ufcwer HD28 .M414 ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT EQUILIBRIUM INTEREST RATE And LIQUIDITY PREMIUM LENDER PROPORTIONAL TRANSACTIONS COSTS Dimitri Vayanos and Jean-Luc Vila WP #3508-92 Revised April 1993 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 EQUILIBRIUM INTEREST RATE And LIQUIDITY PREMIUM LENDER PROPORTIONAL TRANSACTIONS COSTS Dimitri Vayanos and Jean-Luc Vila WP Revised April 1993 #3508-92 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Revised: December 1992 This version: April 1993 '^'^^RIES I f M.I.T. AUG LIBRARIES 3 1 1993 RECEIVED Equilibrium Interest Rate and Liquidity Premium Under Proportional Transactions Costs Dimitri Vayanos and Jean-Luc Vila* Massachusetts Institute of Technology First version: April 1992 Tills version: April •We would like to thank participants at the participants at seminars at Conference on Asset Pricing in Philadelphia: MIT, New York University and Wharton; Drew Fudenberg. Mark John Heaton and Jean Tirole financial support NBER 1993 for helpful comments and suggestions. We also wish to Gertier. acknowledge from the International Financial Services Research Center at the Sloan School of Management. Errors are ours. Abstract In this paper we analyze the impact of transactions costs on the rates of return on liquid and illiquid assets. We consider an infinite horizon with finitely lived agents along the lines of Blanchard (1985). In agents face a constant probability of death, and the population by an inflow of new arrivals. is tliis economy economy kept constant Agents st&it with no financiad wealth and receive a decreasing stream of lal)or income over their lifetimes. In addition they can invest in long-term assets two such are is which pay a constant stream of dividends. assets, the liquid asset and the The illiquid asset. There liquid asset traded without costs, while trading the illiquid asset entails proportional costs. Neither asset can be sold short. Agents buy and sell assets for lifecycle motives. In fact, they accumulate the higher yielding illiquid asset for long-terni investment purposes and the liquid asset We find that when for short-term investment needs. transactions costs increase, the rate of return on the liquid asset decreases, while the rate of return or decrease. The We on the illiquid asset also find, quite naturzilly, that the liquidity effects of treinsactions costs may increase premium on the rate of return on the liquid increases. asset on the liquidity premium, are stronger the higher the fraction of the asset in the returns We economy. and on the Finally, transactions costs liquidity have first and illiquid order effects on asset premium. evaluate these effects for reasonable parameter values. ^ Introduction 1 Although most of asset pricing theory assumes frictionless markets, transactions costs are ubiquitous in financial markets. Transactions costs can be rect transactions costs such as brokerage commissions, taxes, (ii) bid-ask spread, exchange market impact costs and (iii) decomposed (iv) fees into and transactions delay and search costs. Aiyagari and Gertler (1991), report that typical (retail) brokerage costs for 2% stocks average amount of the dollar (i) di- common of the trade while the bid-ask spread for actively traded stocks averages around .5%. Moreover, transactions costs vary across assets and over time. Money market accounts are clearly more liquid than slocks. In addition, deregulation as well as changes in information technology have reduced (but not eliminated) transactions costs. Empirical work on transactions costs documents not only their magnitude but their important effect on rates of return. Amihud and Mendelson (198'6) show that the risk-adjusted average return on stocks is Even more by comparing two assets with exactly the direct evidence can be found same cash flows but different liquidity: be publicly traded for 2 years sell at a (i) 35% positively related to their bid-ask spread. restricted (''letter") stocks which cannot discount below regular stocks^ and (ii) the average yield differential between Treasury Notes close to maturity and more liquid Treasury Bills is about .43%.^ The evidence above shows returns " that liquidity and should be incorporated into impact of transactions costs on issues as well. capital gains asset pricing theory. assets' returns will both reduce liquidity and therefore In this paper 'See an important determinant of shed some Understanding the light on some policy we will affect assets' returns. Amihud and Mendelson Amihud and Mendelson is result, analyze the impact of transactions costs on the rates of return illiquid assets, in a general equilibrium *More evidence As a change with additional welfare implications. framework. (1991a). ^See SUber (1991). ^See assets' Transactions taxes and differential taxation of long and short-term investment decisions on Uquid and is (1991a). also presented in Boudoukh and Whitelaw (1991). We are interested in questions such as: On what characteristics of the economy does the Uquidity premium (the difference between the rates of return on illiquid and liquid assets) depend? IIow do transactions costs effects first or affect the rates of return on liquid and illiquid assets? Are Ihese second order effects? Despite their importance for asset pricing, these questions have so far not been satisfactorily addressed in the theoretical Uterature. A major reason that to an- is swer them, one has to move away from the basic model of asset pricing, namely the representative agent model. (One cannot understand the impact of trade frictions in model where there a is no trade.) Unfortunately, models with heterogeneous agents (and trade), tend to be quite intractable analytically. Since our objective we take risk to is understand the The analysis of the joint effects of risk an interesting question that we leave There are many ways may agents. Agents is, they may have may have on asset pricing, out of the picture: All the assets that we consider (liquid or illiquid) pay a constant stream of dividends. is effects of asset liquidity liquidity for future research. to construct a deterministic economy with heterogenous trade because of differences in preferences or endowments, that different preferences for current versus future different labor precisely, our and economy is consumption, or they income paths. ^ In our economy both motives exist. More a tractable version of a multiperiod overlapping generations economy, the perpetual youth economy, first studied by Blanchard (1985). We believe, however, that our results on the effects of transactions costs on asset returns could appear in other contexts as well. In our model, agents face a constant probability of death (this tion that new makes arrivals. of labor things tractable), and the population Agents income over start with is no financial wealth and receive a decreasing stream their Ufetimes. illiquid asset. The the key assump- kept constant by an inflow of In addition they can invest in long-tcnn which pay a constant stream of dividends. There are two such and the is liquid asset is assets, the ;issrts hquid asspt traded without transactions costs, while trading the illiquid asset entails proportional transactions costs. Neither asset can be *In a stochastic economy, differentiaJ uiformation together with liquidity shocks trade (see Wang (1992)). may also generate sold short. In this economy agents buy and they accumulate the higher yielding and the liquid asset We find that for when illiquid asset for long-term investment purposes short-term investment needs. transactions costs increase, the rate of return on the liquid asset decreases while the rate of return We assets for life-cycle motives. In fact, sell on the may illiquid asset also find, quite naturally, that the liquidity premium increase or decrease. The increases. effects of transactions costs on both the rate of return on the liquid asset and the liquidity of the illiquid asset in the premium, are stronger the higher the fraction Finally, transactions costs have first order effect.s economy. on asset returns and on the liquidity premium. The reason why the rate of return on the liquid asset increase in transactions costs, can be briefly transactions costs increase from same stays the asset in equilibrium. must increase (by the cheaper. Agents to Then, liquidity now consume more e summarized in falls response to an as follows: Suppose that and that the rate of return on the Hquid asset the rate of return on the illiquid in equilibrium, premium) which implies that this asset becomes since they face better investment opportunities (they have the liquid asset at the same rate as before, and an additional investment Moreover, they substitute consumption over time so that they buy opportunity). more of the cheaper demand more illiquid asset securities for and hold two reasons. The it for a first longer period. reason is Thus, they will that they have to finance higher future consumption, selling the cheaper illiquid asset and paying transactions The second reason costs. cheaper illiquid asset goes up. The In addition, if increase more, We is and hold that, it by substitution, they want for a longer period. As a rate of return on the liquid asset has to there are more and the rate illiquid assets in the of return on the to buy more result, total asset fall of the demand to restore equilibrium. economy, total asset demand liquid asset will cannot infer whether the rate of return on the have to fall by will ni'>r<-. illiquid asset will incrcasr or decrease, by a similar reasoning. Indeed, suppose that transactions costs increase trom to The e and that the rate of return on the rate of return liquidity premium. illiquid asset in on the hquid asset then has to fall unaffected in equilibrium. by an amount equal to the This time agents face worse investment opportunities since (i) the price of the liquid asset increases and trading in the illiquid asset (ii) Agents' consumption shifts to transactions costs. down also securities the accumulate less of ambiguous. is more expensive illiquid asset. First, agents effect it for a longer period. on the total demand® have to finance lower future consumption liquid asset but they Second, agents buy less of pay transactions costs when for selling selling the the liquid and illiquid assets, but hold the a longer period. illiquid asset for Finally, the liquidity illiquid asset. The the liquid asset. subject uniformly. Furthermore, by substitution they accumulate less of the illiquid asset, but hold They is It premium depends on minimum the holding period of the increases with the fraction of illiquid assets in the economy, since this period gets shorter. There a growing literature studying asset market frictions such as transactions is costs, short sale constraints or basic questions. The first policy given price processes question (ii) is to find the optimal (i) to derive the asset to evaluate the cost that The answer "equihbrium implications" of market frictions." markets with in particular) frictions. to (ii) is The equilibrium determination it in this i.e. this question to we take the is Finally, the third to endogenize the financial be a fundamental one we do not address financial structure as given. Most of the work on the equilibrium imphcations *In (and the imperfections, also the question addressed in the present paper. While we consider paper of the second question raised in the Uterature on market question addressed by the literature on market frictions structure*. for a particular price sheds some light upon the frictions, taking the financial structure as given, It is demand of Uterature market imperfections impose upon market participants (given the price process). prices in consumption/investment and imperfections. The objectives of the body addressing this question are: process and borrowing constraints. This literature addresses three of market frictions, considrrs number of shares. 'See for instance, Constantinides (1986), Davis and Dumas and Luciano (1992), Vila (1991), Fleming et al. (1992), (1989) and Ohashi (1992). (1990). Duffie and Sun W^S^). Grossman and Vila and Zariphopoulou (1990), among many *See for instance Allen and Gale (1988), Norman (1992), Tuckman and Vila others. Boudoukh and Whitelaw (1992), Duffie and Jackson either a static framework along the among Brennan others, and (1981) and Vila (1992) equihbrium analysis, and Fremault (1991) and Michaely for a general economy where agents hve models give us usefid questions we Moreover, for all assets. It only two periods (Pagano (1989)). for in. model to buy or thus clear that is adequate for Although these answering several of the In static models, assets are not sold but only liquidated. (as well as in a when agents cannot choose equilibrium treatment) or an overlapping generations insights, they are not are interested in a static Goldsmith (1976), Levy (1978) and Mayshar (1979) (1975), for a partial Asset Pricing Model (see lines of the Capital two period overlapping generations model), sell assets, many and the holding period of our results is the same would not appear in that simplified framework. In a context directly related to the present paper, .\mihud and Mendelson (1986) consider a dynamic model where investors have different horizons. investors with, say, an investment horizon of 4 years actions cost when buying and selling assets, will lose year because of the transactions cost. Hence, they who face a 2% They argue roundtrip trans- approximately 2/4% (.5%) per will require a rate of return of .5% higher on illiquid assets than on Hquid assets. Consequently, the liquidity on assets wliich appeal to investors The above reasoning .5%. by transactions costs that premium with a 4 year horizon must be approximately implies that investors with longer horizons are less affected and would select higher yielding illiquid assets. By contrast, investors with shorter horizons select low yield liquid assets. This clientele effect explains the empirical fact that the cross-sectional relation and asset returns is The concave.^ analysis above, while insightful, takes investors' horizons bs given and does not explain transactions costs. the liquid asset costs on the Two is Moreover assumed between transactions costs how they change in response to an increase in since, as in the previous papers, the rate of return for simplicity to differentials of rates of return be on fixed, only the effect of trnnsn< lions and not on their levels can be examinf-'l. recent papers, one by Aiyagari and Gertlcr (11)91), and one l)y Ileaton and Lucas (1992) consider dynamic models where investors" horizons are endogenous. In their models, agents are infinitely lived, face labor 'By contrast, if all investors had tlie same horizon income uncertainty, and trade this relation would be linear. consumption-smoothing purposes. assets for premium puzzle of return (see Mehra and These papers seek Prescott (1985)), i.e. to solve the equity to explain the differential rates between the stock and the bond market. Aiyagari and Gertler (1991) argue that differential transactions costs between these the equity premium. In the equity premium is model their two markets account (as in ours), the "stock' due to transactions costs and not to explains the fraction of the equity They do not however analyze premium which is is riskless risk. for part of and therefore Hence their in fact a liquidity model premium. the effect of transactions costs on the level of rates of return as they take the rate of return on the liquid asset as given. By contrast with Aiyagari and Gertler (1991), Heaton and Lucas (1992) allow for a truly risky asset as well as for aggregate labor income uncertainty. They argue that transactions costs prevent investors from reducing the variability of their consumption by intertemporal smoothing thereby raising the equity premium. In addition, they endogenize the rate of return on the liquid asset and fmd that it falls in response to increased transactions costs. model agents save Wliile in our income uncerttiinty, our the above two papers. premium, is fall, We fmd in particular that transactions costs create a liquidity as in Heaton and Lucas (1992). The contribution of our work twofold: First, our closed form anedysis allows us to precisely identify the different able to easily perform The remainder model. 5, numerical simulation results of and Gertler (1991), and that they cause the rate of return on effects of transactions costs 3. purposes rather than because of labor results are consistent with the as in Aiyagari the Uquid asset to for life-cycle We and interpret various comparative of the paper is statics. structured as follows: In section 2, we describe the determine asset returns when there are no transactions costs In section 4, we on asset demands and on rates of return. Second, we are illustrate we consider the case where there are transactions costs. our general results with some numerical examples. Section concluding remarks and all proofs appear in the appendix. in section In sf-rtion fi contains The Model 2 To analyze the impact of transactions costs on the return on assets and on the A premium, we have adapted Blanchard's (1985) model of perpetual youth. liquidity simpHfied exposition of the original model can be found in Blanchard and Fisher (1989). We uum consider a continuous time overlapping generations of agents with total mass equal to An 1. probability of death per unit time, A. In addition, has a density function equal to \€xp( lives in this economy, their life we assume at a rate — \i). Although expectancy is that death equal to agents can bounded and equal inde- is Therefore the A. and the distribution to one mass equal stationary, witii total is a contin- agent in this economy faces a constant pendent across agents and that agents are born population economy with of age, live arbitrary t, long to 1/A. Agents are born with zero financial wealth and receive an exogenous labor income yt over their Lifetimes. We assume that The aggregate labor income yt declines exponentially with age S>0 yt = ye-''\ Y is constant and equal to y= rXe-''y,dt = Jo The financial structure in this economy time. economy is -^y A + - A; (0 < liquid asset r = (2.2) given as follows. total supply of perpetuities is All assets in this D fc is D/p. The < 1), The also the can be exchanged without transactions costs. The price of the illiquid asset, in total R = D/ P^°. transactions costs: is per unit liquid asset, in total supply denoted by p and the rate of return on liquid assets return equal to D normalized to one so that aggregate dividend. There are two such perpetuities. 1 (2.1) are real perpetuities which pay a constant flow of dividends The ( Trading in the when buying must pay exP transactions ^°Note that we have defined costs. R net of transactions coa<s depends supply of k. has a price illiquid asset is equal to is F denoted by nnd a ml'- '>l subject to proportional (or selling) x shares of the illiquid asset the agent Because of transactions costs, the rate of return as the rate of return before transactions costs. upon the holding period and is The on rate of return therefore investor specific. the illiquid asset and on the liquid asset will be different. The liquidity premium ^i is defined as = R-r. fi none of these assets can be sold short. ^^ Finally, Over the course of stochastic imposes a financial it way: in the following We of TTf/i assume that exchange costlessly^"' is and fully and (Hi) is perfectly competitive, death is an idiosyncratic We full a of assets For example an premium living participant. We assume that (i) insurance companies transfer assets risk. As a result, the both the liquid and do not derive any since, as previously indicated, agents purchase for (ii) costlessly insurable the liquid asset will pay a of, say, is of losing their pay shares to collect the share in the event of death. be equal to the probability of death \dt, utility is on their estate. for a claim that insures one share the insurance market will this risk additional shares of the liquid asset per unit time dt to compensation Its Since death upon the agents namely that risk there exist insurance companies which to the Uving participants in company accumulate both assets. their lives, agents accumulated holdings. ^^ insurance (2.3) premium must illiquid asset. Finally from utility Trdt their estate they insurance. assume that agents maximize time at function of their consumption the expected value of a time separable i.e. u{ct)te-^Ut / (2.4) .Jo Since the only uncertainty comes from the possibility of death ^^If short sales asset instead. 6, which is were costless agents would not Our results do not change a reasonable assumption (see and Vila (1992) for evidence if sell write equa- the illiquid asset but would short the liquid we assume for instance we can that the of short spUing co<:t Boudouiih and Whitelaw ( \.^^l) is liielcr \\\n\\ anH Tn. kmmi on short sale costs). ^^Agents do not leave any heir behind and care onlv about themselves. ^^The introduction of insurance companies is in the introduction suggests that our results generations model with deterministic death. a convenient way to close the model. Our discussion would carry through The latter is in much more a multi-period overlapping difficult to solve analytically. as" tion 2.4 Jo We also assume that the tution equal to 1/.4 function exhibits a constant elasticity of substi- utility i.e. "(c) In this paper we focus on the stationary equilibria of equilibrium, the rates of return determination of J, A. Y = ^-^c^-^i^ r, R and // r and R are constant. as functions of the and D. ^<See Blanchatd '^The case A=l and Fisher (1989) for details. corresponds to u{c) — logc. 10 (2.6) this economy. In a stationary We seek to understand the parameters of the model: e. k. A, S, The No Transactions Costs Case 3 In this section, when case we analyze the determination of the interest rate in the benchmark transactions costs are equal to zero. between the liquid asset and the illiquid asset: r = R and /i — is no difference 0. The consumer's problem 3.1 The financial wealth Wt of the consumer at date consumer's assets. That date is if j-, is the number defined as the value of the is t consumer owns of shares that the at t Wt At date t, Since he consumes dwt = Dit entails (.3.1) Dxtdt + Xpxtdt From equations in 2.5 dividend income plus and > 3.2, + {yt 0; - Wo = Ct)dt = (r + \)wtdt > Wt 0; -\.rt His financial shares worth XpXf. /5 + (t/( - Ct)dt 0. the consumer's problem consumer with discount factor of an infinitely lived per unit time. t/t per unit time the dynamics of his wealth are Ct Ct rate. = pxf the consumer receives a labor income income (per unit time) the In this case there (.3.2) is the optimization problem + A who faces a constant interest This constant interest rate equals the rate of return on the perpetuity, premium paid by r, pltts the insurance company, A. Hence the consumer's problem can be written as r max »(c,)e-<'^+^'Vt = max Jo s.t. Jo r Qe-''+''Vf = max H Jo The problem ^*To calculate 6 >w = (/3 - 3.3 Hr* 1 —L-r'-'',-'''^'^'dt I - A y,c''''^^"df: «> > 0. Jo above admits the following solutiou^^ this solution we have assumed that the borrowing constraint r)/A, and that the maiimuin in 3.3 hold in equilibrium. (See appendix A is finite, i.e. for details.) 11 V' = '' + '^ is + '«'>0. not binding, Both i.e. restrictions . = y^e-' ct (3.4) with (i) = r + A 4- 6 = r + \ + and lb Filially, ijj. the consumer's financial wealth at date - y equals — e— _ p-^« < U-, t o (3.5) Equilibrium 3.2 In equilibrium the aggregate financial wealth Xe-^'wtdt (3.6) Jo /o equals the market value of the perpetuities p i.e. = D/r. Using equation 3.5 we can show that the equilibrium interest rate solves the equation Illtl^ 0*(\ where r*, w*, 0* and i/'* + up with the discount factor of aggregate financial goes down with £ (3.7) Y denote the equilibrium values or Equation 3.7 determines the interest rate rate goes = u}') r* r. uj uniquely. . 6 and d', As expected the 3, the prol)ahility of d^aHi A greater incentives to save. Finally goes up the interest rate goes if <*'. interest and thr income over aggregate labor income D/Y. The the rate of decline of labor income. respectively. interest since an increase in (*' r;iii>> ratp leads to the coefficient of elasticity of substitution, l/.l, down provided the interest rate goes up. 12 that r* be greater than 3. Otherwise In equilibrium, agents use the financial markets to their lifetime: they buy assets when they are smooth their young and begin consumption over selling assets at age r* where t* solves r'xvr' From 3.5, r* is +yr- -Cr' = = u!' T= r volume dollar \e-"\rtvt Jo ^ (3.8) given by r' The aggregate 0.^^ + yt- -^ogi—--]. - in this c,\dt = \ S 6 + (3.9) X economy equals = 2Auv.e-'^' 27—^e-<'+'-*'^'. Note that we do not consider the payment of shares by insurance companies to be a although the agent's portfolio may still portfolio grows at a rate lower than A amounts to defining are different. assets as (3.10) (j)* Since who is . be growing (dW, > opposed to cash and that the agent is considered a spIIt Ilein-f if liis In the absence of transactions costs, this eissumption simplv called a seller we have assumed 0). traile. and who is not. With transactions costs, however, matters that insurance companies pay living participants shares of this transfer is 13 costless, our definition of a seller is the correct Transactions Costs and Assets' Returns 4 In this section, we determine on the illiquid asset, costs. We the rate of return on the liquid asset, R, and the liquidity premium /( + (6- r* R{() = ;/(t) where b and m' are the first we m*)f. +b€ + r' = m'e + o(e) 4- o{e) o(() consider the case where the supply of the illiquid asset. The somewhat different and is first write order equilibrium effects that assets are available to consumers. presence of transactions in the order effect on equilibrium variables. For this purpose = the rate of return small transactions costs and focus on their will consider the case of r(f) r, case where we is /.-, seek to calculate. less than one so both assets are illiquid, all We i.e. k = 1, is studied in appendix E. Before proceeding with the formal derivations, show that useful to it is in equilib- rium the liquidity premium per unit of transactions costs n/e must be greater than the rate of return on the liquid asset, since agents are born without illiquid asset at dollar some point worth of asset later. If r, or equivalently he buys the liquid asset rds for his s shares. Hence illiquid asset, + consider an agent ( and date at t date and t + t is because, must buy the who buys for one At periods sells it + At and At. given the transactions costs he -1 at (1 This t his cash flows are R/{1 + €)d3 e). cash flows are between +1 he buys the Now inclusive of transactions costs at date -1 at If r(i assets, in equilibrium they any financial in their lives. R> for s date between -e)/(l + e) at 14 t t and date t + t 4- At and At. will get I [F( I I- ' l| UR < r(l buying the -I- e), i.e. < if /i illiquid asset. then buying the liquid asset always dominates re, Hence /« means that the In particular, this mium is prices, IX > at least a first liquidity pre- a priori information about equilibrium this demand investor's on the and for liquid illiquid assets when The consumer's problem With transactions consumer's financial wealth Wt costs, the Uquid portfolio, denoted by At. Denoting by and of the value of l)y 0(, (respectively it It) asset (respectively illiquid asset), the = dat dAt Ct From 4.2 above, = = yt = itdt; oq \Atdt + Itdt; Ao = + RAt - it -It- see that the agent's income purchases of illiquid assets With transactions dynamics of + rat It, rat is the sum of the value of denoted his illiquid portfolio, the incremental dollar investment in the liquid Xotdt -I- we can plus the dividend i/t, (4.1) re. 4.1 his re.i» effect of transactions costs With order effect. we next characterize the > Oj and At are given by 0; at ^ > Aj 0; e\Ii\- Ct (4.2) > 0. consumption equals the labor income + RAt, minus purchases of liquid assets minus transactions costs it, minus e\It\- the consumer's problem becomes far more complex. costs, Proposition 4.1 (proven in appendix B) describes the optimal policy of the consumer for small transactions costs i.e. and for a subset of values of r and R that are of intf-r'^st, such that their equilibrium values belong to this subset. Proposition 4.1 possible values, infinity, that is small and for e r and R the optimal policy has the following illiquid asset until ^'Tliis lower For bound an age is when the t^ . He belonging to a svbsft nf llnir form: then buys the liquid asset. The consumer buys He next sells the liquid reached asymptotically when the holding period of fraction of illiquid assets, k, goes to zero. 15 the illiquid assets goes to an age asset until He then asset. We find Ti + A. At age start selling the illiquid asset until he dies. that in equilibrium, agents will buy high yield illiquid assets for long-term investment and low yield liquid assets result for the illiquid asset are the asset are the agents of age marginal investor at date rj -*- is A. As premium liquidity Amihud and Mendelson fairly intuitive The (1986). clientele agents of age less that tj while the clientele for the liquid and the age at which they begin between Tj who buys the investor in short-term investment. This for consistent with the analysis of is he does not oxen any share of the liquid + A, rj the illiquid asset at date Amihud and Mendelson to sell r^ The it. and sells it (1986), this investor determines the (see below). The Hquid and illi([uid portfolios as function of age t are plotted in figure 1. Proposition 4.1 presents the qualitative properties of the optimal consumption/investment sumption how what In policy. at date follows, these qualitative properties will allow us to calculate con(, C(, as a function of the initial cq- We will also show the intertemporal budget equation, properly modified to account for transactions consumption costs, leads to the determination of the initial how the parameter A premium, the sake of the presentation, Over the course of his all life //, and the which Indeed, consider a consumer wants to have the same wealth at t between + dt, ie e^"". and show will level of transactions costs, e. For relevant for the consumption-savings is is ^ = + 1 5 we the agent faces three interest rates. Rl + At Finally, technical details have been sent to appendix B. First until age ri, the interest rate decision cq. can be easily calculated as function of the rate of return on the liquid asset, r, the liquidity t consumption, and t t-rdf. he consume after t at f "^ Therefore, for earlier rather decide? to ronsum*" ^1 [O.r,] + dt. He then buys he consumes the proceeds from avoiding dt. A. e l,'F(l4-e) illiquid consumes the extra dividend flows Hence by foregoing $1 t -\- who -I- than R at < he gets $1 + to \dt (£) buy (I/P(l + (R/([ ^ Tf + e))dt l'"--'^. '"'l s;rriiriii'-s. l-i-''))^^'* "" and ())e^'^' securities, + o(dt) between given, higher transactions costs increase the desire to later. The reason 16 is that the consumer has to buy an which asset is more expensive, but pays the same dividend. Second, between ages Tj and therefore faces the interest rate r Third and illiquid assets, finally, + A, tj + the consumer invests in the liquid assets and A. + A, when after age rj the consumer \ -^ + — = 1 Indeed, suppose that at between 5 (it t -\- dt t same wealth and t 4- dt, + dt. f G after + A,oo) [ti t + He dt. A. e he decides to consume $1 sells 1/^(1 — f.) For R $1 at t he gets $1 + \dt + (/?/(! - {D/P{1 — ejje"^*^' The reason ())dt that the consumer has to is but wants + sell e))e'*'''~'' securities o(dt) given, higher transactions costs increase the desire to rather than earlier. less less illiquid securities. he consumes the extra dividend flow he consumes the proceeds from selUng (1/P(I — Hence by foregoing t divesting out of the he faces a higher rate Rb + to have the is i.e. between consume At and c^"^'. t and later a cheaper asset that pays the same dividend. We denote by p{t) the interest rate relevant p(t) p{t) = pit) and by r = Ri + \ (oT + Ti A for t < date p(t) we indeed show = I Jo t i.e. < n < Ti +A = Rb + Mot n + A < and date p(t) the discount rate betrveen date In appendix B, < for t t i.e. p{s)d3. that the optimal consumption must satisfy Q = coe-"" (I.:'.) with IM{t) where the consumption at birth cq is = {i3 + \)t-p{t) A derived from the intertemporal budget constraint presented below. 17 Given proposition path tion r must C{ 4.1 and equation 4.2, can easily it 1 -I- shown tiiat the consump- satisfy the iniertemporal budget equation r yL-Sie-»(^^dt+ r^^(y, + {R-r)At-c,)e-''^'Ut+ Jo Ije Jri e ^L-iie-^'^'cit 1 Jri+Ci. 'n — = (4.4) € with ^0 1 + e Equation 4.4 says that the Net Present Value of lifetime savings net of transactions costs must equal where we define savings zero, minus what must be reinvested Between periods lO, Ty\ and and therefore savings equal [rj yt in + A. as total income minus consumption order for financial wealth to grow at the rate oc [, this latter ~ Cf Between Tj f>{t). quantity equals the dividend income and t^ + A, only a fraction rAt of the dividends from the illiquid portfolio must be reinvested and thus savings equal labor income, minus consumption yt, plus excess dividends c, {R — r)At. Finally savings are adjusted for transactions costs. We now show how the minimum holding period calculated as a function of A are optimally chosen, this illiquid asset his r, change and not doing in utility if /.i and e. Consider a consumer consumer must be so. of the illiquid asset, Given that he indifferent at age tj. Since between investing u'(c^)(l + e)P he buys one unit of the + u'(c..+^)(l - ti e)Pe-''^ and in the starts selling the illiquid asset at r^ +A illiquid asset at t^ is rn + A - A, can be + r^"" u'{ct)De-^^'-^^dt = 0. (4.5) Jri 'n Use of equation 4.3 and simple algebra show that the above equation can be rewritten as !L^r'^'"\ e Equation 4.6 shows that the is decreasing in its 1 (4.B. - e-^^ minimum holding period of the illiquid asset, A. excess rate of return over the liquid asset. /(, and increasing in transactions costs, e}^ ^®We can also derive equation 4.6 by noting that 18 between n and n + A the consumer invests From equation optimal choice of 4.6 Tj it follows that the intertemporal and A, budget constraint, Net Present Value of consumption equals states that the the Net Present Value of income where the discount factor Hiyt The initial consumption, ct)€-''^'Ut = p(t), i.e. is 0. (4.7) can be derived from equations 4.3 and 4.7. Cq Having characterized the solution to the consumer's problem we turn librium determination of r an for to the equi- and R. Equilibrium 4.2 In equilibrium, the dollar demands and for liquid illiquid assets Jo and: " \e-^'Atdt I /o equal the assets' market value, (1 As we stated in the beginning of this section, costs (small values of we have defined — k)D/r and kD/R b t), and = r*+(6-m*)e + = ;((f) tha.t r*, u;*. 4>* and i'* We cdso define by T\{t) e, on R r, and /(. Recall that r' = + be 7Tj*e + + o(f) and A(e) (4.8) (4.9) oif) (I. o(€) are the equilibrium values of r. ^. o and v for as the equilibrium values of t^ and by r* and A* the respective in the liquid asset. consider small transactions and m* by R{e) of will find their first order effects r(e) and we respectively. limits of ri(e) and A(f ) as e and <= - KM 0. A as a function goes to zero. (Note Therefore the Net Present Value rule applies, and the Net Present Value of investing in the illiquid asset between these dates is 19 zero. that when e equals zero, the liquid asset and the illiquid asset are the same asset and therefore the holdings at and At are not well defined.) In other terms, r* and A* are the zero-th order effects of transactions costs on holding periods. The next proposition Proposition 4.2 of equations ^.S, costs on J,-9 the liquidity There exists an equilibrium where and and premium, return on the illiquid asset, b b. r, R and /t b. have the form In equilibrium the first order effect of transactions Jf.lO. of return on the liquid asset, The m characterizes the equilibrium values of rn' is , — m*, positive while the first order effect on the rate is negative. The order effect on the rate of first has an ambiguous sign. rigorous derivations o[ b — m\ and m*. b as well as explicit formulae are presented in appendix C. Proposition 4.2, that we discuss in detail next, states that transactions costs decrease the rate of return on the liquid asset but have an ambiguous effect on the rate of return on the illiquid asset. We discuss the results of proposition 4.2 in subsections 4.2.1., 4.2.2. and subsection 4.2.1, we of transactions costs characterize the parameters r* and on optimal consumption/savings A* we in the discuss the determination of the rates of return (or, In the zero-th order effect policies. In subsection 4.2.2 go over the determination of the liquidity premium, and 4.2.3 i.e. 4. 2. .3. we rather long subsection more accurately, the first order effects of transactions costs on these variables.) Optimal Switching Times 4.2.1 The age at which agents switch from the illiquid asset to the liquid asset, r* age at which they start selling the illiquid asset, r* from the with 6 = limit case as and = R — r and of the liquid e = A*, can he easily interprftpd goes to zero. Indeed consider the accumulation pfination^ r' . Given the investors illiquid portfolios At At -t- and the to,;e^<'-"''' = and Wt a, total wealth «> = "f + < t* + A* -4,. over time are given by and = xvt at - — {or t < tau[ uv;f'''-"i'' for r^ < t l.J the vahu-s At It = and ivt follows that the values of r^ financial wealth Wt = Oj (ii) + A' < t. and A* can be calculated by noting grows by fxp(AA*) between r* and t' UV; + A- and for r* = + A* (i) that total i.e. uv;e^^* (4.11) that aggregate liquid financicd wealth must equal the supply of hquid assets i.e. \e-''atdt= / Using the expression Ae-''(u-, -ti;..e'"-^''Hi above we obtain the values of 4.2.2 Liquidity In appendix premium, from equation for w, r,* C we show different that the first by first '' ^^-^^^ - from its value in equation 4.13. demand in (i.e. if /t were different in the first A. Therefore, there would a zero-th for liquid versus illiquid assets. (Although there would order change in total asset demand.) The reasoning (and 1 + e-'"^* = \.e-'^' Rates of Return 4.2.3 b order effect of transactions costs on the liquidity would be a zero-th order change order change in the only be a and 4.12 easy to understand the determination of m*. Equation 4.6 imphes that It is fairly order), there 3.5 as well as equations 4.11 Premium in, is given m* were (4.12) and A*. '"* if = (l-A.-)-- b — m*) we r transactions by m*€, for the rates of return for m* will make costs increase. is more involved. the following exercise: To determine the parninf*fr We will assume that In order to preserve equilibrium, given by equation 4.13. We 21 will then find by R for fixed has to increase how much total asset demand and supply change demand states that total asset /~ + Xe-^'iat in the first At)Jt the equation that r = \e-^'wtdt = - k)D/r + kD/R. (1 (4.14) Jo Since this exercise asset decreases useful for understanding is when To determine why transactions costs increase, total asset path of the agent we — m' by b equals total asset supply: Jo that order and infer demand, we must the rate of return on the liquid we go over first it in some detail. understand how the consumption modified by the change in transactions costs and asset returns is are considering. Lemma 4.3 (proven in appendix C) gives us the consumption of the agent at age 0. Lemma Th^ cou sumption at date zero, 4.3 co where Cw is Cq is given by — + eCw + tC, + w' = y o{e) (4.1-5) 0' given by + (77 ^ 1 /" ) ^j(^ -^ ^^^'"'^ - (^ -^ u;-)e-'"']dij (4.16) or alternatively ytl l{m' and Cs is (e--^*' - e-**')rft + (m* + r') H {e""'' - e-''')dt\ Jr-j.^' Jo \ 4>* /'' r*) (4.17) J given by Cs = -\y—\(m' The terms A <p* Cw - \ r') f^' e-'''dt Jo + {m' 4.r') r and Cs have a very intuitive interpretation. interpreted as a wealth effect. For this we need to note that !(A-^6)e-*'' -(A+u;*W-"^-"'| ' 0^ 22 \i.\X) e-'',It]. /r^+A- / First, Civ '"a.n l)e is the present value of the dollar case = e amount The consumer when buying 0. of transactions the illiquid asset between When transactions costs but pays a lower price. is we can positive as is more attractive from to rj. A e) > r, Thus (Agents buy the term this is Having interpreted the expression investment opportunities, illiquid asset (i.e. we can for cq, is also e = plus transactions costs), the buys more of the illiquid asset 4.4 (proven in appendix C) 4.4 Total asset 6 where W\v and Ws W^y = demand -u;* is attractive from how the and holds life it is the wealth effect.) more than compensates it are lower (lowpr price for a longer period. (he saves more) and he the substitution is we determine eir,v + eH', e-»*+^'^.-) o'r* = con- total asset In other sells it at a effect. demand. given hy r+ Ay 2-^(e-(--+^)^i - e saving also clear that It is + (4.l!l) o{€) are given by ^"Compared to the case r. paying transaction more up uniformly. (This lower rate (he defers consumption for later). This Lemma this consumer changes the slope of the consumption path words, he buys more in the beginning of his lemma and Because the consumer has better 0. available at a lower price (which is + €) > briefly describe transactions costs), and because the proceeds from selling In 0, kept is he has the liquid asset at the same price as before, and the illiquid asset), his consumption path goes so that he = € t/'*, negative. sumption path changes compared to the case illiquid asset to the case as a substitution effect. Since i?/(l therefore deferring consumption for later until death. Because the compared which more than compensates them.) costs but at a lower price R/(l — off A see in expression 4.17. The term Cs can be interpreted Tj 4- + ri The term shows. Clearly, since the rate of return in the liquid asset consumer can only be better constant, the is pays the ti seUiug the illiquid asset (from price. in the equal to the present discounted value of these "extra''^° cash flows, times as expression 4.16 term and he pays the transactions costs and receives a lower until he dies), Cw between r and r + dr _ !!!_ r' 0. 23 /" Jo \e-''Atdt + ( \+u>j')(p'r* \ Jr^ + A' Jo / (i.20) and A (A + a:'}(f}'r' Jr^+A- Jo \ I (4.21) The term \V\v represents the additional the consumer path (i.e. if if additional wealth for (in the first order) of the latter changes only the level but not the slope of his consumption the wealth effect change to the demand is in transaction demand present, but not the substitution effect) in response costs for (dollar) and asset returns that we are studying. This wealth has an ambiguous sign because, on the one hand, higher future consumption to be financed and transactions costs to be paid when more wealth, but on the other hand selling assets require illiquid assets are cheaper. The term Ws corresponds to the substitution effect: Indeed as it was said before the consumer changes the slope of his consumption path so that he buys illiquid asset This term is and holds it positive and for a longer period. its more of the This implies more wefdth accumulation. magnitude depends on the elasticity of intertemporal substitution. Finally total asset supply (in the € The difference between always positive. is discussion. asset / It total asset is order) Xe-^'Atdt decreases since the illiquid asset It and — first is is: = tW,^„iy cheaper. demand and supply easy to understand why this Higher future consumption to be financed by is is may \V\v + IK + so. liased selling the and paying transactions costs requires a larger niiwber oi (Although the dollar amount (4.22) \\ .„,.,,;„ on our cheaper securities to '^arlif-r illiqnirl l)e held. be lower.) In addition, the agents change the slope 24 consumption paths of their longer period, The e is then easily deduced, and discussion which explained and that the rate Then, why is higher. the rate of return on the liquid asset on the hquid asset stays the same of return (in equilibrium) the rate of they buy more of the Agents will illiquid asset demand more thus to finance higher future it it securities for up because there their slope will change so that for a longer period (substitution effect). two reasons. First, cheaper selling the because they have illiquid asset and paying illiquid asset and for a longer period. Although the liquid asset first order effect of transactions costs on the rate of return on the unambiguous is (6 of return on the illiquid asset replicate (more costs increase, above and hold consumption by and effect), Second, because they want to buy more of the transaction costs. in equilibrium. return on the illiquid asset must increase (in the more investment opportunities (wealth hold for a negative. order) by m*t. Agents' consumption paths will shift uniformly first are — m* demand and supply even asset it can be summarized as follows: Suppose that transactions costs increase from falls, to order to buy more of the illiquid asset and hold making the imbalance between value of 6 The above in briefly) the R stays the (r decreases — m* (i.e. is negative), the the sign of 6) is first ambiguous. In what follows, we above exercise, assuming that same and order effect on the rate this time, as transactions r decreases in the first order, as determined by m't). This time, agents face worse investment opportunities. The price of the liquid asset increcises while trading the illiquid asset entails transactions costs. This (wealth) effect implies then that their consumption paths hand, by substitution, agents accumulate asset for a longer period. The effect on the shift Indeed, the future consumption to be financed demand is uniformly. for securities less of the liquid and illiquid assets. period. 25 the other is Ijiit illiquid ambiguous. lower and the liquid assri expensive, but on the other hand transactions costs have to be paid. agents buy On both assets but hold the less of total down is m<>rf In a/ldilion. hold the iUiquid asset lor a Iookt Comparative 4.3 In this subsection Statics we study how the depend on the parameters 6 — m' depend on k, effects of transactions costs (More of the model. these parameters.) we precisely, The parameter that is the fraction of illiquid assets to the total stock of assets. In appendix D) we examine how Lemma in k is We 4.5 m* increases , b and in k, b — b depend on »n* — m* find assets' returns how m'. b and of greatest interest lemma is 4.5 (proven in k. decreases in k while (he dependence of b ambignous. briefly discuss the results of this The dependence shorter. The m* on of economy imply in the ni* on A- that the liquidity Lemma. relatively simple to understand. is minimum premium must More iUiquid assets holding period of an illiquid asset becomes increase so that consumers are wilUng to hold illiquid assets for shorter periods. The dependence of 6 — m* on k can be explained in the light of the analysis of the was argued that to understand why the rate of return previous subsection. There it on the liquid asset response to increased transactions costs, falls in the following experiment: to e could suppose that transactions costs increased from and that the rate of return on the order) by ni*e. total We We we could make illiquid asset had could then study the difference between to increase (in the first demand and supply of wealth and infer the direction of change of the rate of return on the Uquid asset. In fact, asset, we can also infer the magnitude of change of the rate of return on the liquid studying the magnitude of the difference between total asset demand and total asset supply. As k increases, m* increases, therefore both the wealth effect are stronger. is greater, The and the effect and the substitution This implies that the difference between asset demand and first order effect on r effects of the other h — iv') is m\ h and 6 (i.e. parameters on are not reported here. 26 bigger (in absoltitf' — m' !='tpply valnr-i. are of less intef^st ;iimI Numerical Examples 5 In this section we present previous sections. In all some numerical examples these examples that the level of transactions costs e we assume equals 3% to illustrate the results of the .4=1 that which figures are consistent (i) the Uquidity down, (iii) is is positive, (ii) when k When k is lemma 4.5, is close to is significant and plot These namely that the rate of return on the Hquid asset goes (iv) the on the liquidity premium and the rate of return on the eff"ect liquid 1. The main quantitative observations premium we the supply of the illiquid asset. the rate of return on the illiquid asset can go up or down, large liquidity figures 2 to 4, all with the results in proposition 4.2 and premium of transactions costs asset fc, logo) consistent with empirical is evidence (see Aiyagari and Gertler (1991) for instance). In various rates of return as a function of = (v{c) When 1, the (about 10% ui the level of the rates of return), (ii) are as follows: (i) close to 1, transactions costs cause a non-trivial fall k is close to in the rate of return on the liquid asset wliile the rate of return on the illiquid asset remains almost constant. These quantitative results have important practical appUcations. To understand the impact of a change in transactions costs in the economy, how derstand assets are differently affected by this change. A it is important to un- technological change, such as a reduction in computer cost, can be assumed to reduce transaction costs for all assets and in our model corresponds to the case k=l. Our results suggest that rates of return will not on one change much. By contrast, a reduction of transactions costs single asset (e.g. by the introduction of a derivative security) will increase the price of this asset without any significant impact on the other assets. Finally, a transaction tax on a significant subset of existing assets (stocks, real estate lower their value by an amount analysis which takes the less than suggested by a simple pnrtial rates of return on the other assets 27 as given. ..) will eq'iilibrinni Conclusion 6 In this work we have constructed imperfect capital market. push the rate of return on a fairly simple general equilibrium Our main result illiquid assets assets goes down that while transactions costs tend to is upward, there which tends to lower rates of return. The net result is a general equilibrium effect is that the rate of return on liquid while the rate of return on illiquid assets may believe that these results are robust to the specification of income shocks'^ or taste shocks and cycle, labor life Our model endogenously generates This clientele effect ity. In fact, (1986). if is model of an We go up or down. the trading motives: (i) the preferences.^^ (ii) clienteles for assets with differential Hquid- consistent with previous work we generalized our model 1o allow for l)y Amihud and Mendelson many assets with different transactions costs, we would obtain the concave relationship between rates of return and transactions costs derived by these authors. we assumed that transactions In this paper, costs were a pure destruction of due to a transaction tax whose proceeds are distributed resources. If instead, they are to the agents, the results are similar. Amihud and Mendelson (1991b) argue that, holding the risk free rate constant, a .5% transaction tax would lower the market value of the NYSE stocks by 13.8%. While we do not dispute the transaction tax will increase the liquidity that the risk free rate will premium significantly, our results suggest so that the stock price fall fact that a small fall is likely to be somewhat smaller. This line of research can be pursued in (at least) two directions. terection between risk and Hquidity is not fully understood. It First, the in- would be interesting to construct tractable models to analyze the interaction between transactions costs and risk and examine in particular ^^S^e for instance Ainihud et al. whether, as spirit to the period is the companion note, model herein. This same for all assets has been areued. illiquid markft'^ nr'- (1992). ^^Tlie treatment of the perpetual vouth intractable. In a it model for a general ulilitv function seems to ns analvtirallv we consider a two-period overlapping generations model model and is simpler but also much as a result the liquidity le^s rich. premium the results are independent of the functioned form of preferences. 28 is similar in In particular, the holding fixed. In this simple model more volatile since investors find more importantly, very little is it more costly to absorb liquidity shocks. known about Second and the determination of the level of trans- actions costs as well as the financial structure created to deal with these transactions costs. 29 Appendix A The No Transactions Costs Case when This appendix considers the case prove that in equilibrium 6 > equilibrium We is must uj and = !/' We transactions costs are zero. + A+u;>0. We r will will first then prove that the unique. calculate the optimal policy which entails solving first roo m ax r ^(o).-"^+^^/i = max T -J—c'-'^e''"^''' Jo Jo s.t. 1 r H = max cte-'^^'"dt - 1 dt .4 y,e-'^^'"Jt; > Wt 0. ( A.l) Jo yo From He and Pages we know that (1991), bounded value a for .3. .3 aliove exists provided that = V' In that case, He and Pages show C( Ct If V' < 0, = = yt for every r + then the value of 3.3 is + u;>0. (A.2) that t \[ uj every {yxl'/(p)e~'^'- for A — t if u; We oo. (3 — < ^, A > S and with o = r r) / show below that + X this + 6. cannot be the case in equilibrium. In equilibrium, the resource constraint implies that Jo Hence the equilibrium utihty to the of the representative agent is liounded by thf^ soluiion program below /•oo max / Jo s.t. r 1 I- A c Xe-^'ctdt Jo 30 e nt = D+ Y. (A.4) . easy to show that A. 4 has a finite value. It is U this > (jj is 8 then the agent does not buy any asset and therefore = 0. Obviously, not consistent with the equilibrium condition \e-^'wtdt /; /o Hence ?(', 8 must be larger than From the expression u; for Ct and 3.2 follows easily that it = _ ^-st (A.6) . y yields the equilibrium condition + u;-) _D r'(8-^) r'{8-^') which must be solved (A..5) equilibrium. in e-u,t <A*(A — r ^f^t Combining A. 5 and A.6 = (r' + X + 8){\ + '^) (A.7) Y for r*. Simple algebraic manipulations show that A.7 above has a unique positive solution r*, that this solution is increasing in /?, is increasing in A if r* is greater than /? A and D/Y and that and decreasing with 31 it is ,4 decreasing in otherwise. 6. It B Proof of Proposition The method of proof as follows: is We 4.1 define the control variables. first Step The 1 Recall that and that is indeed optimal. control problem the per unit time value of the liquid assets purchased at date is it the per unit time value of the illiquid assets purchased at date /( is then Next we construct a candidate derive heuristic conditions for an optimal control. optimal control and show that We t. t Recall also equations 4.2 dot dAt ct The it and (ii) it constraint /( i{t) = \A,dt + yt ^ rot > Ct and It We 0. = = oq ItdU + RAt - .4o it - that a control («(),/()) satisfies the the payoff function, = -L i(dt', It 0: = - is > at 0; i.e. I(t). is maximize adwissihle no short sale constraints denote by C the i* > (B.l) Q > e\It\\ to > -4, subject to the above dynamics of at and we say Formally, it \atdt control problem faced by the consumer controls uous - — 0. 2.5 with respect to the Af piecewise contin- if it is (i) and At > set of admissible controls the utility that the consumer enjoys if as well as the and by J( /()./()) he follows the controls Using the fact that at= f i,e'^'-'U3 (B.2) At= f I.e^^'-'\h Jo (B.31 Jo and the payoff function can be written as J(i[)J[)) = r u{ijt + r /' ;,e'"-"(/.s Jo + R Jo f I,c'"-'^ds - it -I,- c\It\U "'^'^'df Jo (B.4 Hence the control problem is to maximize J( /(),/()) with respect ing to C. 32 to (j( ),/()) belong step To 2 Heuristic optimality conditions derive heuristic conditions for an optimal control, control (i( ),/()), denote by c() the resulting we take a candidate optimal consumption and consider the possible perturbations: Suppose (i) first sumption by Q At he s between sells ae'^'". that > a, Suppose that 0. and + t He does dt, t, the consumer changes his con- and invests a more dollars (per unit lime) t at dollars in the liquid asset. he consumes the extra dividend ore^''"'* and at ( + di not change his investment decision thereafter. His payoff will change by a[-»'(c-)+e-"^+^"^'(e^^'4 rdt)u'{r,^,,)]. Since (i(),/()) and dt is optimal, the change in payoff must be non-positive for every a going to zero which yields the standard Euler equation ^ (ii) Suppose now that in the liquid asset at = = (/i-rK(c.). Then 0. (B.5) the consumer can only increase his investment and therefore condition B.5 must be replaced by ^^<[l3-r)u'{ct). (iii) Consider a policy where At > for every t, (B.6) which will be the case in our candidate policy. (iiia) tion Suppose by a(l the illiquid will + /* > 0. If e) dollars Jisset between t and + dt, t the consumer changes his consump- and does not change his a+ more dollars in investment decision thereafter, his payoff (per unit time), invests a (with I* > 0) change by a[-a'(o)(l which must be non-positive for u'{ct){l + + r Rv'{c,]r-'''-''ds\,lt any a and so + ^)= r Ru{c,)e->^^'-'^d3. 33 (B.7) (iiib) Suppose now that consumption by — (1 /* 0. between If t and t + dt the e)a dollars (per unit time), invests and does not change dollars in the illiquid asset his < consumer changes a (with a + investment decision his < I' 0) his more thereafter*'^ payoff will change by a[-ti'(Q)(l which must be non-positive - + /~ e) any a and so for r u'{c,)(l-e)= (iiic) If /, = 0, then the u'{ct)(l (B.8) Ru'(c,)e-^'^'-'\ls. order condition reads as first - Rn{c,)t-'^^'-'^ds\dt < I" Ru'(c,)e-'^^'-"d3 < u'(ct)(l + (B.9) f). Step 3 Construction of the candidate policy Given Co, t^ A and we define the candidate optimal consumption plan as in equa- tion 4.3 — CqC (0 + \)t-p{t) Cf with u;{t) This consumption plan We now be completely defined once we specify will buy shares of the illiquid asset shares of the liquid asset between assets from Tj +A to oo. ^' ^' Jo -'Note that this perturbation indeed be positive for tj and From equations A will . motivate our definition of these parameters. plan, the agent will sell = every is 1 ~ + rj 4.2 optimalitv condition with respect to /( is it To finance this consumption He will buy and then to ri. A. Finally he will sell the illiquid follows tliat it t However the optimality condition with respect to and A. ' feasible only if A, (. -t- from cq, r^ is tit = > for for every < < n and /. < In the optimal policv, > n + A. For .4, this reason, written as an Euler equation (B.5 and B.6) while the an integral condition. 34 for t < Ti = At for Ti < i < Ti A..e^('-^''; = at f {y, - c, + RA,)e''^'^-'>^'^ds + A and At = /l.,+^e'""-'"^>+'^' /' + h^L5le''(^^->'^')ds; Jn+ti for Ti + A < From 1 at = e t. the above equations together with the transversality condition = lim ylfe-"*" we — get r yiZSi,-Mt)^t = e^^ r ^i^i^e-'^'c/f. — + Vri+A ^0 1 e I (B.IO) € Finally an+A = We define first A by r 6"'"'+^^ = 4.6 that {yt -Q+ (B.U) RAt)e-''^'Ut. is R-T ^l e = e -rA 1 + e 1 - e-'''^ r or equivalently Adding equations B.IO and B.ll define Co (as a function of ri, which together with e, r gives the intertemporal budget equation 4.4. We and R) from the intertemporal budget equation 4.4 4.6 yields the simpler equation 4.7 below Jo /o Finally we We now T and varies R define Ti show that by equation B.ll. this policy is well defined and admissible for belonging to a subset of their equilibrium values. smoothly with e, r and m where m is 35 defined by We e small and for will also show that it R= We will + me. r show the following lemma Lemma B.l Consider r. m and m* such m' / r' > thai 1 (recall that r* There exists equilibrium interest rate when transactions costs are zero). (q is the such that if < [i) (ii) the — \r' r| < cq and r^ R= the consumption plan for proof for the collapses to the optimal one for first e > = e 0. is uniquely defined, is C* well-defined is If 6 is in = and admissible. (c.r.m). 0, this consumption plan The admissible. admissibility of by continuity. will follow A note that the equation defining A Cq (C^) simple. is < -^mt r That plan €-'^ Therefore 7T!| are infinitely differentinhlc Proof: The intuition We £o \m' - eo, consumption plan defined above, where Moreover, A. < e - = can be written as — (B.13) -. m+r (f,r,m) and in verifies 0<A<A<A<'X) for eo sufficiently small. The equation '^y 1 giving Cq can be written as Rl + X + r 6 „-(Rr+\-*-uj,'lri Rl + \ + + + ffs 6 ,-(rX\4.^1^ 1 r iJJL \ + A - + A + ^Z -(r-l-\J-..-lA /("b u.' - \ * ^0 (B.14) with u;^ = ^ and 36 u;^ = i^. From equation B.14, It is fairly uniquely defined and is we can straightforward to show that m and for all values of r is obvious that Cq it is in > restrict to the set defined before, and for is C'°° in (f,r,m,ri). such that 6 all Ti [0,oo[, where A', a positive constant. We now turn to the equation defining + fV 1 Ri + \ + This equation can be written as Tj. - Co- flg^A + cB 1-€V° Ri + 8 Straightforward algebra shows that \ + Rb + ^ we can L.jL \ + 8) ^ ' rewrite this equation as ' y' (B.16) where /(., ., ., ., .) is a C°° function such that / = for e=0 and ||f|</Oin[0,.o] for all vedues of r, m and Consider equation B.16 _ g-(>+<)n The function g{.) : t (restricting €o Tx for e if necessary). A'/ A>A> a positive constant. = g-(A+u;)ri -> e-(*+-^^' _ g-(r + A+*)(n+A) - e-^'^+'^^* 0) that there exists C > _ g-(r + A+u;)(r, +A (B.17) ) _ has the following graph (see figure 5) Therefore this equation has a unique solution (given is such that Using the implicit function theorem, the fact that in (O.r*). rj n :^ r* - It is C aiul r^ easy to show ^ 0<A<A<A<oc \ _ t' and thp I T. l;u I that ||f|< A>in[0..ol for all values of r, m. for e < Co and and rj, we can show for all values of r that we can and m. Moreover, 37 define a C"" function ri(€,r,m) it is easy to show that 2^ < AVin 1 m uniformly in r and n <t' - (restricting cq n +A> C/2 and r* + if is Indeed when = However, particular meaning. defined positive limits as A(0,r.77j) = can be seen that 0, all assets are liquid A(e,r,77?). Given wealth (when e=0) grows + A,oo[ and We between at a rate A it Oj is is m) and A(0.r.n?). m is easy to calculate the time such that accumulated and ri(0.r.777) > > 0, .4^ We 0. to prove that ri(0.r.777) cq, t^ * A. vary smoothly with It is in [0,ri], /, < in above statements. we have easy to see that uniformly. Since n < Co (restricting + r* again = It show by continuity It\(=o + (/2 and (q), In [ri,ri -f A] again, at easily > /( recall that RAt + < is weU-defined and A, we have admissible, briefly sketch proofs of the In [0,ri], e = ni. To show that [ri e A), one can calculate ri(0,r,77r) directly from (or Therefore, the consumption plan ;•, close to its seen above ri(e,r,m) and A(e,r,m) have well- as m is and the switching times do not have any the no transactions costs case. This value ri(0,r,n!) e. m) Co(e, r, goes to zero. As seen from B.13, given e that. small. e straightforward to interpret the values of ri(0,r, less e it This implies in particular necessary). C/2, for Summarizing our discussion above, value. It [0,co] I h > and ;, 0. yt - ct 5(e,r,7n,f) where /t|,=o > 6» > g- in [0. r* which implies that .4, are very close to their that af > it it < in [r* > -CI\.t' ^ CI ^] in [ri,r* in [t* - C/4] 4-C/4,ri 38 + A]. f for j = €=0 and C/21. it follows that for 0. counterpart?. \\f <:\\\ > This implies that a, In [ti + + in [ti,Ti A]. A,oo[, simple calculations using Jt i — e show that ^ ''- ^^^ ' l-^Ua + A A+u;b .-u,r.r. .-w^,-u;„(t-(r.+A)l . ' ' Rb + X + ^.^''' .-.„-6t + i^' The continuity argument can be applied that It < while since 6 0, — u^b \ + > tj > in a compact ioi co small. It will set [r* + (12. T] to be negative if T is show large enough. Finally 1 - \ € Rb + Rb + ^'B and similar arguments show that At > sible. lemma This ends the proof of 0. \ + S Therefore the consumption plan is admis- n B.l. Step 4 Optimality of the control Having shown that our candidate optimal control we will show that it is is well defined and admissible, indeed optimal. For this purpose, we first show B.5-B.9. Lemma Proof: B.2 Our candidate It is control satisfies conditions B.5-B.9. obvious that in [0,ri] dlogit'ic) dt in [ri,ri + = f3-Rc<1- A] dlogu'ict) and that in \t\ + A, oof 39 that it satisfies dloca'ic,) dl Hence B.5-B.6 are For t G It t = u'{ct)e-^^'-'^J3 follows that B.8 For satisfied. + A,oo[ [ti r „ -, =lS- RB<l3-r. G [n,n + is r u'(ct) e-^^^'-' )j^_ "!(^_ "lQ)(l-f] R Rb satisfied. A) / 1 _ ^-'•(n+A-t) r(ri-lA-n 4-(l-£)- «'(q) In addition 1-e < R - 1 _ e-''^'^'^-" : r From equation B.12 we -r(r,+A-o , + (1 e)' < - R ^-""^ -rA i_e-'- e" + (1 ' r - 0' R get that + (l-,f-— = !-Ll. fl R (B.18) ^ r The - ' inequalities B.9 follow. Finally, for t € [0,rij, we have 1 _ e"— (^'-') R ,, ,1 _e- rA because of equation B.18. This proves equation B.7 and ends our proof of We now Lemma show that the candidate B.3 The candidaie Proof: To derive this policy policy lemma we is shall is lemma B.2. U indeed optimal. optimal. show that no perturbation policy can be utility enhancing. 40 of the candidate Consider an alternative policy We know 8ct from equations = R Jo u(ct), it + 6ct) next multiply equation B.19 by u{c, + Ct + 6c,. 8it - Sit - e(|/( + 8It\ - \h\). follows that < u{c,) £ Siy^'-'^ds + rI^ Siy^'-'Us / - f 6I,e^^'-'^d3 u(ct We induces consumption Jo Using the concavity of (r + 8it,It + SIt) which B.2 and B.3 that 4.2, j 8i,e^^'-'Us + T {it Sc,)e-^^^^^'ds < Jo 6it + - e"'''"'"-^", u'{ct) Sit - e(|/t + SIt\ integrate from f u(c,)e-<^'+"'rf5 + K,(t) - \It\)] to t, + (B.19) . and get Ki{t) Jo with K,{t) = j' „'(c.) ('' /' Sine'^'-'Uh - Si,) e'^'^^'^'ds and Ki(t) We = fu'ic,) (^R I' show that when will Shc'^'-^'Uh t - SI, - f(\It + SIt\ - |/,1)) e-^i^^^^'ds. goes to infinity, Ki{L) and Ki{t) are asymptotically non-positive. Integrating the second term of Ki(t) by parts, we get Jo V Jo Jo io Jo ds Therefore, A',(t) equals I^L\c,){r-^)+'^^^yi^Si,e-'\th)e-''ds-(f\ (B.20) We note that Sa,e-^' = [' Sinc-^'^dh. Jo 41 If a, > then condition B.5 holds and the integrand in the 0, above must be zero. — If a, 0, then the short sale constraint 6a, B.6 ensure that this integrand Sat must positive, for large be greater or equal than also t large enough. We For non-positive. is > t first > + A, Tj term of B.20 and condition tze = and thus This implies that the second term 0. have therefore proven that K,(t) is is non- non-positive for t. Consider now K[{t). Integrating by parts ihf Jo ^-{J^ > 0, |/, + we get u\c,)€-^''dh)^' -^ i,'{ci,)e-'''dh)6I,e-''ds. J\f^ equal to is If /, term, Jo 6he-''dh){l^ Therefore K[{t) first — RiT u'(c,)e->^'ds)(f SI,c-^'ds). > 81,, the + «) \I,\ > —61,, the integrand (-u'{c,){l - f) 6I,\ \I,\ ('-u'(cj(l + integrand in B.21 is (B.21) less or /"' Ru'{cH)e-'^^''-'^dh^ 61, equal to = by condition B.7. If /, < 0, \I, + 6I,\ — + is less or /~ i?u'(c/.)e-^"— equal to 61, = Ru'(c, )c-'*''-'^dh^6I, < './/i) by condition B.8. If /, = and 61, > 0, the integrand (-«'(c,)(l + €) + !" is by condition B.9. If /, = and 61, < 0, the integrand (^-u'(c,)(l - + is /~ i?u'(c/.)e"'-'"'"''^/') 42 ^I, < by condition B.9. Therefore the first term in K[{t) is less or equal to 0. For the second term, note that Jo and that 1-e Jt for ^ > Ti it R B. + A. Since 8 At small, _,/Ml-e is > -At, {SAt + At > 0), At -- + > t; > for e follows that A';(0 is asymp- erpi-u^Bt) and A u^-b clear that the term: -/2(^" u'{c,)e-^'ds){f SI,e-''ds) '0 is smaller that an arbitrary ^ totically non > for i large enough. positive. This concludes the proof of 43 It lemma B.3. D C Proofs of Proposition 4.2 and Lemmas and 4.3 4.4 Lemma Proof of C.l Suppose that r = r' and that 4.3 R = consumption small, the optimal at + r' From appendix Tn*e. time B, we know that for given by equation 4.7, which as is e we have seen can be rewritten as ^ ^ ^-(fi,.4X4-6)r, y p-(R[,+ \ + WL 1 Ri r A f The first )Ti 1 in iZ£, _(fij,+A4-#)rif „-(r*-H+u-)A r' u;r, term g ^ + + A + ] _ ^-(r*4-\4-u;)A + i?B B a- A + u,'g brackets (divided by y) can be written as A + ^ r' + A + 6 iZi:, + A + 6 Straightforward algebra shows that this term can be written as 1 1 _ ^nLzJl, ^ "'•--\e-^--r _ ^'+-\e-^-.n-^A-) + (C.2) o(.) or equivalently, as J_(l_c(Tn.*-r*) Similarly, the second P e -*•'</« -e(m* 4- r-) /* c"**'-/* + o(6) . ) (CI) term can be written as l-U-t{i-^)({m' -r') p e-'^'*'(/^ + (n7* + r-)/" ,^~^''*A + ''^A (C.4) Combining C.3 and C.4 we get equation 4.15 44 i.e. 4'' = Co y— + eCw + eC, + o{e) <t> with C\v and Cs given by 4.17 and 4.18. Integrating 4.17 hy parts ('H'-r') -(X+w*)f (e _ we get g-(A+*)( JO JQ r* j -rV + (m* + (e r': -(A + u-*)( _ -(A+«)f^ Tj'+A- + /~ — ((A + 6)e-''+*''-(A + Using equations 4.11 (substituting in from it'f brackets cancel out which yields equation and 3.5) 4. 16. u;-)e-''^'^*^'Wf) 4.1.3, we • find that the This concludes the proof of terms lemma 4.3. Proof of Proposition C.2 Consider r* and 4.2 m* where 7V = 1 r 1 The results of Appendix B imply that + - e -r'\' e-^-^* for e sufficienty small and for r and m be- longing to a neighborhood of r* and m*, the consumption plan defined in Proposition 4.1 is indeed well-defined, admissible and optimal. These results also imply that h is '0 C°° in these variables. We know that F(0,r*,m*) = ((1 -k) — .k — r' It is also easy to see that '15 r' ). ^(0,r.m)=^(0,r.nO7^0 am am (if e = 0. r is kept constant and ni and the proportion of the wealth changes, as it is and in liquid the total wealth if is kept constant changes) and that illiquid assets —Ur^(0,r.m) + —or ^(0.7-.r77)^0 (a change in the is e = case). Therefore the Jacobian invertible It is e, We now e dFi df:^ Or Or dFi dF2 dm din how and prove lemma at the point r and 7tj 4.2. wealth changes when total (O.r'.m*). Moreover, small there exists an equilibrium. which establishes proposition calculate at least matrix and we can apply the impUcit function tlieorem thus clear that for are C°° in C.3 non-zero effect on the total stock of wealth, in interest rate has a changes for fixed e r* and m* 4.4. Lemma Proof of 4.4 Adding the equations describing the evolution of diet + A,) = \{at + at At) and At we +h+ get It dt = (A + r){at + At) + {R- Multiplying by e"^', integrating from appendix B) that r \{at (at + Jo Equation C.5 + r)At to oc At)€~^' goes to zero as At]e-'\{t r= - f" e-''(c, ^ f -^ ]h and - c, - nsiiis; (I,. tlie Inrt goes to infinity, fl/J - ijt we (.'staMi' get -{R-r)A,)dt (C.5) r Jo will allow us to calculate total assume that we are at (e,r*,m*). 46 wealth as a function of e. We will /;e->.,.,../;-e-'.(^-,M,)-/;^..-«.(^ -...) = (C.6) = Co Co ^ m* - / + ^-(x+w.K^ + e-'^+-^K.L_i )•• 1 A +u;' (C.7| Replacing for Co, we get r e-^'ctdt = Jo g ^ 0*(A+u;*) (C.8) Using C.5, C.6 and C.8, Fi + it is F2 to the transactions costs We easy to find the sensitivity of total asset e. The equations next derive the expression for b — in'. in Ipuinia 4.4 follow. For this purpose we differentiate the equilibritim condition Fi + F2 = r \e-^'{at + At)dt Jo = il- k)- + r 47 (iriiuiiid k— + me r I Note that when with respect to e. change. Hence we d{Fr + changes, the cquilibrimn mines of F2) , + 1-° Fe a(Fi4-F,), —IJT-''-*^ -{1 - k)-U=o{b - - /n') + "^ is and ;7?*will le=o or m - U=o - m*) + £^|,.o + '"*)• dc m independent of T -I 1.^0^1,^0 J,n \.=o{{b , dm F,), ^ + ^ ^ d(F--F,) ^2) + d{F, .^ - (r 4- 7ne)2 Using the fact that Fi + F2 ^ at ^, k r ^(^1 r' get , = e ) = for e = 0, 6 - D r' we have m ) m'D k— r* . r* Using the notation of subsection 4.2.3 we get We can calculate OiF + F,) , 5 U^o from F^ + F2 S = ( and derive (6 — + (jj a- )(f> m'). The right-hand is A — side is positive. Therefore (6 negative and — m') is it is easy to see that the coefficient of (6- m*) negative. D 48 D If Proof of Lemma k increases, obviously 4.5 A* decreases. Moreover t* increases and t' + A* decreases. These can be seen from equations 4.11 and 4.12 with very simple algebra. Equation 4.13 implies then that m' increases. Simple algebra then shows that decreases, exp(—(\ + i.e. u!)t) the effect of — exp(-(A e 4- on r* (6 is — m*) which stronger. is to: (Note that the function 6)t) increases in [0,r*] 49 proportional and that Ti < r*).) g{.) : t -^ D The Case k=l E The a case first = /c 1 is We slightly different. find, as before, that transactions costs The order effect on the rate of return on the illiquid asset. case (0 < A; < that 1) is if that cannot be sold short, by zero-th order term. its (i.e. for this result is that the Since we introduce a we have of economy in zero supply, minimum The reason a zero-th order liquidity premium.) holding period has a is first order length. held in the form of the illiquid asset, we have: .'It The dynamics difference with the return will be lower than the return on the ilUquid asset of the consumer's wealth all liquid asset in this have = Wt are described by: iCt (iw, ct = yt = + + Xwfdt Rtu't - Ifdt - It (E-1) t\It\ Proposition E.l describes the optimal policy of the consumer for small transactions costs and for a subset of values of R that are of interest, i.e. such that its equilibrium value belong to this subset. Proposition E.l asset until T\ until e small and for R bclovging to a subset of its optimal policy has the following form.: The consumer buys the the values, For an age an age The proof Tj rj. + He does nothing A when he (i.e. he consumes his income yt possible {illiquid) + Rwt) from starts selling the asset until he dies. of proposition E.l analogous to the proof of proposition 4.1 and is is therefore omitted. In will what follows, we will (briefly) discuss tlip implications of proposition show how the consumption Cj as well as the width of the inaction f perio<l J. W-- A 'an he derived. In the case k equation 4. .3 = I, the expression for consumption to ct = coe-'*'^" 50 t < r, c, must be changed from Q = Rwt + Again the initial consumption co n < yt A < n + i (E.2) can be obtained from the intertemporal budget equation which in this case can be written as r\y, r 'i^e-^^^Ut + -f i •'0 'o e c.)e-''<')c/.' f + ^l^.-"',, ^ y^+A Jri 1 — (E.3) q € where p{t) p(t) = Rl + = + /? p(0 - X ioT A for /?s + < ri A for < t < < Ti Ti ri + A + A < i and ^(0= This intertemporal budget equation evolution of analysis is ivt, Ti. doing utility if is < very similar to the case A condition This consumer so. is < 1 and is omitted. between investing in the illiquid asset starts selling the illiquid asset at he buys one unit of the illiquid asset at Tj From equations between consumption fc age at rj E.l'* «'n+A is and E.2 we and consumption = ^ = n-.^r at -^ n + also given 24 Note that /( = between t^ and is n+ of order A. 51 e: and not A, the change in his by equation 4.5 and get that the following relation age = r^ + A . . Equations 4.5 and E.4 yield the following relation which shows that the period of holding the illiquid asset The derived by the portfolio decision of a consumer of indifferent is Given that he equal to zero. derived from the equation describing the is using our results on the investment policy of the consumer. The parameter age tp{s)ds Jo '0 (L.ll minimum (\ Having characterized tlie 2e i/'* A = + uj'){S -u.-) + A (E.5) n(f) solution to the consumer"? problem we turn to the equi- hbriuni determination of R. In equilibrium, asset demand r Xe-^'ivtdt /o equals asset market value. As before, we D I R. consider small transactions costs (small values of will their first order effects on R. We Proposition b. Proposition E.2 equation E.6, with The proof b E.'2 and find thus write: will = R{c) and calculate e), r' + gives us 6. R is In equilibrium. ^ be (E.6) o(f) uniquely determined. has the form of It having an ambiguous sign. of proposition E.2 as well as the analytic expression for 6 are again omitted. The discussion on the determination of 6 we do not present it here. Instead, focus on the determination of the rate of return on a liquid asset that in this an similar to the discussion offered at the 4.2.2, (the eflects are similar) so end of subsection we is economy in zero supply. Proposition asset, as well as the implicit liquidity Proposition E.3 In the rate of return Proposition for this result on gives us the rate of return on such premium. and on the liquid asset that the we have minimum the liquiditij a zeroth order litiuidity premium. holding period has a = r- - — 4-0(1) A = r* first i^'* 52 ffrrl The order length. ^o(l) -.4^ < mi prrwium. show that r introduced equilibrium, transactions costs hnrr a zrrolh order E..3 states that is E..3 is reason We can a = A- + 53 0(1). References Aiyagari, S. Rao and Mark Certler (1991), "Asset Returns with Transactions Costs and Uninsured Individual Risk: A Stage Monetary III Exercise', Journal of Economics, 27:309-331. Allen, Franklin and Douglas Gale (1988), "Optimal Security Design", Review of Financial Studies, 1,3:229-263. Amihud, Yakov and Haim Mendelson ( 1986), "Asset Pricing and the Bid- Ask Spread", Journal of Financial Economics, 17,2:223-219. .•\miliud, Yakov and Haim Mendelson Securities Returns and \'alues'\ (1990), "The Effects of a Transaction Tax on mimeo. Amihud, Yakov and Ilaim Mendelson (1991a), "Liquidity. Maturity and the Yields on U.S. Government Securities", Journal of Finance, 46,4:1411-1425. Amihud, Yakov and Ilaim Mendelson (1991b), cial Policy", Financial "Liquidity, Asset Prices and Finan- Analysts Journal, November-December:56-66. Amihud, Yacov, Haim Mendelson and Gang Yu (1992), "Income Uncertainty and Transaction Costs", New York University, mimeo. Blanchard, Olivier (1985), "Debt, Deficits and Finite Horizons", Journal of Political Economy, 193,2:223-247. Blanchard, Olivier and Stanley Fisher, "Lectures on Macroeconomics", MIT Press, 1989. Boudoukh, Jacob and Robert Whitelaw (1901). T/»f Bmrhwark Japanese Government Bond Market", Journal of Fixed Income, Efjfi n, ih. Spptpnil>f-r:.')J- 59. Boudoukh, Jacob and Robert Whitelaw (1992). "Liquidity as a Choice \'ariahlr: A Lesson from the Japanese Government Bond Market", forthcoming, Review of Financial Studies. 54 Brennan, Michael (1975), "The Opfimal Number of Securiiies folio in a Risky Asset Fori- when there are Fixed Costs of Transacting: Theory and Some Empirical Resxdts'', Journal of Financicd and Quantitative Analysis, Septembcr:483-496. Constantinides, Georges (1986) "Capital Market Eqvtlibrium with Transaction Costs.", Journal of Political Economy, 94,4,December:842-862. Davis, Mark and Andrew Norman (1990) "Fortfolio Selection with Transaction Costs", Mathematics of Operations Research. Duffie, Darell and T. Sun (1989), "Transactions Costs and Fortfolio Choice m a Discrete-Continuous Time Setting", mimeo, Stanford University. Duffie, Darrell tracts", and Matthew Jackson (1989), "Optimal Innovation of Futures Con- Review Dumas, Bernard and of Financial Studies, 2:27-5-296. Elisa Luciano (1991), An Exact Solution to the Fortfolio Choice Froblem Under Transactions Costs", Journal of Finance, 46,2.June:577-595. Fleming, Wendell, Sanford Grossman, Jean-Luc Vila and Thaleia Zariphopoulon (1992), "Optimal Portfolio Rebalancing with Transaction Costs", mimeo. Mas- sachusetts Institute of Technology. Fremauit, Anne (1991), "Stock and Stock Index Futures Trading in an Equilibrium Model with Entry Costs", mimeo, Boston University. Goldsmith, David (1976), "Transactions Costs and the Theory of Portfolio Selection", Journal of Finance, 31:1127-1139. Grossman, Sanford and Jean-Luc Vila (1992), "Optimal Investment Strategies with Leverage Constraints", Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis. J7.J. June:151-168. Ileaton, John and D. Lucas (1992)., "Evaluating the Effects of Incomplete Markrls mi Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing", mimeo. Massachusetts Institute of Technology. He, Hua and come: A H. Pages (1991) "Consumption/ Investm.ent Decisions with Labor InDuality Approach", mimeo. 55 Haim Levy, (1978), "Equilibriam in an Imperfect Market: ber of Securities in the Portfolio", A Constraint on the Num- American Economic Review, September:643- 658. Mayshar, Joram (1979), ''Transactions Costs in a Model of Capital Mar-ket Equilib- I rium", JournaJ of Political Economy, 87:673-700. | Maysliar. Joram (1981), "Transactions Costs and the Pricing of Assets", .Journal of Finance, 36:583-597. Mehra. R. and Edward Prescott (1985), "The Equity Premium: A Puzzle". Journal Monetary Economics. 15:145-162. of Michaely. Roni and Jean-Luc \'ila (1992), and Trading Volume: Evidence from "Tax Heterogeneity. Transactions Costs the E.r-Diridend Day", mimeo, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Ohashi, Kazuhiko (1992,) Fee", "Efficient mimeo, Meissachusetts Futures Innovation with Small Transaction Institute of Technology. Pagano, Marco (1989), "Endogenous Market Thinness and Stock Price Volatility'', Review of Economic Studies, 56:269-288. Silber, William (1991), "Discounts on Restricted Stock: The Impact of Illiquidity on Stock Prices", Financial Analysts Journal, July-August:60-64. Tuckman, Bruce and Jean-Luc Vila ( 1992), ".4r6i/rn^e with Holding Costs: A Utility- Based Approach", Journal of Finance. 47.4:1283-1302. Vila, Jean-Luc and Thaleia Zariphopoulou (1090). "Optimal Consumption and vestment with Borrowmg Constraints", mimeo. Massachusetts Instjtutp ..| [n. |.-. ||. nology. Wang, Jiang (1992), ".4 Model of Competitive Stock Trading \'olume". mimeo. Mas- sachusetts Institute of Technology. 56 Figure 1: IIoldinEs of the liquid ;< and illiquid assets o 0.0 0.: 0.1 0.3 Figure 0.4 2: 0.7 0.6 0.5 Rates of return as functions of k This figure plots the rates of return as a function of the fraction, assets. costs. dashed The solid line represents the The dotted 0.9 0.8 bencmark case where there line represents the rate of return line represents the rate of on the /c, are no transactions illiquid asset = 2%; 6 = 4%; l3 while the return on the liquid asset. For this figure we have used the following parameter values: A of illiquid = 0.2%; .4 58 = 1; D/Y = 50%: r = 3%. 1.0 o 0.0 0.1 Figure 3: Rates of return as functions of k This figure plots the rates of return as a function of the fraction, The assets. costs. solid line represents the The dotted line represents bencmaik k, of illiquid case where there are no transactions the rate of return on the dashed line represents the rate of return on the liquid illiquid asset while the asset. For this figure we have used the following parameter values: A Compared = in 6 = 40%; (3 = 2%; A= to the previous case, the agent shorter horizon. than 20%; As a result, the interest rate 1: is D/Y = 50%: f = 3%. more impatient and has therefore a and the liquidity premium are higher the previous figure. Qualitative results are however unchaiiKcd. 59 o 0.0 Figure 4: Rates of return as functions of k Tliis figure plots the rates of assets. costs. dashed The return as a function of the fraction, k, of illiquid solid line represents the The dotted line represents bencmark case where there are no transactions the rate of return on the illiquid asset while the line represents the rate of return on the liquid asset. For this figure we have used the following parameter values: A = 2%; 6 = 4%; /3 In this case (where financial the following paradoxical = A = 0.2%; income phenomenon is 1: D/Y = ?.m%: f = 3%. much morr import nnl than labor occurs: transactions rost? lower return on both assets. GO tlic iii<<tiiic| rairs of Oi Figure 2935 5: The graph 5 61 o( g(t) MIT 3 1060 LIBRARIES 00fiSb2fciM M Date Due APR. S^P 3 1 BASEwi^NTv CfQi 1999 Lib-26-67