><.<.T. UBRARIES - DEVVPY HD28 .M414 & / ^ Oewey \ 6j^ BOARDS AS NORMATIVE ARENAS: $* ' CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND THE ROUTINES OF CEO SELECTION Worldiig Paper No. 3724-94 WILLIAM OCASIO Massachusetts Institute of Technology Sloan School of Management E52-562 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, Massachusetts 02139 Tel. (617) 253-8412 E-Mail: wocasio@sloan.mit.edu. September 1994 ;.;assachusetts iNsriTure OF TECHNOLOGY DEC 01 1994 LIBRARIES Boards as Normative Arenas: Corporate Governance and the Routines of CEO Selection' William Ocasio Tel: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Sloan School of Management E52-562 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02139 (617) 253-8412 e-mail: wocaslo@sloan.mit.edu September 1994 I would like to thank Mauro Guillen, Rebecca Henderson, and Nick Ziegler suggestions, Hyosun Kim, Sandy Raju, and Hee-Jun the Stanford Graduate School of Business and the research support. Rho for assistance MIT Sloan School of in for comments and data collection, and Management for Boards as Normative Arenas: Corporate Governance and the Routines of CEO Selection Abstract I develop a conceptual model of corporate boards as normative arenas, self-regulated by rules embodied in the organization's norms and routines. routinization of CEO selection in I apply this theory to explain the U.S. industnal corporations. An analysis of the competing nsks of insider versus outsider succession provides strong evidence for reliance informal CEO selection routines. selection routines, structure, I and early To test for alternative explanations for examine the mediating CEO on formal and why boards effects of performance, firm age, rely on ownership departures on their persistence. The findings support the view of boards as normative arenas. The governance of U.S. corporations is undergoing renewed scrutiny by organization theorists, strategy researchers, financial economists, and by the general business press. While both organizational and economic theorists have traditionally viewed corporate boards as mechanisms for adapting the organization to Salancik, 1978; Fama and environmental and market demands (Pfeffer and Jensen, 1983), researchers are increasingly questioning their effectiveness as instruments of corporate control (Walsh and Seward, 1990). Jensen (1993), address his presidential to the Amehcan Finance in Association, attributed the inability of U.S. corporations to adapt effectively to changing competitive and financial environments during the 1980s to the inertia Kodak provide and confronted with crisis. to foster change in corporate strategies and structures, e.^ept Jensen (1993: 863) argues board ineffectiveness, with truth corporate governance. General Motors, IBM, and Eastman well-publicized instances of the persistent failure of corporate boards during the 1980s and early 1990s of failure of their that board culture is when an important component emphasis on "politeness and courtesy at the expense of and frankness." However, the question remains: why do boards value consensus and discourage overt conflicts? What causes inertia in corporate governance and the "failure" of boards of directors to foster corporate adaptation? I will argue that existing explanations literature of corporate and controversies regarding boards interests in shaping board decisions yet logic of governance are incomplete of directors much, if has focused on the — most of the role of contending not most, of board actions are governed by a appropriateness and rule-following (March and Olsen, 1989). Corporate governance typically involves not instrumental control over contending interests, but reliance on the appropriate rules of corporate behavior. This implies that board decisions are often determined, not by a calculus of the norms, rules, consequences of alternative standardized patterns of behavior, conventions, and organizational routines to the specific situations faced by the organization. actions courses of action, but by the application of become institutionalized and norms Board routines persist through time as of appropriate beliefs 1 their and behavior are established Boards as Normative Arenas (Zucker, 1977; March and Olsen, 1989). The reliance and the persistence in of routines of board decision-making implies that the formal mechanisms of corporate governance are characterized by organizational inertia (Hannan and Freeman, 1984). Adaptationist theorists have highlighted the importance of mechanisms by which organizations and CEO boards are able their succession and selection as to align the organizations with environmental contingencies and resource dependencies (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978; and Romaneli, 1985). Outsider succession, organizational in particular change (Helmich and Brown, 1982). But of either insider or outsiders as informal routines of CEO CEOs selection. is has been seen as a trigger of this paper will contend that the selection a routinized process, conditioned by the formal and These norms and boards and serve routines of CEO accountability and they capacity to foster organizational change and adaptation. limit their reliability of to selection increase the channel corporate actions. At the This paper examines the persistence of routines of corporate governance selection of insiders versus outsiders as to develop a theory of corporate boards logic of CEOs. The (2) to persistence of formal and informal routines of is research on CEO time the context of normative arenas, which are guided by a apply the theory to explain the reliance on and CEO selection; and, (3) to examine how the mediated by the age, economic performance, and ownership structure of the corporation, as well as by the timing of theoretical literatures in same objectives of the paper are as follows: (1) of directors as appropriateness and rule-following; persistence of routines Tushman CEO departure. This paper contnbutes both to the on corporate governance and organizational routines and to the empirical selection. THEORIES OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE Boards as Governing Councils Following Berle and Means' (1967) classic study of the separation of ownership and control American corporations, theory and research on corporate governance has focused in attention on Boards as Normative Arenas the question of who controls the corporation managehal, shareholder, and class interests theoretical approaches predominate and in its board of directors and the relative power of shaping instrumental control. Three alternative the organizational literature: agency theory imported in , from financial economics (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Fama and Jensen, 1983; Tosi and Gomez-Mejia, 1989; Zajac, 1990), focuses on the effects of ownership structure and board control in management, the agents, aligning the interests of with the interests of the shareholders, the principals; managerialist theory (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978; Fredhckson, Hambhck, and Baumrin, 1986; Boeker, 1992; Cannella and role of management and political coalition; Davis, 1 in controlling board Lubatkin, 1993), focuses on the processes to guarantee survival of the firm and Useem, 1984; social structural theory (Mizruchi, 1982; Palmer, 1983; 391) focuses on '' e interests and position of networks of elite its members board in ^ shaping board behavior and decision-making. Agency, managenalist, and social structural theories of corporate governance vary managers, or networks of implicitly elites in their predominate views of whether the interests of shareholders, in board decision-making. All three perspectives agree, however, on the disciplinary role of boards of directors as governing councils, which control and mobilize resources in support of contending economic and Governing councils are social groupings that mobilize both social for controlling and disciplining the behavior of actors activities (White, 1992). Examples and capital political interests. and material resources identities in production of governing councils given by and exchange White include Hollywood production, parliaments, cooperative federations, commissahes, and royal councils. Actors film in governing councils are characterized by their dependencies on the rooted interests of the diverse factions to which they are maneuverings compensation, examples that of tied. The essence of governing councils are the these factions around substantial outcomes (White, 1992). Executive CEO dismissals, and the adoption of takeover defenses are of the substantive decisions by corporate directors boards allocate resources in in some of the which past studies have found support of the interests and allegiances that they represent Boards as Normative Arenas (Wade, O'Reilly and Chandratat, 1990; Boeker, 1992; Davis, 1991). The directors as governing councils highlights their strategic role ignores the routines which characterize much of in identity of boards of firm decision-making, but what boards do. Boards as Normative Arenas Participants and observers of board decision-making note corporate actions, seldom firm's political coalition, explicitly boards rarely that corporate members consider the conflicting interests of the initiate of the and almost always reach decisions by consensus (Mace, 1971; Lorsch, 1989; Bowen, 1994). Boards of directors are subject to norms and rules of appropriate behavior that structure board meetings and decision-making. While most governance focus on the instrumental existing theories of corporate control function of board of directors, the obse . atioiis of board behavior present a very different view, one that highlights the rule-bound process of board decision making. Hirsch (1982; 12) companies found or organizations that directors in their role do not interviews of board in think of members of Fortune 500 themselves as representing any outside interest as board members but are self-regulated by a "widely shared normative structure of appropriate behavior and forms of control." To account for these observations and for the prevalence of routines in corporate governance, I will argue that boards often serve as normative arenas,' where decision are governed not by a logic of interests or consequences, but by a logic of appropriateness and social identity (March and Olsen, 1989; March, 1994). ' I use the term "normative" with some concern that connotes many some might be misinterpreted, as a Parsonian, oversocialized conception of behavior. As it Garfinkel (1967) and others have shown, norms and routines both inside and outside of organizations are extremely as for it fragile rigid rules and subject to challenge. followed by "cultural dopes, social identity to those that enact " Norms are best understood, but as tools that provide a them Norms of corporate in my sense of interpretation, not meaning and governance are not external board members, but are actively created and reproduced by participants in the arena. to Boards as Normative Arenas Building upon both White's (1992) theory of arena disciplines and March and Olsen's (1989) analysis of rule following, institutionalized action, and the logic of appropriateness, I will define normative arenas as social groupings that create and enforce socially constructed rules and procedures that represent the social appropriateness of their activities. identity of the participants in the Examples of normative systems, and editorial of and material what among is or is in their ability to activities of the actors in the discipline in discipline, distinct select and exclude the terms of socially-negotiated rules not the right thing to do. Normative arenas are charactehzed by a conversation a community of participants, one which the vocabulary of motives in on normative commitments rather than on material presuppose a corporations, appellate court in peer review boards. Normative arenas are a form of from governing councils, whose control function resides social arenas include professional and licensing boards, functional departments accreditation arena and the common appropnateness social identity by participants of the rules down, and decisions interests. will is based ^.rimarily Normative arena disciplines and shared assumptions regarding the and standards. OthenA/ise, arena disciplines are likely to break be based instead on the concrete economic, social, and political networks of relationships of participants within the arena. Normative arenas place strong reliance on histoncal precedent to guide their decisions. The rules, standards, and principles which take force within the arena are no: and I beliefs of their participants (White, argue that boards of directors and appropriateness rules, standards, ^ and fixed, however, but evolve and change with the values 1992)^ typically act as normative arenas, concerned with the legitimacy of board decision-making, principles prevalent White's (1992) concept of arena is in and with matching corporate decisions to the the organization. They exert control over the much broader than that of normative includes other forms of selection processes including exchange markets. arenas and Exchange markets share with normative arenas a concern with self-regulation based on the values established by participants in the arena, but in the former case the values are market pnces while they are normative commitments. in the latter Boards as Normative Arenas corporation not by "deciding" on how resources stakeholders that constitute the firm's of the activities are allocated and distributed political coalition, among the various but by evaluating the appropriateness and procedures undertaken by the organization. The view of boards as normative arenas emphasizes the active agency and ongoing achievement required on the part of board members things are done in the reproduction of the rules, routines, and conventions that govern organizations and in example, boards of directors will how organizational members play by those rules. For be concerned with monitohng established procedures articulation of a strategic direction, plans, how for the and objectives by management, and making sure that those strategies selected match the then-prevailing standards of appropriate firm practices. But contrary to what is implied in the view of boards as governing councils, directors rarely initiate corporate strategies or independently evaluate the consequences of the alternatives considered, and it is a taboo subject to consider openly the effects of such strategies on the various organizational stakeholders (Lorsch, 1989). The identity of boards as normative arenas highlights standardization of prevalent in their role in the formalization modern corporate bureaucracies. Boards are both a symbol and of the rationality corporate structures (Weber [1922] 1978, Meyer and Rowan, 1978), and a controller of corporate activities to assure their accountability Freeman, 1984). These functions presuppose a set of and reliability (Hannan and agreed-upon norms and routines of corporate governance, which serve as precedent and guidance for board decisions. Examples of informal norms of corporate contacting fellow board governance include members limits on open criticism of the CEO, not outside of meetings, and for most boards, using a rhetoric of shareholder interests to explain board decisions (Mace, 1971; Lorsch, 1989). Examples of routines of corporate governance include the formal reliance on committees of outside directors for setting executive of all compensation and capital expenditure decision for above a monitoring corporate audits, the approval by boards certain amount, and the standardization of the succession and selection process. Routines of executive succession and selection, in CEO particular. Boards as Normative Arenas embody the board's role power and in what Weber ([1922] 1978) authority of the founding chief executive the formal position, rather than in governance embody the mission, (Selznick, 1957). The normative arenas is identity, shaped by both the normative commitments that board 70). Norms and board members The norms and is invested understandings, and commitments of the corporation guides the disciplinary function of boards as and the legal fiduciary requirements (Clark, 1991) members exercise the duties of loyalty, care, due diligence, their ultimate responsibility to "do the right thing" (Lorsch, and 1989: reliability of accomplishing these fiduciary duties and normative commitments. FORMAL AND INFORMAL ROUTINES OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE The in routines of corporate routines of corporate governance increase the accountability in charisma" as the becomes depersonalized and the individual occupant. logic of appropriateness that good business judgment, with calls the "routinization of routinization of organizational activities tradition in organization theory and decisions is ^ an idea with a long history and (Weber, [1922] 1978; March and Simon, 1958; Cyert and March, 1963; Nelson and Winter, 1982; March and Olsen, 1989; March, 1994). Although the specific terminology used differs by vanous authors and includes bureaucratic rules, programs, standard operating procedures, routines, conventions, and organizational norms, the various terms connote behavioral, cognitive, and decision making, In this paper cultural persistence in organizational use the term routines I patterns of behavior, cognition, and values and procedures, as of the organization environmental deschbe the regular and predictable organizations. Routines include both formal rules in well as informal rules, or norms. Routines are history-dependent, socially constructed programs of action that memory to behavior and stimuli. and its embody the knowledge, capabilities, beliefs, values, and members and which Routines both facilitate are invoked in response and constrain behavior by (1) to conserving on the cognitive capabilities of individuals (March and Simon, 1958); (2) providing for accountability Boards as Normative Arenas and reliability of channeling organizational activities political conflict in The Role of Routines in (Hannan and Freeman, 1984); and, Alternative Theories of Corporate into the research persistence of routines has been found formal activities is a Governance commonplace in the organizational That they also characterize major decisions of boards of directors accepted or incorporated role, e.g., and organizations (Cyert and March, 1963; Nelson and Winter, 1982). That routines characterize organizational literature. (3) limiting in literature. decisions is less-well Although empirical evidence for the in which board members play at least a corporate mergers (Amburgey and Miner, 1993), the theoretical literature on corporate governance has not acknowledged or accounted for the routinization of board decisions. Furthermore, the concern with instrumental control and resource mobilization that characterizes existing views of boards as governing councils would imply that board routines, observed, are an ephiphenomena, a reflection of bounded rationality interests by the board's dominant coalition. In particular, the in ^ if the pursuit of matenal view of boards as governing councils implies that routines of corporate governance are unlikely to persist as the conditions that led to their establishment vary, as failures and as the material interests of controlling board While the persistence of board routines governing councils, Routines embody in it is is performance trigger search in new routines, members change. not easily reconciled with views of boards as an observable implication of the view of boards as normative arenas. the normative commitments and fiduciary requirements of board and, as stated above, serve as tools which increase the members for accomplishing their duties. According to reliability this view, members and accountability of board routines are not readily immediate material interests of board amenable to members or to their network of connections. Therefore, an examination of persistence change and cannot be reduced to the board in the routines of corporate governance allows us to test empincally the implications of viewing boards as normative arenas. Boards as Normative Arenas Routines of The CEO reliance on Selection and persistence of routines of CEO selection provides an important testing for the implications of the views of boards as normative arenas. While case boards for may delegate to CEOs new CEOs provides an opportunity for realigning the corporation with the controlling interests of as agents important decisions that occur within the board of directors. governance In particular, their tenure, the selection of both agency and managerialist accounts of corporate CEO highlight the importance of succession and selection as a mechanism for adapting the organization to environmental and economic contingencies (eg, Zajac, 1990; Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978). These accounts suggest that routinized, but will reflect instead the interests of those The view 1954; Carroll, 1984). At the or who selection is unlikely to same is time, the effects of succession firm profitability and/ or CEO a potentially disruptive activity for organizations (Gouldner, ambiguous, and even the results decrease be control the corporation. boards as normative arenas suggests a very different perspective on of selection. Managerial succession highly CEO its of on corporate performance are academic research on whether is likely it to increase survival prospects are equivocal (e.g., Carroll, 1984; Zajac, 1990). Given the potential hazards and ambiguity surrounding the CEO succession and selection process, boards as normative arenas focus on controlling for the accountability reliability of organizational activities. Boards' reliance on succession and selection provides a sense of order commitment to the in norms and routines and of executive governance decisions, communicates corporate mission and programs, and channels political dynamics into acceptable practices and procedures. Formal routines of insider selection. process in large U. S. corporations found evidence for the prevalence of two distinct variants of formal routines of insider apparent Vancil's (1987) descriptive study of the succession in CEO selection The more common form was the existence of a heir the form of a president and chief operating officer (COO), distinct from the CEO. Boards as Normative Arenas Cannella and Lubatkin (1993), following a managerialist theory interpretation of Vancil's study, found that the designation of a heir apparent decoupled the relationship between firm performance and outsider succession. The second variant was the reliance on a "horse race" among internal competitors for the top spot, usually presidents. In both variants the contender(s) for the board of directors, affording on-the-job training members with the opportunity to gain termed as vice-chairman or executive vice CEO were also members position of the and allowing outside board for the candidates, knowledge and experience regarding the inside contenders. Both types of insider internal labor market CEO for selection described by Vancil (1987) constitute a formalization of an CEOs, which embeds the routines of executive succession and selection within the formal authority structure of the corporation. This internal market for is characterized, as are other forms, by promotion from within, the salience of formal job and career ladders, and a reliance on and making (Doeringer and when Piore, 1971). rigidity of Boards formally designated by both their job will title directors, signal to the internal contenders for CEOs, rely for the chief commit themselves and external communities When 1: The formal designation officer, or vice Informal routines of CEO candidates either heir apparents replacement. Job their designation that their titles of as inside occupants are potential boards in likelihood of insider of executives as directors chairman increases the CEO faced with formalized internal labor markets on prevailing succession routines and increase the operating CEO the logic of appropriateness and rule-following prevalent Hypothesis to insider and board membership as and vice chairman, coupled with executive position. titles formal rules and procedures for decision (Cannella and Lubatkin, 1993), or as potential contenders for president, chief operating officer CEOs and likelihood of insider will CEO lead them to selection: either as president, chief CEO selection. selection. Boards as normative arenas are influenced both by the organization's formal routines and by its informal 10 norms and procedures. The reliance on and Boards as Normative Arenas persistence of informal routines executive succession. organizational response in First, memory and is influenced by several factors, which are not exclusive to the adoption of an organizational routine increases increases the likelihood that future circumstances (March Amburgey, 1991). Second, the bargaining and open will availability in be invoked as an organizational and Simon, 1958; Walsh and Ungson, 1991; reliance on political conflict in it its and persistence of routines Kelly and reduces the costs of organizations, as routines constitute a form of "truce" (Nelson and Winter, 1982: 107-112), with stable accommodations and quasi-resolution of among conflict the divergent interests adoption of routines signals their become in the organization (Cyert and March, 1963). political viability and appropriateness. Third, routines infused with value, as symbols of the organizational mission and as institutional purpose ^Selznick, 1957), increasing the social The can embodiments of identification of the organization's executives. These routines These and motivational factors cognitive, political, may vary effects governance in in their that influence the persistence of informal strength for routines of either insider and outsider must be understood in light CEO selection. of the broader institutional field of corporate which publicly held corporations operate, where routinization occurs not only the level of the individual organization but at the organizational 1983). Insider succession has particularly for larger become the (statistical) norm (DiMaggio and Powell, for U.S. publicly held corporations, companies. While executive succession effects are likely to matter as experience with insider field at is a commonplace, firm-level and outsider selection will alter board decisions through the routinization of charismatic authority and the separation of the firm's identity from that of its founder(s). Following Amburgey and Miner (1992), I organizational experience as an indicator of reliance on prevailing routines. political effects of outsider selection experience at the firm level insiders, however, as activities and signals its its adoption both increases political its may be rely The on past cognitive and greater than for availability in the board's repertoire of appropriateness within the focal organization. The motivational 11 Boards as Normative Arenas effects of insider and CEO between the board and top executives implicit contracts internal labor selection are likely to be greater, nonetheless, as informal markets for CEOs. The examine separately the subsequent effects of insider CEO and motivational effects selection on and outsider firm-level norm formation lead us insider selection increases the likelihood of subsequent selection. CEO selection. ^ likelihood of of insider succession subsequent ^i> ' Note that while views of boards as governing councils could account 1 based on either the superior for the reliance performance of insiders as CEOs 990) or the power of insiders over the board of directors (Cannella and Lubatkin, can less to succession expehence on Hypothesis 2b: Past reliance on outsider selection increases the outsider of CEO selection: Hypothesis 2a: Past reliance on insider CEO more formal paralleis the effects of different cognitive, political, reliance on routines of insider versus outsider commitments directly account for the 1 on routines (Zajac, 993), they existence of both insider and outsider selection routines. PERSISTENCE OF ROUTINES OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE The view of corporate boards as normative arenas emphasizes not only their reliance on routines for decision-making, but the persistence of these routines under diverse set of economic and environmental conditions. This persistence is closely related to the function of the board of directors as controllers of organizational accountability and must distinguish between theories of bounded rationality and political albeit one limited by constraints on rational decision making, and theories of rule-following the institutionalization of action (March and Olsen, 1989), structured, socially-constructed reliability Here we (March and Simon, 1958; Cyert and March, 1963), where routines result from a logic of consequences, cognitive reliability. and accountability commitments of the board where routines convey to the organization's of directors' 12 commitments and highly- purpose and agenda The to the organization's mission Boards as Normative Arenas entails a high degree of persistence and (Hannan and Freennan, 1984). To adaptability, routines of whether that CEO selection CEOs Effects of The and those inertia in distinguish emphasize the routines of corporate governance between accounts their inertia, I will of routines that stress their evaluate how the persistence of are affected by firm's performance, age, ownership structure, and by are dismissed or depart prior to normal retirement. Economic Performance on Persistence and Change effects of economic performance on persistence and change in governance routines provide a strong test of the theory of boards as normative arenas and of the logic of approphateness and rule-following in adaptive models of decision-making programs and routines in response corporate governance. is to An important component their hypothesis that organizations change of their * environmental change and failures of economic performance (March and Simon, 1958; Cyert and March, 1963). But the view of boards as normative arenas implies a different perspective, one where appropnate behavior under periods of economic adversity implies a continuing commitment and routines. In to the boards' values, norms, beliefs, discussing boards' commitment to norms and routines of their social identification with the rules CEO and culture of the organization, and not selection their I mean personal allegiances to individual incumbents of the executive positions. Boards as normative arenas respond to economic whether they should determining what is adversity, not by evaluating the persist with their past choices or economic and political consequences of whether they should change, but by the appropnate thing to do as determined by the prevailing rules and routines of the organization. The implies that board decisions will commitments. This form of reliance on rules be governed by and routines under economic adversity their past experience and organizational board behavior can be characterized as form of a threat-rigidity response (Staw, Sandelands, and Dutton 1981), rather than failure-induced change (March and Simon, 1958; Cyert and March, 1963). It does not mean, however, 13 that boards w'll fail to Boards as Normative Arenas act under adversity, but rather that their actions embedded in The theory of boards as normative be guided by an will the culture of the organization and in its rules institutional logic, and routines (Ocasio, 1995). arenas and theories of adaptive change consistent with the view of boards as governing councils provide contrasting hypotheses regarding persistence and change in routines of CEO selection: Hypothesis 3a: Under economic routines for insider and outsider adversity, corporate boards CEO selection. Hypothesis 3b: Economic adversity leads routines of insider versus outsider CEO on formal and informal will rely (Boards as normative arenas). to failure-induced change in the organizational selection. (Boards as governing councils). Firm Age and the Persistence of Routines The view of boards as normative arenas implies that the persistence of governance routines increases with the age of the organization. The mission and purpose of the organization becomes embodied become in the normal and rules of the organization, and organizational routines taken-for-granted and less subject to question or challenge. Hannan and Freeman (1984, 1989) argue that organizational histories generate constraint on structural change by providing legitimate justifications beyond self interest for opposing change, and precluding considerations of alternatives repertoires. Consequently, the reproducibility of organizational routines increases monotonically with age. Furthermore, pressures toward internal consistency and homogeneity are likely to relationship Hypothesis of members' perceptions also suggest that organizational norms and routines increase with age (Aldnch and Auster, 1986). These arguments imply a direct between 4: firm age and the persistence The persistence of routines of of routines of CEO 14 CEO selection; selection increases with firm age. Boards as Normative Arenas Structure of Firm Ownership and Routines of One CEO Selection possible explanation for the existence and persistence of routines of CEO selection is they result from agency problems associated with the separation of ownership and control U.S. corporations. boards In this interpretation, shareholder interests because neither board fail to act as governing councils members nor management have in the proper incentive structure for board While prior research vs. outsider effects CEO in CEO sufficient stake in norms corporate governance results from the lack of inertia of members and managers (Walsh and Seward, selection has in protection of the firm's ownership to act vigilantly (Jensen, 1993). According to this view, reliance of and routines of decision-making and the shown that the structure of 1990). ownership affects insider succession (Boeker and Goodstein, 1992; Cannella and Lubatkin, 1993), on the reliance on routines remains unexplored. The view arenas suggests that increased firm that of its boards as normative ownership by management and board members, rather than increasing their reliance on a logic of consequences for board decision, further enhances their commitment to the norms and values of the corporation and to the organization's routines. According to the view of boards as normative arenas, any increased commitment to the corporation resulting from firm ownership commitment to the norms and is likely to translate instead into routines of the corporation. Two alternative increased hypotheses are presented to explore how the structure of ownership affects the reliance on routines of CEO selection: Hypothesis 5a: Increased ownership by management increases reliance on routines of CEO selection. (Boards as normative arenas). Hypothesis 5b: Increased ownership by management decreases selection. (Boards as governing councils). 15 reliance on routines of CEO Boards as Normative Arenas Early CEO Departures and Dismissals and Reliance on CEO Selection Routines Political or managerialist theorists of corporate governance and executive succession often distinguish between the effects of CEO dismissals and early departures, and other forms of succession (Fredrickson, Hambrick, and Baumrin, 1986). Empirical studies have supported view, finding that the determinants of retirement (i.e., 64 years and older) CEO succession and selection vary for CEOs this facing and younger executives (Puffer and Weintrop, 1991; Cannella and Lubatkin, 1993). This managerialist interpretation implies that the persistence of routines of of CEO CEO selection more likely to hold for the normal process of retirement. dismissals and early departures, corporate governance sociopolitical process, Alternatively, the and the view of is CEO routines that are invoked the case boards as governing councils would hold. CEO selection departures as well as to retirements. The norms and repertoires of may vary under the two sets of circumstances, however. Note that the appropriateness and rule-following that underlies the theory of boards as normative arenas does not imply that these norms and routines are invariant to the external contingencies faced by the organization. Different rules and routines different circumstances. For dismissals and other for example, a different set of norms CEO may be may be retirements. In the former case, boards of insider succession. and may internal applied under appropriate for reliance on routines of outsider succession. In the latter case, they are norms In best understood as a view of boards as normative arenas implies that routines of apply to cases of early logic of is CEO increase their more likely to rely on According to the view of boards as normative arenas, norms and routines are likely to affect board decision making under either circumstance. To distinguish whether the view of boards as normative arenas applies only to cases of retirement, or more generally, Hypothesis 6a: Early CEO I offer the following set of alternative hypotheses: departures increases reliance on routines of outsider selection and decreases reliance on routines of insider selection 16 (Boards as normative arenas). Boards as Normative Arenas Hypothesis 6b: Early CEO outsider CEO departures decreases reliance on routines of both insider and selection. (Boards as governing councils). METHOD Sample. A random sample of 120 U.S. industrial corporations or the Moody's Industrial Directory for 1980 population listed in sample includes publicly held companies listed in exchanges and contains a broad representation of observation is ownership data 108 firms. became Not the company New companies companies had data publicly held after 1960. for the Many in York, American, or regional stock of firm size and ownership Given lack of complete period. Many were became The unit financial and structure. the original sample, the sample others merged, total selected for the analysis. This year, covering the years 1960-1990, for fourteen of the all the was 4.45 percent of the was reduced to found«=>d and/ or bankrupt, went private, or otherwise ceased to be publicly held companies duhng the decade of the 1980s. The methodology treats any spells ending ownership as right-censored in bankruptcy, acquisition, and change to private at that point. This implies that the effects being measured relate exclusively to normal forms of succession within the current ownership of the firm. sample used included 2,287 company-years The sample was selected as of high-techology companies, to sample selection bias, 1980 total of data. to permit corporations become The founded since 1960, including part of the sample. This creates some potential for as firms that disappeared between 1960 and 1980 were excluded from the sample. Sampling as of 1960, however, would have excluded newer firms from the sample, which then would have been less representative of firms in 1990. Sampling in 1980 was selected as a compromise solution that would both reduce sample selection bias and produce a representative sample of industrial firms Independent Variables and CEO in 1990. Selection Events. 17 Boards as Normative Arenas CEO CEO succession and selection. succession events were coded from Standard and Poor's Directory of Corporations. Officers, and Directors based on changes relevant officers. CEO selection A total of 216 succession events occurred Following Cannella and Lubatkin (1993), . had been employees of the company for at least in the sample. Insider vs. outsider CEOs were coded were appointed employment CEOs were in history. if they reports, and Who's some in instances, preparation for becoming and Directory of Corporations. Officers, supplemented by proxy statements, 10Ks, annual verify prior as insiders was undertaken because, outsiders are appointed to the corporation for a short period of time Finance to of the two years phor to becoming CEO; otherwise they were classified as outsiders. This procedure CEOs. Data from Standard and Poor's names the in Who in Industry and Outside members of the board of directors classified as outsiders. A total of was Directors, who 157 insider succession events and 59 outsider successions were recorded. Routines of CEO CEO internal labor markets, for insider directors, other than the officer, or vice board in CEO. A chairman was succession were coded based on the job formal ILM listed of formal routines, or was recorded when as both an officer of the inside a president, chief operating company and a member of the . CEO succession were in place Succession Routines examining whether the outsiders, or whether it firm has . I in 65.4 % of the measure past CEO-years Directors . CEOs of in the sample. reliance on informal relied exclusively in the past (since has experienced both. The history of 1950 was recorded from Standard and Poor's Directory new companies were insiders or outsiders, using the coding all CEO CEO was selection routines by 1950) on either insiders or CEOs in the company of Corporatio ns. Officers, classified as founders since and Others were classified as scheme and data sources described above Four mutually exclusive categories of past succession experience were coded: current titles of Standard and Poor's Directory of Corporations. Officers, and Directors Formal ILMs for insider Past CEOs. The existence Selection. Formal ILM for the founder. Past insiders , when 18 all CEOs None when , the since 1950, other than the founder, Boards as Normative Arenas were insiders, Past outsiders outsiders, and Both when , sample 52.0% of the 15.3% as Both , when CEOs all CEOs since 1950 included both insiders and outsiders. company years were insiders since 1950, other than the founder, were classified will the as Past insiders, 12.6% as Past outsiders, and outsiders, and 20.1% as None. The informal succession routines In test of the hypotheses on focus on the effects of Past insider and Past outsider, and interaction effects with performance, firm age, CEO ownership structure, and age. Moderators of Persistence of Routines. Performance. Return on assets (ROA), adjusted industry average, obtained from COMPUSTAT, was measure, following past studies of (1990) finding that relative and unadjusted ROA was used as a measure ROA .94 CEO and the on was do not change materially ROA were averages were also estimated, but a one year . used as an economic performance compensation. The correlation between adjusted results of performance. Data Firm age The firm age . firm CEO CEO Directors, proxy statements, lOKs, "voluntary" departures CEO in year Standard and Poor's Directory of initial founding or incorporation. . CEO was it and and Who's Who 63 years old or under. in Industry would have been preferable companies. Control Variables 19 and and Finance, and the Wall theoretically to distinguish "dismissals", Wall Street Journal I Data on the Directory of Corporations. Officers, between and other published sources departure are either incomplete or unreliable for a large number of firms particularly for smaller five is Departures Following Puffer and Weintrop (1991), CEO's age was obtained from Standard and Poor's . Two and ROA ownership was obtained from Value Line Investment Survey and from departures as those were the Street Journal Although unadjusted lag provided the best results. calculated from the date given corporate proxy statements. Early classify early if lagged one year. Corporations. Officers, and Directors of the year of the firm's Ownership Data on for succession and selection and Gibbons and Murphy CEO affects its in for the sample, Boards as Normative Arenas I included control variables for firm size, as well as characteristics of the year of hire), directors). and The chairman and proportion of outside was based on the findings of recent managerialist selection of control variables and Lubatkin, 1993). in selection (Boeker was obtained from COMPUSTAT. Industry and Finance Tenure measured the number . 1960 are subject to left-truncation, included, beginning address the problem of incumbents in measure we as variables prior to 1960 all CEO-years were the duration in was first on phor remainder of the CEO's tenure was included the estimates and in Size in the sample, full all was excluded. To tenure were recorded for all the sample. This procedure reduces the bias in the case of the piecewise-exponential model used, leads to consistent estimates (Tuma and Hannan, 1984; Quo, 1993). The results of CEOs appointed prior the tenure spells began, but the CEO Who the sample for each company, and only the in in and Who's CEOs models estimated. when and incumbent has served as of years the not recorded. For firms incumbent other control reports, 1960, but the tenure prior to 1960 left-truncation, data 1960, or for the in all knovw All Directory of Corporations. Officers, supplemented by data from proxy statements, 10Ks, annual information on on and Goodstein, 1992; Cannella except employment data, were recorded at the were obtained from Standard and Poor's CEO. Tenure was used as to CEO All control variables, beginning of the year. Data on firm size Directors, and (tenure, age, of the board of directors (separate board interpretations of insider versus outsider variables CEO, this procedure are conditional having survived to 1960. was measured as expectation is the loganthm of the that larger firms takes the value of zero if CEO the equals the current age of the age, age has no effect on will is of employees have a greater degree is 60 years variable assumes to succession The effects of age on outsider have a CEO positive effect selection 20 Year - that it thousands). The CEO and Age succession or selection, but that expected (in of insider old or under, CEO. The Age60 CEO each year afterward. Age60 number selection.. Age60 60, otherwise, up where Age to the sixtieth year of has increasing effects on the rate of insider of hire for CEO measured the year the Boards as Normative Arenas CEO was and was intended hired (minus 1900), succession. A positive trend was expected, to capture historical trends in the rate of taking into account increased pressures CEO CEOs on during the 1960-1990 period studied, particularly for outsider succession. This variable assumes that that CEOs are affected by changing norms and expectations about were prevalent duhng the beginning remainder of of time trend, number which assumes that changing norms of directors. chairman of the board of directors Sample statistics. Table 1 affect measured the number Chairman is a dummy differs and much their tenure. This variable provides a Proportion of outside directors total of their tenure CEO succession that these rules are set for the better fit than an alternative measure new and incumbent CEOs of outside board members variable that takes the value of from the CEO, and 0, equally. divided by the 1 when the otherwise. presents the sample means, standard deviations, and the Pearson correlation coefficients for the variables used in the analysis. The unit of observation is the company-year. Insert Table 1 about here Modeling Procedure I tested the hypotheses by specifying continuous-time, event history analysis of the competing risks of insider versus outsider transition rates to CEO selection. This and outsider selection and that the and two events are the trajectories. CEO risk model estimates the two mutually exclusive events, insider succession and outsider succession. The competing hsk methodology allows insider competing A CEO result of highly routinized this contention, selection the year of turnover, which is is separate mechanisms that yield consistent with the underlying assumption of this paper processes with different underlying causes chi-square contrast of the competing succession supports history analysis of is for estimating the and is risk model with the pooled model available from the author. preferred to the more common method subject to sample selection bias and implicitly 21 The use of of of event sampling only assumes for Boards as Normative Arenas equilibrium using in the maximum CEO selection process (Tuma and Hannan, TDA package likelihood with the software 1984). The models are estimated (Rohwer, 1991). TDA allows estimation of models with time-varying covariates and takes right-censoring into account by using the information provided by the cumulative survival time of censored spells (Tuma and Hannan, 1984). Functional form. The use of event history analysis requires that specification of the functional forms for the transition rates estimated. The selection of functional form must also account left-truncation in the sample, as CEOs appointed prior to 1960 are part of the sample. To achieve consistent estimates with left-truncated data, (Guo, 199"^). The hazard risks of insider rates r(t) of for CEO and outsider succession I use a piecewise-exponential model succession are defined under the two competing and r(t)^ r(t)2 , respectively, as follows: Piecewise- exponential model: r(t), = expfa,,+.... + ap, + p,X, + r(t)2 = exp fa, +.... , + a^^ + P,Z, Note that the independent variables X and ..+ p^J. +...+ p^J. Z, respectively, are not restricted to piecewise exponential I competing for the be the same. tried several alternatives. The periods for both insider and outsider succession; years, and 17 years and above. There are three periods, but the fourth and fifth Alternative models estimated. including control variables, the all performance (ROA), ownership This last I risks of insider - In and outsider succession selecting the time periods a,p for the results presented include five time 2 years, 2 7-12 7 years, - statistically significant years, 12-17 differences between the first are not statistically significantly different form the third. first estimate a baseline model for comparison purposes main effects of the moderating variables of structure, and an interaction effect between firm age, ROA and age 64. covariate controls for the findings of past studies were performance had limited effect on succession for CEOs facing retirement. To test 22 Hypotheses 1 and 2, I then estimate a model Boards as Normative Arenas main that includes the effects of multicollinearity separate models in for the effects of interaction effects with the A full model CEOs performance (Hypothesis 5). In measures Formal ILMs, Prior of combined 63 years old the .10 level is and under, and compare the shows the baseline model formal and informal routines of The include separate insider. Prior outsider, is and Both the omitted be estimate the model for the subsample of full sample. CEO Selection. Table 2 presents the results of the for CEO CEO selection for and provides tests for Hypothesis comparison purposes. Model 2 presents the effects selection. The combined results of and informal CEOs, increase significant at the .001 level. Model statistically significant at of board decision-making as normative arenas, firm's formal * Table 2 about here 2, 1 -5. of with a chi- the .001 level. governed by the rules routines. findings strongly support Hypothesis form of ILMs I results to the square contrast of 39.7 with the baseline model, are They sustain the model and ' competing nsks of insider versus outsider in 4), ~ Formal and Informal Routines of embodied estimate I age (Hypothesis I the limit also estimated. Finally, to estimate whether the effects Insert 1 To selection. effects of those variable found to selection routines apply only to retirements, RESULTS Model 3), firm estimating these moderators, that includes the statistically significant at CEO CEO and outsider) succession experience. (No succession experience category). of of evaluating the effects of moderators of persistence, ownership structure (Hypothesis (insider and informal routines effects of formal 1 t.iat formal routines of insider the board's selection of insiders as CEO selection, in the CEOs. These effects are Hypotheses 2a and 2b are supported with past routines selection increasing subsequent insiders, statistically significant at the .05 level, of insider and past outsider routines increasing outsider selection, significant at the .01 level. Informal routines of 23 Boards as Normative Arenas both insider and outsider selection affect board decision on stronger in Note that if size and statistical significance for routines of CEO selection, with the effects outsider selection than for insiders. the firm has had experience with both insiders and outsiders as CEOs, this increases the rate of both subsequent insider and outsider succession. These results are weaker, however, than outsiders. The in the case of exclusive reliance on routines of either insiders or findings suggest that both cognitive and political effects of routines affect board decisions, as past experience with subsequent utilization when greater and political viability 1 that these effects are either insider or outsider selection dominates. about here 1 presents graphically the effects of the formal ILMs for routines on the competing risks of insider versus outsider are estimated from Model pattern of findings show 2, with all independent of each other. selection. past The CEO selection transition rates of CEO of formal selection The have large and informal routines are a separate analysis, not presented here but available from the between the formal and informal routines not found to be statistically significant). compahsons and informal routines on board decision. The effects (In author, the interaction effects CEO CEOs and the control variables estimated at sample means. that both formal statistically significant effects the pairwise selection selection routines increases their and appropriateness, but Insert Figure Figure CEO CEO The most of insider versus CEO of CEO selection relevant findings are the differences selection for formal and informal selection routines. First note that in each of the eight the case of no routines were between combinations of (i.e., founders without internal ILMs) the transition rates for insider and outsider selection are approximately equal (.021 vs. 018, for insiders and outsiders, respectively). But with an ILM but no succession experience, the rate of insider selection .028) Past insider selection with an ILM (.109 vs is is almost double that of outsiders (.052 vs. the condition most favorable to insider selection 040) Past outsider selection without an ILM 24 is most favorable to outsiders (.027 vs. Boards as Normative Arenas .080). In the for CEOs case of both insider and outsider experience, the presence or absence of an alter the are more likely dominance of subsequent insiders or outsiders: without the ILM, outsiders (.040 vs. .062), with the rate of Insiders Insert Figures 2 Effects of Performance is higher (.099 vs. .094). and 3 about here on the Persistence of Routines. Model 3 analyzes CEO performance on persistence of the formal and informal routines of chi-square contrast between Models 3 and 2 significant at the .05 level. The is Hypothesis 3b, on failure-induced change outcomes (Milliken main effects of and likely to persist ROA and its is CEO negative and existing routines. The effect of show that formal one must account ROA (-.088, which and informal is the statistically significant at the .01 level for for succession, firms facing findings no prior economic adversity full CEO for both the selection effect in the case of no outsider selection, and experience with or formal will more likely choose outsiders rather than insiders, consistent with the existence of a generalized norm under poor performance. Formal ILM are invanant effects, with small statistically insignificant interaction effects with to performance effects of little evidence that performance triggers a failure-induced change routines CEO CEO The succession and selection routines, while not unequivocal, and are a more consistent with a view selection decisions. for outsider both insider and outsider selection. The performance on informal for under both positive and negative performance positive but not significant for insider selection. With mechanisms under economic and provide no support selection interaction effects with the formal main The 19.21, with 8 degrees of freedom, statistically Lant, 1991). In interpreting these effects routines. First note that the routines) in the effects of selection. results are consistent with Hypothesis 3a, that adversity boards rely on dominant routines for and informal routines are ILIVI that boards rely interaction effects of past insider 25 in show the application of dominant on dominant responses and ROA, negative for their for insider Boards as Normative Arenas and positive for outsiders, although not significant, are inconsistent with adaptive The insider selection routines. and significant for insiders, to the main economic ROA is for past insider shows and that when likely to persist and past outsider selection routines that ROA interaction effects are best is economic adversity increases both when added under understood graphically Figures 2 and insider 3, and outsider CEO 30 percentage points below the industry average, boards are with insider selection. Figure 3 performance of outsider selection, poor in in negative, but not significant at the .10 level for outsiders, yet The combined main and adversity. respectively. Figure 2 more and positive and effect yields a negative effect, implying persistence with outsider routines and are shown selection interaction effects of past outsider change is more shows likely to that for firms with dominant routines increase persistence with outsider selection, consistent with Hypothesis 3a. Insert Figure 4 Effects of Firm Age on Persistence the persistence of persistence of CEO CEO about here of Routines. Model 4 selection routines. The shows the analysis of selection routines for the case of past insiders (Hypothesis 4), but freedom, which statistically significant is is significant at the .05 level in political to insider becomes is The mediating increasingly 10.0, effect of firm embedded in with 8 is age on the persistence is of its consistent with the The dominance of insider the firm's political coalition and institutionalized of the organization (Selznick, 1957). become no same term becomes Figure 4, indicates that as the firm grows older and mission less likely to is only interaction term that (Note that the effects of insider selection routines. within the social structure outsider routines in 6). level. The succession increases This increase over time and motivational selection Model shown insider selection routines, commitment not statistically significant. past insider, at the .10 age on results provide limited support for increasing support for the other cases The chi-square contrast between Models 4 and 2 degrees of firm The dominance of institutionalized overtime, lacking internal constituents 26 Boards as Normative Arenas to support its interaction effects of to statistically significant, the direction of the that the effects of formal routines are larger for because they are more result both true of formal routines of selection. While the age and formal ILM are not some evidence effects provide may The same may be perpetuation. salient when there is newer firms. This no realized succession experience guide board decision-making and because for rules to become institutionalized over time not sufficient that they be part of the formal procedures, but it is it is also necessary that they be consistently practiced. Insert Figure 5 about here Effects of Board Ownership. Model 5 presents the results of insider ownership on the adoption of routines of CEO selection, The chi-square with 8 degrees of freedom, significant at the .05 level. contrast between The Models 5 and 2 is results support Hypothesis 5a, 20.0, on increased reliance of inside selection routines for insider ownership, and no support for hypothesis 5b. The interaction effects of insider ownership and insider selection routines positive, albeit not statistically significant, for insider selection significant at the .10 level for outsider selection (This result the .01 level in Model 6). and negative and becomes is statistically statistically significant at Also note that the interaction of combined insider and outsider selection experience with insider ownership has a positive effect on insider selection, significant at The the .01 level. results do not support Jensen (1993) contention that cultural persistence in corporate governance results from the lack of ownership incentives by board executives. board On the contrary, as members in Figure 5, in CEO comes the rate of outsider selection, while the rate of insider selection invariant to insider ownership. Thus insider top increased ownership by managers and increases the proportion of insiders selected as CEOs. Note that this about through a decrease and outsider shown members and is ownership decreases the combined rate of insider selection, thus increasing the relative reliance 27 on routines of insider Boards as Normative Arenas agency theory. No selection, a set of findings not consistent with were found on reliance on either formal Combined Model. Model 6 combines the chi-square contrast with Model 2 the .01 level. When is ILMs or routines of outsider 40.4 with 10 degrees of freedom, even selection, if was found is strengthened. This omitting interaction terms that effect of past insider effect of insiders and persistence on routines corporation. The main significant, supporting due were not The 3-5. statistically significant at significant I include its effects Models except that the 2-5, statistical to the reduction in multicollinearity that results Note that as statistically significant. in Model 4, from the main small, negative, but not significant, while as stated earlier, the interaction is age and past is be Models both terms were not significant. Note that the results are substantially equivalent to those found in significance to ownership selection. statistically significant effects of a particular interaction term on both insider and outsider effects of insider is now significant at the .05 level. This suggests that the reliance of insider selection are strongly conditioned effects of formal Hypothesis 1 on the age of the ILMs and outsider selection routines are positive and and 2b, respectively. Insert Table 3 about here Effects of Early full CEO sample, from Table Departures. Table 3 presents a compahson of Models 2 and 6 3, with the analogous Models 2a and 6a, for the CEO years old and under. The results support Hypothesis 6o that early reliance on informal routines of outsider succession insider succession. outsider CEO Note that the coefficient selection, and larger in the 2a, but large, positive, rate and significant ^t the is positive for both insider is small, negative, The in is and not 28 full of and significant in also positive, size of these coefficients are also larger than for the 63 either case. For past 01 level for subsequent outsiders. on combined selection experience on outsider succession the .05 level. CEOs departures increases although not significant outsider selection, the transition rate to insiders of and decreases reliance on routines of past insiders latter, subsample for the Model The transition and significant at sample in Model 2. Boards as Normative Arenas This suggests that the case of early in CEO departures, whether by dismissal or voluntary, routines of past outsider selection have a large and significant effect on board decisions to Model 2a select outsiders. Also note from in the of firm full that formal ILMs increase insider sample. Model 6a provides results similar to those of Model age and past 6. CEO The selection, as interaction effects insider are similar as before, albeit significant only at the .10 level. Control variables. The effects of the control variables are unremarkable with one exception, the effects of proportion of outside directors. Tenure Both insider and outsider succession were . found to increase with tenure, although the effect the case of CEOs is nonmonotonic for outsider selection or in 63 years and under. Performance had a negative and effect on both insider and outsider succession. Note however, that without controlling succession experience, the size of the effects than 63. The effects of performance on succession experience, as well as by significant for insider that the effects of Lubatkin, 1993). CEO CEO and negative but not of hire was positive similar for both, when CEO's age the age. Age64*ROA was positive and successors. Chairman magnitude. was It was was is less statistically significant for outsiders. This confirms earlier findings differs for and CEOs facing retirement (Cannella and significant for both insider and outsider selection, although larger for the latter, suggesting both a general increase and increasing reliance over more recent for past selection are therefore strongly mediated by past performance on succession Year is significant effect CEO in CEO succession cohorts on the selection of outsiders as positive for both insider and outsider selection and statistically significant for insider selection in all of similar models, but the significance not robust across models for outsider selection. This suggests, consistent with the findings of Cannella succession, and Lubatkin (1993), it has limited effect size increased insider selection that while having a separate Chairman increases on the selection of insiders versus outsiders. Size Large and decreased outsider selection. Firm age were mediated by past succession expenence with no consistently Proportion of insider ownership CEO No age The . 29 effects of firm significant statistically significant effects of insider firm mdin effect. ownership were Boards as Normative Arenas found. Boeker and Goodstein (1992) also failed to find statistically significant effects, but they which did find effect for the concentration of insider ownership, Proportion outside ownership . The proportion of outside owns The main were not findings effects of proportion of outside directors in the two studies may be sampled both phvately-held and 1969-1989. Both for representation in their and other forms interpreted th'^ publicly held of statistically significant, and dependencies for likely to (Pfeffer is more the case across the population studied here of view of board as normative arenas contrary to boards Silicon Valley represent ties to venture capitalists of executive succession activists board members, the be applicable. This is may have limited effect on CEO and political less likely to be publicly held industrial firms all from and Salancik, 1978). Their findings were likely to may be more in smaller publicly held firms, outsider and those with more boards as governing councils political structure of bring an possible explanation for the disparate and are more consistent with a managerialist model where the the likely to the stock, to lead the corporation. semiconductor firms sample may more be more selection. In both privately-held firms model One here. the different populations sample. Boeker and Goodstein privitely held firms of resource measured ownership had a positive main effect outsider, possibly from the firm or organization that the findings of Boeker and Goodstein (1992). not ownership holdings are more selection. Firms with large outside on outsider is from 1960-1990, selection, and the applicable. DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS The general pattern of results provides strong empirical support for directors' reliance on formal and informal routines of CEO selection and for the view of corporate boards as normative arenas. Both the adoption of internal labor markets for new CEOs and the past reliance on informal routines of insider and outsider selection had large, statistically significant effects on the competing risks of insider versus outsider easily derived from a model CEO succession The general findings cannot be of adaptive behavior by 30 board members which follow a logic of Boards as Normative Arenas consequences decision making, nor from existing theories of boards as governing in their councils, which mobilize resources support of contending interests. The results are more in consistent with the theory that boards are constituted as normative arenas, which follow a logic of appropriateness Routines of and rule-following, CEO Selection. At one as embodied in paper applies and extends both old ideas from level, this classic theories about organizational routines (March and more recent quantitative empirical research on Amburgey and and CEO Miner, 1992) to a selection. new area The paper extends of persistence of routines is precedents, norms, and routines. and Simon, 1958; Cyert and March, 1963) their effects (Kelly and Amburgey, 1991; of application, the study of corporate this line of research by explicitly testing governance how the effects mediated by economic performance and the structure of ownership, and by distinguishing between formal and informal routines. The results do not support the early March-Simon-Cyert formulation of failure-induced change routines, but are more consistent with the view that responses to in organizational economic adversity rely on dominant organizational routines (Staw, Sandelands, and Button, 1981; Ocasio, 1995). Organizations change in response dominant patterns and rules to economic of behavior. that firms will persist with their strategies economic performance agency theory is These and good or whether interpretations, the reliance decreases, with inside ownership by board The effects of organizational our understanding of how ways that are consistent with results support Milliken is poor. The results also and Lant's (1991) view whether recent show that, contrary to on organizational routines increases, rather than members and of formal top executives. and informal routines contributes organizational inertia increases with firm age. Formalization an activity of insider may be versus outsider CEO 31 If a routine is The selection suggests that a necessary condition to guarantee as firms grow older (Selznick, 1957). to was sufficient to explain the persistence of routines with age. dominant routines internal political support for institutionalization it in routines, independently of age on persistence found to be neither necessary nor different effects for adversity, but at its odds with the interests Boards as Normative Arenas of internal groups, as in the case of routines of outsider selections, its persistence increase with age. This suggests that the institutionalization of action requires is unlikely to political support historical precedent. as well as The formal routines of insider CEO selection were found to strongly increase insider succession, and these effects were relatively invariant to the level of economic performance, firm age, ownership structure, or whether succession occured under retirement or early departures. The formal commitments internal labor to insider succession, commitments, independent markets for CEOs imply both and boards were much more political likely circumstances facing the firm or the of the CEO and normative than not to honor these CEO succession ^ process. .» Boards as Normative Arenas. At another level, this paper develops a new theoretical perspective on corporate governance, that of boards of directors as normative arenas. The theory integrates the work of March and Olsen (1989) on the institutionalization of action and the logic of approphateness of discipline variants of in in political institutions social structures. one form reinterpret existing theories of corporate in U.S. industrial terms is interest. of corporate activities to protect This normative accounting for board decision making The theory is boards as normative arenas implies that at odds with board decisions one or strongly supported by also explains previous descnptions of board behavior by participants and observers, which were of argue that normative arenas. Board decision process constitute a form of peer review the empirical results of this paper. The view I better understood as following another form of and evaluation, rather than an instrumental monitoring another governance as of discipline identified by White, that of governing council. corporate governance discipline, that of I with that of White (1992) on alternative forms norms of existing theohes. reflect socially constructed rules of behavior, which cannot be reduced to either the interests of the participants nor to adaptively, rational behavior driven by a calculus of consequences. As described above, 32 Boards as Normative Arenas CEO the effects of performance and insider ownership on persistence of suggest that agency interpretations and bounded norms selection by themselves, rationality cannot, at least explain the reliance on and persistence of routines of corporate governance. While there some evidence is that routines of insider selection are sustained by managerial interests, the general pattern of results also suggests that managerial interests alone cannot explain the routines of corporate governance. Note that there evidence both is for the existence of a generalized norm of outsider succession under adversity, and for increased reliance on routines of outsider succession for CEOs departing prior to retirement age. Neither effect with a purely political explanation of CEO additional analysis, not reported here, selection routines. Furthermore, I is consistent also conducted of the mediating effects of the political structure of the board as measured by a separate chairman, the proportion of outside directors, and board on routine persistence. I found that none of these measures of managerial control over the board of directors had a noticeable nor a formal or informal CEO size, statistically significant effect on the utilization of either selection routines. This strongly suggests that the operation of corporate governance routines cannot be reduced to an explanation based on the view of boards as "pawns" of management (Lorsch, 1989). The theory of boards as normative arenas highlights the commitments and boards of directors with the mission, purpose, and social (Selznick, 1957). Legal responsibilities of reflected in norms and does not imply apolitical and same identification of the corporation and normative commitments by board members are board members abiding by the routine. At the identification of institutional embodiment of purpose in time, this routine-bound character of board decision that routines are always consistently applied nor that the process conflict free. The effects of routines the view that routines matter, and matter greatly their application is inside ownership, far the firm's in in is making purely the transition rate models strongly support board decisions, but they also show that from inevitable The different moderating effects of age, performance, and early CEO departures for insider and outsider selection routines, imply 33 Boards as Normative Arenas that norms and politics, game corporate in both as vehicles for and constraints on managerial power. The reliance on norms and routines of in precedents serve to establish the rules of the historical CEO selection and corporate governance also suggests that political maneuverings organizations are unlikely to be directly expressed nor mobilized within the board of directors. This is consistent with a view of managerial power and power struggles rather than fixed political coalitions managerial entrenchment, and the political dynamics driven by emergent and where overt institutionalization of executive effective (Ocasio, 1994). Political struggles efforts at social influence, power are not and maneuverings occur not as likely to be part of the formal board process, but are driven by inside participants and hidden behind the bureaucratic ethos and rhetoric that The routinization of the predomina*3s CEO in U.S. corporations '^Jackall, ^ 1988). selection process by boards as normative arenas is closely tied to the routinization of charisma and depersonalization of executive power. This process embodies and legitimizes the authority and control by of the corporation in specific individuals (Weber bureaucracy, boards as normative arenas procedures to define appropriate its rules and procedures rather than 1922], 1978). But unlike the pure form of rely on historical power in Weberian precedents as well as formal behavior and to guide their decisions. Normative arenas and governing councils can be considered as ideal types, rather than as exclusive descriptions of understood as different all forms of board behavior. The two forms of discipline can be identities that external contingencies (White, 1992). are occasions for a number boards of directors take when facing different internal or March and Olsen (1976) argued of different things including; (1) fulfilling executing standard operating procedures; (2) defining truth and that choice processes role-commitments and virtue; (3) exercising relationships of trust, antagonisms, power, or status, and, (4) expressing self-interests group interests. The governing councils. first In two conditions are characteristic of normative arenas, the board decision making, like in 34 last and two other decision processes, different of Boards as Normative Arenas orientations may prevail depending on the problems and solutions being considered, and on the structure of participation (Cohen, March, and Olsen, 1972; March and Olsen, 1976). Further theoretical development and empirical research are required to explain under what conditions is the model of boards as normative arenas applicable, and under what conditions do governing councils, or other forms of discipline, if any, apply (White, 1992). White's statement that "identities are triggered by contingencies" (1992: 5) that may and form is evocative of the emergent process lead certain types of boards, under certain conditions to adopt one or another identity of discipline. Unfortunately, no testable propositions can be readily derived from White's theoretical framework on what these contingencies likely to have. In Valley, I suggested that boards of many governing councils than have privately held or is is true in governing councils CEO on young semiconductor firms may be more in Silicon operate as likely to necessary on whether and how the separation of ownership and control may to that of boards of directors from their traditional role as normative arenas. The discrepant findings could also suggest that the view of boards as governing councils Inertia effects they are general for U.S. industrial corporations. This suggests that led to a transformation of the functions of industries, or in what effects of proportion of outside directors with substantial reliance on venture capital, further research or presenting the difference between the findings of this study and those of Boeker and Goodstein (1992) on the selection, may be may be more applicable for new and emerging cases where resource dependencies on external interests are and the "Failure" of Corporate Governance. I began this high. paper by invoking Jensen's (1993) presidential address to the American Finance Association, and his lament regarding the inertia in corporate governance and the failure of corporate boards to foster adaptation industrial corporations. The view rationale for the observed inertia empirical evidence on needs to CEO of boards as normative in be reevaluated according to different criteria. 35 U.S. arenas provides a coherent theoretical corporate governance, and one that selection. But this view also in is supported by suggests that board effectiveness Agency theorists, led by Jensen, have Boards as Normative Arenas evaluated U.S. corporate boards as mechanisms of instrumental control and have found them to be directors is that the predominant, albeit latent, function of that of normative control, rather than instrumental control: to and accountability their paper suggests deficient. This in guarantee and procedures of the firm's rules and that values accountability reliability, Freeman, 1984). The peer review function in and normative commitments ways that the reliability terms of may prove boards of Another larger question remains, however, changed in is, in in with the bureaucratic model of organization, routinization in corporate strategies directors have failed or not, and whether they need of course, pretend to institutions answer and functions to the bureaucratic this to evaluating board effectiveness. that results variability of less desirable? There and with the benefits is inertia in corporate environmental change increasing dissatisfaction of standardization this and model. Whether boards of our evaluation of whether bureaucracies have in this paper. governance in I will 36 will not, suggest, however, that the current boards as normative arenas bureaucracies and to their maintenance and sustainability. I U.S. industnal corporations are closely tied of organization, as the role of to the legitimate authority of corporate from the Has the world be supplanted by other organizational forms. question of corporate model be adaptive (Hannan and and routines associated with failed or not, is closely tied to relatively stable, the providing stability and enforcement of governance become less attractive? Are the frequency and is world under such circumstances, highly desirable. and accountability increasing such that organizational stability to their construction their appropriateness. In a and when environments are persistence of routines of corporate governance fiduciary duties reliability the rules of corporate behavior. Board responsibilities are defined, not by independent evaluation of the consequences of corporate actions, but by and reproduction boards of is critical Boards as Normative Arenas REFERENCES Aldrich, 1986 Howard, E., and Ellen Auster "Even dwarfs started Barry Staw and L.L. small: Liabilities of Cummings age and size and (eds), Research in their strategic implications." In Organizational Behavior, 8: 156-198. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. Amburgey, Terry 1992 activity.: S. Strategic and Gardiner Berle, Adolf, Jr., 1967 and Anne momentum: The "Strategic merger L., Miner effects of repetitive, positional Management C. and contextual momentum on Journal, 13: 335-348. Means The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: Harcourt, Brace, an'^ World. Boeker, Warren 1992 "Power and managerial dismissal: Scapegoating at the top." Administrative Science Quarterly, 37:400-421. Boeker, Warren, and Jerry Goodstein 1992 "Performance and successor choice: The moderating effects of governance and Academy ownership." of Management Journal. 36: 172-186. Bowen, William G. 1994 Inside the Boardroom: Governance by Directors and Trustees. Ne York: John Wiley & Sons. Cannella, Albert A., and Michael Lubatkin 1993 "Succession as a sociopolitical process: Internal impediments Academy Carroll, 1984 Glenn of Management to outsider selection." Journal. 37: R. 'Dynamics of publisher succession in newspaper organizations." Administrative Science Quarterly, 29: 93-113. 37 Boards as Normative Arenas Clark, Robert C. 1991 "Agency costs versus fiduciary duties," In Pratt, eds. Principals and Agents: The Structure John W. and Richard J. of Business: 55-79. Boston: Zeckhauser, Harvard Business School Press. Cohen, Michael 1972 D., James G. March, and Johan P. Olsen "A garbage can model of organizational choice." Administrative Science Quarterly, 17: 1-25. and James G. March Cyert, Richard M., 1963 A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Davis, GerTid 1991 F. .v*^ Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. 5^ - "Agents without pnnciples? The spread of the poison pill through the intercorporate network." Administrative Science Quarterly, 36: 583-613. DiMaggio, Paul 1983 The iron D., and Walter W. Powell cage revisited: Institutional organizational fields," Doeringer, Peter 1971 Internal Fama, Eugene 1983 B., Amencan and Michael J. isomorphism and collective rationality in Sociological Review. 48: 147-160. Piore Labor Markets and Manpower Analysis. Lexington, MA: Heath Lexington Books. L., and Michael C. Jensen "Separation of ownership and control " Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 301-325. Garfinkel, Harold 1967 Studies in ethnomethodology. Englewood Gibbons, Robert, and Kevin 1990 '"Relative J. Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall Murphy performance evaluation for Chief Executive Officers." Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 45: 30S-51S 38 Boards as Normative Arenas Gouldner, Alvin W. 1954 Patterns of Industrial Bureaucracy. New York: Free Press. Guo, Guang 1993 "Event-history analysis for left-truncated data." Methodology 1993: 217-243. Cambridge, MA: Hannan, Michael 1984 In Peter V. Marsden (ed.), Sociological Basil Blackwell. and John Freeman T., "Structural inertia and organizational change." Amehcan Sociological Review, 49: 149-164. 1989 Organizational Ecology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Helmich, Donald 1972 and Warren L., B. Brown "Successor type and organizational change Science Quarterly, 17: in the corporate enterprise." Administrative 371-381. Hirsch, Paul 1982 "Network data versus personal accounts: The normative culture of interlocking directorates." Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, unpublished manuscript. Jensen, Michael C. 1993 " The modern industhal revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems." Journal of Finance, 48: 831-880. Jackall, Robert 1988 Moral Mazes: The World of Corporate Managers. New York: Oxford Univ?,rsity Press. Jensen, Michael C, and William H. Meckling 1976 "Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure." Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305-360. 39 Boards as Normative Arenas Kelly, 1991 Dawn, and Terry L. Amburgey momentum; A dynamic model "Organizational inertia and of Management of strategic change." Academy Journal, 34: 591-612. Lorsch, Jay W. 1989 Pawns Mace, Myron 1971 or Potentates. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. L. Myth and Directors: Reality. Boston: Harvard Graduate School of Business Administration. March, James G. 1994 A Primer on Decision Making: March, James G., and Johan 1976 Ambiguity and Choice 1989 Rediscovering March, James 1958 G., in and Herbert New Organizations. Decisions Happen. New York: Free Press. ^" Olsen Organizations. Bergen, Norway: Universitesforlaget. Institutions: The Organizational Basis A. of Politics. New York: Free Press. Simon York: Wiley. Meyer, John W., and Brian 1977 P. How Rowan "Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony." American Journal of Sociology, 83: 340-363. Millii^en, 1991 Frances "'The J. and Theresa K. Lant impact of an organization's recent performance history on strategic persistence and change." Strategic in Paul Shrivastava, Management, 7 Anne Huff, and Jane Dutton (eds.). Advances 129-156. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. Mizruchi, Mark 1982 The American Corporate Network, 2904-2974 Beverly 40 Hills, CA; Sage. in Boards as Normative Arenas Ocasio, William 1994 dynamics and the "Political circulation of power: CEO Succession in U.S. Industrial Corporations, 1960-1990." Adnninistrative Science Quarterly, 39: 285-312. 1995 A "The enactment of economic adversity: change and threat-hgidity." In L.L. Organizational Behavior, 17: (In reconciliation of theories of failure-induced Cummings and Barry M. Staw (eds.), Research in Press). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. Palmer, Donald A. 1983 "Broken ties: Interlocking directorates and intercorporate coordination." Administrative Science Quarterly, 28: 40-55. Pfeffer, Jeffrey, 1978 The and Gerald External Control of Organizations. Puffer, Sheila M., 1991 R. Salancik and Joseph B. New York: Harper and Row. Weintrop "Corporate performance and CEO turnover: The role of performance expectations." Administrative Science Quarterly, 36: 1-19. Rohwer, Gotz 1991 Analysis of transition data: European University A practical introduction with TDA. Unpublished manuscript, Institute. Selznick, Philip 1957 Leadership in Administration. Evanston, IL: Row, Peterson. Staw, Barry M., Lloyd E. Sandelands, and Jane E. Dutton 1981 "Threat-rigidity effects in organizational behavior: A multilevel analysis." Administrative Science Quarterly, 26: 501-52''. Tosi, 1989 Henry L., and Luis Gomez-Mejia "The decoupling of CEO pay and performance: An agency theory perspective." Administrative Science Quarterly, 34: 169-189 41 Boards as Normative Arenas Tuma, Nancy 1984 and Michael B., Hannan Social Dynamics: Models and Methods. Orlando: FL: Tushman, Michael 1985 T. L., and Elaine Romanelli "Organizational evolution: In L.L. Academic Press. Cummings and A metamorphosis model of convergence and reohentation." Barry M, Staw (eds), Research in Organizational Behavior. 7: 171-222. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. Useem, Michael 1984 The Inner Circle. New York: Oxford University Press. Vancil, Richard M. 1987 Passing the Baton: Managing the Process of CEO Succession. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Wade, James, Charles 1990 A. O'Reilly, "Golden parachutes: and CEOs and Ike Chandratat the exercise of social influence." Administrative Science Quarterly, 35: 587-603. Walsh, James 1990 "On the P., and James K. Seward efficiency of internal Management and external corporate control mechanisms." Academy of Review., 15: 421-458. Weber, Max 1978 Economy and Society Guenther Roth and Claus Wittich (eds.). Berkeley: University of California Press. White, Harrison 0. 1992 Identity and Control: A Structural Theory of Social Action. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. 42 Boards as Normative Arenas Zajac, Edward 1990 "CEO J. selection, compensation, empirical analysis." Strategic and firm performance: Management A theoretical interpretation and Journal, 11: 217-230. Zucker, Lynn G. 1977 "The role of institutionalization in cultural persistence." 42: 726-743. 43 American Sociological Review, in ,-„u. ^r-^(0^tD^tD^ C o c o Q. -a -„iD04o2^^'-^(DOO^OJCMt-^V,01 ooo^o^o^oootoco^cn^ogo ^ o n o o^ o »- TOO to f^ _ T- _ r- -^ CM -^ o h- SinQU-)r--^h-^cD'-'ooooo*^OT^odoiricMQmoooo 00 in O 00 Table 3 Likelihood Estimates of the Competing Risks of Insider vs. Outsider CEO Selection, Piec ewise Exponential Models Comparison of Full S a mple with Early CEO Departures* Model 6a Model 6 Model 2a Model 2 Maximum Variables to 2 years Insider -7.708 -6.168"" (0.756) 7 to -5.782"" 2 years 1 (.730) -5.590"" 12 to 17 years (.728) 1 -5.484*"* 7 years or over (.608) ROA (.011) .086**" Age60 * ROA .079" Age Prop Outside Directors Inside (.008) (.012) (.009) .048 .150* .130 In & O (.086) (.149) .009 -4.960" (.028) In & (.035) (031) -.016 -.017 .141" -.040 (.096) (.084) .057**** (.122) (.017) .602** (.028) .040" (.020) .539" .621* .014 (.014) -.262" .029 .657 (.228) (.271) (.425) (.232) (.362) (.271) (.432) -0.642 -.993 -0.293 -.616 -0.745 -1.425 -0.505 -.980 (.736) (1.135) (.536) (.901) (.740) (1.115) -.012 .017 -.003 .035" (.010) (Oil) (.014) -.004 (.014) (.012) .863*** (Oil) (.904) .009 -.003 .029*" (.009) .907**" .424 (.010) (.006) (.008) (.009) .003 .033*" -.006 (Oil) (012) .906*" (.243) .749** (.322) (.304) (.534) .252 1.480*** (.403) (.535) .651* 1.226" (.382) (.618) .375 .034**** .003 (.009) (.009) .837**" .307 269 (.381) (.244) (.323) (.296) 530 1.355 -.043 1.077 -.280 2.366" (.471) (.860) (.454) (.781) 1.955**** (.620) (1.010) (.584) (.605) 2.388*" .393 (.547) (861) 1.885" (.513) .536 2.500*" .315 (.947) (.417) (.788) .068**** (.756) (.021) .101**** (.047) (.031) (.027) .018 .027* .022 (.016) (.014) (.020) -.003 (.588) (.009) (Oil) .039** In .& (.015) .05; in *** -473.148 -736.628 38 85 48 159 57 p<.0001. 38 parenthesis. 46 .461 (.914) 3.397*" (1.195) .076"" .053 (.023) .100*" .024 -.067*" .007 Events 2.746"* .335 .021" 38 159 p< .01; .156 (.295) .016 -756.809 .037**" (.389) Out Inside ownership 10; -.019 (.013) (.010) .450 -.027* (Oil) -.216" .028*" Out. Standard errors (.017) (.357) Likelihood Ratio ' (1.768) -.089**** (.030) .027 **p< -.035" (1.971) -7.456**** (.015) .092*** Inside ownership of (1.147) -.085*"* (.024) Combined -6.985**" -6.690 -7.416**" .153 Past Insiders * Firm age Past Insiders -p< (1.239) (1.976) -6.735"" (.152) ROA Df Number (1.367) (.044) Combined * (1.244) (2.065) -7.483**** (.087) *ROA * (1.398) -6.571* -6.862"** .146* Past Outsiders * (1.302) -7.994"** (.015) .037 .629" (1.459) -6.839* (2.206) -7.575"" .042 (.062) (.017) (1.368) (1.192) -10.204* (.015) (.016) .097**** (.008) (.020) (1.626) -7.352* -.035" Out sider Insider -8.350' -9.600* -4.818" (.009) -.199* (010) .579 -5.124" -.015* -.006 (.006) -5.527" -.023**' (.106) (.005) Combined (.660) (1.766) -7.537" (.081) .053*** Outside Ownershi -.001 Past Outsiders (.766) (1.091) -.021* -7.144" (083) .040" Ownership -.003 Past Insiders (1.932) -7.379* (1.165) -7.297" (.059) .028*** (.528) Formal ILM (.773) (1.184) ,58* .563" Chairman (1.951) -7.172* (1.323) -6.289**** .112* of Hire (0.798) (1.204) (007) (.004) Year (2.038) -7.142* (1.356) -6.064**** -.014" .000 Size (.862) (1.257) Outsider Insider -6.450" (2.157) -7.598* (.024) (.034) Firm -7.939" (1.409) -6.246**** (.029) -.040* (.015) Age64 (1.327) -6.683**" -.024*" -.023" Outsider -9.260* Insider -8.663" (1.544) (.823) 2 to 7 years Outsider -8.439' (.035) -.108*" .010 (.024) (.016) (.035) -.018 .035* -.026 (.825) (.020) (.027) -454.120 57 48 85 38 in o o CO O LU O o "D CO CO i_ g jo CO > g (D lO o O CO c g o CO CO ^° CO Q. CO E o O E a: (D ZJ Ll o — DC o o (D E i_ o LL ^ CD C o CO CO o LU O 3 CD g O 'co *a) o6 g -c CO CO Q. g 'co c "5 O g CO CO CD _c g D CO O Q_ to E o "co CO CO Q_ _c "co CO "cc CO C O CO CL 47 C O o m c g (/) (/) < 0) <] o o u I Q CO CO O LU O g o "(/) o ^ C/) C/) 0) o o g C/) (/) 0) o o 13 o O g LJJ L_ '(/) c o Mil (/) llflRARieS o 00 g CO 0) (/) c $ 0) o o O g CO o LU O g o CD 0) •U C ~ i_ CD CO CO c >^ X X X X X X X '^ CO o g X X o J^ X X X g c O CD CO (/) CD O o a. CO o CM o LU O g i_ CD CO — C/) o o l^ . . CO 03 Lo q: CD ^— =3 .2) LL o r— i3 C O 2 176 :^iO 51 Date Due OEC 3 ! 1119 ^1i4l!9S Lib-26-67