^^^^% % Jo HD28 .M414 9^ ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Seasonal Inventories and the Use of Product-Flexible Manufacturing Technology by' Jonathan P. Caulkins Charles H. Fine WP#3011-89-MS May MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 1989 Seasonal Inventories and the Use of Product-Flexible Manufacturing Technology by Jonathan P. Caulkins Charles H. Fine WP #3011-89-MS May 1989 JUL 2 4 19^ J Inventories and the of Product-Flexible Seasonal Use Manufacturing Jonathan Technology Caulkins P. Charles H. August Operations Massachusetts Cambridge, Fine 1988 Research Center Technology Massachusetts 02139 Institute of ABSTRACT As advancing makes technology Systems (FMS's) a viable option for and products, determining their increasingly important. the effect of the the ability Despite Manufacturing an increasing number of firms economic value has become Flexible considerable or inability to research hold interperiod value of FMS's has received relatively little in this area, inventories on attention. This paper proposes a stochastic dynamic programming model production capacity investment decision that explicitly allows the firm carry interperiod inventories for safety stock and to seasonal stock motives, and it analyzes a simplified convex A programming model that considers seasonal stock motives only. variety of qualitative results are obtained for the case of periodic market conditions that are not known when the firm makes its investment decision. The complete solution is reported on for the varying market conditions. periodically case of deterministic for the Examples are given for both cases. The analysis leads to some surprising results, including the fact can flexible capacity be and that inventories interperiod an Hence, the analysis can be substitutes. complements as well as important supplement to unguided intuition. Inventories and the of Product-Flexible Seasonal Use Manufacturing Jonathan Technology Caulkins P. Charles H. Fine Introduction and Overview 1 A corporations' low relatively of attention requirements investment stifle procedures in investment this situation current U.S. for flexible in has received a that their These investments. because to financial strict requirements can accounting cost/benefit adequately assess the value to fail FMS's offered One explanation attributes justifying for been of levels manufacturing systems (FMS's). great deal have explanations of variety (Michael of flexibility and Millen, 1984; Suresh and Meredith, 1984; Kaplan, 1986; Kelly, 1988; Port et. 198 al., As 8). a result, companies have relied instead on managerial judgement (Gerwin, 1981; Miles, 1988; Schiller, 1988) which, without the support of well-designed decision inadequate (Kaplan, limited Progress on one product Holland, their lines of type conventional that to a at cycle sets Kulatilaka, competitors of often procedures in met with develop comprehensive models diverse a of set time. Models have been developed effects on value the comparison of with the benefits. that to focus analyze FMS's (Hutchinson and of FMS's that arise from of indivisibility transfer 1986), benefits from being able to produce with either factor inputs 1986; 1987), and is quantitatively accounting 1982; Fine and Li, 1987), the benefits (Burstein, capture to made, however, by developing models been has life efforts tried because FMS's yield such success modularity two FMS's Early overlook. have researchers of benefits the tools, 1986). response, In support to credibly and (Kulatilaka the ability threaten entry to Marks, deter into 1985; 19 86; market markets in entry by which the does firm not benefits related compete currently 1986), and demand (Fine and Freund, 1986; 1987; One is inventory hold to used are production hold to like and/or optimally respond to particularly unpredictable decomposing the may Firms for at and least investing analyses. into In interaction been analyzing firm of flexible in full constituent uncertainty, This conditions. generality, but by steps can be parts, cycle invest product-flexible motives, stock motives. in safety Techrrology have stock investment been by studied at economics of the flexibility in Graves (1988) has examined safety stock have product mix and capacity flexible However, flexibility. seasonal stocks has model for ignored. extends benefits the seasonal a product of and and Fine the multiperiod interperiod setting safety Freund flexibility in which inventories. (19 8 to 7) hedge the firm Section 2 and seasonal stocks. The rest programming model which excludes on analyze seasonal the when stock hold presents for a both of the paper analyzes a convex safety Section stock 3 considerations presents six and theorems when market conditions are seasonal but firm makes its technology investment decision. model the issues. against can dynamic programming formulation which allows stochastic would capacity (1987) and Vander Veen and Jordan (1987), facilities in uncertain market considerations stock addition. uncertainty that in and/or reasons: stock between paper This focuses the with the option firm a non-stationary its inventories three Kekre when requirements safety value the flexible in addressed although they do not look explicitly largely that is it. hold cycle Karmarkar and the future Since production and affect know how to be to seasonal and decisions their to variability variability toward analyzing motives, about al., 1988). models inventories. dynamic, complex too is capacity et. meet demand, intuitively one would to inventory taken market capacity. holding problem uncertainty these all 1988), 1986; Roth He and Pindyck, inventory Ultimately one would of against interperiod together ability the hedge to assumption of restrictive not allowed expect ability Pappu, with flexibility (Gaimon, associated the and (Fine Section 4 reports on a complete solution for the case of deterministic, periodically known with unlikely to studying this Examples results Market conditions are rarely varying market conditions. are so certainty, be applied solution given in and conclusions. the directly provides both solution in practice, insights Sections described 3 about and 4. in Section but we the general Section believe 5 4 is that problem. discusses The General Stochastic Demand Problem 2 Problem 2.1 Description The problem considered here firm must make face of can about uncertainty capacity investment market conditions. future switched be period's production the produce any capacity requires of resolved before is to the N have the in The firm can products larger a find the optimal capacity and its trade-off but sells, it investment initial into all completely This makes firm after committed is it that facilities does than unit problem the can production flexible per that is to between the benefits of flexible production higher investment cost. subsequent single a Each products. the The crux of Fine and Freund (1986, 1987) address when N the production flexible capacity dedicated to a single product. production period. suppresses and sales this activity This simplification yields the issues posed problem by can useful for the be collapsed results, interperiod case but it inventories. paper extends their model to an arbitrary number of production sales period 2.2 decision a Because of the uncertainty, production capacity. like of among any and inventory decisions but in would firm cost uncertainty investment its zero at demand and zero, a in period's to irreversible At time following. mix of non-flexible production capacities each dedicated one of its N products and/or more expensive flexible capacity that invest to an the is and periods into the allows the firm subsequent period. Formulation The formulation uses the following indices: >^(1 N} indexes the product, se{l,... ,S) indexes the tG(l,... ,T) parameters: state, indexes the f>eriod; and to carry inventory from any a = r = the per period discount rate and purchase the product one of cost and rp i, vector of capacity purchase costs, the is [ri,r2,...,rN,rF] capacity of unit T[ dedicated is to the purchase cost of one unit of flexible is capacity; variables: K = [Ki,K2,...,Kn,Kf] is the vector of production capacities, K; the amount of capacity dedicated to product i, and Kp amount of the period period product of produced on dedicated capacity in produced in i on flexible capacity t, = amount of product lit i t, amount Zit= is capacity, flexible = amount of product Yit is held in inventory from period i to t period t+1, and <Jt and = the state in period functions: = revenues generated by selling x units of product Rit(x) state = cost of producing x hit(x) = cost of inventorying x units of product It which assumed is on the time and the in state that s the is future of the state in s'lot = s) period t+1 given that determined example, Y, = noting by 0, and for Y^j e Yii, Y,2 inventory t levels i from and period a market depends only = as 1, ..., a is in state s in period SR are For . K, the vector of capacities chosen T, pt(s,I[_i,K) function t. The dimension of vectors can which subscripts have been omitted. The decision variables time in state s, the probability the market is it Boldface will be used for vectors. be i current state and not on the firm's past decisions. its s' units of product realized to the next period. formulation, Pi(at+i = will be in state in i s, Cit(x) in So t; of the the period current inventory vector, and the vector of capacities. t production state, the at and current The following General K.p,(s.I,.K) t Demand Problem dynamic programming formulation: V Max Stochastic = l...,T 'OO'^O N = -Xr.K, - ffKf ,=1 (GSDP) has the the In H sequel, * and the superscript variables capacity decision denote the vector of will production all and denote optimal will values. Since any at given time, demand future market motives as can be However, well. of function a this numerically because the solution difficult to obtain analytic To our knowledge, the that interaction of Graves safety would model. goal (198 relative desire only 8). to The work That required to one analyze in the with both is large, stochastic work between product mix inventories flexibility for is that a safety remainder of this general solve it is made progress on and safety the stocks difference is in mix Ultimately one effects in one paper moves toward this with flexibility. and in to stock complete system no mix this dynamic programs. has flexibility difficult and work characterizes for seasonal captures it formulation space results the time, uncertain, Since the state of formulation clearly includes safety stock motives. the is seasonal by analyzing the interaction between seasonally varying market conditions and flexible manufacturing capacity. 3 The Unknown Seasonal Demand Problem 3.1 Formulation The General Stochastic Demand Problem (GSDP) considered in previous chapter is too complex to yield to tractable analysis. the However, functions, it revenue the We functions thereby periodic, programming model that Demand Problem (USDP). This we formulation cost result Unknown requires this stock safety The the label and accomplish excluding focusing on the seasonal stock problem. issues and convex on structure can be simplified into one that does. making these by more imposing by is a Seasonal following the assumptions. The revenue, production Al: = Ot-i si holding This can be modelled periodic with period two. Pi(at = and cost, r) =( 1 1 if s is if s is odd and even and = s s = functions are conditions for cost as: - r r 1 + 1 otherwise. However, more is it natural identify to the market both odd and even periods with a single state and the time subscript t. Then A2: the = C-i(x), Rit(x) and h-j(x) = h-i(x) Cit(x) = Ci2(x), R[t(x)=Rj2(x), and h[t(x) = h-jlx) Rji(x). state s is for all when the technology investment However, the firm learns unknown. sets of functions, Assumptions Al before production periods. (1) demand, This is inventory (2) and A2 at even and t, t. undertaken, is the state, and beginning of period one. the imply odd for all At time zero, therefore both that = C-t(x) that all uncertainty is resolved and inventory decisions are made for any of the T a strong policies technology assumption, can be used investments but to it captures respond must be to the key ideas uncertainty made before in the of resolution and production inventory and investments, policies holding (4) uncertainty after (3) are resolved, is constrained by inventories can interperiod the sunk the affect the of flexible capacity. utility Periodicity common. in uncertainty, this and inventory, production, in conditions sales is For example, producing and transporting bulk commodities Lakes Region the Great more expensive is the winter than in the in Likewise, holding summer because the Inland Waterway is closed. For U.S. automobile manufacturers, holding costs may be seasonal. cars from summer to winter is more expensive than holding them from winter to summer because many new models are released in the fall, reducing the value of cars held in inventory from summer to the company for a less can Cost differences winter. toy of from arise not just from weather. itself, manufacturer may be lower its Christmas seasonal warehouse space Seasonal Season. For example, holding costs spring in devoted is within variations in toys demand in because fall stockpiling to variations than the for extremely are common. The subsequent analysis depends on the following assumptions about the capacity costs, revenue functions, and cost functions. assumption about production costs the in is ever likely Only be restrictive to practice. A3: The revenue functions differentiable argument A4: The argument cost differentiable is zero. quantity they bounded, that are nondecreasing strictly concave, when their of each convex functions Cit(x) functions are are that strictly finite increasing, when their Production costs are a function only of the which kind of capacity Strictly are zero. production convex, total is functions Rjtlx) product produced is in the not period, of used. production imply diseconomies of costs scale, 10 are but relatively linear rare because production costs. which common, reasonably are The formulation. assumption are that reasonable The holding convex, functions cost our costs are when Note, if argument their that inventory levels are strictly nonnegative and are zero. is uniquely are sales increasing, strictly holding cost functions the is costs. are h,i(x) functions differentiable finite convex, A6: production in example, raw material costs are the dominant for if, component of variable production and unit encompassed and roughly equal for flexible and dedicated capacity linear A5: also are determined, convex but not but not strictly production the separately. Production in advance of demand and storage costs more than production in the subsequent period. N A7: rp > r, > for all i, rp< ^r, but i=l were If rp never A8: than less equal or economical be i. sum firm of the the ri's, flexible capacity. (R,[W - Cij(x)) is This is is a ri in some to i, then purchase it would have no incentive nondecreasing at x the proof of the = to would capacity were greater than or equal If rp technical condition which used only for firm the for dedicated to product to to the purchase 0. would generally be true and uniqueness of the Karush-Kuhn- Tucker (KKT) multipliers. With models the greatly these eight seasonal simplify the stock assumptions but issues, analysis. 1 1 the three formulation reasonably more assumptions will ) The A9: N = analysis restricted is two-product-family model; that to a is, 2. This assumption greatly facilitates explication of the model and has applications in a number of settings. To 198 7.) distinguish products are capacity will subscript 'F'. labelled be 'A' the product and 'B' is All: The inventory can firm carry period indices, Also, sequel. subscript the AlO: The planning horizon and the in by identified (See, e.g.. Fine and Freund, the the flexible instead 'AB' two of the infinite. into the first period a at cost equal to the production cost in an even period plus the holding cost from an even period AlO Assumptions with associated They with exploited extensively. boundary effects, up building With (ordered) the another way, the production Letting j a the the boundary complicating desired of level time infinite effects transient inventory. set set even of of odd all the and even periods or periods inventory levels are the is and no cannot be Or, periods. "after" that horizon odd periods do not necessarily have coming "before" periods and for to an from the (ordered) optimal and period distinguished of as eliminate symmetry between even and odd periods create also All and terminal a associated effects an odd period. to to put it to be thought them. Thus, the same for all odd even periods. be the index identifying odd and even periods e {1,2} ps = P(ai = _ and ^=77~ii 1 respectively, Demand Problem (USD?) Max V = - r^ Ka - rg Kb - ^i Ps i I s=l ( s), , the Unknown Seasonal is: r AB «:.( Kab + y:,. z' * .;- i:J - i=Aj=l 12 c:,( y:,. z;j - h:,( i:j subji : Lemma In (i) 1^2=0 3. : 1 any optimal solution Z, for That both. or is, (i,s), = l'i or never optimal for the firm to carry is it product/state pairs all inventory of any product in both odd and even periods. s (ii) 2 S 2 / s s S=l is some some s pair / That . for all products there is, which in uses firm the available all And, if Y there and is be fully utilized. will See Caulkins (1988). USDP The 3.1 Actually Z has a unique optimal solution. not are surplus capacity the firm determined uniquely necessarily is indifferent producing with dedicated or flexible capacity, but their sum is uniquely of K, X, and determined, I is because of and, indifference, = Y + Z knowledge See Caulkins (1988). The next theorem gives formulas Tucker (KKT) multipliers. It which all are USDP is the this X between essentially a complete solution. Proof: Straightforward. KKT Ka + \ s Zaj + Zbj state/period pair, production capacity Theorem the and / j=l both dedicated and flexible, to produce that product. Proof: Straightforward. because \ J=l state/period capacity, in s s \ s=l Kb + Kab = Max Max \Yaj+ Ybj+ / Kab = Max Max Yy + Zy In any optimal solution H, Kj + constraints strongly consistent; conditions given by sufficient for optimality. for the Karush-Kuhn- optimal possible to find a feasible solution for is satisfied i.e., I it - as satisfies strict so inequalities, Slater's condition. the Thus VII below are both necessary and Primes denote derivatives. 2 and vice versa. 14 If j = 1 then j = Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for Qptimality: i (II) Y p,[r^'(y;,+z;,+ i;^-i;)- c^'fY^+z;,)) = i (III) Y p,fRj'(Y^z;+i^-i;^) - Ki'^l^K^K-^^ (IV) = A.B; h^'( Y- = 5-j-q'j = A,B; j = 1.2; s = 1..S y;-5;-uJ j = 1,2; s = 1..S j = 1,2; s = 1..S +z;)i = A,B; s sjj — =- YPs|M^^\R..;:-h / - Cy j = U; 1.2: s = 1..S i = A.B; j = U; i = A.B = A,B; i = j — _ 5 = ^. = m.AB - r: s = 1..S s = 1..S /_s\ B 5 Rn _s : ZSc^ij X ZY - r..vB j s=i j=l See Appendix. Proof: These have multipliers The multiplier interpretations. a., shadow value oi having another i available value in of Similarly state period corresponding the the positive is 5.. whereas multiplier pan firm should dedicated as to willing product of the period to negative j to pair pay so that in i Finally, (s,j). to 'upgrade' state/period u-j one pair able in The it unit the is to state part. of amount of capacity unit (s,j) value. can be used one unit of flexible capacity. Suppose dedicated values A be shadow shadow value of having an additional the is absolute the is the j product to shadow value of being from period value absolute s^ of part of the i dedicated Multiplier negative capacity in state/period flexible the y. the is q.. of capacity (s,j). inventory one more unit of product s, simply the positive part of the is unit pair economic straightforward in Ka' that capacity of having optimality the product exceeds at for an additional each period and each = 0. dedicated In capacity for unit Then by is the product .A must 1 6 the mA sum of dedicated > fall before hold for price of the shadow to product and thus by VI, 0, amount by which Similar results Kb and Kab- I'V, purchase unit of capacity mA other words. purchase that technology. respect to state. .A. per it mg is price of optimal to the and mAB. with These interpretations of left hand sides of conditions of condition restriction whatever that conditions and II product to can statements Similar be to be concept optimal of period in i produces it made to product must about each purchase flexible The solved independently. Max V = subject -r. K, - decomposes subproblems Subproblem ^tpsl variables all sides of consider A and two convex are for i proof uses Its these B is the subproblems their sharing i = i;,) A or one subproblems. programs B that for can is: - C^jIy^j)- h^(l*)! S = j = j = l,2;s=l..S. KKT = 1..S. conditions are: C^'( Y^)) 2 SS«ij 1.2; s nonnesative. Yp,(R^'(Y^+I;--I*) - ri j. to: The corresponding (III) period hand left the and sufficient condition for into R^( Y^+l]^- I^- Y--i;-<0 (I) in to firm does not purchase flexible the If Yy -K, < with the hand side subject is sold capacity. We subproblems. problem product. be the necessary a of flexible production capacity. the that j because the only linkage between products capacity, left with III. The next theorem gives it For example, the III. - I consistent are gives the marginal value of having an additional unit of I dedicated capacity multipliers the + mi 5=:j=i 17 =ay-5j-sj j = U: s = 1..S j = 1,2; s = 1..S be (IV) a;j(K.-Y;j) = j (V) ,s s mi Ki = s (VI) s s s aij,5ij, qij.Sy, and mi are all nonnegalive. = The a hand side of right of flexible unit firm should invest than less is shows how without capacity solutions much Denote the Theorem 3.3 and multipliers m^B problem and Theorem in 3.1 r^s^ implies the satisfy m^ multipliers the solution < is The formulas S. subproblems 0, K^b = a solution satisfy that is y and the full u, 0, to the all so r^B ^ unique, Let r = the formulas of Theorem 3.2. K^i^ KKT S implies r^s^ and {t^, rg, r^a) V*(r) (ii) V*(r) That acquiring is V*(r) capacity The convex is = - the K r' + for the But since r^B optimal the *^ S, KKT Since an not optimal. < S implies K^^b* > denote 0- value of problem f(E). in r, nonincreasing in is ^yJA = - (ill) earn. multipliers 3.4: (i) of 0, 3.2 yield a set which contradicts the nonnegativity of < as a function of r by V*(r) Theorem = Theorem in then If optimal solution always exists, can Z = yields Hence, r^^ < S implies K^^ = multipliers. costs This 3.2. KKT of set multipliers. subproblems USDP both subproblem problem. full subproblems with the suppose optimal this the 0. Now of the it flexible in Only solving generally because of investing problem. full the marginal cost its useful is It benefit if that hand side of the inequality in the statement Suppose r,j^ > S. Then augment the solutions S. for a benefit. asserts right By Theorem conditions. Kab* = by defined as and solving than easier the simply and only if marginal the solving needed, are Proof: of measure to marginal marginal benefit of the is theorem this capacity flexible in expected the so capacity, condition this K, is for i and = A, B, and AB. nonincreasing in r acquisition convexity advanced r, increase of V*(r) manufacturing 19 is the quite maximum suggests technology decreasing intuitive; that profit as continues the to the firm cost of decline. firms tells enjoy will exactly large increasingly how improvements. profit Part (iii) rapidly profits improve as capacity acquisition costs decline. Knowledge reductions V*(r) of acquisition in useful for evaluating potential returns to is and because there costs often is uncertainty about these costs, so sensitivity analysis with respect to the capacity costs can be informative. Theorem 3.4 describes behaved function, so form its and guarantees that but difficult, is well- a is it reasonable to draw inferences about V*(r) is it obtaining V*(r) general, In from points obtained numerically. Proof: Proof of Let (K,Z) Since (K,E) V*(r2) > - be K + Proof of = V*(?cri + (1-X) Let (ii). r let [0,1] vectors cost = Xti + (1-X) corresponding solution - ri^ K to r. + f(E) and ri and vi Assumption A7 such that V*(r) r2), so be ri two is convex capacity > ri and ri ^ r2. in r. cost vectors Let (K,2) be Then V*(ri) = - ri' V*(r2) > - r2' K + f(S). But unique optimal solution corresponding to ri. the K optimal capacity Thus XV*(ri) + (l-X)V*(r2) > - (Xrit + (1-X) f(E). r2')K + f(E) = V*(r) satisfying two For arbitrary X e unique the be feasible for all cost vectors, V*(ri) > is r2' and ri Let ri Assumption A7. satisfying r2. (i). + {(E). Since (K,Z) is feasible for rj, then V*(r2) - V*(ri) > (ri'- Proof of (iii). theorem (Varian, This r20K is > 0, so V*(r) direct a nonincreasing in is application of the r. envelope 1978) as extended to nondifferentiable functions by Fine and Freund (1987). 3.3 Case of Quadratic Revenue and Holding Cost Functions and Linear Production Costs Analysis of Special As discussed above, knowledge of V*(r) reasons. For a general USDP, V*(r) but even more can be said when the is is a well-behaved function of r, USDP has quadratic revenue and Theorem holding cost functions and linear production costs. an exact, second order Taylor expansion for V*(r shows that the optimal values 20 of valuable for several the -t- Ar). decision 3.6 gives Theorem variables 3.5 are piecewise continuous, of case USDP, the function, solution, entire the USDP Theorem 3.5: functions and linear production costs, are vector r, the optimal the value all linear that statement decision 3.6: K function the in is from the directly quadratic a is M is optimal the dr^ dr^ capacity and the first The first programming unique. is for vector, which V*(r) then is Ar for drg drg drg where = - positive ^^AB ^^AB semi-definite Proof: Formula positive semi-definite av*(r) piecewise function. of a region interior dr^ ^AB and capacity cost of the V*(r+ Ar) = V*(r)-rAKA-rBKE-rABKAB + -Ar'MAr, 1 M is small, sufficiently (1) If r is and quadratic r optimal variables' continuous, a is and Theorem 3.1 which guarantees the solution Theorem dependence on its consequence of the theory of quadratic a is value r. objective the and special this optimal the just functions function The second statement follows Proof: not for with quadratic revenue and holding cost piecewise continuous, function of quadratic fact For and r, Hence r. simple nature. of a particularly values of well-behaved function of a is functions linear = -K, for i (1) follows directly because V*(r) from Taylor's Theorem. is convex. = A,B, and AB, where K, is the dli a Hence, M^j = v*(r) arjar. a /av*(r) ar. ^(-K,) = ar. ar, 21 -^ ar, By Theorem optimal M is 3.3, capacity. 3.4 Example This and functions gives section unitary maximum volume. a demand. inelastic per If assumed costs will be Revenue to be functions concave are Assumption A3. generated Similarly, not 1,2 } unitary concave, holding linear cost they so functions not guaranteed, but that is if Yjjj. = Rik ~ volume sales j hjj if state s is not a demand can be for product i in period k if i in period j and selling j and sold X Y^,, z;, and sold = i if state s is j to realized, produced on dedicated capacity in period k if state s is realized, i in period I Z^k, period k in it be the amount of product j from period be the profit from producing one unit of product in period period i realized, be the amount of product k=l is state s is realized, in period Zjjij a result, realized, is s period i convex Let be the cost of carrying one unit of product ^ijk violate are As be the constant revenue per unit sold of product k are demand inelastic so they violate Assumption A5. maximum be the Rji^ costs be the index of the sales period, state hij holding with linear costs and unitary inelastic restated as follows. Djjc and some to example. this USDP { by strictly uniqueness of the optimal solution k € sold, zero. but but not strictly convex, The up unit Hence, without loss of generality, production holding cost functions. concern for per production unit USDP with linear cost A firm facing unitary production costs can be absorbed into the revenue and then constant, So Y^ = of demand earns constant revenues inelastic curves example an and k=l 22 ![ and produced on flexible capacity k if state s is realized. = Y^^- + Z^.-. in The objective function can be V = -r'K + = The maximum II I XPs s written '^.jklvjjk+z; (y^.+ z;J i=A j=l k=l l imposes the following constraint: condition sales as: ^iik + Zji,^ + Yi2k + Zi2k ^ Dik for in addition to the usual constraints. This such techniques program, linear a is simplex the as so all can it and i,k, solved be method. s can It demand remaining yielding triplet capacity from yielding positive a one If lists formula general Z.jk K-AB- where has U(7Cx, T^y) Ky or Kx = extent greatest possible, the unit profit either until all (1) and TCy been allocated the k's descending in solving for linear the cost all (2) a k^. order second functions problem with Zijk), U(7rijk, 7tijk)(Yijk + Z,jk) Ki - rty - } Yjjk, U(7tijk, Kijk)Zijk in the list unitary U(7tijk, :tijk)Yijk - U(7tljk, 7tijk)Ziji^} modified unit step function. precedes a is: U(7iijk, JrijkXY.jk - then of profitability, stage + U(7:,jk, rtijk)Zijk is or profit. = Min{ Dik = Min{ D,k - Yijk per greatest demand and inelastic the One trivial. is product/production-period/sales-period the for the to solved demand has been product/production-period/sales-period combinations production met meeting, continues standard be also numerically because solving the second stage problem simply by of U(7ix. T^y) = 1 if :tx > Otherwise, U(;rx. Jtijk's. Ky) = 0. Example nature The example of relationship it considers the (parameterized uncertainty between about inventories two extreme and situations: by market flexible (1) ^) considers conditions capacity. when the firm how affects the the Specifically, knows with demand for each product will be, but it does not know how seasonal the demand will be (^ = 1) and (2) when the firm knows with certainty what total demand for each period will be, but certainty it = what does not total know how it will be divided between the two products (^ 0). 23 The underlying demand product However, random each in actual the with variable and period, assumed is demand total demand be for one unit of each to is always product/period in pair four units. (A,l) a is following distribution: the x Pai = 1-2Pai x=1 x Assume for moment the =2 these that random two variables are independent. Furthermore, let ^ ^ < 1 be the fraction of the change demand for product/period pairs (A,l) and same product but the other period, and comes from the the variability is between periods. same period but 3.1 - ^ be 1 the other product. between products, and Table (B,2) that if ^ = 1, Table 3.1 Description of s the Thus all fraction if ^ = Demand States the that 0, all the variability summarizes the demand distribution each of the nine possible states of the world. State comes from in is in between when happens what consider First = ^ so 1 Similarly, pairs. product/period and states and 2(Ka + Kg)). relative to over both holding - 2(Ka + second stage assume costs and both products meet demand if K^s^^ ^ under each state r^B > (Specifically, idle - [1 how much are large - 2Pai)(1 - (1 i.e., K^^ = inventory be will s. (fab - ta - 2 fAB < ta + 2 PaiPb2 Likewise, optimal. Kg = otherwise. 1 Hence, for holding the (l/2)(4 - revenues and holding of part the costs function objective to: Max V = if in easy to solve the is it do not depend on the decision variables, the reduces for four is costs any purchased capacity; determine to constant the investment capital With these assumptions Kg)). problems Ignoring that all always firm the periods firm can always Finally, (l/2)(4 So, ensure for so they can be omitted from the objective 2PB2)]h) so the firm does not held to equal be sold unit enough high be solutions, all so the state, per product/period all With these assumptions revenues are the same Demand function. revenues let pairs meets demand. every is periods. Let the per unit holding costs h be equal for all variability all costs cost of h, PaiPbz h)KA + - 2 PaiPb2 h)KB. rfi is optimal. Otherwise, Ka = is Ka = is optimal; ^b + 2 PaiPbz h, then Kb = then tab < if (tAB " 1 is. problem and these parameter values, increasing this favors investment in flexible capacity, and decreasing reduces amount capacity flexible expected the So flexible capacity and inventory are inventory. however, that even if nine states inventory only flexible capacity is still This used. is is of Note, substitutes. purchased, in six of the simply because no amount of flexible capacity can shift a unit from one period to the next; only inventory can. favors then Also, investment Kab = is purchase flexible variability, capacity. optimal no matter how increasing Pai or Pb2. i.e. (However, large Pbz that if is, if Pai ^ for were positively correlated the firm would be less flexible one would capacity expect and, conversely, 25 if —2h— and vice versa.) demand Intuitively products in increasing their two the likely demand to were 5 negatively correlated, This intuition flexible capacity. Suppose P(s = 6) = P(s = PaPb + Then £• demand for function is Now will The firm knows 2e =. — = in for A and The objective r= and stockout meet demand under the possible there all variability what demand will the severe, is each in divided be or high, sufficiently is firm will long as Pai and Pb2 are both ^ 2-Min{KA, Kg} because it is of as demand optimal not is it it capacity. flexible one product. always optimal to have Ka = be four units and 2, Then and inventories, so 0, are sufficiently are implies that this revenues If states. = ^ certain for must have Kab will and Kab = B. costs all firm rg, 2(PaiPb2 - e)h)KB. rfi- know how demand does not it A products nonzero, extreme, other the but be, equivalently, 0, P is demand favors larger demand favors investment in consider between products. Tab < ta + demand coefficient between correlated correlated negatively between invest to and P(s = 5) = P(s = 9) = e = (rAB- ta- 2(PaiPb2 - e)h)KA + (rAB" positively season likely now Max V So, = PaiPb2 - same period the in more be correct. is 8) correlation the B would firm the Since for inventory carry to 0, Kg = even if holding costs are zero! Clearly case this The only way capacity. be in demanded is to inventory A can create 2-Min{KA, Kg} is stockout costs converts one converted initial are not product into dollar substitute for flexible large. which In a sense, Shortage another. losses of even a single unit of product B. not necessarily optimal, however, arbitrarily into will No amount capacity. flexible inventory of product Kab ^ a meet uncertainty about which product purchase to not is can be of one recovered stocking out product by if is reduced outlays or increased sales of another product. example suggests that insight can be gained by decomposing total demand variability into variability between This products suited and for variability meeting between variability periods. between 26 Flexible products capacity and is best inventory is best the suited meeting for objective function by either product which flexible periods in variability measured is either capacity and inventory this example, between periods. in period, stocking out provides compensate can which can be generated dollars, compensate can However, since means by variability between variability between for for a products. In negatively investment how this safety correlated in flexible stock both increasing demand capacity. for This considerations would paper for seasonal stock variability the general products and favored matches intuition and suggests modify considerations. 27 two in the results obtained in Known 4 The This section one results KSDP identical is for the Known of the USD? case special a vary periodically, conditions of the reports (KSDP), Problem Demand Problem Seasonal but are USDP which in market The formulation deterministic. of the to that Demand Seasonal except that there state. Market conditions are rarely deterministic, so model applied be will practice, in nonetheless. For example, we observe investing flexible in can capacity useful gives but it that (1) insights holding inventory and complements, be unlikely this is it (2) can it optimal to purchase less capacity dedicated to a product than in any period, and (3) Section if gives 4.1 not, expressions revenue case is KSDP. in called some optimal the functions that always hold. fact, for are analysis sensitivity how are Seasonal (1988). is when variables This linear. special Demand Problem or Qsolutions to the Q-KSDP. derived. Section 4.4 gives results. results were compressed sufficiently informative. one might expect to be decision the costs solution The derivations of these 4.1 of and KSDP the to possible to obtain closed form is It Known the sold constant. solutions 'properties' Section 4.2 gives properties of optimal Section 4.3 describes be known and is of optimal values quadratic Quadratic the demand its is be be optimal to use flexible capacity to properties and shows by example do may it produce a product even true just is They are to are present reported in quite here, their involved, they and if they would no longer entirety in Caulkins Interested readers are invited to request a copy. Properties of Optimal Solutions The following statements about production and inventory hold for all optimal solutions to the 1) If it is optimal to purchase flexible capacity, used to produce one product the other KSDP. in it will all one period and the other product period. 28 be in For 2) acquired at fully is utilized capacity All 3) one least product, capacity that is both periods. in utilized fully is dedicated the in at one least of two the periods. 4) It never is product/period pairs any optimal inventory carry to which flexible capacity in product/period is which out both of used. 5) In all dedicated capacity for that product will also be employed. used, also is It possible pair in make statements to capacity flexible relating production product in is and sales. There 6) which sales other period. 7) for product are that sales If never slack capacity is for Sales capacity flexible in for is at least at a as great as a they period are in the in product are constant, capacity dedicated to that a product will be fully utilized 8) for least used both periods. in one of the product/period pairs must be greater than sales for which in that product other period. the 9) the If optimal solution has sales of both products equal in each period, then no inventory or flexible capacity will be used. Combining these properties gives Theorem KSDP, 4. If 1 it optimal is to the following useful result. purchase flexible capacity for the then in the optimal solution either: Zai = ^82= K^B. Za2=Zbi = (Ya2 = Ka or Ybi = Kb or or Ib2 = (1^1 = ( Sai> Sa2 or Sbi < 0, Y^i = Ka, Yb2= Kg, or both), both), and Sb2 or both), or 2ai=Zb2=0,Z;^=Zbi= KaB' Ya2= Ka, Ybi = Kg, (Yai = Ka or Yb2 = Kb or both), (Ia2 = ( And, or Ibi Sai< Sa2 if Za1=Za2= it is Zbi = = or both), and or Sbi > Sb2 or both). optimal to purchase Zb2=0- 29 no flexible capacity, then As a result, optimal all belong solutions one to of three The two Kab =0 and two with Kab > 0categories with Kab >0 are symmetric (See Figure 4.1.) because either product could be called product A and, by Assumptions A 10 one categories, with and All, either the odd or the even periods could be labelled with a Figure 4.1 Optimal Patterns of Allocation of Flexible Capacity Za2- Kab> Zbi = Period Product A Product B X Period 2 1 X and linear expect particular, can lead use flexible inventories demand." just the i.e. The the true the A Product B KSDP that do present and/or minimum that in will be in every dedicated the at least sold in any fori = A,B. 30 demand always hold. appealing period capacity might and In heuristic to state, coupled meet and with demand in excess of base how to meet swing demand. as much dedicated capacity symbols, k' > Min{s-j} fact, intuitively does not specify firm to purchase used. one 'properties' "Use dedicated capacity meet 'swing demand', heuristic several following is with unitary inelastic not, solutions. demand capacity to tells that suboptimal to demand', 'base be to shows it of a demonstrates costs intuitively as Product Period 2 1 denotes a product/period pair in which flexible capacity The following example It Period state and period. In This heuristic simplifies demand so the analysis meeting swing demand. problem the on can focus by the 'subtracting more base out' problem of difficult Example rA = rB= r^ 1.0 Dai =5 Da2 = = 1.1 Dbi=0 5 ^Al = hA2 = 0.25 Db2 = 10 hBi = hB2 Rai = Ra2 = Rbi = Rb2 = By Hbi = hB2 = «> it is meant = ~ °°- holding costs for product B that high the firm would never inventory product B. = Rbi=Rb2='*' means demand always is problem reduces Using met. to ensure KSDP. the the following linear program: the to of properties the so Rai = Ra2 Similarly. high enough stockout costs are that are Max -Ka-Ke-1.1Kab-0.1Iai s.t. Ke+Kab^ Ka+ Kab- Iai Ka+Iai 5 ^ 10 ^ with Ka, Kb, Kab. and The > >0 5 and heuristic Kb ^ Ka = is: optimal 12.25, 5, is solution if nonnegative. Iai K^ ^ Min\ = Ka 0, minimum It may be to 5, to for the its given a to some of sales optimal demand is over to all use striking state/period flexible known and purchase no capacity dedicated to 3 I that is ^ 5 It and Kg The 15. true a cost of parameter values, gives the optimal conclusions. much dedicated capacity as pairs. capacity constant. cost Its Ka and Kab = ^0 ^^^^ not always optimal to purchase as the if So, = 0. assume Ka safe to by constrained and Kab = 0, Iai is it suboptimal solution. 1.375 or if hAi = hA2 > 0.8. leads rAB > It even 0. Kg = implies that solution completely different. 1) 2) = 10, Iai This example leads is S,j/ The optimal Kb = solution: heuristic the 0. 5 In to fact, product. produce it may a product be optimal and capacity Flexible 3) inventory can 1.375 no inventory or flexible capacity is used, is A optimal to inventory 5 units of product each even period and decreasing the acquire to cost of complements. be but if < r^^^ 1.375, from each odd period 10 units of flexible capacity. can capacity flexible increase 1-1' if unit, no longer is it holding increasing Properties KSDP The A5. called is Quadratic-Known Seasonal Demand the strictly cannot be guaranteed, but if the model parameters set, then the any continuous is Q-KSDP many model (There parameters continuous are condition is satisfied satisfied, solution will violate solution that does could in with it the not is property, violate principle the be probability 1, in and any capacity: 32 there property. violated "knife- certain a each property.) for according open any the by these the an optimal always an optimal Hence, an if that case is any to set, although optimal solution these solution, See Caulkins (1988) for optimal open solutions Furthermore, even 0. always not can safely be assumed that they hold. With distributed probability of optimal satisfy over for 0. conditions distribution probability conditions properties randomly are any over distribution exactly different are distribution probability additional properties parameters are linear, uniqueness of the optimal nonuniqueness occurs with probability condition. Q-KSDP and so violate Assumption convex, that edge" flexible in revenue functions and linear holding is the So, Q-KSDP the to this unless Similarly, capacity. investment Since the holding costs for the convex but not For the Thus, increase above 0.8 per flexible less to Solutions with quadratic the If lead The only consequence of solution hold can of Optimal Problem (Q-KSDP). are purchase to to smaller inventories. and production costs they optimal costs capacity as well as 4.2 A holding costs for product it optimal inventory levels as well as investment in flexible capacity. with r^B = 1^3 > If using it details. flexible The firm (1) in not will which flexible capacity one If (2) both or inventory carry both into product/period pairs used. is dedicated of types capacity used are then inventory of both products will not be carried into the same period. capacity If (3) not is fully utilized some product/period in no inventory of either product will be carried into both If (4) carried types into possible is leads to some very long, inventory used, are only pairs. Q-KSDP. and completely solve the to The derivation of useful insights. is be will Q-KSDP of the It capacity period. that most one of the four product/period at Solution 4.3 dedicated of then pair described briefly here solution this which solution, the but can and Zjj for found be is in its entirety in Caulkins (1988). There are 15 decision variables: 1,2 and for r; i of which variables are positive are their at not but boundary of derivative of the objective variables equal to Solving optimality. order conditions expressions strategy properties in optimal. It decision there that sufficient Section is the of these free condition for first form when values optimal possible conditions expressions for its for derive to the in It a show one can 4.1, category. optimal within conditions, setting closed yields variables variables' the comprised of the of equations free on that over four million strategies, but using the are each of the strategies within the all necessary upper variables be so strategy, a a = optimal. is In principle for of gives system the the for always to their definition, with respect to one function zero By at bound cannot upper their at j defined as a specification is upper bound. corresponding region the strategy = A.B and i which are positive but not zero, bound, and which are that A = A, B, and AB. Yij, Ijj, is only that necessary and strategy in a decision variables to be optimal find necessary category with K^g > category for a fixed value of Kab- the conditions to possible also sufficient K^^ = category with can ever be 137 derived from and to Then using the first be the order one can compute the optimal value within the category as 33 a function of categories three optimal Comparing K^^^^. for of within and period, optimal values No one these of intuition the overall the Sensitivity Since decision variables have all objective itself function. is particularly is the interpretations and results for key to developing Q-KSDP the gives form closed strategies all expressions terms in of of any function Y the for the problem of the decision be computed rule: dY* aY* dx 3x partial aY* 5Kab derivatives If the ^AB = ^nd there (4.1) 3x -.T^* optimal solution directly. 0' for the sensitivity K^^^, each in general. in for by cost expressions the and analysis sensitivity demand with respect to changes in a parameter x can by the chain The the holding conditions variables give and of do as interpretations to solution the and decision able Analysis variables parameters interpretations, economic problem The be to conditions comparing strength K^. strategy a demand the to for types: relative on the following the for of being but significant, the economic the obtaining on conditions straightforward of three are capacity conditions conditions sufficient category its dedicated of cost parameters, 3Y — — Z is and in 3Y no alternate solution with is can be computed the category of solutions with K^ dK* > 0, then dx * 0. yields Kj^q solution. optimal 4.4 values possible all The necessary and the optimal solutions within each of the the For solutions with K^ > * 'AB (4.2) ax 34 V^ denotes where denotes the second the derivative partial derivative, partial by differentiating the obtained _a_ av (Ka^x), a x) Rearranging By strategies that gives can aV (K^x). aK^^x) ^^ be = 0. ^^AB^' ^k^k^ optimal be V,, x, formula can This etc.... to (4.2).' computation, direct x| aK^B terms respect 0. V (Ka^x). dK AB ax with order condition first av(KA^xU) = dK AB V of nonzero (with negative strictly is for probability), so all (4.2) aK vD does not division entail bv Furthermore, zero. sgn( . ) = dx sV With and (4.1) variable to straightforward any of but particular strategy the derivatives of do have and strategies the all not if all, of that increase or will etc..) same. remain the used be Similarly to for 'decreases'.) and using amount of used, insights. can be zero for certain combinations of strategies, the The most important of inventory the economic interesting (Since most, so they will be described. quantities term on general yield term 'increases' (increasing, greater than, more, describe were however, are the same for derivatives, the not depend they a is derivatives the because here decision parameters model's of any of sensitivity values hence and used, The signs of many of interpretations, The reported not are the reduced the calculation. computed combinations obtaining (4.2), capacity flexible into a not the in product/period pair is product/period pair and a for the which in using complement 35 that in of carrying cost substitute a is holding always substitutes. pair Hence, pairs. results increasing is product/period and decreasing product/period are capacity flexible these flexible inventory flexible carrying to cost The optimal carrying of capacity out is of those capacity inventory carrying inventory in into inventory out a that of product/period that product/period analysis sensitivity one with associated product are one with associated priori which to allocated, general complementarity the reveals how affected by decision changes or product, ^ = the sensitivity for variables parameters in Y For any function associated with the other product. variables be will about a and flexible capacity. of inventory substitutability The made be known not is it capacity flexible pairs cannot statements Since pair. of the decision parameters x all dx with associated by the second term of entirely a product, other the (4.1), parameter associated with product value of y^AB' then amount of -1 since product absolute value. product i's dedicated other the holding costs in affect a the capacity dedicated to product may other period but generally has increased the out of that the investment direction of the amount no greater in Thus changes in . amount of their effect capacity on the other capacity flexible Production product. decrease, overall but firm the period. demand If capacity effect for product a it will and used, is thus of less other the production will inventory less of the also inventory less of the will Increased dedicated on investment 36 demand and in demand opposite effect on inventories. in optimal the which flexible capacity in more As one would expect, product through solution. product out of that period, but first to or change shows how changes pair purchase increase only also optimal the — the with associated (dKABl = sgnl— K[, capacity. product/period to increase. product analysis optimal is will it optimal the affect flexible sensitivity increases sgnl parameters to The /d|K-+KABJl Hence amount of it parameter a opposite direction and by an the in changing if Furthermore, product. other — K" Hence, . does not influence the optimal i capacity dedicated to the dK'1 ^ 377 ^ 0, if changing value of then ^^ changes the optimal value of K^b. i optimal . determined is not influence the optimal value of will it so in to the flexible in the other It also leads first product, capacity and capacity dedicated in is other product depends the to on which strategy in use. If in which Production possible that production of the second product surprisingly, On of out than out decrease of inventory If costs more and direction of overall values. carry the will and pair purchase less capacity became product may Finally, the all demand down. Inventory- product, either so total if more costs a pair. product, first the parameter inventory used, is will, It on carry to capacity flexible such into depend levels the to The product. other the to dedicated capacity it purchase more flexible will into firm the a will however, increase its same two periods. the price of one of the dedicated capacities increases the firm capacity. are magnitude product. first for firm the other product between flexible other the dedicated which in inventory the of in inventory into a product/period pair in production Not surprisingly, inventory of the If on effects capacity, less product/period that smaller be will affected used, is capacity less product/period not carry to which flexible capacity capacity inventory is of Not decrease. levels it in overall in decrease. will out less increase that period other the decrease the increase an to is it inventory more of the other product will it the in rise will and increase, offset production inventory will but period, that giving overall other hand, the the and than product that cenainly possible that both production of is it firm the more will of may product other the product, first Of course production. pair. of production used, is increase its inventory out of a product/period pair carry to capacity flexible decrease. the more costs it consistent increases, of both kinds Production more of expensive increase derivatives with profits or the whose product more dedicated production decrease; will and of the decrease. of one's capacity dedicated of the optimal intuition increase. 37 objective about When the costs function model. go up. value When profits go Conclusions and Discussion 5 The advent manufacturing flexible economic the assessing of value of capacity conditions so extends value gives the case when assessing firm can the the hold and building insights. intuition FMS to for This paper on the complete solution for a special case, reports some The T+1 FMS's of product-flexible inventory, explore both in one model. to Freund (1986, 1987) model and Fine the useful is systems both ways firms can respond to varying market are it manufacturing flexible made has Holding inventory and investing in (FMS's) an active research topic. flexible technology investment decision problem was formulated as a first programming problem called the General Stochastic Demand Problem (GSDP) that explicitly allows the firm to hold inventory. Few analytic results investment period GSDP can be obtained for the uncertainty market about Section dynamic production some unless imposed on the structure is conditions. considers 3 and GSDP when the variability the in market known when production and inventory decisions are made but unknown at the time the firm makes its With this structure it is possible to show a investment decision. conditions and periodic is unique optimal solution exists; give explicit formulas for the optimal Karush-Kuhn-Tucker conditions for optimal value characterize for the to it a is the special multipliers; and necessary state sufficient be optimal to purchase flexible capacity; show the and well-behaved function of the capacity costs; optimal solution as a function case of quadratic revenue and of capacity the costs holding cost functions and linear production costs. 4 reports Section market conditions its investment stated for is drawn from functions and the the periodic decision. general on and known Many revenue case special and at properties cost when time the of the the optimal functions as variability are firm in makes solutions are conclusions complete solution for the case of quadratic revenue linear production and holding costs. 38 Two can capacity determining allowed be intuition can be misleading. is for and results, such numerical those as to from results special expected to capacity not Although 2) demand is produce a demand is not vary 3) demand of the of modellers and Section 4 problems, those the solution is a but a that paper will Some practitioners. are on hoped is this in The rule. depends the it are practice, In the Likewise, and long, closed form solutions and the examples case is unguided that that be guarantee that 3, is it when inventories probably parameters. consequence of the can following the is to investing be of holding flexible in market variability, the two They may be complements, not possible to cost and inventory how changes or make substitutes, general statements about inventory the affect value the cost of flexible capacity in of affect levels. may be optimal to purchase flexible capacity even In fact, it can be optimal known with certainty. exclusively product known with with flexible and demand certainty even capacity for if if to all product does that over time. Sometimes into two uncertainty between first it the in inventory It Section in substitutes. flexible capacity optimal the models. numerical ways firms respond both how changes from holding Hence or neither. considers importantly, capacity will that are showed realistic and more generally. hold always solutions special of more flexible inventories only seems unlikely it flexible for examples the are of intuition the structure 1) are of this analysis contribute 4 example the Hence inferences well-behaved function the and obtained draw to value the be will ability when more and that certainty of Section in are 4 investment model complex, itself intuition world a flexibility, solution allowed Section Nevertheless, the derivation of the solution deterministic. expressions in FMS a The product of benefits of difficult. is even useful value the from conclusions overall it is useful components: periods. to decompose uncertainty Flexible kind of uncertainty; inventory is 39 capacity between is about uncertainty products most useful most useful for the for second. and the 4) demand 'base demand', met with use dedicated to knows firm the Thus heuristics dedicated capacity, and period. state be always optimal not is It will for certain that 'subtract leaving capacity exist in every base demand, to out' smaller a meet to and hopefully simpler problem can lead to suboptimal solutions. The ultimate objective of research of FMS's investment models develop tools practitioners can use to to is the process, so it be done the at require will literature them on testing Developing making. decision in economic evaluation the in world problems. real important that is a level of practical the including This will be a long and difficult begin now, but there it from tools of work, deal great technology assist is also more to academic research. This paper was based on the Fine and Freund (1986, 1987) model quantifying for number of models the in product than other value the FMS's. product-flexible of flexibility. focus that literature is It likely There are a on benefits of FMS's extending that them to consider inventory effects would yield useful insights. There are and/or invest in cycle considerations, and economies life have between models and even inventories and flexible include that statements focuses all about the exclusively other the different quite three effects unlikely of to the on Hence capacity. nature overall hold inventory These factors can of scale. opposing are firms market conditions, product varying capacity: flexible why reasons three least at yield the relationship comprehensive simple, relationship. qualitative This paper on the effects of varying market conditions, but two deserve study. Further work could center on these related problems, but there how holding inventory affects the value of product-flexible FMS's when market conditions vary. The analysis in this paper rests on many assumptions and simplifications. It would be useful to know what results presented here continue to hold when these assumptions and simplifications is also are certainly to be learned about relaxed. Direct may more not be generalizations the of the model most productive avenue 40 presented for further here, however, research. The how holding problem of determining no flexibility with conditions is possible because to analyze. considered it Periodic conditions. structure particular too general inventory conditions are to affects variability the The analysis in value the this market in thesis varying periodically complex enough to of was market bring out the dynamics of the interaction between inventory and flexible capacity, but simple explore be enough other interesting analysis. facilitate of market types but to simple variability enough to simpler above, that constituents, variability between overall such as that variability 41 are be useful to complex enough to may the results the idea decomposed between periods into to can variability products. would analyze and compare The key obtained with those presented here. mentioned It this be be and References M.C., Burstein, Automation "Finding the Manufacturing", for ORSAITIMS Conference on New Economical Mix of Rigid and Flexible Flexible Proceedings the of Second Manufacturing Systems, Elsevier: York, 1986. Caulkins, "Inventory and the Strategic Value of Product-Flexible J. P., Manufacturing Systems", Department of Electrical Engineering M.I.T. and Computer Science Masters Thesis, August, 1988. Fine, C.H. and R.M. Freund, "Economic Analysis of Product-Flexible Manufacturing System Investment Decisions", Proceedings of the 2nd ORSAITIMS Conference on New Manufacturing Systems^ Elsevier: York, 1986. , "Optimal Capacity", M.I.T. 86, Flexible Investment in Manufacturing Product-Flexible Sloan School of Management Working Paper #1803- December 1987. Fine, Flexible Automation", Paper #1959-87, Fine, "Technology Choice. Product Life Cycles, and C.H. and L. Li, C.H. and Sloan School of Management Working November 1987. S. Product-Market M.I.T. Pappu, "Flexible Competition", Manufacturing Sloan M.I.T. School Technology of and Management Mimeo, August 1988. Gaimon, C, "The Strategic Decision Proceedings Manufacturing of the Acquire Flexible Technology", ORSAITIMS Conference Elsevier: New York, 1986. Second Systems, to 42 on Flexible Gerwin, Case D., "Control Flexible of and Manufacturing Engineering Management, Graves, "Safety S., and Manufacturing Vol. Stocks the in Systems", EM-28, No. Innovation IEEE Management, Operations Transactions on August 1981, 62-70. 3, Manufacturing in The Process: Systems", Vol. Journal No. 1, 1, of Spring 67-101. 1988, He, Evaluation and H. R.S. Pindyck, "Investments Production Flexible Management Mimeo, May 1988. Capacity", M.I.T. Sloan School of Hutchinson, G.K. and J.R. in "The Economic Value of Flexible Holland, Automation", Journal of Manufacturing Systems, Vol. 1, No. 2, 1982, 215-228. Kaplan, "Must R.S., CIM be Business Review, Vol. 64, No. Karmarkar, U.S. and and Mix Decisions S. Kekre, Justified 2, "Manufacturing Configuration, Capacity Considering Operational Systems, 1987. Kelly, K., "That Old-Time Accounting Week, No. 3055, June Kulatilaka, N., When Harvard Alone?", March-April 1986, 87-97. Manufacturing Business by Faith 6, Isn't Costs", Journal of Good Enough Anymore", 1988, 112. "Optimal Switching Modes and the Value of Flexibility Firms Face Stochastic Prices", Proceedings of the 1986 IEEE International Conference on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, Atlanta. GA, October 1986, 846-851. , "Economic Value of Management Mimeo, Flexibility", Boston University School of 1987. Kulatilaka, N. and S.G. Marks, "The Value of Flexibility in a Certainty", World of Boston University School of Management .Mimeo, February 1985. 43 "The Strategic Value of , Compromise", Boston Paper #5/86, July Michael, Computer-Based School of to Management Working 1986. and G.J. University Reducing the Ability Flexibility: R.A. "Economic Millen, Automation Factory A Equipment: Modern of Justification Status Report", Proceedings of the First ORSA/TIMS Special Interest Conference on Flexible Manufacturing Systems, Ann Arbor, MI, August 1984, 30-35. Week, No. 3055, Miles, G., "Selling Rockwell on Automation", Business June 6, Pindyck, 1988, 104. R.S., "Irreversible Value of the Firm", NBER Capacity Investment, and Choice, the Working Paper No. 1980, Cambridge, MA, 1986. Port, O., R. King, and W. Hampton, "How the Adds Up", Business Week, No. 3055, June 6, New Math 1988. 103 of Productivity - 114. Roth, A., C. Gaimon, and L. Krajewski, "Optimal Acquisition of Technology Subject Technological to Progress", Boston FMS University School of Management Working Paper, 1986. "Numbers Don't Schiller, Z., June 6, Suresh, Flexible 1988, N.C. Tell the Story", Business 105. and J.R. "A Generic Approach Meredith, Manufacturing Systems", Proceedings ORSA/TIMS Special Interest Conference on Systems^ Ann Arbor, MI, August 1984, 36-42. Vander Veen, Week, No. 3055, D. and Machine Investment and W. Jordan, Utilization", Working Paper, Warren, MI, 1987. 44 Flexible "Analyzing General Justifying to of the First Manufacturing Trade-offs Between Motors Research Labs Varian, H., Microeconomic Analysis, Norton 1978. 45 & Company: New York, s s Appendix: Proof of Theorem 3.2 Proof: KKT conditions except perhaps mi for be complete By AB = A, B, and shown is it V satisfies so the direct substitution they these and VI. So, the proof multipliers three Let X be any set — shown be will it V. satisfies are of optimal _S X that variables all are nonnegative. that multipliers. First the obvious that is it in determined uniquely is and IV, - I i if and X nonnegative KKT E 3.1, defined multipliers above are uniquely specified. multipliers will of collection the By Theorem theorem. satisfy denote Let X _S Sij-qii = s s _s So since the optimal solution is unique, by III, Y Ps\ ^i2~hii- Rii/. ~s ~s —s ^s _S —S _s _S _s _s Likewise, 5i2- qi2= 5i2 - q,2 Since 5ij q^ = 0, 5.i-qii = Sii - qn~S ^S _s _s > and Similarly, the formulas in the J q^ > q^ for all i,j, and s. 5ij 5, _s _s — s ~s ~s __s . • Theorem KKT and Transposing condition ~S s a,j=a,j + terms, ~s ~s _s aij>aij. Similarly, multipliers, imply _s / _„S ( 5..- _s - Sy+ Because X . is Hence, since a > V. 5^- Sij= a^- — ~s -s \ 5.J a,j- Since Sjj. 5,j- s^. — s a^ Sij= 0, ~ Yj^Yj satisfies it I an optimal y > a, set of and q > "i, KKT q, X also satisfies V. —* ~' Next will be it = Oifi"J<rij. So S Then and since KKT shown 7jjY-j _S if satisfies VI. s Since X satisfies VI, SyYjj =0. Suppose l\>'s;y Also, from the formulas in the Theorem 7jj>rjj implies Y-j s a^ Sij=0, condition = X I, 0^, 7jj =0. = 7'j ~ + (5ij-5j-(aij- a-J • So if rij>s'ij, it must ~S _s be that Since X is an optimal set of multipliers, by V 5,, > 5;;. ~s ^% —S — s ~s S S S implies Furthermore, since that > I,j=Y,j+Zij. q^, 5ij 5ij- qij= 5ij ~s — _S _s s and thus By VI this implies lij = Sjj > 5ij implies that q^j > qi,>0. Y-j =0. Hence s"ij>7ij implies yJj = 0. 46 So since SjjYJ, = 0, s^,jYJ, = 0. Next "ij implies that ~s V^ t'y = y'j ~S _s > q,, llj ' q, MlJ- — + zJj Next , > Yj^Yj. ~ .. . ~s _s u,j>Uij. > since 6, - q, an optimal set of multipliers, ~» Likewise, 5,j > implies that is s lij=0. =0. Hence u,j>u,j implies Z-j=0,so be shown that mAKA=0. If mAKA>0, = 0. so Z-j UjjZij will then 01^ > it _ K^ and Then S.-q,- Since 5,j>5,j. Since X . implies qij>qij^O Suppose that UijZij=0. and = "u+l5ij-5j-[Yj-Yj this I-j shown will be it Ka> 0. s mA= implies _s 2 So by IV, rA= XX°^Aj. and thus . S=l J=l "^A = 2-2^\"aj~ *^aJ^ This implies there . some exists state/period S=l J=l pair ~s _s a,j>a,j. such that (s,j) ~s implies _S 5ij>5jj, ~s implies S V which by implies S _s which q,j>qij. S Z^> implies ~s Finally, m^ ~* shown =rA-SS«A. ^ mg > m^ and > So X 0. X Furthermore, K > K multipliers. by IV > implies and the XS"aj a set of optimal unique the is and So X m^ = nonnegative. are m^ VI. satisfies ^ Similarly, 0. S=l J=l Suppose X and X are 0. Hence is qjj r^ - S=lj=l to s lij=0. m^,mB, that required are steps "" —s s and q^ lij=0, q,j will be it Since aij>a,j, _s > q|j So Contradiction. Iaj=0. Similarly mBKB = 0. Several more '^aKa=0show m^K^ = 0, but the reasoning is similar. Also, since . s VI by Ya,= Ka>0. Yaj+ Iaj= ~S _s Also a,j>aij ~S _s Buta,j>a,j also s Then by V, tw^o m^ = mg formulas in set KKT multipliers. KKT of optimal distinct vectors = m^B = the of m^ = Theorem, multipliers if KKT optimal = mB = rn^e XX ^aj = ""a • = s=lj=l S 2 ^^5 ^^ s XS^aj- ,^ s s "^ s So since a,j>a,j, a,j=a,j for all i,j, and s. Similarly, Y = Y. s=lj=l Then unless by I, ~S _s 5„ > 5,>0 5 -j + F-j = 5 _S and ,j + T.j . Since 5,j>5,j, 5,j+ s,j= ~ ~S s„> s,>0. 47 But since X 6,j VI, s,j ~S s,,>s,, -5 satisfies + — 5 implies Yy = implies ujj 0. Similarly, > Uij>0 which Assumption A6, Y* = smce implies 0<Ki — Y=Y, ~S _S 5ij+ Uij= 5,j Zij=0. Yij= Z-j= implies ~S _S lij=0. Then by _S __s + u^, so 5^ > implies I, I-j = . YPsR-j(O)- 5ij By cJj(O) = aii-Sii-Sji- But Sij>0 implies 0^=0, so r[j(0)- cjj(0)< which Thus And since contradicts Assumption A8. 5 = 6, s = s, andu = u _ ~ ~ ~s ~s _ _s _s q = q. Thus X = X, contradicting the hypothesis that 5ij+ Sij= 5ij + Sij, • they are distinct. So if K > 0, the formulas above are unique. k^hl U32 48 optimal multipliers given by the Date Due Lib-26-67 MiT 3 '=1060 MBRARIF<; niiPi J 00Sb?M33 5