FEB S'iS88 I ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT OVERIKWESTMENT WITH RELATION- SPECIFIC CAPITAL Rotemberg and Garth Saloner Julio J. Working Paper #1950-87 October 1987 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 OVERIKWESTMENT WITH RELATION- SPECIFIC CAPITAL Julio J. Rotemberg and Garth Saloner Working Paper #1950-87 October 1987 Overinvestment With Relation-Specific Capital Julio J. Rotemberg''' and Garth Saloner* October 1987 Abstract We consider a situation in which one party (the owner) owns a project. He is better informed than another party (tlie worl<er) about the payoff this project would have if investment specific to their Initially many workers compete to be the relationship is undertaken. owner's partner in the project. If the investment is undertaken the worker gains knowledge which makes him worth more than other workers and which allows him to capture some of the payoffs of the project We show that the equilibrium contract generally involves overinvestment We consider both the case in which the owner can credibly commit never to undertake the project with a different worker and the case in which he can't. In the former case tliere is always . overinvestment. In the latter case, there are multiple equilibria. Overinvestment equilibria always exist, underinvestment equilibria never exist and efficient equilibria sometimes exist. We would like to thank Drew Fudenberg, Oliver Hart, Paul Klemperer, Meg Meyer, Paul Milgrom and Jean Tirole for helpful conversations and comments, and the National Science Foundation (grants SES 8R19004 and 1ST-85101G2) for financial support. ''"MIT. , 1 FEB 81988 When assets arc specific 1o a particular relationship, the contractual forms that are feasible for governing the relationship are crncial in determining the ability of the parties to exploit The importance profitable investment opportunities. of relation- specific assets derives from the quasi-rents they create. These quasi-rents are the difference between the value of the assets current relationship and their value such assets are instaDed, at least if to the relationship earns less, under any original agreement, than the By threatening quasi-rents. new (more favorable) to Once the relationship ceases. one party the in total vaJiie of the withdraw from the relationship unless contractxial terms are agreed, that party may be able to Improve his outcome. If the original contract cannot prohibit renegotiation, inefficient investment in relation-specific assets in the original undertaken at contract may be distorted, all, efficient. Klein, This idea a is result. a vertically integrated market transaction would olherwise be more central to the work of Williamson Crawford, and Alchian (1978) who suggest that underinvestment will Prices some projects not and others mediated within enterprise even when may result. (1975) and in general For example, Klein, Crawford, and Alchian (1978, page 301) conclude: "...Less specific investments will be made to avoid being locked in". Several recent papers have formalized these ideas. (1984) considers the relationship between a union and a firm latter must decide whether or not to undertake a Grout where the T-elationship- specific - 3 Efficiency requires that the firm be reimiMirsotl investment. the cost of the investment the gains from if Grout points out, however, that costs. (through excessive share of the gains once they are invest even it if is worthwhile. iTivestment exceed a its attempt to garner an to reali7,ed, may not the firm on the other hand, binding If, contracts are possible, investment will obviously be efficient WhUe least the imion cannot commit if binding long-term contract) not a llie at 1 . binding long-term contract ensures efficiency this in several authors have pointed out that efficiency can be setting, obtained with simpler, less complete contracts. 2 Tlic reason is that farsighted agents are able to anticipate the outcome of the anticipated bargaining and can make transfers before in\'estment must take place that are sufficient to yield efficiency. example, the parties realize that the agent if investment wilJ fall ex post transfer of $x to that pa7-1y in (Notice too that partners competing for competition In this tlie among them who must make will , it the they can, ox a nte, agree is contract of this kind, if there are many is potential noninvesting right to participate in the relationship, result in an offer of $x for that right.) mutually worthwhile. it to a the contingency that the investment way the investing party can always he induced investment when for $x short of recouping the cost of the investment in the division of the spoils undertaken. Thus, In order to to make the implement a must be possible for the third party enforcing the contract to observe whether the investment did take place: investment must be a contractible activit.y. in fact llolmstrom and 4 - - Hart (1906) provide an example (along the lines of Grossman and Hart (1986) and Moore and Hart (1985)) that illustrates that underinvestment can even investment is res\jlt if bargaining and efficient is observable to the parties, provided investment not is also contractible. While that example shows that underinvestment can result investment is in addition, IV) shows that noncontractible, Tirole (1986, Sec. bargaining inefficient, is underinvestment a characteristic of the optimal contract. must undertake if, necessarily s In his model the "firm" (unobservable relationship-specific investment a i if to the other party, the "sponsor") that determines the firm's costs of producing a good that that the sponsor desires. Aftei- tlie investment has been made, only the sponsor learns the value of the good. parties then bargain (under incomplete information) about firm should be paid if it produces. how The mvicli the Since mutually beneficial opportunities are typically foregone when bargaining occurs under incomplete information, the firm anticipates thai full benefits of its investment and so invests too In contrast to Tirole adverse selection it in (1986) which one will not reap little. we focus instead on of the parties value of the relationship prior to the time 1lio situations of (the "owner") when the knows the relation- spe cific investment must take place but the other (the "worker") does not. Such an asymmetry tlie worker finds project. it of information more would arise, foi- example, whenever difficult to evaluate the quality of the Then projects which the owner would know to ho rliffei'ent would be viewed as identical by worl<ers seems to characterize many relation -specific capital is An . of the cases in an issne. asymniolT-y of inforniaiion which investment in For example, General Motors might have had better information than Fisher Body about the payoff making their joint venture; a firm considering investment may be better informed of individual worker with which considering installing cable to the bargaining; TV may know Defence, which knows how of new capital value than the union or its a municipality moT-e about community than potential providers Department into a is it a the ultimate value and the of the service; eacli piece of hai-dware fits weapons system and how weapons systems combine defence network, has better information about the value to form them to a total of each individual project than any of the contractors bidding for the contract. This asymmetry of information realized value of the project itself is is inconsequential contract ible case an efficient long-term contract can simy^ily . Foi- specify of the spoils as a function of the realized value. the if in tliat llu> division In practice, however, there are numerous reasons why the outcome may not be contractible point which . Tirole (198G) contains an extensive discussion of this we shall not more obvious reasons. in other projects it repeat here. First, if payoffs of his various projects. accrue in We merely mention three the owner may be impossible to to is of the simultaneously involved separate the costs and Second, the payoff may in part nontangible benefits that are difficult for an outsider to evaluate, sucli as the cffert on of thp parties. tlie firms rppvitatioii or this is utiJitiGs an outsidor may not know tho opportunity Finally, cost of funds or other inputs the parties commit to if llio common knowledge to the parties even project, tlie themselves. With the exception of adverse selection the situation we study is the canonical one in this literature. participation of the worker ventvire. order in The events unfold in to The owner requires the carry out his proposed three stages. In owner bargains with the worker over the terms tho first stage, the of an e x ante contract. Once hired, however, that makes him superior any replacement and which therefore, ex po st, to worker acquires training endows him with some leverage. the second stage, the owner must decide whethor to undertake a gains from the investment are realized and, ex post bargaining ovpt We in the third stage, there tiiose gains. restrict attention to the case which w(^ believe to be of bargaining position ex an te. we assume that the We formulate complete-information setting. (198,3) is conducive In the second, the stronger ways. at the first jinte identical.-^ discussion that this ass\miption in is this in two owner can bargain many workers who are ex Takahashi he does so, the If most practical importance: where the informed owner- first that With the specific worker in place, in particular investment he has under consideration. is knowledge ot- In the stage with Recall from the above to efficiency in the as in Sobel and and Fudenberg and Tirole (1903), the owner makes take-it-or-leave-it offer to a specific worker- before investment takes a - 7 place. Examples where the When are workers a firm is hiring many workers with Ex post first to formulation work similar skills in a appropriate abound: new factory, e x ante tliere who are competing for the job. however, the workers acquire specific human capital which , allows them to acquire some rents which the plant. partner is to depend on the productivity of consider the case of an inventor who needs a Similarly, supply inputs. Ex ante there may be many potential such suppliers but only one inventor. Particularly in this case of ex ante large numbers, the formalism of the three stage model neglects Such feature of real world contracts. a a potentially important model implicitly assumes thai the owner and the worker are able to form an exclusive relationship in the sense that the owner can credibly promise that he will not engage in the project because in in our model incorporates bolii a it is relationship, Where it lump-sum payment is This generally optimal to design whether he invests or not) and investing. any other worker. the future with a to the payment n is important contract that owner (independent that is of contingent on his impossible to specify an exclusive the "noncontractible projects" case, an incentive is introduced for the owner to abscond with the lump-sum payment and then solicit an offer anew from another worker. owner may find it Indeed an ini scrupulous profitable to go into the business of colJecting lump-sum payments without ever investing. This would be a particularly attractive option for an owner with a very unprofitable 8 - investment opportvinity There are contractible. An example similar businesses which a variety of is and where circumstances in. Investment by wlvirli it manufacturing process might be way in from other projects the owner particular in a in is new engine this category. however, the project may be contractible. not is several in difficult to specify the is GM project a where the owner operates a particular project differs involved in other cases, In For example a project to provide a cable television service to a city or the automobile bodies for an automobile producer are easily definable. venture one partner may be able specific line of business will be Our focus is to promise thai Similarly in a joint all conducted via the his efforts in a joint venture. mainly on the contractible projects case, Our formalized by the three stage model. result in this case unambiguous: the optimal long-term contract leads relation -specific capital. to is overinvestment This results despite the fart that it in i^s possible to structure a contract that leads to efficient investment. When the contract undertaken when undertaken yields it is is structvired so that projects are only efficient to do so, the average project a positive payoff to the relationship. Since bargaining yields some of this surplus to the worker, competition at the first stage forces workers to offer a lump-sum to the owner for the right to participate in the relationship. However, since workers cannot distinguish owners with good projects from those with bad, this lump-sum payment must be paid even to an owner who in fact has a bad who has no project and intention of investing. particularly attractive to an owner who has fact in outcome Sucli an a is not good project since he shares some of the potential spoils with his unattractive Indeed, such an owner would prefer a lower counterparts. payment and higher payment made contingent on investment (which he a intends to undertake) this kind, lumpsum they . Since workers are happy to oblige an owner of will offer the preferred contract. But then the higher investment -contingent payment induces overinvestment. Althought the focus of the paper on the contractible is projects case, we We model by extending the horizon beyond three periods and this briefly examine the noncontractible projects case. enabling the owner to offer the project anew to previously contracting with another. a worker aftoi' Not suprisingly, multiple equilibria arise in this case. We are able underinvestment cannot arise in show, nonetheless, that to equilibrium and provide sufficient conditions for tho outcome to involve strict overinvestment. The second formulation bargaining power is where he offer to a specific worker. of Sobel is \u which the owner has relatively more able to In the make absence a take-it -or-leave-it of discounting, tlie models and Takahashi (1983) and Fudenberg and Tirole (1983) feature such take-it-or-leave-it offers from the informed to the In this case there are again multiple equilibria. Of these, one yields the efficient outcome while the others overinvestment. by the owner all uninformed. involve Moreover, those with overinvestment are to the efficient equilibrium. all preferred 10 We are not tlie first to demonstrate that relation-specific capital can lead to overinvestment. this is possible in his model if Tirole (198G, investment is Sec. V) shows that observable. This occurs because investment alters the parties' relative bargaining strength. The Idea that investment alters bargaining strength central to the analysis of Grossman and Hart (1986).'^ also is Crawford's (1982) model has the same ambiguity in that both under- and The ambiguity there overinvestment are possible. arises for a he considers risk -averse workers who completely different reason: wish to intertemporaUy smooth consumption and may therefore dislike the contract that gives efficient investment. In a Webb arid paper addressed to a rather different question De Meza (1987) also derive an overinvestment result. an investing firm which must borrow to finance its Tliey consider setting differs fundamentally from ours in that the investment specific, and in Their investment. is not that binding contracts can be signed before investment takes place. Indeed the faUuro that drives their results is in the financial markets the presence of limited liability and the impossibility of observing the true value of the project, even ex post . Despite this large contextual difference, their model somewhat similar to ours in that there is is adverse selection and that the financial institution (which corresponds to the worker in our model) expects to earn more on projects that are in fact good. this expectation that leads the financial institution to offer contracts that are sufficiently attractive that even poor quality It is 11 projects are undertaken in equilibrium. However, their result in some sense derives from the fact that they do not allow for the possibility of payments which are not contingent on investment actually taking As discussed above, we consider such place. in ovir analysis and they turn out to play an important role. The paper is organized as follows. the case where there are large Section of potential 1 Ex ante large numbers workers while in of Section We begin by the payoffs. workers recalling the timing structure, The owner has a project an amount K and by describing which yields G if if owner can enter into a contract with a particular worker. is second stage, investment specific ends. K is expended. If In the third stage, verifiable We III. participates and if in Contractible projec ts (i) place we analyze we examine take-it-or-leave-it offers by the owner. 11 present our conclusions I numbers In Section by a third invested. to thai a worker In the first stage the owner and 1h;il In the worker lakes investment doesn't take place the game G is learned by the worker (but is not party) and the owner and worker bargain over its division The outcome of this game depends on what be contracted on at each stage. First, is known and what can we assume throughout thai the third stage payoff cannot be contracted on in the first stage so that ex post bargaining (we use the generalized Nash bargaining solution) 12 is The the rule. due to a inability to commit to third stage payoffs could be One variety of factors. activity the worker is that the actual carry out cannot be specified to is possibility advance so in the worker can threaten to hold out after the investment takes place. Second, we assume that the contract can be made contingent on the owner/worker specific investment taking place. This possible is can be verified (by the Courts) that the owner invests K specific capital.^ The and central assumption, third, is if it the in that the owner knows G exactly while the worker only knows the distribution F(G) from which G has been drawn. owner in is many assumption make In is that the owner. that emerges between workers when we suppose that they make offers of them, at the first stage. willing to final a better bargaining position than the To capture the competition there are The owner to tlie These offers specify payments the worker is exchange for becoming involved with the owner. With contractible projects and investment there are two such payments that can be made. The first owners who actually invest. The second which the owner promises never different worker." is Thus to investment in and V is is a a payment L in to exchange undertake the investment with general an offer in an amount paid by the worker later takes place, payment V which accrues only a is to the firm is whether or not investment contingent payment that for the equilibrium offers. problems of this kind, we solve it a !L,V}, where L a pair is made only fact takes place. We now solve for As is usual for by backwards induction. If the if 13 third stage reached, there is bargaining is information: iindei- full sunk and the surplus G must be divided. capital costs are The generalized Nash bargaining solution to this bargaining problem mazrmlzes Pq^""?^" (where Pq and P^^ are the payoffs to the owner and worker respectively) subject payoffs restricted to equal G. is sum to the restriction that the The ' of the third stage payoffs to the owner and worker are therefore (l-a)G and aG respectively." Now consider the second stage and suppose that the owner has accepted an offer of {L.Vj. independent of is received by the owner whether investment takes place, the owner finds investment worthwhile will L Since, if and only (l-cx)G if V + > K. Thus the owner undertake any investment for which G Thus an > (K-V)/(l-a) = gV. offer of {L,V] that G^, such that only investments cutoff are undertaken. (1) accepted results is is The higher Is the lower the cutoff. V, is received in In the event that undertaken the more projects are undertaken. Consider the and suppose that an accepted offer first stage Then the amount involves a contingent payment of V. expects a ciitoff, that yield a return higher than the other words, the higher the payment that investment in to receive in the continuation f [aG-V]dF(G) G^ = f gV game aGdF(G) is - that the worker given by: V[1-F(gV] Since competition between workers ensures zero profits for the workers, (2).' it must be the case that L is given by the expression in We can thus characterize the contracts by V with L being (2) 14 determined by (2). Furthermore, we can restrict attention from (1), this since, is V<K an implication of nonnegative G. Of the possible values of V, which one (with L from to To examine (2)) will be offered in equilibrium? corresponding its this question consider a proposed JL,V! equilibrium contract and an owner for G>K under Since such an owner that contract. the worker wishes to enter into a relationship, that there prefer. fixed, is most-preferred contract amounts to V, subject to (1) and (2). d0/dV implies that low. I, is + 1 -aGVf(GV)dGV/dV = [K-GV]f(GV)dGV/dV will negative. selecting his maximizing i^(V)=L(V)+V with respect = Extremal solutions, which and since K and G are , Thus L+V. owner would aii This gives: dL/dV = to sucli L+V-K + G(l-a) his preferences are increasing in whom must be the case it no other breakeven contract which Since such an owner earns the kind with is whom - [1-F(gV)1 + + Vf (GV)dGV/dV F(gV). + 1 (3) be considered below, arise when (3) This can happen, for instance, when by equating Interior solutions are obtained (.S) to a is zero which gives [K-gV] = Since the right-hand-side overinvestment F(GV)(l-a)/f(GV). is positive, (4) we have K>G^: there is in equilibrium. The second-order-condition for a maximum is: d20/dv2=[K-GV]f'(GV)[dGV/dV]2 + f(GV)dGV/dV-f(GV)[dGV/dV]2<O, or [K-GV]f'(GV)-(2-a)f(GV)<0. 15 In order to interpret and the overinvestment result (3) let us consider a proposGd [L,V| equilibrium contract and suppose that a worker wishes to improve upon the worker wants to In particular, it. design a contract that, compared to the proposed fL.Vi contract, has the effect of inducing the marginal investment not to be undertaken whUe not affecting the Inframarglnal investments. the amount of investment that undertaken is contract will have to have a slightly lower same time, at the inframarginal, to thai order to reduce new equilibrium, the V than before. In order, be as attractive to an owner whose investment owner must be kept as the decrease in this, in In well off as before. is To do V must be matched by an exactly equal increase in L. So consider the effect of increasing L by by |f $1. There are two effects: (GV)dGV/dV I when V First, is decreased by $1, Note however that, by definition, the owner breaks even on the marginal projed This moaTis thai the efficiency . gains that result from the abandonment of marginal projects to the first worker. term in These gains from the decrease (3). The second effect is would not have undertaken the project The probability thus an Increase V whiJe reducing The marginal such fewer projects are undertaken. project loses [K-G"]. $1 that the owner in the payment is in to a Any owner who any case receives of this type is accrue V are given by the distributive. in all F(gV). $1 more. There is noninvesting owner of $F(G^) . If [K-GV]f (G^)dG^/dV exceeds F(G^) then the worker gains from the change since he can induce every investor to accept his new contract. 16 With this Intuition in mind (3) why - is it easy to see directly from the equilibrium contract cannot involve only efficient Investment. In the efficient case vanishes and we are $1 while increasing left L by K=G^ with F(G^) $1 has a efficiency of investment that . so that the first term in At the point K=G, reducing V by second-order effect on the undertaken. is However order effect on the lump-sum payments that are made owner who does not invest, (3) In other has a first- to the type of it words, resources are sqviandered on the kind of owner whom the worker does not wish to attract in the Although increasing V induces some inefficient first place. investment, this has the effect of enabling the worker continue to attract owners with good Investments sum payment. because it The reduction In whUe offering them a lower lump- the lump-sum payment is desirable applies not only to owners with good investments, but to those with bad investments as well. We now show that the above equilibrium renegotiation between the robust to signing and the undertaking of the At this point the owner has already received L so that Investment. when initial is the payoff is between G^ and K both parties to the relationship could be made better off by agreeing not to go ahead with the Investment. The gain from cancelling the contract gain in is split worker a(K-G). therefore, the usual way, To implement the owner must net is K-G. If this (]-a)(K-G) and the the outcome of this renegotiation, the worker must offer the owner (l-a)(K-G) not to invest. This would require the worker to know G, however. If, as we 17 have assumed, G is unobservable, the worker mvist offer an amount the owner not to invest thai is AU noninvestors would now to Suppose the worker independent of G. Then investors would receive offers M. before. - as mvich as they received receive an additional M. This would have exactly the same effect on investment decisions and on the payoffs of the worker as increasing L in the original contract while leaving L+V unchanged. Since the worker could not improve that the has no effect on the outcome. initial optimal contract ensured his lot in this way, renegotiation This occurs essentially because owners accept the contract so that Its all acceptance yields no information that can improve the allocation. This argument demonstrates that our original equilibrium robust to renegotiation. equilibrium even fact that It also implies that this when renegotiation is is the only is This results from the allowed. were there any other equilibrium with renegotiation, the worker coul offer our equilibrium contract instead, knowing would be accepted by an investing owner and Ihal it that i1 would be robust renegotiation We now consider the effect of an increase in a, the share of the ex post benefits that accrues to the workers, on the efficiency of investment. Intuition would suggest that such an increase makes overinvestment more severe since efficiency obtains when a Indeed, when the second order conditions obtain, there relation between a and eqviilibrium G^ (assuming can be obtained by differentiating (4): it is is is a zero. monotone interior) which to 18 dG^/da Up = [K-GV]f(GV)/{(l-a)3d2,^/dv2i. now we have considered to possible that di^/dV is of the form is [0,V'i witli is In this associated Combining . (1) given by: G'' Is (2), it has L equal to zero because more attractive contracts it with negative L's will not be accepted by noninvestors and Yet, positive even for L equal to zero. case, the equilibrium contract cutoff G''; interior solutions. \ a[G-G''']dF(G) [1-F(G'''][K-G"1 - = (5) G" Since the first term smaller than K in so there also apparent that G ' is positive, is (5) the cutoff value overinvestment. falls when a must be G'' Differentiating (5), it is rises so tiiat the extent of overinvestment diminishes. might be asked under what circumstances extremal solutions It are likely to emerge. In other words when does (3) imply that L negative so that nonivestors are unwilling 1o participate. occurs F(G'') if is Indeed, G''. is there are a great in this effort, case (3) that, is likely to contrary to is very costly be positive even for all so that F(0) individuals of a worthless project is will which G^ Then (3) equal to witho\it is Then, as long as 1, is choose to become owners of such projects arbitrarily close to one and f(x) arbitrarily small. worker. to the endogenous and that essentially any individual can, become an owner so that our assumption, ownership of projects indistinguishable from worthwhile projects. positive This projects with G loss tiian K, high, and any lump sum transfer Suppose itself many is is positive for all foi- x positive positive G^ and is tlie 19 thp unique equilibrium. Is {0,V'''} distributed , it is If, G instead, uniformly is straightforward to show that the interior solution when more than applies - half the projects are worthwhile while the boundary solution applies otherwise. The extremal occurs for two reasons. equals -l/(l-a) is (5) a low a First, Second, holds, K-G*^ zero L implies that If This also tends small. is if (3). to is a equal zero, it important is which the incentive for the owner to to consider abscond with rise to an infinite horizon that achieves this is to to invest, in general, include payment and an investment-contingent component. assume that the game This gives a lump-sum Here, however, the lump-sum component does not automatically create an exclusive relationship. ^^ is lump- game with no discounting but with complete As above, contracts can, interest a an offer anew from another worker plays a solicit second stage the ownei' decides not Our a unambiguously positive. is begins again with workers making new offers to the owner. recall. zero so reduce the Indeed, for so that (3) not contractible is The simplest modification at the when L Noncontractible Projects sum payment and role. in K equals G" the project a setting in means that dG^/dV, which low n means that, a importance of the negative term (ii) This a is low. small in absolute value so the negative term of (3) is relatively small. that when solution also tends to arise not equilibria that can arise. in fully characterizing the possible Rather, our concern is with the - 20 conclusions that can be drawn about the amount of investment that can occur The in equilibria. underinvestment point to note first in equilibrium in the sense that an owner whose G exceeds K must eventually Invest. H. Suppose, to the The reason is the following. contrary that, the best project actually undertaken has a payoff G" which to that there cannot be is is Define, for any equilibrium, above K. be the net payoff of the projects which Z(t) be undertaken after will the t'th round of the game but which have not yet been undertaken by Then, Z(t) the t'th round. Therefore, for each This means that at t, T is there is obviously nonincreasing a T such the owners of expect a payoff no higher than all that Z(T) t^^ smaller than at T, there exists owners whose project yields less than G" who would prefer the offer {0,aKj to continuing with the original equilibrium. such an offer, if z. projects can collectively Therefore, e. is in to accept Yet, Thus there accepted yields profits to the workei-. cannot be an equilibrium with G" greater than K. Our remaining findings contract which nets an owner rely who offer is accepted. {0,V'''l the observation that tio actually invests less than V'' will actually be accepted in equilibrium. an offer oti To see this, suppose that such Since the owner could Instead have accepted the which workers are always willing to make, it must be the case that the owner intends to earn more than {0,V''j by absconding with the lump-sum component of the offer. Thus workers would not this offer. This observation has two consequences. First It Implies that make 21 when the solution is !0,V'''l (the extremal case) are noncontractible. it is in the contractible projects equilibrium also the unique equilibrium The reason is that, when projects there this case, in no is contract which nets more to an investing owner while letting workers break even. The second implication contractible projects equilibrium parameter values for which all that, is is interior, previous section implies that there which is V larger than aK is equal to aK is range of some {L.Vj combination (since overinvestment preferred to fO.V] by investing owners. is a Interiority of the solution in the guarantee that the contract {L',aK! where isn't, there in the the equilibria without contractible investment feature overinvestment. positive L and even when the solution preferred to [O.V'l; Indeed L' it is witli assured) is This does not V given by (2) with often is When not. it equilibria with noncontractible projects involve all overinvestment. This occurs because, to obtain efficient investment, owners would L' + aK is lets liave to accep^t contracts lower than V, there workers break even that Thus is will whoso V equals aK no offer whoso be accepted prefers the SL',aK] contract to the To equilibrium. The range we have not considered interior solution in the three stage model in equals aK and which for a wide range of parameter values there overinvestment. show that in V this when Yet, . is is strict where there is an and the investing owner iO,V''=} contract. range the efficient equilibrium is It is easy sustainable. to -"^^ gain some understanding of the relative importance of these 22 ranges we consider the case mentioned above (0,V'j is in which G is then the most attractive contract {0,V'''! so that preferred to [L'.aKj is if we are not and only if less if Even when more than than half the projects are worth undertaking. half are worth undertaking, As uniformly distributed. in the extremal case, less than two thirds of the projects are worth undertaking. Ill Tak e- it-or-leave-Jt offers by the owne r A workers different method for eliminating the bargaining power of the is to put the informed owner it-or-leave-it offer to the uninformed particular, of B the owner offers to invest This method to him. is in the position of making a take- worker if attractive at when the workers are cannot be a lump sum payment such as L. sum payment by the firm firm makes is if it The is will rejected If simply be turned down. it the offer level of transfer, in some any for such a B, that the owner to the is lump Tlie offer the is payable only accepted, investment takes We analyze the pure strategy signalling game. in doesn't. from the worker may signal something value of G. is In There thus Any request thus a request for a transfer R whicli investment takes place. place, unable is carry out the project with some new worker. to stage. the worker makes a transfer sense already employed by the firm and the owner event first tlie willing to accept worker about the true equilibria of this Although there are multiple equilibria, several properties that any equilibrium must satisfy can bo readily if - 23 established First, if B aK the offer > an owner offers aK, G must equal lose by making the to at least earn aE(G|B) expectation of G given an offer of B. at least K and B, where E(G|B) - Thus, if is offer of the B equals aK, E(G|B) owner wUl never of this result is that the ask less than aK since he can be sure to gain more by asking aK. second consequence he will is that there cannot be underinvestment By asking aK, an owner can earn (l-a)G always undertake an investment for which G There exist other signalling equilibria. between G'' and K, there investments whose is G exceeds given G' in this range These offers as is the worker has nothing to lose by accepting the offer. The consequence equilibrium. If K, for otherwise he would On the other hand by accepting an offer. B the worker expects be accepted by the worker. will is + in Therefore aK. K. > Indeed, for a signalling equilibrium in which all G' all The equilibrium G' are carried out. supported by offers equal well as smaller offers are accepted, A to for a K- (]-a)G'. larger offers are rejected To see that these are indeed equilibria, owner who makes an equilibrium a)G', which Is positive if He earns (l-a)G offer. and only G if consider first the > G'. So, -K+ K-(l- owners whose G exceeds G' benefit by making these offers and gain nothing by making smaller offers. On the other hand owners with G<G' will offers which will be rejected. make larger Therefore a worker who accepts the K + (]-a)G'. offer of K-(l-a)G' earns aE(G|G>G') - This gain is, 24 - given (5), nonnegative as long as G' > It. exist, G'''. worth noting that, not only do overinvestment equilibria is they are extremely desirable from the point of view of the owners whose bargaining power assumed is to be strong. Specifically, owners prefer equilibria with higher transfers so their most preferred equilibrium the one where is all projects whose G exceeds are G'' undertaken. We now briefly consider what would happen if, instead of giving the owner the right to make take-it-or-leave-it offers in the first stage, we endowed both players with more closely resembles that difficult to there is know what outcome to predict bargaining strength that stage of our game. It is suggestive is to is from such bargaining since a dearth of extensive form models analyzing this case. possiblity which stage, in the third a imagine that, even in the One first the two parties are trying to divide the benefits of the relationship with a fraction a going to the worker. This can be achieved by letting V equal nK is The owner then invests . positive so that efficiency prevails importance of the change in ^'^ . if (l-a)(G-K) This points to the bargaining strength between stage one and stage three for our overinvestment results. IV Conclusions Our main conclusion is that adverse selection creates a tendency towards overinvestment. investment is Moreover in the important case where contractible and there are ex ante large numbers 25 overinvestment characterizes the unique equilibrium contractual relationship. That optimal contract has the feature that sum payment model is it requires a lump- for the exclusive right to the particular project. correct we ought to observe such payments. In many such as cable television franchises and military procurement, uncommon of the we would argue are characterized by our assumptions, situations which not our If to see substantial supply the good in question . is it lobbying efforts for the right to Provided the granter of that right Municipality or the Defence Department in these examples beneficiary of these efforts, then the initial - is - the a lobbying can be interpreted as the lump-sum (noncontingent) payment in our model. Besides the wining-and-dining that rent-dissipation process, is usually part and parcel of the such benefits might also include uncompensated design work, feasibility analysis, and consumer surveys performed by the lobbying firm. In order to higlilight the effect of adverse snloction on overinvestment, we have made some strong assumptions. our discussion in Section II suggests that the asymmetry bargaining power may be necessary for the result. in For example, in initial Similarly, Grossman and Hart (198G) or Tirole (1986), investment if, as itself is not contractible a countervailing tendency towards underinvestment arises. Finally, our assumption of efficient bargaining is clearly important. Suppose, for purposes of Illustration, that bargaining dissipates some fraction, say t, of the gains from a project. Then we should replace 26 G by tG in our analysis. example, it is - In the contractiblo projects case, then immediate from equations could be underinvestment in equilibrium. as T approaches unity there and (1) This be no investment will that there (4) fairly is for obvious since Thus at all! while the presence of bargaining leads to overinvestment, costs of bargaining move the outcome We close with a in the opposite direction. comment on the implications if the costs of organizing economic activity are different within the firm than arms-length contracting integration 1"^ . our analysis That analysis for the traditional aniysis of vertical integration. asserts that of is markets then situations in inefficient may give which in rise to vertical This raises the question of the incentives for One common way vertical integration in our model. this is issue is to of thinking suppose that the firm faces a trade-off in vertical integration decision. On may remove the third stage (and replace the bargaining authority relationship), bu1 in its the one hand, vertical integration on the other hand, , about Uioi-o it with an may bo some inefficiency involved in carrying out the transaction "in house". If bargaining that was the case, is then owners for whom the third -stage particularly costly would have a strong preference for vertical integration. These are the owner's for whom G is high. An equilibrium of a model with endogenous vertical integration and contractible projects might therefore have two cutoffs instead of just one: Owners with projects project "in house". that exceed the higliei- cutoff Those with projects below thi.s would do the cutoff would offer 27 their projects In market as tlie in - our model. 'llic second cutoff would divide these projects into those that are undertaken and those that are not. self -select out of the remains On is in Since the owners with the best projects would market, the adverse selection problem that reduced and the overinvestment that results the other hand, equilibrium is less severe. some inefficient vertical integration then coexists with the market's overinvestment. 28 FOOTNOTES 1 Williamson (1983) shows that efficiency obtains with binding contracts if (and only if) transfers that are valued equally by both parties can be made. 2 This argument contained, for example, is in Hart and Holmstrom Grossman and Hart (1986), and Milgrom and Roberts (1987). (1986), what WUliamson (1975) refers 3 This 4 Tirole (1987) provides an example that illustrates is overinvestment can arise 5 This is a stronger in to as ex ant e large numbers, how their model. requirement than requiring that investment spending be verifiable since it must also bo verifiable that the investment which took place is specific to this The investment must owner and worker. this not be sucli tlial the ownoj- ran benefit liy excluding the worker. 6 it If will this amount L be accepted by is all positive at the equilibrium contract offered owners regardless of their G. noninvestors would never take a contract whose L means that contracts with negative L's is By contrast, would only have payments investors and can be lumped together with contracts whose L With this proviso, we can view L as being paid to 7 See Roth (1982), Grout (1984). This negative. all owners. is to zero. 29 8 there imniGdiate from this that, is It is underinvestment investment if In this case . it is is noncontractible, not possible to make transfers which are contingent on whether investment first stage actually takes place. Yet, investment is the owner will only invest So, socially worthwhile as long as investments for which the payoff is G (l-a)G if K. > Thus, > K. between K and K/(l-a) will not be undertaken even thougli they are socially worthwliile. 9 workers knew G, the expression If projects then forces V to equal aG 10 It . (2) would be aG-V for Competition between workers which investment takes place. in The owner then gets (l-a)G-K + aG Therefore he invests invests. in if G exceeds K and might be asked why workers ever offer why owners do put differently, and then pursue this is that has once accepted a lump to svim associated with a bad project. lump sum component or, another worker. draw the inference sum transfer L The reason that an So, for owner who payment and then not invesled is in fact while the payment of L doesn't necessarily exclude other workers in the future, in efficiency results. not simply take the lump a relationship with workers are free a he if it may make workers the future more reluctant to deal with this particular owner. 11 there This is riiles out the only conceivable form of underinvestment when no discounting. If the payoffs from agreements in later rounds are discounted relative could say that there does not invest at is to the payoffs from the underinvestment if first an owner whose the first available opportunity. It is rovind one G exceeds K possible to 30 - construct examples of such delay when the future as L" + aK In the latter case Z all discounted as long V''. any given round either some investments take place or none do. In 12 bigger than is is unaffected while in the former Z is falls since the projects undertaken have payoffs in excess of K. 13 This can be done as follows. Workers make offers any owner who has not yet accepted an offer. of !l,',aKl Owners who accept one G below K. Once again, owners have no incentive not to accept the offers and those whose have to offer a positive than L' + aK. If G exceeds K will, For a deviating worker to attract an owner he would inve.st. in fact, a lump sum components because worker deviated in this fashion, V''' is {L'.qK! to an owner Workers would be willing who has spiirned owners spurn deviators. Thus to He would extend the offer a deviating woj-kor the owner is smaller the owner would accept the offer but would not invest regardless of his G. then request new offers. borause strictly better off all by not investing with deviating workers. 14 In the case in which a discrete number of values, is one half while the G's can take only this solution is identical to the one obtained by applying the axiomatic approach of Harsanyi and Selten (1972) and 15 Myerson (1984). Although literature, it is this is commonly asserted of They these offers and do not invest are not extended further offers. are viewed as having a level of to to be the case questioned by Grossman and Hart (198G). in the a 31 REFERENCES Crawford, Vincent: "Long-Term Relationships Governed by Short Term Contracts" International Center for Economics and Related Disciplines, London School of Economics, Theoretical Discussion Paper 1982 82/59, De Meza, David and David C. Webb: "Too much Investment: A Problem Asymmetric Information," Q uarterly Journal 1987, of Ec ono mics , 102, of May 179-22. Fudenberg, Drew and Jean Tlrole: "Sequential Bargaining wilh Incomplete Information," Review of Economic Studies , 50, April 1983, 221-48. Grossman, Sanford J. Ownership: A Theory Political Economy , 94, and Oliver Hart: "The Costs and Benefits of Vertical of and Lateral Integration," Jou r nal of August 1986, 691-719. Grout, Paul A.: "Investment and Wages Contracts," Econometrica , 52, in the Absence of Binding March 1984, 449-60 Harsanyi, John C. and Reinhart Selten: "A Generalized Nash Bargaining Solution for Two-Person Bargaining Games with Incomplete Information", 32 Management Science , 18, 80-106 1972, Hart, Oliver and John Moore, "Incomplete Contracts and Renegotiation," June 1987, mimeo. HoLnstrom, Bengt and Oliver Hart: "The Theory of Contracts," Advances Bewley, Klein, In Eco nom ic Theory, Fifth World Co ngress, ed. by Truman New York: Cambridge University Press, 1987. Benjamin, Crawford, Robert and Armen Alchian: Integration, in "Vertical Appropriable Rents and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics Milgrom, Paul and John Roberts: , October 1970, 297-32fi 21, "Bargaining and Influence Costs and the Organiz.ation of Economic Activity," Research Paper Series No. GSB Stanford 93'1, University, January 1987. Myerson, Roger B.: "Two-Person Bargaining Problems with Incomplete Information," Econometrica , 52, March 1984, 461-488. Roth, Alvin: Axiomatic Models of Bargaining Verlag, New York: Springer 1979. Sobel, Joel and Ichiro Takahashi: Review , of "A Multistage Model of Bargaining," Economic Stu dies. 50, July 1983, 411-27. 33 Tirole, Jpan Economy . : 94, . "Procurempnl and RenQgotiation April 198G, " , Journal of Politica l 235-59. Theoretical Industrial Organization , 1 987 , mimeo WUliamson, Oliver: Markets and Hierarchies: Ana ly sis and Antitrust Implications , 1975. . "Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange," American Economic Review , 73, September 1983, 519-40. U53ls 059 Date Due Lib-26-(;7 MIT LIBRAHlfS 3 ^Oao 005 135 3t0