LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY OPTIMAL COMPETITIVE fJARKETING BEHAVIOR IN OLIGOPOLY 6A3-73 Jean-Jacques Lambin*, Philippe A. Naert** and Alain V. Bultez*** January, 1973 MASSACHUSETECHNOLOG 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE INSTITUTE 01 f..1ASS. . Z_.. RECEIVED APR 11 1973 M. I. T. LIBRARIES INTRODUCTION The problem of marketing mix optimization has received considerable attention in the literature. For the profit maximizing firm such an optimization is the extension of the "marginal revenue equals marginal cost" rule to determine optimal levels for all marketing instruments rather than just price. Dorfman and Steiner derived an optimization rule for a sequently applied by Palda [27l A monopolistic firm [9], which was suband Lambin [20l in empirical studies. large number of normative models of competitive mar- keting behavior in oligopolistic markets have also been formulated. Various assumptions related to industry demand (stable versus expansible) and to the type of competitive reaction der) have lead to a large variety of models. (follower versus lea- Many of these are theo- retical in nature and have not been directly applied, such as the competitive models, by Mills [231, Gupta and Krishnan [14. 15, 19], Shakun [29l. Baligh and Richartz [2], Kotler [161. Naert [241. and others. Examples of empirical studies dealing with stable industry sales are Lambin typp reaction) (follower) [231 ( fo 1 [sol, lower- type reaction) taken into account and Telser and with expansible industry sales and Bass (follower) In those studies where ly [221 (leader), it (leader- are Schultz [3]. competitive reaction is explicitis implicitly assumed that compe- titors react with the same marketing instrument as the one which C37234 causes their reactions, that is, they react to by change in price, to a a change in prices change in advertising by a a change in ad- vertising. We will identify this kind of reaction with the simple competitive reaction case. It is more realistic, however, in the spirit of the very concept of marketing mix we will call multiple competitive reaction competitor may react to price, a , 1 , to and more consider what that is for example, a change in price not just by changing his but also by changing his advertising and, keting instruments as well. To our knowledge no possibly other mar- optimality condi- tions have been derived yet for the multiple competitive reaction case . In this analysis. the multiple through a developed, paper we will remain within the realm of static First, we will derive profit maximization conditions for competitive reaction case. We will then demonstrate series of corollaries how optimization rules, previously are special cases of our more general rule. The second part of this article will be devoted to the estimation problems arising in a multiple competitive reaction framework. Through the ana- lysis of the data collected on a stable industry demand market, evi- dence of the importance of considering multiple competitive reactions will be presented. . I. PROFIT rAXiniZATION A : GENERALIZATION First, we will derive optimality conditions in terms of the vector of total sales elasticities to decompose les E its various in q.u E We will then show how . q .u components related to industry sa- effects and marKet share effects. The notation adopted is defi- ned in Tab le I INSfRT TABLE 430UT HERE I 3 Consider the following company profit function (1) Tr q.[p-c.(q,x}]-s = For the profit maximizing producer, ned by setting the derivative of sion variables equal to zero u be of vector a u. - (p 3u X - n) 1 1 here ip ly i (p,s,x]. -q .-1] 9q With marginal cost MC = . 9u q 9u • 9q = ) 9u 9u matrix of the elements diagonal ^ - by D /q, 9q .— 3s gq ^ - 9tt/9u D -i^ 9c 9C (3x3] ng 3c^ c u' 9u Premu (p. respect to each of the deci- q-( c) 9u (n v/ith 9P = Let D Let . 8q Sir it optimality conditions are obtai- 9c. 9p . " 9u 9s i D D "^ 9u -ii q ._ 9u = -— 3q • -r— q. u 12) where condition obtc. ins the following& optimality j ^ E •= 3u E - 9c. no -s/q. H I* ^H Ip. + -X g^ identity matrix. From which the is I (P • q.U can deduct (3) Equation rule]. generally known as the Dorf man -S t e i ner theorem (or is (3) In fact, merely states that at optimality. marginal reve- it 5 cost for each marketing instrument nue must equal marginal . The Dorf man-St ei ner rule is generally written in the following form (4) n °ij q.p 8q — ds . ihere p = p • • Equation (4) holds, I BR . s £ X Equations . * t3) n q.s q> X 9c/3x and = ri q.x ._PX 1 ,. 9q/3x • _, and , — = n q,x = v ' 3c/ ^9x , • -c q sine = pq ^^-^ • _ " (4) p X —s • q s ^ * 3q/ 9x 3c/3x — 9q 3s . * 9q ~ = p '^9s x^ _ q • ' £ x . * are thus equivalent. = V • "^q.x , and : l-rcm equation (2) one can easily dei'ivethe optimal values for the decision variables. (5J u In \t-^ = vector notation, we obtain • 1 D^ h. . -q : . q.u where D^ E is a diagonal matrix of the elements of vector q.u We now want to show how the vector E E q.u ^ of total sales q. u elasticities can be decomposed into various elements in the case of an oligopoly. First, \-je can distinguish between and an industry sales effect. effects a market share effect And secondly, we can separate direct (assuming no competitive reaction) from indirect effect (com- petitive reaction effects). The theorem proposed below traces the linKs between tctal sales elasticities, industry demand, market share, and competitive reaction elasticities. THEOREM The vector of elasticities of company sales with respect to its decision variables is equal to a matrix partitioned into an identity matrix and the matrix of competitive reaction elasticities postmultiplied by the sum of the vectors of industry sales and market share elasticities, Proof : i.e. E = [lyR] • [F„ + E ] Company sales can be written as industry sales times market share : — q = q = m • (u, Q^ The derivative of U. 2) ' (u,U) m^ with respect to the decision vector q 3Q, 9U 8( 3u 9U • 9u 9U, 9U. 9U 9u 9u du r 9u Premu 1 1 is u 3U — 3m 9u 9U ip 1 - y i by ng D /q. we obtain D 9q "q" Tu D^ ~ * Q 9Q^ D^ 9u "q" 3U * Tu 30^ * '9 U "' 9m^ ^ m * u ' 9m^ 9U ^ m 3u * u * "Fu ' 9lj whi ch reduces to (6) E = q (7) E .1 E_ 0- u = q.u R . • u [I.R] E„ 0-p • [E^ Ot * E , U , . m E m.,u + R • E ni.,U ] ' The optimality conditions are then obtained by substituting the ele- ments on the right hand side of equation (7) for the elempnts of in equation (2 ) . E q.u COROLLARIES The optimization rules used in the empirical studies re- ferred to in the introduction can be derived very easily from corollaries to the theorem. In deriving these corollaries, we will use both forms of the theorem as obtained in equations (6) and (7). When we use the phrase "no competitive reaction" we mean that the company in deciding on values for its decision variables follower or a assumes no change in decision variables. That is the case of the values of competitors' Cournot-type oligopolist. a "Competitive reaction" will refer to the case where competitive reactions are explicitly taken into account in determining values for the decision variables. This 7 is the case of a leader, as defined by Stackelberg . MON_OPOLY_AN_D_MONOPOLlST_IC_ COMPETITION^ Coro 1 lary that E a : In monopoly q = 0, and U and R do not exist. It follows : (6) In 1 = q, u E„ 0^, u monopolistic competition situation, each firm faces its own de- mand curve and no industry demand is defined. This is the case derived by Dorfman and Steiner [9], stein [13] industry, [20]. to and applied by Palda \27], and Feld" study cases of monopolistic competition in the drug and by Lambin for a frequently purchased consumer product OLiGOPOLi a;:p S_TAB_LE INDUSTR1'_D,MAND (E = 0) Qrp elasticities (9) Wit. R E a = = In which 0. case : F .ultlpllctlvs „..Ket sH.re function of t.o -roUowln, n * s i . It is (ID) t ype PI i .1211 easil y seen that E = - - E F Equation (7) then reduces to Mn E = q. u E m . u This has been used by Lambin in a consumer durable good [22]. study of a low price Sometimes one use'JSB. market r^^r<-c=^ share ~k functions with the cision variables in share form. 'm^.pO P P e... m. , s' de- 9. For this type of marKet share function it is ea-ily shown that (12) " ^m^.U where D q is ''^' ^mj.u° * diagonal matrix of the elements of vector a -^^ Equation °U° ^ ^ ^2 ' ^ ^2 ^n ^ ^ can then be written as (9) %o = ^.u ' E^^^^. Equation (13) is appropriate for Cowling and Cubbin's study of the car market in the United Kingdom med E q . m u Corollary 3 : , [8], u' Simple Competitive Reaction R * R^, where R. has the same diagonal elements as R d d but has zero off-diagonal entries. (14) E q, u altough they implicitly assu- = [I'R^l • d and in the special case of Equation (7) becomes : E I a market share function in relative form, u 10, (15) E = [I R^] - • since according to equation E = E (10' [I.R,] [I.R^l d q, u an expression equivalent to equation . Telser, (15). advertising in the cigarette industry [30], derived ween absolute advertising elasticity n * , r\ [221, and Telser's findings, We may also observe that for dustry demand all : E = q, u E m , u Using this in equation (15) gives E^ = m, , [I - R^l d • E^ m , . , u which is the form actually used by Telser. Coro 1 lary a 4 : Multiple Competitive Reaction Only En = 0, end hence study of relation bet- and relative elasticity which is the advertising equation in (15). For of Lambin's results flS^ in his a see Naert comparison [251. cases with stable in- u 11. (17) E q.u = [I.R] • E m^ or with the market share function in relative form (IB) E q.u = [I R] - • E I The special case of equation (IB) has been derived by Bultez [6] We refer to section II for an empirical example. OLI_GOPqLY_ AND EXPAllSI_BLE_INDUST_RY_ DEMAND Corollary mes 5 No Competitive Reaction. R : = 0, (E ^ 0) and equation (6) beco- : (19) E q.u = E„ 0- + . u E m . , With the market share function in relative form this becomes (20) E q.u = E„ * 0-p u . E m , u The study by Bass on advertising and Given In share (21) f E q.u = market share function with the decision variables a orm, eoua t i on E^ 0^ cigarettes is of this kind [3]. . u (19) D,,o U can be written as • E^ m _n , u : 12 Equation (21) is thp relevant form of equation dy of competition between airlines in Corollary 6 (22) E^ Simple Competitive Reaction. : q = ,, » u n.R.l d • [E E^ * (6) for Schultz' stu- two-city market [28]. a R R = , and equation (5) ] m Telser's study of advertising and cigarettes contains a relation equi- valent to (22) for advertising [3D]. This equivalence is demonstrated intheappendix. With the market share function in relative form one gets (23) Core 1 lary E_ q 7 = , [I.R^] • d u petitive Reaction - * [I - R^] E^ • .* 'i' Oligopoly : E„ - Expansible Industry Demand - Multiple Com- Specific Functional Form for Market Share. The theorem holds for any kind of market share functionIn the special case of a market share function with the decision va- riables in relative form, we find (24) E = q a I u [I.R] • E„ Q_ + [I : - result also derived by Bultez [6]. R] • E m i . , u 13 The theorem and corollaries rized in Tab le II 2 to 6 are succintly summa- . INSERT TABLE Corollaries 2 to 7 I I ABOUT HERE demonstrate how total sales elasti- cities relate to industry sales and market share elasticities for various kinds of competitive reaction in different types of oligopolies. In each case, we have presented this relationship in general, and also for specific forms of the market share function. For each corollary wo have referred to at least one application, except for the multiple competitive reaction cases. Empirical evidence demons- trating the importance of considering multiple competitive reaction will be presented in the following section. Figure 1 illustrates the explicit decomposition of n q for the cases considered in this section. INSERT FIGURE 1 ABOUT HERE , s 14. II. THE EMPIRICAL STUDY The objective of this section is to present an empiri- cal application of the multiple competitive reaction concept intro- duced in the first part of this paper. The product studied is low a price consumer durable good having reached the saturation phasis on its life cycle curve. The market is dominated by three brands which represent altogether approximately 90 Firms A, B and C % of total industry sales. manufacture different brands of the same general product category. They do not offer, however, identical quality nor do they charge identical prices. Advertising expenditures represent in each case a significant but variable proportion of total sales revenue. Since primary demand is stable, a all the increased sales of given firm come necessarily at the expenses of its rivals and con- sequently the degree of recognition of mutual interdependence is very high. Thus, the market has the structural characteristics of diffe- a rentiated oligopoly. The data available for this study are fairly reliable. Market shares, retail prices and distribution rates come from a dealer panel. These panel data, which are purchased by the three firms are available on a quarterly basis from 1960 to 1966 and over four geographic regions. Company sales data come from company sources and total industry sales can also be estimated through statistics published by governmental agencies. Media advertising expenditures radio and television) per brand, month and region are provi- (press, ded by a commercial service from which monitors the media and values 15 list price. time and space at the rate card Point of sales promo- tion expenditures arc not included in the sample. Nedia expenditures advertising outlays. Each brand quali- represent about 85 \ estimated by a synthetic index, derived from ; empirically selected product attributes where ty is rential scale [26] of total a semantic diffe- period by period, by the marKeting staff then subjectively rated, of one of the firms. Bain [1] suggests that product differentiation inhibits changes in the percent of the market held by the oligopolistic firms In contradiction with this view, a high degree of market share ins- tability is observed in this market during the period under study. 10 The estimated indices of market share instability for each region in Table III. among the three firms 30.2 %, 37.9 % and In 1960, the partition of the market the others not included - 31.9 for firms A, \ are presented B and C - was as follows : respectively. The dominant fact of the 1962-66 period is the aggressive and successful marketing strategy of firm 32.8 in \ policy, 1962 to 66.1 in whose market share increased from 1966. As a result of firm B aggressive drastic changes occurred in the degree of market concentra1 tion. % B, The Herfindahl on figure 2, 1 index of Table III, graphically represented illustrates this fact INSERT TABLE III AND FIGURE 2 ABOUT HERE 16, In acsuming the leadership of the market, firm 3 pla- ced heavy emphasis on advertising a"d its share of total industry advertising expenditures increased from 18.9 in 1965. % 1962 to 61.7 in % Because of the ratchet nature of advertising and of reac- tions from the competing firms, (deflated) total industry adverti- sing expenditures have dramatically escalated and were four times higher by the end of the period studied. The advert i si ng- sa Ics ratios of the firms are presented in Table IV. They show that adver- tising has been particularly instrumental in the growth of firm's B marKet position and present evidence of strong competition by means of advertising. INSERT TABLE Selected ordinary IV ABOUT HERE 1 eas t - square s estimates of market share elasticities with respect to price, quality and advertising are also presented in Table V. These results suggest that price and quality have also played significant role since a a significant part of the firms market share variance can be associated, not only with changes in advertising intensities as expected in oligopoly, but also with price and quality adjustments. tegy has been that of tne marketing mix. ve situation it is of In Thus, the firms stra- view of this comptiliti- interest to see how the competing firms have reacted to the aggressive policy of firm B and, successfully or not, adjusted their own marketing variables to the new competitive situation created by the leader. The multiple reaction functions concept 17 should be a„ for that purpose, instructive analytical tool INSERT TABLE V ABOUT HERE RJAJTJOJ JLASTICIJ IJS, ESTIMAlIOJ^_Ol THE C_OrFETlTlVl e.poctod rival re^pons. Is pointed out Oy Bre.s [Si. dimension. dl.snslon as .ell as an e.t.ot „„oertaln ..d Has o tl.o soon will rival --espood and How o.estlons, .ow will t.o AS 0. th. two .e respond, for.er. less relevant tHan the the latter Is not T.e cnan.es Is .ad>caoo.petitlve reaction to price tl„ln, o. expected rival reactions to cnan.es the tl.ln. of expected ,, different fro™ and puaUtv Price variables sucH as advertising in tne non-price variations in action immediately, wt,hile variations can be put into technological research. Similarly, attributes often require q .ality required for the limitations and of the time because of media spac reaction Pv ca»pal.n, competitive preparation of an advertising reactions. generally slower than price „eans of advertising are Thus, follows the functions are as Pt V "P.P Pt 'P.= =t . : x"'"-" "t The douPle for advertising and duality. with the inter here to cope explicitly .o.arlth.lc for™ is adopted varlaOles. Thus, the existing amon, the .arKetin, and sl^llarlv. Put la..ed. ,,,,„, pattern elasticities [R]. matr IX of reaction is constant The periodicity of the data used to estjma'.^ t h r- Key- porameters is annual because sales being very concentrated in one period of the year, act within a it is practically impossible for competition to re- shorter period of time. By pooling the data over time and regions we obtain a total of 28 yearly observations. However, ce the quality of products sin- charged to the consumers and the prices are identical across regions, we only have 7 degrees of freedom left 1 1 ower reaction theory we for these variables. On the basis of the 1 eade r- fo designed various simultaneous equation models and estimated them usinj 12 the well-known two-stage le as t major assumption, : namely - squares method in interdependence between order to test one P, S and X, which would result from the followers full marketing mix orientation. Because of the postulated fundamental three leader's decision variables detected dependence between P. S dependence of P, S and X on the same p, s and x, we wondered whether the and X might not merely be due to a 1 3 spurious correlation effect. The test we devised was unconclusive Furthermore, the contemporaneous covariances of the residuals across equations were not sufficiently high to justify the application of the joint generalized As a least- squares technique [32, pp. 295-311]. result of this preliminary and rather unsuccessful econometric investigation, we turned back to a much simpler set of independent equations to estimate [R]. We used then the CochraneOrcutt [CDRO iterative procedure [32, pp. 253-256]. The results are presented in Table VI. f 19. INSERT TABLE VI A30UT HERE The direct reaction elanticities cre all three positive and statistically significant at the 97.5 per cent level or higher. Their order of magnitude imply fairly strong response from rivals to the leader's moves in price and quality. As expected in the phase of innovative maturity the high quality reaction elasticity suggests an almost explosive reaction pattern in terms of product quality adjustments. Significant support is also given to the multiple reaction concept, ( of -diagona 1 since three out of six indirect reaction elasticities cellsJ are significant. significant indirect The most reaction elasticities are observed in the quality reaction function (despite the number of degrees of freedom left}. The signs of the price and advertising variables are as B's competitors expected. They indicate that brand not only have reacted in terms of product quality ad- justments to the leader's move In quality, but also to the leader's move in price and advertising. In the advertising reaction function, the positive sign of the price variable is surprizing at first sight. We may have expected, indeed, a reverse counteraction, i.e. an In- crease in competitor's advertising to annihilate the leader's aggres- siveness in price. In fact, this non - i n t ui t i ve result is simply the manifestation of brand B's competitors failure to counteract ciently. During the period under stuay, brand B effi- has consistently do- minated his rivals not cnly in terms of his pr oduct - qua 1 1 ty ratio, but also in terms of its advertising intensity. Thus, this positive 20, sign may sirr.ply reflect the passivity of brand B's competitors who succeeded to fill up their gap vis-^-vis the leader. By drama- r.over tically Increasing itz share of total Industry advertising expenditure (up to 65 %) brand . B has prevented its rivals from effective conteraction by means of advertising. In other words, competition was unable to follow the advertising escalation in order to compen- sate for this price-quality gap. pretation is A further confirmation of the inter- given by the modest order of magnitude of the direct ad- vertising reaction elasticity. Thus, those results seem to be consistent with the com- peting firms actual marketing behavior. They also support the proposition that the firm competitive behavior must be analyzed within the context of the whole marketing mix. EST I HAT I ON _0F T^HE LE ADER^S _S ALE_S J^ LA ST I_C IT I_E S_ We now report results obtained when we assume a simul- taneous dependence between the level of advertising expenditures and the ble. level of sales or market share since the industry demand is staA static and a dynamic version of the model were estimated using the instrumental variables method (equivalent to the two-stage least- squares in this case). Brand B's market share elasticities are reported in Table VII. INSERT TABLE VII ABOUT HERE 21. static and dynamic versions In both solute values of fr.s tlie signs and ab- oaramcters are as expected and are comparable with the ordinary leas t - squares estimates of Table V. They are all significant at the 95 per cent level or higher del, m the static mo- In . the test for serial correlation is performed by calculating the Durbin statistic sion of [ m T) m based on the residuals from the multiple regres- d .• , s « s ] on all t the predetermined variables of the system, whether or not they occur in the fitted equation with non- zero coefficients [10, p. ble [32, pp. correlation. 377]. Referring to Durbin and Watson ta- 724-725], we realize that In the dynamic version, indicates d a positive auto- correlation the test for serial is carried out by testing the significance of the lagged residuals in the regression of the residuals on the lagged residuals and the explanatory variables [33, pp. 420-421]. The namic market share model is in fact the the lagged residuals coefficient. We can thus t d statistic of the dy- statistic corresponding 1 the dynamic market share model are uncorrelated cal specification point of view, to conclude that the residuals • From the dynamic version seems preferable to the static version. However, of 5 of a statisti- the model given the charac- teristics of the market and the periodicity of the data used, the static version is subjectively perfectly acceptable. As both versions have their merits we will continue to take both of them into account for the rest of the analysis. Having ascertained the validity of the empirical results we may now return to the theorem we proposed in the first sec- 22 tlon of this paper. The leader's sales elasticities are to ved. In E = from the application of corollary 4, this case, [I - R] of table VI suiting E • ^. and the E m deri- i.e. Table VIII shows how from the [R] matrix ^, . h"^ u* vectors extracted from table VII, the re- vectors arc obtained. Equilibrium long-run market share E elasticities, defining the full impact over time of changes in price 16 advertising and quality, wers also computed quality, . Except for product- important disparity appears between these long-run elas- no ticities derived from the dynamic model and the elasticities deriVRd from the static model. INSERT TABLE VIII ABOUT HERE ECONOMIC INTERPRETATION OF THE RESULTS The vector contains the total sales elasticities E taking into account the reactions of competitors while the elements of vector E^ ^* do not reoct not react . [R] are the total This can easily be proven since if competitors do [0] = sales elasticities when competitors and ^n ^ "^ * ^m * ^^^^ important feature ena- bles us to visualize the demand for the leader's products as ked resrcnsc curve, ticities (E elasticities » 5 ABOUT HERE worth noting that these estimates of sales elas- are significantly' different from the market share ^ 1 q is kin- drawn on figure 3. INSERT FIGURE It a u (E rn ,, u *). Thus, anyJ judgment on the firms' behavior ba~i t^ 23. sed on the pie, the If we E m vector would have been roriously' bifjsed. Fcr exam- * , u leader's monopoly power would have been underestimaL--^: asc'jme prof i t -maximi z i potential degree of monopoly power, 100 marK-up on marginal cost, then our estimate of the ng behavior, is — • equal to [-100/(1 + the percentage Our estima- )]. n tes of price elasticities are -1.673 in the case of the static version and -1.734 in the case of the dynamic version. This gives a percentage mark-up of price above marginal cost of 114.54 136.29 % or respectively and the corresponding percentages of gross %, margin are 5 3.39 % and 57.68 % . To appreciate the welfare loss attribuable to this monopoly power the ratio of competitive price (nC] to moriopoly price (p) is also very instructive creasing function of the price elasticity : (1 : 1/n it ). is a de- The ratio estimates are 0.46G1 and 0.4232 in this case. All these results conhigh degree of market concentration observed by the end firm the of 1966. As far as the advertising policy of the leader's is concerned, we can compute the value of the adve r t i s i ng- sa 1 es ratio at optimum derived from the Dorf man- S t ei ner rule, according to equa- tion [3] : thus at optimum 24. The static model give^ estimate of in equal to a 0.063 and the dynamic form an estimate equal to 0.002. of r> cc^n,-? rl these values v/ith the observed advertising-sales ratios, mean of which is 0.0B8, shows that although firm B son the had been over- spending from 1363 to 1965, on the average, its advertising behavior had been rational. An adriitionnal confirmation of this fact is obtained when the firm's marginal return on advertising is com- puted: MRA (p - no (p - no . -^ on the ave raj MRA Assuming we get a 53 ^ = (q/s) q.s gross margin and using the static version estimatrs, _. : MRA =(10.71) • (0.118) (983,000/1,407.257) • _= $ 0.6B3 Thus the last dollar spent in advertising produces approximately 1 a 8 net return of 88 cents If we rely on the dynamic version estimates we should 19 take the long-term impact of advertising into account . The long- term marginal cost marginal revenue equality rule in actualized formthen becomes: 3q (25) z 1 = (p - nc Z 1 = (1 + r) 8 25 20 where the cut-off rate. is r price and quality fixea Assumiriji q = ^t*B Y = "^ • 1/(1 n ^*, - t + . , m s , s ^ s T=0 t+B-T-1 A) Thus, for (26) ^ B = 'i' ^^t^B [n Substituting the value of — - q , (1 -X) s n m . . s *] .when / B extracted from (26) into equation (25) z (1-A) -n, '^m^.s*'^t 1 At equilibrium. (28) li-n t-coo ts ] = (p - MC: (1 * r - A) r "t*6 26 and as a consequenci n (29) (p - MO • Q q.s 1 where r • n m^ r - X , s k • 6 1 - Y . n, The long-run optimal equilibrium value of the advertising expenditures s = I (11 .57) • is thus equal to (2.100,0003 • (0. 149 1 : .524 , 0.093 1 (1.524) • + + r r 0. 147 X - 0.344 (0.093) To discount the flov; of returns produced by the advertising invest- ment various interest rates may be considered. Yield on shares in the same industry would give an idea of profit opportunities offernd to the firm by alternative investment decisions. However over the period studied, dividends were not high enough to compensate for the going down stocks so that yield on shares is not indicative cf the external investment opportunities. As a result we turn to tha interest borne by commercial bills over the same period. A 6.5 '<. average rate was observed and the corresponding long-run optimal 27, levGl of should be tht; advertising expenditures amounts to cor,.p::rBd with firm B's real expenditures though the average amount spent is ^clov; ced to conclude that firm B has 1966 period. s e A s s we are, =$1,424,079 "s = $ 1 , 407 257 , wM.h . once again, Alindu- b een overspend i ng over the 1964- sensivity analysis of the long-r'jn equilibrium level to the discount rate rather insensitive to r, INSERT TABLF IX ABOUT HERE 28 CONCLUSIOi\. In this paper we first generalized the well known Dorf man-St ei ner theorem in considering explicitly the multiple compe- titive reaction case. We then reviewed the literature through ries of corollaries. On the basis meters we turned to a a se- the theorem we developed, we of attempted to shed light on an oligopolistic market over racterized by the rapid raise of a a period cha- leader. To estimate the key-para- very simple model. The shortage of degrees of freedom prevented us from trying any more complex form. Hov/ever weak the statistical properties of some of our estimates might be we are nevertheless confident in their descriptive as well as in their normative value. Indead they seem to perfectly describe the firms' com- petitive behavior and reflect our subjective the market. From a a priori feelings about predictive point of view, the competitive reac- tion elasticities should probably be Judgmental ly guessed and 2 rathEir than econometrically aerived a Justed 1 . econometric estimates were converging. In our case. Judgmental and 29, .S ^"-..S 30. EVOLUTION OF MARKET CONCENTRATION 0, 33 ) FIGIJRF 5 X - 4 ESTITATEn KINrFO RESPONSE CURVEJ 3 X - 3 « - ? q NO COWETITIVE RtAC = f (s/p, 32 c * 3 3-- 3- 33, TABLE II DECnnPOSITION OF TOTAL SALES ELASTICITIES IN OLIGOPOLY No competitive reaction E SfLECTEO INDICATOR'S OF MARKET STR'JCTURE IN'OICATGRS TABLE I V ADVERTISING SALES RATIOS' PERIODS 36 TABLE SELECTED MARKET SHAP^ V ELASTICITIES O O CvJ lo 39 TABLE VIII TOTAL SALES ELASTICITIES 0.023' 0.273 -0.774 0.901 Dynamic riodel Static nodcl Long-run Short -run m 0. 147' . u -1 .673 116 0. 188 i , 0.223 u 0.667 0.583* 0.503 0. rL-R 1 . 1 1 5.676 -3.726' 5.543 ,L-R q.u . 138 0.093 0. 171 1 L-R .734 0. 142 0.261 TABLE I X SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS OF THE LONG - RUN OPTIMAL EQUILIBRIUn LEVEL OF ADVERTISING EXPENDITURES r 41 APPENDIX Tslser derived the following relation (translated in • between the various elasticities with respect to our notation) ad- I vertising (A.I] n m, = m) (1 n , s Hn 5 , s = n m , , s " - »S.s' this should have been written as two separa- fact, In (A. 2) { q they result from different assumptions. te equalities because let us • s First, take n„ m, = s n m (1 . , 'S.s s This holds in the case of an oligopoly with stable in- dustry sales, simple competitive reaction and the marKet share func- tion in relative form (see equation On the (A. 3) ^^ other hand - "^^ • (15]). , ^\.s - Is the advertising equivalent ly with expansible industry demand, -^q ,s of equation that is an oligopo- simple competitive reaction and the marKet share function in general form. now be demonstrated. (22), This equivalence will 12. Equation 1-m (A. 4} q with = q m,s = n + . (A. 3} +77 ^ ^r' Q 30 (A. 5] n O.s q,s Ti„ s can be written as q,s CO 3s Q 3rq/ (q+0 n s 3rn s 3m m 9s m 33 3q 30 3q q c 3q q 30 I (A. 6] 3s 3s 3s Substituting (A.B) in the second term of s 30 _ q.s S [1 - Hi = _s 'q.s q.s ^ _^ B^ 3^ _ ' _ q » 3s C ^ , r,, £-1 _ 30 s ^ _s m c y 1 . Is. * 3s + * 1 m (A. 5) - c 3s I 3s * nee c 3s 3s i * ^ _3_m 3s In 3s ^ _3_0 £ 3s m 3s _3n^ , 3s 3S 3s m 3s m 3S 3s ^^•^^ %,s ° ^0^,s * ^S,s • ^Q^.S * "^m^.s * Ps.s * ^m^.S which is the advertising equation from vector equation (22 FOOT N' DIES presentation of the marKeting mix concept, see Borden ^ For ^ Some reactions may be virtually instantaneous, v/hile others may a occur after considerable time lag. For example, price reactions a Advertising reactions, however, usual- are often almost immediate. involve substantial time lags. So, ly '\.t 3u ^ A . k.t-1 ** "K.t-1 , , Whereas ^^^^^^^ ^k.t p %,.u. ^l'"l could be defined as p '"^2ht ~ l.t 1 be ,t 1 .t l.t more general profit function could be considered including dis- tribution, a [ markup, etc. This simple form is used here to establish link with Dorfman and Steiner's work. Throughout we will assume that the second order conditions are satisfied. ^ For a comparison of alternative models of determinants of marke- ting expenditures in the firm, 6 30t/3U is an (n x 1) see Elliott [121. vector, and 3U/3u is an (n x n) To be conformable for multiplication we should write ^ For a matrix. 30t basic discussion of the Cournot and Stackelberg competitivf reaction models, see for example Intriligator [17, pp. 205-19]. 45. The direct elasticity not taking (i.e. into account possibli competitive reaction^ of market share with respect to price 3m . 3pm— has been defined as • i .5* m m .x ^ i >• _ ^ m p* m .p* m £ i.e. . 3p m, .p' a i' *^ .(p*) (X*) (s*) which simplifies to. 'i' Similarly one obtains n r, m^.P = " n m^.p''1 Analogous results obtain for the other decision variables and in vector notation we can write E ^ m , u =-E m , M U = E m , u * The direct elasticity of market share with respect to price is then P m .^ ' P- P a'n„ i.P p*P I m m. ,p i' (p + P) 3p m p*P .s ^ (s°) (x°) . , X o n m , .(x°] 1 _, ^ . X I which reduces to. " "^m^.p m , '^m^.p° ' _o • P o • n p m , tP^P p Similarly one obtains n = m^.P„ n More generally, m 1° , m^.p we can writi m u An index devised P . , m U U , u by Hymer and Pashigian [161. I^ and I^ are res- pectively the unv/eighted and weighted sum of absolute changes in market shares 1=7; •2 = J^ : W '^.T I^.T - - '"i.ii ^.ll • %.1 where m is the marKet share of brand i. n is the number of competing brands. at time t 47 an average instability is I the extent of the observation period. is t index computed over the whole period T of Observation, i.e. I ^ = 1 ^^ . -1 j Hymer and Pashigian's indices. However, ^^ For see Theil ^^ jm^^^ - m^^^_J they were computed as pp. [31, - also computed and reported in Table III, 316-18]. These simultaneous equation models are discussed in Bultez X , P S , -» ^ t-1 riables and m s , x^ - t-1 » s^ ^, t-1 \ were the jointly dependent variables, P^ ^, t-1 S^ ^ t-1 and m^ ^ t-1 7 ] x left in the estimation that the of freedom were results are not worth reporting is are willing to accept that the distributed according to a t^ statistic computed here Student's density function, an assumption, which may be asymptotically valid in the case of simultaneous equation model. , , the predetermined va- . So few degrees If we . ^ comparison of the merits of the Herfindahl index with those a the entropy measure of n ^E^ . ' 48 '^ Note the new Durbin statistic tests thrit against the alternative hypothesis of pendence scheme. the case of In a a the non-autocorrelation first-order Markov de- KoycK model where the original disturbances are independent, when we apply Koyck's transiformation the resulting error terms get correlated according to a first-order moving average scheme and thus the Durbin statistic is ir re levant . this asymptotically valid test has been desi- Moreover, gned for single equation regression model. Its performance is un- known when we apply it to residuals from one equation which is part of ^^ system. a The long term market share elasticities are the elements of 1 the vector (log rn ) • variable, E m * , u where X is the coefficient of the 0.344. i.e. The significance of the , estimator is unknown and depends E critically on the statistical properties of the [R] and E^ ^' i estimators. However the distribution of such an estimator may be empirically approximated by Monte Carlo experiments with various sample sizes. ^^ Assuming a 58 % gross margin and using the dynamic ver<=inn short- run estimates, we obtain MRA ^'^ = (11 .57) : (0.093] • (963,000/1 ,407,2571 = $ 0.752 49 *^ A detailed demonstration of the long-run result may be found in BULTEZ 20 [7]. Since we expect <_ X < 1 . I X*^ = 1/(1 - A) T = 2^ Since we need estimate them. a long period of stable competitive behavior to n . REFERENCES [l] [2] BAIN, J.S., Industrial Organizations York, 1959. and L.E. RICHARTZ. BALIGH, H.H. . John Wiley and Sons. New "Varl ah 1 e-Sum Game flodels of Marketing Problems". Journal of Marketing Research No [3] 2 (May, P.M., BASS, 1967), pp. "A Vol. . IV, 173-1B3. Simultaneous Equation Regression Study of Adver- tising and Sales of Cigarettes", Journal of Marketing Research Vol. [4] VI. No 3 BORDEN, N.H., (August. BREMS, HANSEN, H., M. pp. 291-300. "The Concept of the Marketing Mix", Journal of Ad- vertising Research [5] 1969), "Price, . Vol. 4, No 2 (June, BULTEZ, A., in 2-7. : KJAER (ed.). Readings in Danish Thcorij of Marketing 1966, pp. . - North- 149-159. "Leader's Marketing Behavior in Oligopoly", C.I.M. Working Paper 6-71, College I cicr.ccs du Msnagcment [7] pp. Duality and Rival Response", Holland Publishing Company, Amsterdam, [B] 1964), teruni vers i t aire d'§tudes doctora(C.I.M.), Eru; ine 197 BULTEZ, A., Competitive Strategy for Interrelated Markets, published Ph. D. 1 Un' dissertation, Louvain University, in process , 51. [ol COWLING, CUBBIN. and J. K. Competition : [9] pp. DORFriAN, Quality and Advertising An Econometric Investigation of the United King- dom Car Market", Economica 1971), "Pr::ce, , Vol. (November, XXXVIII, No 152 376-394. STEINER, and P.O. R. "Optimal Advertising and Optimal Quality", American Economic Review. Vol. XLIV, No 1954), [10] DURBIN, pp. 626-836. "Testing for Serial Correlation in Systems of Si- J., multaneous Regression Equations", Biometvika pp. [11] (December, 5 Vol. . 44 (1957), 370-377. DURBIN, J., "Testing for Serial Correlation in L eas t - Squares Regression when Some of the Regressors are Lagged Dependent Variables". Econometvica [12] Vol. 38. No 3 Comparison of Models of Marketing Investment "A in the Firms", Quarterly Review of Economics and Business II (September, FELDSTEIN, M.S., 1971). pp. 53-70. "Advertising Research and Profits in the Drug Industry", The Southern Economic Journal ry. [14] 1970). pp. 410-429 (hay. ELLIOTT, J.W., Vol. [13] , , Vol. 35, No 3 (Janua- 1969). pp. 239-243. GUPTA. S.K. and K.S. to Marketing", 1967), pp. KRISHNAN, "Differential Equation Approach Operations Research. Vol. 1030-1039. 15, No 6 (Nov. -Dec, [15] S.K. ting". Operations Research, Vol. pp. [16] "Mathematical Models in MarKe- KRISHNAN, and K.S. GUPTA, No 15, 6 (Nov. -Dec, 1967), 1040-1050. HYMER, S. and P. PASHIGIAN, "Turnover of Firms as a Measure of Market Behavior", The Review of Economics and Statistics XLIV, [17] No (February, 1 INTR ILIGATOR V\ , .G ., 1952), 82-87. "Mathematical Optimization and Economic Theory". Prentice-Hall. [18] pp. Inc.. Englewood Cliffs, N.J., 1971. "Competitive Strategies for New Product Marketing KOTLER, P., over the Life Cycle", Management Science cember, [19] 1955), KRISHNAN. pp. and S.K. K.S. [20] pp. , Vol. GUPTA, "Mathematical Model for Vol. 13, No (April, LAMBIN, J.J., Eoor.omics. 7 Duo- a (March, "Measuring the Profitability of Advertising Empirical Study", Journal of Industrial Economics [21] (Oe- 4 568-583. LAMBIN, J.J., No 2 No 12, 104-119. "polistic Market", Management Science, 1967), Vol. , 1959), pp. , Vol. : An XVII, 86-103. "Advertising and Competitive Behavior", Applied Vol. 2, No 4 (1970), pp. 231-251. . 53, [22] "Optimal Allocation of Competitive HarKeting J.J., LAflBIN, Efforts", Journal of Business [23] Vol. 43, No 4 (October, 1970), Irwin, NAERT, in Promotional Competition". In F.M. BASS Mathematical Models and Methods in Marketing, (eds]. al. R.D. [24] "A Study MILLS. H.D., et , 466-484. pp. Homewood, Inc., Illinois, 1961, pp. 245-269. "Optimi^inp; Consumer Advertising, P. A., Advertising and Markup in gement Science, Vol. 16, a Intermediary Vertical Market Structure", Mana- No 4, Pt. II (December, 1971). pp. 90-101 [25] NAERT, P . A . "Optimizing Marketing Mix Decisions: ., Analysis," in David Sciences , C. Murphy (ed.), Recent Developments in the Decision Proceedings of the American Institute for Decision Sciences Northeast Regional Conference, 1972, pp. [26] OSGOOD, C.B., of Meaning [27] [28] PALDA, An Economic G.J. SUCI and P.H. .1-8. TANNENBAUM, The Measurement University of Illinois Press, , K.S., Urbana, 1957. The Measurement of Cumulative Advertising Effects, Englewood Cliffs, N.J., Prentice-Hall, Inc., SCHULTZ, R.L., "Market Measurement and Planning with 1954. taneous Equation Model", Journal of Marketing Research VIII. No 2 (May, 1971], pp. 153-164. Simul- a , Vol. 54. [29] SHAKUN, n.F., "A Dynamic nodel Tor Competitive MarKeting Coupled Markets", Management Science, Vol. 1966), [30] TELSER. THEIL, L.J., H., , LXX, No 5 (October, in (August, 1962), pp. 471-499. Economics and Information Theory, North -Ho 1 land 1967. THEIL, H., Principles of Econometrics New York, 12 "Advertising and Cigarettes", Journal of PolitiVol. Publishing Company, Amsterdam, [32] No 525-529. pp. cal Economy [31] 12, 1971. , John Wiley S Sons, Inc 0G15'89 APR OCT 2 8 '77 MOV 1 1 "81 SEP 11 3 ZOdl mmmmii .... -)^ 4^^ 3 TD60 003 702 3 TOaO 003 b71 507 2*=I4 4fil 3 TDfiO 003 3 lOfiO 003 b71 M40 3 TDfiO 003 b71 t.71 mb llllliilllilllll!:il!liiil!li:l!;!lll!illlllini 3 TOaO 003 70S 3 TDfiO > 1 I ,^^ 4bfi 003 70E 47b 6^/7-73