m.l.T. UBRAR^ES - DEWEY Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/accesspricingcomOOIaff Cewe\ HB31 .M415 working paper department of economics ACCESS PRICING AND COMPETITION Jean-Jaques Laffont Jean Tirole 94-31 July 1994 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 ACCESS PRICING AND COMPETITION Jean-Jaques Laffont Jean Tirole 94-31 July 1994 Access Pricing and Competition^ Jean- Jacques Laffont^and Jean Tirole^ July "We thank Jerry Hausman and John 6, 1994 Vickers for helpful comments. Unstitut Universitaire de France, and Institut d'Economie Industrielle, Toulouse, France ^Institut bridge, d'Economie MA USA Industrielle, Toulouse, France; CERAS, Paris; and MIT, Cam- Abstract In many industries (electricity, telecommunications, railways), the network can be described as a natural monopoly. A central issue is how to combine the necessary regulation of the network with the organization of competition in activities which use the network as an input and are potentially competitive (generation of electricity, valueadded services, road transportation). In this paper we derive access-pricing formulas in the framework of an optimal regulation under incomplete information. First, we study how access-pricing formulas take into account the fixed costs of the network and the incentive constraints of the natural monopoly over the network. Second, we examine the difficulties coming from the accounting impossibility to disentajigle costs of the network and costs of the monopoly's competitive goods. Third, the analysis is extended to the cases where governmental transfers are prohibited, where the competitors have market power, and where competitors are not regulated. Fourth, the possibility some consumers bypass the network is taken into account. Finally the role of access pricing for inducing is assessed. The conclusion summarizes our the best market structure results and suggests avenues of further research. Introduction 1 many In scribed industries (electricity, telecommunications, railways), the network can be de- cLS a natural monopoly. However, many activities which use the network as an input are potentially competitive (generation of electricity, value added services, road transportation). A central issue is how to work with the organization of competition Two different types of policies combine the necessary regulation of the netin those activities. can be observed. In the USA, the local network mo- nopolies in the telephone industry have been prevented from entering the value added markets as well as the long distance market because of the Department of Justice's belief that in is it impossible to define access rules to the network which create those markets'*. The argument here is that the network to provide unfair advantages to R superior quality of access, D iS2 cost auditing. In the language of it is its subsidies...) competition too easy for the monopoly in charge of own products even if (favorable access charges, subsidieiries are created to modern regulatory economics, asymmetries between the regulator and the monopoly are so large that tion fair fair improve of informa- competition is not possible. The alternative policy of defining access charges common. The long also (BT) to reach market. The and regulatory choice of the access charges regulatory review of 1991, its European Community BT is BT in the long distance complex. For instance, in the has argued that the current setting of access charges creates competitor (Cave (1992)). Note also that it is the goal of the to define "reasonable" access charges to organize the competition of electricity generation in Europe. Other examples of computer reservation systems and gas It is difficult is distance operator Mercury pays access charges to British Telecom consumers through the local loops and compete with unfair advantages for monopoly compete letting the activities with regulated access are pipelines. to appraise the difficulties of regulating access if all the imperfections of regulatory processes are taken into account simultaneously. In this paper, we start from an optimal benevolent regulation of a network monopoly facing a competive fringe in the potentially competitive markets focus and we successively introduce various imperfections. To on access we neglect the relevant incorporated into our modeling. policy. a first of a The modeling step, we choose of the costs to focus more general theory in issue of network externalities, which could be easily Perhaps more importantly, we ignore the divestiture and benefits of on the vertical integration is complex, and, in vertically integrated structure as a building block which breakups might be desirable. '"DOJ... did not believe chat judicial and regulatory rules could be effective in preventing amonopolist from advantaging an affiliate that provided competitive products and services" Noll (1989). , The existing theoretical Uterature on network access pricing includes two papers build- on contestable markets theory. Willig (1979) studies interconnection by competing ing He suppUers. may stresses the fact that strategic behavior deter socially beneficial entry (for example to expand regulation) and analyses the extent to its lead the network operator to rate base under rate of return which Ramsey pricing market structure. Baumol (1983) discusses similar is compatible with the best issues in the framewTark of railroad ac- cess pricing. Vickers (1989) addresses the access pricing issue within the model of regulation under incomplete information. monopoly (network plus integrated sector of services with commodity services) with the case of in particular a vertically an imperfectly competitive and without participation of the network operator. Section 2 describes the model. olized He compares Baron- Myerson A monopoly operates a network. (for concreteness, local telephone), as well It produces a monop- another conmaodity (long distance telephone) which faces a competitively produced imperfect substitute. The long distance operators require access to the local network in order to reach the final consumers. That the potentially competitive market needs to use the monopolized commodity as is, The purpose an input. access. We start of the paper is normative theory of how to price to develop a by postulating that the regulator has complete information and faces a social cost for public funds associated with the deadweight loss of taxation. must then exceed marginal price deficit. Equivalently, access The access cost in order to contribute to the reduction of the overall can be priced at marginal cost and a tax levied on access. Sec- tion 3 studies the impact of the regulator's incomplete information about the monopoly's cost structure for a further any, is meant on the monopoly's informational Incomplete information rents. departure from marginal cost pricing of access. The may call further distortion, if to reduce the monopoly's rent. Section 4 explores conditions under which the observability of the monopoly's subcosts, namely the cost related to the monopolized good and the The analysis ceive any its cost related to the competitive is extended good respectively, improves social welfare. in Section 5 to the case where the monopoly does not monetary transfer from the regulator and therefore must cover revenue. The access charge is cost with then higher or lower than in the absence of a firm-level budget constraint, depending on whether the monopoly's fixed cost 6 generalizes our access pricing formula to the case in is its re- is high or low. Section which the substitute commodity produced by a competitor with market power rather than by a competitive industry and Section 7 considers the case in competitive segment at all which the regulator has no mandate to regulate the (including the production of the competitive good by the monopoly.) Sections 6 and 7 emphasize the complexity of regulating a competitive segment with limited instruments. when consumers Limitations on regulatory instruments are particularly penalizing of the competitive commodity can bypass the use of the monopolized good The determination (local telephone). of the access price conflicting goals of limiting inefficient bypass it approximate the efficient level of off the and of contributing to budget balance (be the State's or the firm's). Unless the regulator distance market to raise funds to cover the must then trade is able to simultaneously tax the long firm.'s fixed cost and use the access charge to bypass, only a rough balance between these objectives can be achieved. The separation of the regulatory function from the teixation authorities creates serious difficulties in the presence of bypEiss (Section 8). Section 9 links the determination of the access charge with the choice of a market structure and with the promotion of entry in the competitive segment. ponent pricing rule recently advocated by some economists is The efficient com- assessed in the light of our normative treatment. Section 10 compares the theoretical precepts with two regulatory practices, namely the British Telecom. fully allocated cost method and the Oftel access pricing rule for summary of our analysis and discusses The Conclusion provides a brief avenues of further research. The Model 2 A monopoly operates a network with Co Q where of c.d.f. effort F{.) With > /3 is , on [^, ^] : Coeo < Cog , > 0, (1) a parameter of productivity, and a level eo exerted by the firm in operating the network. with a is private information of the firm strictly positive density function /. rate assumption {jg[F{0)/f{l3)] > We make ; l3 has the classical 0]). the network the firm produces a quantity ^o of a monopolized telephone). let Co0 , a parameter of adverse selection which monotone hazard and Co{^,eo,Q) the level of network activity, nonmonetary ,3 is a is = cost function commodity (local Let us assume that ^o units of this commodity require qo units of network S{qo) be consumers' utility for this good, with S' The monopoly produces also a good 1 > 0, S" < 0. (long distance telephone) in quantity qi. This other production has an imperfect substitute produced in quantity 92 by a competitive fringe. Let V{qi,q2) be consumers' utility for these two commodities. In addition to the network input the production of Ci where ex is = good 1 also generates a cost (2) Ci(/i,ei,9i) the effort e.xerted to reduce the cost of producing good 1. The disutility of effort is i/;(eo + ej) with 0' > 0, 0" > and > ^p'" 0. In addition to the network input the production of c common is good 2 generates a cost cq2 where knowledge. Because we wish to focus on the network monopoly's incentive to provide access, we need not Total network activity investigate incentive issues in the fringe. therefore is Q= ?o + ?i + 92- Let a denote the access unit charge The paid by the competitive fringe to the monopoly. fringe's level of profit is then : n = P292 - cq2 - aq-i. (3) Under complete information, the utiUtarian regulator observes and effort levels. lator. We make Let t prices, quantities, costs, denote the net transfer received by the monopoly from the regu- the accounting convention that the regulator reimburses costs, receives directly the revenue from the sale of the competitive good and network good to the con- sumers, and that the firm receives the access charges. This obviously involves no loss of generality. The monopoly's utility level then is : U = - iPieo + ei) + aq2. t The 1 -f- regulator must raise A (where A S{qo) + > t + Co + Ci— poqo — pi^i (4) with a shadow price of public funds because of distortive tcixation). The consumers'/taxpayers' utiUty V{qi,q2) - poqo - Pi?i - /'2?2 - + (1 ^){i + Co + Ci - poqo - Piqi). is (5) Under complete information an utiUtarian regulator would maximise f'>)+fi)^ (^) -_ S{qo) + V{qi,q2) - Poqo - Pl9i - P2?2 - + [t- 0(eo + ei) + aqz] (1 + + A)(< P292 + Co + Ci - poqo - Pi9i) - cq2 - a^j] (6) under the individual rationality (IR) constraints of the monopoly and the fringe U= t-ri;{eo n= P292 - + ei) C92 — + aq2>0 (7) > (8) a<}2 0. Since public funds are costly, the monopoly's IR constraint can be rewritten is binding and social welfare + 5(^0 ) - + (1 Similarly, raising V{qi,q2) + A)(0(eo ei) Apo9o Api9i The (9), social S{qo) - (1 + A)(^(eo Assuming that S and is + V + + ?i + gj) + Ci{/3,ei,qi)). access charge = is ei) + p2 — (10) + Coil3,eo,qo are concave + Piqi + P2q-i) A(po?o + qi + ?2) + = ^^-=^ = = Pi - ^°Q 172 1 + ei) we can write ^J_ I 1 + + A (?7l^2 7/2 = -Ci,,. = ^70 a-nd '7i'72 + T}\'n2 + 72=772 dm = — r^ Pi uPi '7. . -^12'72l) (13) At/x -Co«o Straightforward computations show that ^0 (12) 7/0 - ^1.1 ^ = (11) in {eQ,ei,qi,Q), optimal are (respectively) the price superelasticities of goods 0, 1, 2, 0'(eo , + cgj). r^^ +A P2 771, C'i(/3,ei,gi) and Co and Ci convex Pi 77 chosen to saturate the fringe's IR characterized by the first-order conditions, that ^ , valuable (see c. ^'O where is (9) welfare takes the final form V{qi, q2) Lo 770, cq2 : Substituting (10) in where + Xaq2 - the access charge from the fringe a regulation + Co{/3,eo,qo money through the term Xaq2 in social welfare). constraint + + and (15) ^^ (,f•^ <T]2 ['') '7i'7i2 ; '72721 = '?.; 1^- J^^ The benchmark i , = l,2 pricing rules are = z , Ramsey l,2. > pricing rules because A 0. The access charge can be rewritten ^ n-r Access fi^^^y 2 is (18) priced above marginal cost because deficits are socially costly. is can be viewed as a tax used to raise money. low or when issues raised If P2 a. the social cost of funds is high It is when the high. In the next section elasticity of we address good various by asymmetric information. the regulator has two instruments, the access price and a tax on good (14) can The term + be rewritten a T2 = Cqq + yta^ Furthermore, marginal cost of access. it is 2, r2, equation can obviously be taken equal to the ^.nd a clear that if the regulator had access to a nondistortive (lump sum) tax, marginal cost pricing of commodities and access would be optimal. Access Pricing and Incentives 3 The first issue we consider is the extent to which asymmetric information pricing. Let us consider the case where accounting cifFects access rules enable the regulator to observe separately Co and Ci. Let Eo{t3,CQ,Q) denote the solution in eo of Co the solution in Ci of Ci = t Ci{/3,ei,qi). The {f(/3), which Co(/?), CM, we Co(/5, eo,(5) ^.nd let £'i(/?, Ci,?i) firm's utility + a92-^(^o(/3,Co,g) + .Appealing to the revelation principle = can be written consider a revelation qiih q,{h specifies the transfer received, the sub-costs to produced, and the access price to be received if (19) ^i(/?,Ci,9i)). Qih mechanism m] (20) be realized, the quantities to be the firm announces a characteristic ^. Neglecting momentarily second-order conditions, and using the rent variable ^(^) = i(/3) + a(/?)<72(/3)-V(£'o(/?, Co(/3), Qm + E,{P, Ci(/?), ?i(/?))), monopoly can be written the incentive constraint of the t-(^)=-,'(e„^eO(f.f). Since -g^ > ^> and > (IR) constraint {U{3) the rent 0, decreasing in is down for all /3) boils Ui0) Optimal regulation > and the individual rationaUty to 0. (22) from the maximization, subject to (21) and results {s{qoiPom) +V{q,{pM,pM), I' /3 (21) q,{pri/3), (22), of : pM)) +x[po{i3)qo{pom+pmqi{pm,P2m+P2{0)q2{pm,P2m] -(1 + + We + X)[4^{eoil3) e,m + Co(^,eo(/?),9o(po(y3)) + 9i(pi(^),P2(^)) + 92 (Pi(/?),P2 (/?))) C^{^,e,i|3),q,{p,{0),p,i|3)))+cq,{p^i0),p2m]-XU{0)yF{0). obtain (see appendix 1). Po-CoQ ^ Pi - Cqq - A l + X f F A 1 xh' d Coe{/3,eo,Q) \ f _ Cl^^ A pAoQi X 1 A 771 Co.o(/?,eo,g)i P2-C0Q-C _ P2 J^ + 1 Pi '^ (23) + A F vy_^( w' d f _ A J_ l 172 + 5?i I X f / p^dQX p2dQ Ci,.(/3,ei,5i)/y' CW(/g,eo,g) Coai/3, eo, Q) ^~ ' ^ ^ | Coeo(/3,eo,g)i' All prices are modified by an incentive correction related to the sub-cost function Cq and pi has The an additional correction associated with C\. access charge can now be \ + written X r]2 Let us analyse the new term, which that there is no correction for 1 is + A / dQl Coeo J due to incentive constraints. the most efficient tv-pe as F(/?) = 0. First, we observe Second, ^^ — 3(3 —Coff/Coeo the same is the rate at which the firm must substitute effort and productivity to keep level of cost for the to determine the firm's is The rent. we (21), see that if it is negative. The it is a crucial term regulator wants to Hmit this costly rent. he raises the access price and therefore reduces quantities positive, conversely network acivity. From If ^(-^) to extract rent and on the access charge thus depends on effect of incentives fine characteristics of the cost function. Access charges must be increased (decreased) for incentive reasons of the network Co is <« >- — CoeaQCog > CquqCoco "Spence-Mirrlees"' condition on cost, Copq clear positive sign is obtained if Intuitively, production > and our previous assumptions, a marginal cost. However, effort increases the is must be decreased (increased) increases (decreases) the "ability" of the firm to 0- (<) reasonable, effort decreases the marginal cost, the effect terms, the cost function such that >« With the if lie about if, as is more ambiguous. if an increase Q in the level of its characteristics (in elasticity the quantity elasticity of the marginal effect on cost of the productivity charac- if teristics is larger (smaller) than the quantity elasticity of the marginal effect on cost of effort). From Leontief 's theorem charge (and on good 1) we know^ disappears iff Co If there furthermore Ci is is in addition that the incentive effect there exists a function ( such that = Com,eo),Q). separable in on the access (/3, (28) on the one hand, and ej) no incentive distortion on any commodity : qi on the other hand, the dichotomy between pricing rules (unaffected) and the cost reimbursement rules (see below) holds. The access pricing rule can then be rewritten : "^ a = Cog (29) -r 1 Note that Pi ~ Cqq — Oiqi _ + Hi A^2 a P2 Pi It is also possible to find conditions conclusions for the incentive correction — Cqq on the cost function that yield nonambiguous when it exists. For instance, the following class of cost functions leads to a well defined sign of the incentive correction in the access charge ^From Leontief s iheorem we know that ^^^ independent function ^(.) such that (20) holds (see Laffont-Tirole (1990a)). 10 of Q is : equivalent to the existence of a cnl> Co=/3Q'-elQ If d > b{d < now Let us 6), the inceatiye correction consider the effort levels (in the case of dichotomy) obtained by maximizing under (21) and (23) positive (negative). is (22) with respect to (eo,ei). V''(eo 2AF O + A)/ (eo + e,) ei) + ei) -Coeo = (eo Equations (30) and (31) can be interpreted + eO^^^Coeo (30) -Ciei dEi\ .fdEo \ ,,. = (^ + ^j + ^'(eo 2XF + We obtain cis ,,, cost , ^ d'^E^ reimbursement (31) rules. If the con- ditions underlying the irrelevance of subcost observability (see Section 4) hold, one can obtain sufficient conditions for the optimal contract to be implementable through a gle menu of linear sharing rules share of the total cost which is ^ = A — B{Cq reimbursed. -h Ci) where B = From (30), (31), and F{0^ the most efficient type receives from the regulator a tract) and equates its disutility lump sum = tp'^^ = V''fc^ we 0, is sin- the see that transfer (fixed price con- of effort to the marginal cost reduction as under complete information. REMARKS 1. - for The most relevant cost functions seem to be such that higher production levels call higher effort levels and therefore induce higher rents. Incentive considerations raise marginal costs and therefore indirectly call for a general reduction of quantities. Access prices are increased for the competitor but simultaneously the high prices for its own product and own the competitor's, the current model misrepresentation. efficiency of its this link 2. - If is is products. Because access costs are the The may is penalized by for the monopoHst's monopoly same understate the incentives for firm cannot claim simultcineously high access costs and high own products (see Laffont-Tirole (1993, Chapter 5) for an example where suppressed). the fringe is not regulated but is competitive, the same results obtain ; p2 = a + c then ensured by competition rather than by the existence of a shadow cost of public funds. 11 3. Let us consider implementation of the optimal revelation mechanism with the follow- - ing specification : = CQ Ho{l3-eo)iqo Ci The where now includes t - ,32) i7:(/3-ei)9i. (33) monopoly can be rewritten objective function of the m = + qi + q2) V( - V.(2/3 V yqa the access charge. ^^\ + + q^J) - ^r^(-)) \q\Jy qi The second-order (34) condition of incentive compat- ibility is and the revelation mechanism The price firm now is equivalent to a nonUnear reward function is free to choose its access charge but and the quantity of good {&s well 1 access price defined in formula (27) since same weighted An cost, which determines alternative implementation Co, Ci, production levels ^ot the conditional demand is cis good it is indifferent 2, 92 = ^2(911 it chooses. for e.xample) service (good 1) which selects the level of among is c-|- a) = -Q + = prices leading to the Col,i3,eo,Q) -iqi -HCi(/?,ei,9i). 12 For this purpose consider and substitute in (36). It some unobservable action : Ci all decreasing in the access charge raises the cost for the network, Co will affect the can be advised to choose the picks. it easy to check that the transfer received by the firm vestment it obtained by writing the transfer as a function of costs function of good Suppose that the monopoly knows that its rent. is 4. - It 2). and access charge a ?i it : i (an in- but decreases the cost of its Under complete information the optimal investment = is i level, which minimizes total cost, qi/Q. Under incomplete information, the moral hazard constraint on investment is or qidEJdCr QdEo/dCo' To decrease the Co and Ci, (implying exist may |^ 7^ rent of asymmetric information the regulator, use cost reimbursement rules with different rates |^) and this may who observes both for sharing overruns lead to a distortion of investment (which would not the regulator were not observing separately sub-costs Co and Ci as in the next if section). If 1 i is too low (too high), the access price good (favor 2) and may be viewed by is to foster is increased (decreased) in order to favor good an increase (decrease) of investment. the firm as a nonrecognition of On low access charge investment costs in the network. its indeed low to decrease those types of investment which 4 A may be It excessive. Sub- Cost Observability Section 3 derived the optimal regulation under the assumption that the regulator could audit the costs of the regulated monopoly from the cost of the commodity produced Using Ck instead of A e^ in the well enough to separate the cost of the network in the competitive sector. optimization leading to (30) and (31), we have high-powered scheme on activity k corresponds to a case where the transfer received by the firm is highly dependent on cost Ck, i.e. where ( — |f^) is high. Indeed if ^ is high in absolute value, marginal cost reductions on activity k per unit of effort are small and therefore the firm is already induced to exert a large effort on activity for further reference that if the cross If terms ^^ vanish sub-costs are not observable, the firm minimizes chooses {cfc} or, equivalently {Ck}, so as to minimize 13 k. Also, note the terms (-ffj-) are equal. its effort for any cost ELo ^k{/3, Ck, Qk) target. subject to Co It + = C Ci (with the convention = Q,Qi = Qo Hence, in the absence of sub-cost 9i)- observation the marginal effort levels to reduce sub-costs {—-g^) are equahzed®. Whether the on the in the ca^e of sub-cost observability hinges that this expression is /? determinant of the firm's rent. no point and If different activities ^^ cross-partiiil derivatives A in absolute value proportional to g^ which the firm can substitute rate, there is on regulator wants to give differentiated incentives effort in activity k (see -^ ). (note measures the rate at Section 3) and it is the main the level of cost or the level of effort does not affect this in using sub-cost observability to try to affect the firm's allocation of effort to minimize cost in order to reduce rents. More formally, let us subject to Cq + =C Ci solution to the system { assume that the minimization of has a unique solution |^ = |^ ejt for all {k,i) = total effort Ek{0, C', + Ci and Co =C Solving for the optimal regulation we obtain (see appendix 2) Under sub-cost observability the firm faces uniform incentives ii) is useless if This result d^Ek/dCkd^ tells •£^fc(/?, is Ck, Qk) the unique }. : : the firm faces higher incentives i) HJ-q Qq, Qi), which = on those on activities for all activities K for all k which low costs reduce rents and therefore sub-cost observability and some constant K. us that the incentive constraints of the firm are identical with or without sub-cost observability when d^Ek/dCkd/3 = constant for k = the optimal pricing rules and in particular the optimal access pricing 0,1. Consequently unaffected in this is case by sub-cost unobservability. A characterization of the subclass of cost functions satisfying the sub-cost-irrelevance property with that K = is all k, the subcost functions must be such : ,^^ = 0for/t = 0.1 ^ for For easily obtained. some functions Hk and Gk On for i- ek = = 0, 1 Ek{P,Ck,Qk) and, since Ce^ = < Hki0,Qk) 0, Cjt = the other hand, recall that the dichotomy property holds Ck = Ck{W.tk),Qk) for A; = + Gk{Ck,Qk) Ck{Qk, Hk{0, Qk)-tk)- when : 0,1. costs evaluated "'Then, the theory of access pricing is similax to the one of Section 3 but for marginal observable. not at the effort levels induced by the incentive scheme defined when sub-costs are 14 These related conditions are dQk different. 00 \ The dichotomy ' dCkd/3 dQk J requires dQkd/3 while the irrelevance of sub-cost observation requires d^Ek = dCkd0 The satisfies class of cost functions the sub-cost irrelevance property for any dk, b^ (with Ckq^ property for dk On Kiora.\[k. = > 0) and the dichotomy 6^ only. the other hand, Ck{0-,tk,qk) = ^ satisfies the dichotomy property but not the sub-cost irrelevance property. Optimal Access Pricing ernment Transfers 5 We now us for cLssume that the regulator is prohibited from transferring example consider a constant returns irrelevance of subcost observability hold Co and let cq = i/o(/5 — eo) Cx , = = Hq{0 to scale case - eo)(9o + <7i(Pi,a to the firm. Let where the dichotomy and the + 9i + 92) fixed cost for notational simplicity). Under symmetric information, the budget constraint -co(<7o(Po) money : Hi{0 — ti) (we omit the Po<?o(Po) Absence of Gov- in the + Pi9i(Pi, a + c) + c)-h92(Pi,a + 15 of the monopoly is + 092(^1,0 + c) c)) - Ci9i(pi, a -f- c) - > i 0, (38) where t must now be interpreted consumer charges The = — [so if as the firm's manager's v{eo t + compensation and is paid from ei)). regulator wishes to maximize, for each value of Cq, Cj, f, social welfare : S{qo{po))+V(^qi{pi,a + c),q2{pi,a + c}j-poqQ{pQ)-piqi{pi,a + c)-{a+c)q2{pi,a + c) + U subject to constraint (38) (where U the firm's welfare). is Under asymmetric information, the U{I3) leads to the incentive = m - rPieom + e^m, and individual rationality constraints U{|3) = -^J;'{eo{^) > U{0) The budget constraint is, for each -co{qoipom + The qi{px{i3),a{0) ci9i(pi(,3), a{0) regulator's optimization + c) = program is j-0 max f [5(9o(po(3))) + : + e^m (39) (40) 0. : Po{0)qo{pom+Px{l3)qi{pm,ai0) - namely firm's rent, V(?i(pi(/3),a(/3) + c) + <i(/3)92(pi(/?),a(/3) + c) + c) t/(/?) + + q2{pi{0),a{l3) 0(eo(/?) + + c)) (41) e,{/3)). : + c),g2(pi(;9),a(/3) + c)) - Po(^)9o(M/5)) l0 -Pi(/?)9i(pi(/3),a(^) s.t. + c) -P2(^)92(pi(/3),a(^) + c) + W)]^W) (39), (40), (41). Let /^(/?) be the Pontryagin multiplier of the state variable multiplier of the budget constraint. Optimizing over prices as in Section 2 with sality condition /z(^) U and we obtain (1 the '\{,d) replacing A. Using the Pontryagin principle = we have 0, 16 + \{/3))f{P) the same equations and the transver- Optimizing over effort levels we get finally : and When the ^^^^^ (i+A)/U dichotomy does not hold, formulae similar to those of Section 3 are obtained replaced by jr\0)md0 (l + A(;3))/(^)' In particular the access pricing equation becomes (42) Under the assumption of dichotomy, the ratios of Lerner indices are unaffected lack of transfers, but the whole price structure on how binding the budget constraint is. is shifted upwards or downwards depending Consequently, the access charge than in the absence of budget constraint when the fixed cost 6 is is higher (lower) high (low). Access Pricing and Competitor with Market Power Competition for by the in the markets using the network as an input is often imperfect, as is the case competition in long distance telecommunications, or competition in the generation of electricity in England. To account analysis of Section 5 with the for this market power we pursue the balanced- budget same technology (guaranteeing the dichotomy and the irrelevance of sub-cost observation). 17 the competitor has market power and If is unregulated, the mciximization of expected welfare must be carried under the constraint that the competitor chooses price so as to maximize its profit : + P2-^{puP2) - q2iPuP2) From + a)-^{p^,P2) = OJ {c ap2 (43) Cfp2 the first-order condition of this maximization program (see appendix 3) obtain the access pricing rule a : \{,d)p2 P2 = L'oQ we = 1 f P2m^,(^)+Pini2i^{^) 1 (44) < 1 + A(^)lr/^ = 72 75 T]2 Vi'n2-m2r}2\ with l2 Equation (44) • complex, but can be given a natural interpretation. The two terms is the derivatives of the elasticity of in and in pi p2 t^j if 77217712 corrected for market power. > 71(^2 — !)• > budget (reflected in A to A is To explain It demand for 0) calls for a higher final price notice that the this, -). More changes interesting case good (7721 2), = 7712 = 0), the is exceeds the regular superelasticity demand elasticity — effects of 772 772 < if ^2 the need to balance the than in the absence of monopoly monopoly power amounts to a social loss equal times the monopoly's profit P2<}2/V2, OQce the standard subsidy P2<l2/^2 (see (44)) made to offset the increase in p2 (that monopoly expression of in the in the access price) reduces this is, 7/2 Because marginal revenue distortion. However, with dependent demands, there the good 2 describe the In the independent and therefore (assuming a constant power. for on the mark up or monopoly power 1/(1 superelasticity and only demand : ) pi is is monopoly decreasing, an is profit. Hence t/j a second eifect (described by the term < ^2- 77217712 reduced to lower the monopoly profit P2q2/V2- To rebalance consumers' choice between the two substitutes. p2 must also be reduced, and so must be the access charge. If the social welfare function did not include the competitor's profit (an extreme way of depicting the redistribution problem), similar calculations a = ^ CoQ , -I M3) P2 T~~::~ P27i9f7(;^)+Pi7i2af7(;^) 1+A(i)j?2 ".A.n alternative formula would yield would be obtained 7172 if - : + ^_ ^2- '/12'721 a nonlinear access pricing rule was used. conclusion. 18 See the Restricted Regulation 7 In practice, the regulator may be instructed to let (or good and the access set its charges the natured monopoly select his and regulate only the price of the monop- pricing behavior in the "competitive mzirket" olized let) on value added services. This section studies the design of such restricted regulation under simplifying assumptions. a competitive fringe. We an announcement prices Pq{$) /? Telecom price to the network. For instance, France We come free to and consequences back to the case of consider the class of regulatory mechanisms that associate with and a{$). The managerial compensation t{$) defined as a residual by the balanced budget constraint, once efforts Cq Pi is and ej is then and price have been chosen. The monopoly has an additional analysis proceeds as in Section 5 except that the moral hazard variable pi which leads to the first-order equation, that the monopoly's marginal profit be equal to zero = .V/P 91 : + 1^ [p: - Co - ci] -H dpi we make the following assumptions Concavity of profit : ^ c] 0. < : ^¥^ > 0. condition for strategic complementeirity d[qi + j^lpi - Co is - Ci]]/Jp2 > 0. Here, the monopolist also receives income from giving access. for = : Generalized strategic complements The standard - Co 1^ [P2 dpi generahzed strategic complementarity is A sufficient condition strategic complementarity plus the condition that the marginal profit on access increases with p2 (condition that holds with hnear demand and constant Appendix returns to scale). shadow 6 shows that for a given price, the access price is lowered relative to the unrestricted control case, in order to reduce the strategic raises pi. The complementarity for a given On the other hand, monopoly power on good To rebalance the consumers' choice between the two goods, effect of restricted regulation However, pi. monopoly price through (generalized) in the case of linear on the access price demand, for remains the formula of full regulation. 19 is therefore the optimal pi, p2 must be ambiguous 1 raised. in general. the access pricing formula Access Pricing and Bypass 8 A practical problem encountered ing access to the network may in the useful as is telecommunications sector is the following giv- : expands the space of commodities offered and it decrease the rents of asymmetric information by shrinking the incumbent's scale of More operation. the incumbent cations for directly may it also be useful for yardstick recisons if the technology of correlated with the monopolist's technology. However, in teleconmiuni- is example giving access to the network to long distance operators leads to the possibiHty of bypass of the local loop by large consumers to connect with these operators. So far we had no need of long distance, to distinguish between producer prices and consumer prices and we could assume without was loss of generality that access pricing the only tool used to oblige the competitor to participate in the fixed costs of the local loop. However, when bypass feasible high access prices required for funding these costs is induce inefficient bypass. may help mitigate this dilemma*. But, of dealing with this problem which amounts to discon- Nonlinear prices for local telecommunication there is a much more way efficient necting consumer prices and producer prices^. The monopolist has marginal The fringe has marginal cost C2^°. cost cq for the local network and Ci for Consider the case of a continuum long distance. [0,1] of consumers with identical preferences V{qi,q2)- Let V{pi,p2) be the indirect utility function. The bypass technology b is the Let same T2 is characterized by a fixed cost 6 for everyone, 9 be a tax on good With a competitive = P2 The price of good 2 charged to those P2 The marginal price of good [0, oo) and a (low) mctrginal cost b. distributed according to a c.d.f. G[9). is 2. € — a -h C2 4- T2 a = C2 local loop 2 is then : is + T2. through bypass = P2 + ^ - given that consumer 6 has paid a fixed cost good . who bypass the 2 obtained P2 fringe the price of is de facto a 6. *See Laffont-Tirole (1990b) for a different example of the use of nonlinear prices to fight bypass. ^However, this option is rarely available to regulators. '°The dichotomy property is assumed so that we can study pricing issues independently of incentives issues. 20 For given prices who bypass P2,a) consumers (pi, are those with 9 lower than 9' defined by V{pi,P2) Leaving aside good Max [v{puP2 ^ + = -9' Vipi,p2 + b-a)-9 + [V{pi,P2) + (1 + {l + X)[{pi X)[{pi - Ci - ?i Let = = qiiPuP2 demand + b-a) 92(a) Let AR 2) AR = is - (pi ci - Co)(9i(a) effect. when a consumer It is - qi) + {p2 - a - C2)q2{a)]]dG{9) (45) AR < + b - a) ?2(Pl,P2)- demand - a and and revenues associated let 171, 772, ^712, '721,-^1, -^2 functions 91,52- - 03)92(0) - (P2 - C2 - £0)92- the loss of profits (including access charge and switches to bypass. means that less This should favor a lower access price than If we it is tcix on think of the difference between prices the difference of "collected taxes" taxes are collected when no switch when when the switch occurs. occurs (see equation A5.3 in 5). seems difficult to predict AR Si 0". the sign of AR. So we wiU Then, from appendix 5 we have A I Pl P2-C2--Qd + 1 At/i A 1 P2 give the complete results only : Pi-ci--Co where q2{pi,P2 ^i(a))-R2(a) be the elasticities costs as taxes for raising funds, the switch occurs. appendix = functions qi{a),q2{a) and the prices pi,p2 an income and marginal = ?2 the elasticities and revenues associated with the for (pj -ci- Co)qi + {P2 -C2- Co)q2]]dG{9) <ll{Pl,P2) 771(a), ^2(0)1 '712(a), '721(0)5 with the It + co)qi{a) : for ease of notation ?i(a) good + b-a). optimal pricing and access pricing are then the solution of 0, J^^ where + + 1 A 7/2 fi, ^2 ^^^ superelasticity formulas for the hybrid population of bypass and those ''Note that if who do consumers who not. in addition a direct subsidy (or tax) for bypass was available this effect would disappear. 21 The deviation of the access price from the marginal cost a - A Co 1 P2 If elasticities where is ^2 mation are constant, if +A W2 72(a) TiiT]2{a)!' the proportion of those who bypass the classical super-elasticity and similarly ^^ w ^1)^^, is smeill (then fj we obtain the Pricing access at marginal cost approxi- is Co. then appropriate. have assumed here the existence of transfers. If there is no transfer, similar hold as long as the tax revenue on good 2 goes to the monopoly. If not, bypass inefficient is : The The concern was the cost. The optimal now that the competitor access pricing rule for some services efficiency of supply of services given existing words we have assumed that the regulated firm's the access price. Suppose Compo- Efficient So far we have focussed on pricing access when there exist competitors firms. In other and very be expected. to Access Pricing and Entry nent Pricing Rule. which need access. results access prices participate strongly in raising funds to pay for the fixed costs of the local loop 9 *^ V2 : act We then is may be must pay a affected rival enters regardless of fixed entry or operating by the existence of this fixed cost, because the entrant does not internalize the consumer surplus created by the introduction of good Ideally one 2. would hke to use direct entry subsidies to deal optimcdly with the entry decision. [Under incomplete information about the entrant's cost, one would need a nonlinear transfer function of the quantity to be produced is about the variable fixed cost if cost, induce a better entry .Also, it the asymmetry of information and a stochastic decision of entry as a function of the announced the asymmetry of information alternative instruments if is may be optimal about the fixed cost]. In the absence of such to lower the access price obtained so far to decision^"'. concerned with entry decisions, Baumol has proposed a simple and influential '-In the absence of these assumptions different taxes for those who bypass and those who do not would be desirable. '•^The relatively favorable interconnect prices levied are a dynamic version marivet structure. A on Mercury to access British Telecom's network widely believed that they were designed to realise a pcirticular different but related reason for low access prices is the high switching costs of of this point. It is consumers. 22 access pricing rule ^*, component pricing called the "'efficient (ECP rule" rule) which foUows from the precepts of contestability theory. In our notation, this rule the monopoly's price and its recommends an marginal cost in the competitive mairket a The if idea and only is ECP more if it is rule : = pi- ci. (46) that an entrant with marginal cost c on the competitive segment will enter efficient P2 • access price equal to the difference between : =a+c= (pi - ci) under perfect substitutes +c< The : pi «c< Ci. following assumptions make this rule optimal. First, the monopoly's and the entrant's goods are perfect substitutes. Otherwise entry by a less efficient entrant may be Second, the regulator observes the desirable. monopoly's marginal cost on the competitive market. Third, the entrant has no monopoly power. Otherwise, the choice of pi not only determines the access price, but also constrains the entrant's monopoly power. Fourth, and relatedly, the technologies exhibit constant returns to scale. Fixed entry costs for instance would create severed difficulties with the Baumol On in rule. On the one hand, the no-monopoly-power assumption would be streched. the other hand, the entrant might not enter because he does not internalise the increase consumer surplus created by [Incidentally, pricing. But, p2 = a -h c is entry. Fifth, the Baumol seems lower than the On to benchmark pricing recommend Ramsey Ramsey rule is marginal cost pricing as the benchmark. price for cost (co -H c) if pi the is Ramsey the other hand, if those five conditions are satisfied, argued that the access pricing rule (46) is irrelevant. for cost (co -f- ci).] should supply only access (pi is irrelevant) ; or c > ci Either c < Ci it price can be and the monopoly and no access should be given (a is irrelevant). • ECP rule under imperfect substitutes differentiation (as we have done the competitive segment. To we assume constant returns entrants, until now) : In the rest of this section to justify the presence of several firms in retain the spirit of the for the much as possible, known marginal cost for the Baumol to scale, competitive entrants, and the dichotomy property we introduce rule as monopoly's cost function. For instance, we can take the sub-cost functions assumed in Section 5. The dichotomy ensures that the pricing rules will not be affected by incentive corrections. "If a component of a product is offered by a single supplier who also competes ••See Baumol (1993) with others in offering the remaining product component, the single-supplier component's price should cover its incremental cost plus the opportunity cost incurred when a rival supplies the final product". : 23 model the Baumol In our amounts rule to a(;3)=Pi(/3)-cx=pi(/3)-^. Competition = Pi{/3) + c — competitive segment implies that p^iP) in the Ci. Optimizing expected social welfare under constraint (46) and under the incentive constraints (see appendix 6), we obtain the = a where an "average is 772 . V2 = P2 qi ——'71 P2 (47) + 92 to the formula a ?2 + 9i = + Cqq + 772 , — —T~"'?21 - - -7/2 here of dichotomy), the elasticity used The A(/?) + Cqq elasticity" Pi 9i Compared access pricing rule 92 P2 92 Pi 9i + 92 9i J/n- ^L ^ obtained in Section 5 t (in the case - ^12 '721 '7i'72 + '72'72i ^71^2 = 772' difference between the two formulas (assuming that there Baumol is rule ties the no need P2 -c- Co = pi - ci - costs. One then for = 771 772 and c = Ci. an in- : These imply that Co, or a Thus has for two prices on the competitive segment. Let us compare the two rules in some specific cases Symmetric demands and assumed not the correct one, namely is centive correction) stems from the fact that the - (48) 91+92 symmetric demands and = pi- ci. costs, the efficient component pricing rule is consis- tent with optimal regulation. - Linear demands, symmetric costs, and captive customers. ous symmetry assumption in one respect : the monopoly has captive customers while competitors do not. Under hnear demands, the with d <h and 02 < ai. demand (7i = ai - bpi + q2 = 0,2 — bp2 + dpi > P2 and 24 a < functions are dp2 Marginal costs are identical Pi Let us alter the previ- pi : — ci = C\. c. Our formulas then yield The intuition that the is monopoly must charge a higher price because captive customers make markup relatively turn, this high efficient - markup on good component efficient in covering the fixed cost. In can be viewed as an access subsidy relative to the 1 pricing rule. Linear symmetric demands, cost superiority of monopoly. previous example that ci = 03, but ci < P2 Pi The intuition now is < Then our formulas c. and that under linear — partially reflect the cost differential C2 a < demand Ci. price cap Price Caps : — pi Let us assume in the yield : Ci. the price differential p2 There "cost absorption". is must therefore be lower than that recommended the Remark on thcin its competitors efficient Suppose that the monopoly is — Pi must The only access price component pricing rule. regulated according to the : aopo with the access pricing rule + aipt < p, (49) : a = pi-ci or P2=Pl-Ci+ C. This of course lator If makes use is not pure price cap regulation (neither is practice) because the regu- of the cost information ci. the weights Qq and Oi are chosen approximately equal to qo and we obtain (see appendix 7) Po - Cqq _ (1 Po Pi - i^) lo - Cqq - Ci^, _ 1 Pi where u is qi 4- 92 respectively - V V2 the multiplier of the price cap constraint and a = Uoo H fj^ is given by (49). Then • Tz ^2 Comparing with —i^. On we notice two differences. First the other hand, under a price cap, effort production level effort level (48) qo + (^i + ?2 and therefore Cqq than under optimal regulation. 25 is is 1 - 1/ will in general differ from optimal conditionally on the total evaluated at a (conditionally) higher Access Pricing in Practice 10 To assess current practice Co = + CqQ Fully distributed costs a) : markup above marginal ^^^^^ Po 1 = Co + -, = Ci ko, = = C-i cq2. method populeir of pricing access consists products in a mechanistic way. For instance, a may be uniform cost pi and Ciqi The most in allocating the fixed cost to the firm's product's model, assume that in the light of the theoretical (ci + Co) This accounting rule generates "'excess" revenue + -, : a = Co + -. =^ + ^^ + ^^ = A:o, that covers the fixed cost. It interesting to note that this accounting rule satisfies the efficient is component pricing rule, as Pi - = ci a. This of course need not be the case for alternative methods of distributing the fixed For example, a markup proportional to marginal cost, namely cost. Po where S = Co(l + Pi <^), = (co Pi is — Ci demand and proper cost, > — The Ci)qi, Oftel rule and B2 = long distance, access). The = co(l + S), a. is {a entry considerations. : — The idea of the rule fully distributed costs. Let arbitrary and has no reason to reflect the The access rule designed Telecom's (BT) network can be sketched as follows Co a no point dwelling on the conceptual drawbacks of us just recall that the fixed cost allocation b) <J), chosen so as to ensure budget balance, yields is There + Ci)(l + is Co)?2 : by Oftel Let So denote BT's profits in AD "access deficit" is its = for the access to British (po — <^)%i ^i to set a usage-based price of access to is (Pi — various product lines (local, here equal to the fixed cost .\amely the margin above the cost of giving access = BT's ko. local network. proportional to the access deficit per unit of BT's output in this activity and to the share of BT's variable profits provided by this activity. For the long distance activity, one thus has a — Co = AD qi : Bi Bq 26 + Bi + B2 (50) Note that B2 depends on the access price and that itself mination of access prices under fully distributed costs) (as is the case for the deter- formula (50) involves a fixed point. In practice (again as in the case of fully distributed costs), the access price outcome of a dynamic tatonnement, whose path ought to be studied If the budget balanced (that is AD = is, if in must be the more ^o+^i-f ^2), the Oftel formula detail. interestingly reduces to = pi-ci a which under budget balance the yields To there exactly the "opportunity cost" of is is is Oftel formula thus rule. usage -and not only cost- based, suppose that competition not only on the long distance domestic market (goods but also on the international market (good 93 produced by competitors). its The in the activity. component pricing efficient see that the access pricing rule BT The BT and good q^ qi and 92)? produced by Oftel rule then defines different access prices for competitors, 02 on the domestic long distance market and 04 on the international mcirket despite identical access costs^^.With obvious notation, 02 and — Co = AD —5Bx — so 02 04 The markups The Oftel rule is — _, and a^ — cq = Co Bi/qi Co ^3/93 AD B3 (51) are thus proportional to BT's unit revenues on the competitive segments. therefore related to our access pricing formula, in that both are usage- revenue imposed by competitors on the network provider. The based and reflect the loss of difference between the Oftel rule and our formula (29) is that the unit revenues replace the superelasticities. 11 Conclusion In a first best world, access pricing to a network (hke any other pricing) should be marginal cost pricing. In practice the appropriate rule departs from the first best and depends on the constraints and on the available instruments. First, the provision of the nondistortive lump sum •For the sake ta.xes. network imposes fixed costs which cannot be financed by Competitors should then contribute to the fixed cost of In practice, a domestic call uses two domestic local loops while an Further, the access price peak load structure can only be coarse, and differ for the two types of calls if their timing stuctures differ within pricing of the argument. international call uses only one. iherelbre network costs may bands. 27 the network. This contribution, which takes the form of an access price above marginal cost, reduces either the financial burden of the regulator (in the case of transfers) or the price distortions associated with the firm's budget constraint. Second, asymmetric information of the regulator about the firm's costs may introduce other standard distortions, because informational rrats must be taken into account defining proper marginal costs. may be Further distortions desirable if when network and competitive segment subcosts cannot be disentangled. When taxation of the competitive goods is feasible, access can be priced at margined cost while taxes contribute to covering the fixed cost. [Note nevertheless that the marginal cost referred to firm, and is is the marginal cost which arises from the optimal regulation of the in general different from the first best marginal cost because effort This disconnection of consumer and producer prices very handy is competitive segment can bypass the network. By and taxation mandates reduces the number price regulators' if pricing rules to the coverage of fixed costs. become more and more complex to use access prices, rather lower]. consumers on the contrast, a separation of regulatory of instruments, must then arbitrate very imperfectly between the goals of limiting and participating is It is clear and the access ineflScient bjT)ass more generally that access as well as inefficient as the regulator tries than complementary instruments, in order to meet various market structure goals such as inducing proper entry or reducing monopoly power in the competitive segment or to achieve distributive objectives. Last, we have shown that our analysis can shed substantial light on the effectiveness component pricing of policy proposals such as the efficient rule and of existing poUcies such as the Oftel rule for British Telecom. Looking forward, our analysis can be pursued in several directions. With a proper regulatory model of predatory behavior, one should be able to investigate the conjecture that access pricing products. The is a intuition more is efficient tool to the following : A prey than the pricing of the competitive low price for the competitive product signals a high efficiency. This information can be used by the regulator to extract the monopoly's rent in the future. On the other hand, a high ciccess price seems immune to ratcheting. Next, one could substitute to the optimal regulation various types of current regulations (price cap, rate of return) and analyze how the deviations from optimal regulation impact on the access pricing formulas (see for example the Remark could even depart from the regulatory context and see in Section 9). how competition One policy alone would deal with access pricing. Excessive access prices could be considered as a predatory tool to eliminate competition as has been claimed in the ATi:T case before divestiture. Our framework also enables us to discuss a current debate in Europe. Telecormnuni- cation companies are required to offer universal service of local telephone (here good zero) 28 at a low price. Their budget constraint would normally force them to increase the price of their other services as well as the price of access to the network. A concurrent low-access- Community might demand marginal charge constraint (for example the European cost pricing in order to increase competition) then forces the network firm to further increase the price of its other services and and to lose its competitive edge. We are not then very far from the solution adopted by the U.S. courts, which prohibits the network from offering competitive services. There, universal service charges to the network instead of the profits made by is financed by appropriate access the network firm on its additional services as in Europe. We have not discussed nonlinear access pricing rules, for long as the fixed part of the tariff plays the role of a to raise the money needed lump sum tax, it is some example Laffont-Tirole (1993) tariffs. As an excellent tool to pay for the fixed cost of the network. However, take in account the fact that beyond rate (see for example two-part one must level the fixed charge lowers the connection ch. 2). Similarly we have not discussed the important practical issue of peak load access pricing. Finally, let us stress that, to a large extent, we have left aside various dynamic issues : investments (in particular unobservable specific ones) for network development (see however Remark 4 in Section 3), consequences of regulators' limited well as regulation of entry. Inefficient commitment power, as developement of the network, more costly rents of asymmetric information, and inadequate entry behavior are then to be expected. These questions can be addressed within our general regulatory framework (see ch. 1,9, and 13 in Laffont-Tirole (1993) for the basic principles). 29 APPENDIX Let /i(/3) 1 : Optimal regulatory rule (Section be the co-state variable associated with U. From the Pontryagin principle = /i(/3) Using the transversality condition fi{0) /x(/3) The = = we have AF(/?). {S{qo{poim + V{qi{pi{0),P2m,q2{pM,P2{m +a[po(/5)?o(Po(/3)) + A/(^). differentiation of the Hamiltonian H= -(1 3) A)[0(eo(^) + e,i/3)) + + Pi(/3)gi(pi(/3),P2(/5)) Co(/?,eo(/3),9o(Po(/3)) +P2(/?)92(Pi(/5),P2(/?))] + ?i(pi(/3),P2(^)) + 92(pi(/?),P2(/3))) -M(/3)0'(eo(/?)+e:(/3)){^(/?,Co(/3,eo(/3),9o(po(/?))+9i(pi(/5),P2(/3))+92(Pi(/?),P2(/3))), qoipom + qi{pm,P2m + q2{p,m.P2m) with respect to po, pi, P2 gives (24), (25) and (26) and with respect to and (31). 30 eo, ci gives (30) APPENDIX Part (i) dCkd0 = is the same /? — results from ioT k = Sub-cost observability To prove that sub-cost observation (37). is useless 1,2 note that, at the optimal regulatory policy, That for all k. {t{/3),C(/3) ,Qi/3),qi{/3)} This incentive scheme to its : is, when d^Ekl {—dEk/dCk) given the firm's scheme under sub-cost observability, {t{/3),Co(^) ,Ci(l3),Q{0),qi{0)} consider the associated incentive scheme >• type 2 /3 announces ^ it is under sub-cost unobservability, where C{0) incentive compatible. will To show = Co(/3) this, it suflBces to -I- — Ci(/3). show that if choose the sub-cost cdlocation {Co(/3),Ci(/3)} corresponding announcement, even though the regulator cannot control sub-costs. Note that from (37), there exists a such that ^(/?,C,(/3),(3,(^)) =a k = 0,l and Coi0) where Qq =Q and Qi = + C,0) = C{^), q\. But the condition d^Ek/dCk 5/? = impHes that ^0,Ck0),Qk0)) = a for all k, as well. /3 From our assumption, {Cq{^) + Ci{0) = C{0)} is the imique cost minimizer for type when it announces /3. We can thus implement the same allocation when sub-costs are unobservable as when they are. 31 APPENDIX 3 : Competitor market power Because of the dichotomy assumption, the optimization with respect to the access price can be carried out under complete information max^ {S{qo{po)) + : V{qi{pi,p2),qi{pi,p2)) vo - -PiqiiPi,P2) (a - poqoipo) + c)q2{pi,P2)} (A3.1) s.t. PoqoiPo) + Piqi(pi,P:i) + aq2{pi,P2) -Ciqi{pi,P2) q2{puP2) From P2 I + ei) (A3.2) + P2-^{puP2) -{a + c)-^{pi,p2) = ap2 +c= p2 + (A3.3) 0. Op2 g2(PliP2) -9——! ^iPl,P2) Substituting into (A3.1), (A3. 2) max X i^{eo + 9i(pi,P2) + 92(^1, P2)) (A3. 3) a PO>Pl > Co(?o(po) = P2(l - l/r]2{puP2))- we have S{qo{po))+V{qi{pi,p2),q2{pi,P2))-Poqo{Po)-PiqiiPi,P2)-P2q2iPi,P2)+ ^ ^ ^' ^ V2[Pl,P2) L s.t. Po9o(Po) + Pl?l(Pl,P2) + P2q2{Pl,P2) - -Ciqi{pi,P2) cq2{pi,P2) + qiipi,P2) + ?2(Pl,P2)) Coiqoipo) > r + ^(^0 + ^l)- -, V2{P\,P2) Let 1 + A(/3) denote the multiplier of the contraint. We substitute A convenience. Maximizing with respect to (^1,^2) we obtain : dV dqx dV dq2 dq]_ dqi dpi dq2 dpi dpi ^(1+A) . _ dq2_ dpi dqi dq2 fdqi dq2 opi dpi \dpi dpi 32 to A(/3) below for i J dq2 dqi -CiOPi c-^— dpii dV dV^ dq^ dqx dp2 +(1 + A) dpi \ dq2 dq iSl op2 ap2 dp2 dq2 dp2 dp2 dq, ?2 dp2 „ 9qi dqi - dq2 dqi dp2 dp2 - Pi dpi dpi P2 — + -^^ dp2\ P2 Co - T]2 5p2/ J Ci -Co -c 1 - Co . —Co — Ci 1 C + + A 1 El + The second term I J^ dp2 \ r]2 J A dq2 1 -1 _d_fm2\ dpi\ dqi dq2 d (P2q2\ dp2\ T/2 / dp2 dp2 _ dq2_ ^21 921. dpi dq2 ' dn dq2 ^ _ T}2 J ^31. i33. 9pa d f 1 9pi \ dp 1V772/ \dp2'dpi dpi'dp2 P2_ fdq]_ dq2 dqi dq2 dqi__d_n\ \dpi' dp2 dp2'dpi dpidp2\r]2J B2. 11 + J dpi dpi T}2 I r]2 of the right-rand side equals 1 P2 fdq2_ dq2 dpi \ +A V2 T]2 dp2 Cn( \dp2 dqi - -P2 dq2 dqi Pi J dqi dq2 dp2 . T]2 ^ .dp2 dq2 d dpidp2\T]2^ dpidp2 \r]2 dp2dpi\i)2) Pii2i^{^)+P2mii;{^) + '7i72 - '7i2'72i A El th^i4(^)+P^'?"af7(i). + '7i'72 - 7i2'72i 33 dq2 g2 dpiT]2 + dqi q2 dpi r/2 . Pi - Co - Pi 72 Ci Pi P2 - - Co = Since a a A 1 + 7172 '/I A 1 1 72 72 I 2li 72 - 712721 P^'?^afc(^)+P^^"a^(^ —+— C P2 where Rk + 1 t{^)+P2m.^{^) 7i72 - 712721 Pkqk- = P2 =^ uoQ — c — P2 we have 22. A(/3) r 72 1 + P2— A(^)^ 72 with 72 A(/?) 1 . = l + A(/3) P27ia^fe)+pi7i2gf7(;^) 7i72 — 712721 + 72172 - 721712 7i72 72- 27172 34 7i - P2 712721 APPENDIX The dichotomy 4 Restricted regulation : implies that price formulae can be obtained as in the full information case. Let W = S{qo) + V{qi, 92) - poqo - Piqi - P2?2 denote the consumer net surplus, and MP = q^ + p^[p^-Co-c^] + p-\p,-Co-c] Opi OPl denote the monopoHst's marginal profit and let P denote its profit. The planner solves : W max {P0,Pl,P7} subject to P -y; = (BB) po9o + Piqi + {p2 - MP = Let (1 + hand side of to pi is A) and v denote the shadow (B5) Cxq\ - V" = and 0. prices of the maximized with respect is - CqQ - 0)92 two constraints. Because the left- to pi, the first-order condition with respect : dW f dp\ \ dpx Because the net consumer surplus sumption on profit, we obtain 1/ < 0. dMP \ decreaises The ) with prices, and from our concavity as- derivative of the Lagrangian with respect to pi yields dW - dp2 The ing. dP_ dp2 dMP _ dp2 first-two terms are the standard terms obtained in the The correction in the access pricing formula {a d{MP)/dp2, which is is p2 — c) also increased and the p2, and therefore the access result aimbiguous. However, functions and constant returns to scale both effects cancel, giving the formula as in the case of full regulation. 35 pric- depends on the sign of positive under generahzed strategic complementarity. equation shows that for a given pi the price lowered. But pi = absence of monopoly price, This last should be for linear same demand access pricing APPENDIX = Let e- be defined by 9' V{pi,p2 +b- - a) 5 V{pi,p2). Hence dO' ^= de' 91 - gx(a) = ?2 - ?2(a) = 92(a)- + ip2 dp2 dO' da Let AR = (pi - - ci Co)(gi(a) - qi)) Maximizing (45) with respect to pi,p2,a 0(9') \q,{a) +(i-G(n) yields + A) [ip, A91 + (1 + +(1-G(n) + (1 + A92 + A) [(pi - Ci ' - A92(a) - (1 (P2 - C2 A) (^^ (l + + (P2 - Co - C2)|^]] '^^a^^'^) (A5.1) + (P2 - a - C2)^(a)]] A) A) [(p: - ci - + A)Air: co)||(a) + A)Ai2 = + (p2 (A5.2) - a - C2)|^(«)]] = Hence G{9') A9i(a) + -(1-G(5-)) A9i +^(^-)(l (1 + + (l A)(p, + A)(px-Ci-Co)|^(a) - c, -co)^(a)J^-;^^-^_ + (1+A) + co)92- + A)Ai2 = -''- +^(^*)?2(a)(l -(A,2(a) - : - Co)|| + +5(n[92-92(a)](l G(5-) - 02)92(0) - -c- Co)||(a) + (P2 " a - ^2)^(0)]] +5(^')(9i-9i(a))(l G{9') A92(a) a dq2 (1 + - A)Ai? 9i-9x(a)-92(a)^^^/^^^^^)|-0, 36 (A5.3) and [l-G{e')]^Xq, + {l+\) (p,_e,-co)|l + (p,-c.-co)|l]] +9iO')q2{l Given the ambiguity of the sign of + A)Ai? AR, we = 0. will consider the case AR = 0. -Ci-co) (Pi (1 + A) iP2-Co- C2) -{l-G)Xq2 or {l+X)A Pl-Ci-Co P2- Co- C2 OCX "2 . 9n det n _ - GfA A = G{\- G)^^A{a)A^ + (1 with A _ ^9i^<?2 ^92 591 a?! 5?2, dpi ^p2 5pi ap2 dpi dp2 A-' = dqx dq2 dp2 dpi i^-G)t -i^-G)'^ -i^-G)t + (^-G)t lS^. dpi '^"1 Bi-) apjV 1 det X A This yields -A[G'(9i(a) Pi - Ci - Co - 92(a)l{^) + (1 - G)?:](l - G)|^ + {1 - G)^A92|^ = (1+A) (l-G)2A + G(l-G')A(a)fe/g^(a) A[G(<7i(a)-<72(a)#|^)+(l-G)9il(l-G)|^-A(l-(?)g2 P2 — C2 — Co = 'dp '}P7 (1 + A) (l-C?)2A + G(l-G)A(a)(|^/|^(a) 37 Pi 1 ,,-c,-c {^^•('^- + A 1 P2 + GA{a);^^ + {l-G)A + A- l + Xrfi ^^^ + ii!}) + (l-G)(,. + ,.,)^_ GA(a);^^ + (l-G)A A- 1 with A= = A(a) These formulas reduce to the From 771772 - 771(0)772(0) 7/127721 - 7712(0)7721(0), classical superelasticity formulais when G = 0. (A5.3) Cq-q _ ~ P2 A 1 + 1 A Pi -Ci -Co 772(a) A ^ l + pi f 7712(0) i?i(o) 772(0) 1 ^ R^ia) _772i(o) j ^1772(0) ^2''' I Al772(o) 38 _ , P2 - C2 p2 - Co + , A^, APPENDIX The 6 : Implications of the Efficient program regulator's then is Component Pricing rule : max^''[5(9o(;'o(/3)))+l/(gi(pi(;5),pi(/3)-^i(/3-ei(;3))+c),92(pa(^),Pi(;3)-tfi(/9-ei(^))+c) -Po{0)qo{pom - pMqiipii/3),pi{0) - H,i0 - eri0)) + c) -{pM -H,{^- eM) + c)q2{pi{/3),p,{/3) - H,{^ - ei(/3)) + c) + U{0)]dF{l3) s.t. Um > 0, and Po(^)?o(Po(/?)) + Pi{/3)qi{pi{(3),pi{0) - + [px(/3) - H^{0 - e^m]q2{p^i0),p^{0) Hr{/3 ^i(/3 +92(pi(^),Pi(/3)-^i(/3-ei(^)) -//i(/3 - ei(/3))9i(;7i(/3),pi(/3) Proceeding as in Section 5 0'(eo - ei) = - ^i(/? - + c) - ei(/3)) + ei) = //o(?o H[q, - CoQ - e^) + c) - ei(/3)) + c) + c)) W) - + 91 + 92) - ~ + V(eo(y9) + - j[mmd0 — -= = r , C, ^ ^'"(eo V"(eo ^+ + eO OP2i \{0) A(/3) i . I -((?! 1 + 'xm r-' 39 + ei) A{p))j[p) dp2 Pi + c) we obtain (1 w'(eo ei(/?)) - H,{P - - eomiqoipM) + qi{pxm,Pxm - -i7o(/5 - + «72) p A(/?) 92 ei(/3)) = 0. with V91 + 92/ P2\qi + q2/ Hence a(/3)=pi(/?)-/ri(^-ei(/3)) A(/3) , with ri^ = p, ^T,". 40 _ m p2 APPENDIX 7 The Lagrangian : The Component Pricing Efficient monopoly's optimization problem of the rule under price caps is Poqo{po)-Ho{/3-eo){qo{po) + qi{puPi-Hi{^-ei{^)) + c) + q2{pi,pi-Hi{0-ei{^)) + c)) +(p: -Hr{l3- ei)){qiipuPi - H^{0 - -V-Ceo The first-order conditions e,{0)) + c) + q2{pi,Pi - + ei) + j/(p - aopo - OiPi). with respect to pq and p\ are bo - Cd)^— + 90 = olqv dpo .f9qi ( If oq ~ qo and ai ~ ^i + q2, po — Co w Po Pi rj^ is 1 — 1/ Vo Pl-Co-Ci where dq2\ dq2 dqi \-Vp2 12 given by (47). 41 Pi H,i/3 - t^{0)) + c)) REFERENCES BAUMOL, W.J. (1983), "Some Subtle Pricing in Railroad Regulation", In- temational Journal of Transport Economics, 10, 341-355. BAUMOL, W.J. phone Service"', AEI Studies can Entreprise Institute CAVE, M. (1992), for in ENSTT of Local Tele- Telecommunications Deregulation, Ameri- Public Policy ReseMch, "The Growth of Competition UK", kets in the and Residual Regulation (1993), "Deregulation Colloque - in New York University. Telecommunications Mar- Le Management des Entreprises de Reseau. LAFFONT, J.J. and J. TIROLE (1990a), "The Regulation of Multiproduct Firms", Journal of Public Economics, 43, 1-66. LAFFONT, J.J. and J. TIROLE American Economic Review, LAFFONT, J.J. and and Procurement, NOLL, R.G. (1990b), "Bypass and Creamskimming" 80, 1042-1061. TIROLE (1993), A MIT Press. J. Theory of Incentives in Regulation (1989), "Telecommunications Regulation in the 1990s" in Directions in Telecommunications Regulation Policy, Vol. ed. Duke VICKERS, kets", University Press, J. (1989), Durham and London. "Competition and Regulation (1979), "The Theory of 3 in Vertically Network Access Pricing", (ed.), Issues in Public Utility Regulation, PubUc Newberg, Related Mar- mimeo. WILLIG, R.D. bing 1, P. New Utilities 1 Papers. 78 42 in H.M. Tre- Michigan State University MIT LIBRARIES 3 TDflo DDfl^t.sl^ s Date Due ,0.2 •#&-' iCT, O/ 1996 MAH. 1 Lib-26-67