25 -0.034 0.219 0.020 0.171 1.2 0.7 0.04 0.26 -0.052 0.249 0.016 0.330 This table compares empirical differences in volatility and comovement of real income growth (left panel) and terms of trade growth (right panel) with the predictions of the basic model of Section 2 (top panel) and the model with monetary shocks of Section 4 (bottom panel). The first row reports the estimated difference in volatility and comovement between the richest countries in the sample (with log per capita GDP = 9.5) poorest countries in the sample (with log per capita GDP = 6.5), based on the regressions with controls in Tables 1 and 3. The remaining rows report the predictions of the model for the difference in volatility and comovement between a rich country (with x=0.6) and a poor country (with x=0. 1 ), for the indicated parameter values. Table Volatility 3: and Comovement of Terms of Trade Growth Volatility Basic With Controls With Controls, Nonlinearities Coef Std.Err Coef Std.Err Coef Std.Err 0.023 0.013 -0.034 0.013 -0.048 0.030 0.000 0.002 0.003 0.001 0.005 0.004 Primary Product Exporter 0.004 0.003 0.005 0.003 Trade-Weighted Distance 0.006 0.002 0.006 0.002 -0.007 0.010 -0.008 0.010 0.145 0.020 0.138 0.025 Intercept ln(Per Capita GDP Revolutions and at PPP) Coups Std.Dev. Inflation Dummy for Rich Countries 0.036 0.043 Dummy for Rich Countries x -0.004 0.006 ln(Per Capita GDP at PPP) R-Squared Number of Observations 0.002 0.565 0.570 76 76 76 Comovement 0.004 0.159 -0.026 0.252 0.062 0.419 0.014 0.020 0.012 0.028 -0.001 0.060 Primary Product Exporter -0.001 0.063 0.012 0.064 Trade-Weighted Distance 0.018 0.028 0.021 0.028 0.032 0.221 0.058 0.238 -0.089 0.427 -0.318 0.478 Intercept ln(Per Capita GDP Revolutions and Std.Dev. at PPP) Coups Inflation Dummy for Rich Countries 0.644 0.775 Dummy for Rich Countries x -0.068 0.096 ln(Per Capita GDP at PPP) R-Squared Number of Observations 0.005 0.012 0.036 76 76 76 This table reports the results of cross-sectional regressions of the standard deviation of terms of trade growth (top panel) and the correlation of terms of trade growth with world average income growth excluding the country in question (bottom panel) on the indicated variables, for different samples and control variables. Poor (rich) countries refer to countries below (above) median per capita GDP. In the columns labelled 1960-79 and 198097 volatility and comovement are calculated over the indicated subperiods. The control variables consist of a dummy variable which takes the value one if the country is an oil or commodity exporter, a measure of tradeweighted distance from trading partners, the average over the period of the number of revolutions or coups, the standard deviation of inflation, a dummy for countries with income greater than the median, and an interaction of this dummy with per capita GDP. See Appendix for data definitions and sources. Standard errors are heteroskedasticity-consistent. *** (**) (*) indicate significance at the 1 (5) (10) percent level. 47 Figure 1 and Comovement Volatility : Volatility 0.14 - y = -0.0133X + 0.1612 n rwa £- 0.12 R2 = - D D NGA S o D 3 o.i TCO D COG - D CD D E § 0.08 yl^TSTGO Q - D BGD LSO ^D Da MR! S - 0.04 - D MW ' D D „ CAFc > DZA D EMDPER FN D D « ITO LUX pry DN ISL D MYS PR P p WG ISR a9 iKG j^"^^ THA ' f ESP CD 2 D f ^^P*-- GHA CD ft. ft emj^^a 0.06 GAB D MUS NER ' § o 0.2941 GUY aTJWw-., D GT0 ca 0.02 - - 7 6.5 (5 7.5 8 9 8.5 9.5 10 ln(Per Capita Income) Comovement 0.8 - 0.6 - CAN NLD c £ !Io o <d £ 0.4 - arcg E £ 11 Dia DTGO a 0.2 - „ «5o nmo DGIM D Ca D BEN DaC1S dzmb D,HA caf ZAR pD-SHfi _^—— D n - nc* QEEfc D ^ 6b -"" PRY tJSlMNGA CHN rtrP , „ H n M eCLT ,. CCfeEgjAAUS D GRC ( a Q CHL °J^JJa«i ^aWn^ ""TfpRr D "C D RWA T3 «I -0.2 D - D CHE D ARG DZA, 1 o MAR MRT D BDI JPN D 1 I 2 fin Lca«--"0 usa SEQ D IDN y = 0.1 083x- 0.5859 D C0G R2 = 0.2224 BGO a mus -0.4 - 1 5 6.5 7 8 7.5 8.5 9 9.5 10 ln(Per Capita Income) plots the standard deviation of the growth rate of real per capita income over the period 1960-97 against the log-level of average per capita GDP in 1985 PPP dollars over the same period. The bottom panel plots the correlation of the growth rate of real per capita income growth with world average income growth The top panel excluding the country in question over the period 1960-97 against the log-level of average per capita 1985 PPP dollars over the same period. See Appendix for data definitions and sources. 48 GDP in Figure 2: Sample Paths of the Productivity Index Country-Specific Variation Only (11=0) Time Global Variation Only 0i=1) Time Both Country-Specific and Global Variation (0<ii<1) 71 Time Figure 3: Theoretical Volatility and Volatility of Comovement Graphs Income Growth Comovement of Income Growth 0.45 e=°oA=o 0.25 0.1 0.3 0.2 0.4 0.5 0.6 x This figure plots Equations (14) and (15) as a function of x for the indicated values of 6 and X. products in discussed consumption in is set equal to v=0.2 and the parameters the text below. 50 of the productivity The share process are set as of a- — Figure Theoretical 4: Volatility Terms Growth of Trade 8=2A=0^5 -] ^^Z^f 0.02 = . 0.015 of Trade and Comovement Graphs Volatility of 0.025 Terms J 0.01 - 0.005 - /^^^ ^^^ /^^ ^sf^ e=oo,X=0.35 "e^S . i 0.2 i 0.4 i i i 0.6 0.8 1 X Comovement of Terms of Trade Growth 1.0 9=oo,X=0.35 0.5 0=2,^=0.35 0.0 o / o 2 0.4 0.8 0.6 e=2,a=o -0.5 1 &=°°,\=o -1.0 This figure plots Equations (17) and (18) as a function of x for the indicated values of 9 and X. products in discussed consumption in is set equal to v=0.2 and the parameters the text. 51 of the productivity The share process are set as of oc- Figure 5: Volatility and Comovement Terms of of Trade volatility y = -6E-05x + 0.0232 0.07 0.06 R 2 = 2E-05 -| ZAR - D .c GAB s o H o to 1_ 0.05 a - D COGD D ZMB D 8RA LUX ISL ARG 0.04 - D 1- D o <n E 0.03 - DTGO nB^ D ^a 1 U11U D RWA D HTI D NGA D TCD - n 2 - 0.01 n D D D "• ,,,,„ MWI CHL cPeK. a a i > 0.02 GUY CAF 1— 55 D ISR PER ( D c D rjpNBSYi D ^ , ««i ^i TTO ury t|tvft il.KQ? Ba i a slv PRY D JAM IRL a^-SW .. a zaf DEW O MEX nratft£ WE esp n «*"n MAR Ca „ Q BEN EJ-i^M D MDG D BGD KEN a n jpn EK<BNK atW,B AUS a can D USA CHN , 8 7.5 6.5 , 8.5 10 9.5 ln(Per Capita Income) comovement 0.6 PHL 0.5 D % 2 o o> T3 CO (A ° 0.4 o <u Q- C E o I- <u D 0.2 0.1 TO ° 2 BDI DBEN DQV D CAF -I D D ZAO a mwi D D NER TCD D NIC ™D^ SEN D NGA ° IDN a S n D RWA D M D ca -0.1 -0.2 ZAF MDG 0.3 -co. o D MYS n GRC PEC3 E O u n isl THA 2MB D URY D PRT a n D %w<. u a fin^ D FRA R f&p a "^ ODjmS I^can rft^E ^ JAM cat? DZA D ECU NZL isr BEL KCR Q a a CRI ffifc4§ft> n ARG USA BGD mMAFY MEX ° MRT D TTO a a mus -0.3 che = 0.01 39x + 0.0035 6.5 7.5 8 8.5 R *M0056 : 10 ln(Per Capita Income) plots the standard deviation of the growth rate of terms of trade over the period 1960-97 against the log-level of average per capita GDP in 1985 PPP dollars over the same period. The bottom panel plots the correlation of the growth rate of the terms of trade with world average income growth excluding the country in question over the period 1960-97 against the log-level of average per capita GDP in 1985 PPP dollars over the same period. See Appendix for data definitions and sources. The top panel 52 Date Due ^ 4/ ^ Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02246 1096