PUBLIC-PRIVATE GOVERNANCE, UNCERTAINTY AND LONGEVITY IMPLICATIONS: EXPLORING WATER SECTOR PARTNERSHIPS IN THE DEVELOPING WORLD Ilze Kivleniece Imperial College London South Kensington Campus, London SW7 2AZ ilze.kivleniece@gmail.com Working Paper to be presented at the Tilburg Law and Economics Center (TILEC) Workshop on “Economic Governance and Organizations” June 6-7, 2013 Tilburg ABSTRACT While public-private ties are increasingly recognized as novel organizational forms for governing economic exchange across public and private sector boundaries, little is known on how organizational actors select among different public-private governance alternatives, and what are the long term performance implications of these choices. We build on a theoretical distinction between integrative versus autonomous public-private organizational forms to investigate how different forms of exogenous environmental uncertainty affect the emergence of alternative public-private governance structures and their subsequent longevity. Our results, derived from public-private water sector partnerships in the developing world, suggest that a hybridization of underlying governance allows organizational actors and private actors, specifically, to differentially address market-based as well as political and social contingencies. While political uncertainty is shown to be associated with autonomous public-private governance choice, high market-based volatility is linked strongly with adoption of integrative public-private arrangements. Overall, our study highlights the critical impact that institutional, not just transactional, alignment between governance features and ex ante external environment conditions plays in the formation and duration of underlying organizational ties. 2 INTRODUCTION Recent studies draw increasing attention to the phenomenon of interorganizational or hybrid governance forms recognizing that they may exhibit a distinct rationale and a high degree of variation on governance dimensions far beyond the intermediate values assigned to them by traditional „markethierarchy” or “public-private” dichotomies (Demil & Lecocq, 2006; Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012; Makadok & Coff, 2009). Nascent insights on public-private organizational ties, in particular, point to governance forms that cross or fuse elements and features of private hierarchies and public bureaucracies into novel organizational constellations with divergent ownership, authority and incentive strength (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012; Rufin & Rivera-Santos, 2010). Yet, few empirical studies exist on the determinants of public-private governance variation and the long term performance implications of these relationships, particularly from a private actor’s perspective. This lack of insights lies in a stark contrast to literature on private-private or interfirm organizational relations, such as alliances or joint-ventures, where a large amount of studies are dedicated to the antecedents of interorganizational boundary choices, such as contractual, relational and equity based arrangements (e.g. Folta, 1998; Hagedoorn & Hesen, 2007; Hennart, 1988; Oxley, 1997; Pisano, 1989), as well as their stability, longevity and performance implications (e.g. Ariño, 2003; Gulati, 1998; Lunnan & Haugland, 2008; Zollo, Reuer, & Singh, 2002). In the present study, we built on the theoretical insights on public-private ties as distinct, discrete hybrid governance alternative (Henisz, 2006; Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012) to investigate empirically how different forms of market and institutional environment based uncertainty are associated with a rise of different forms of public-private organizational structures and their varying longevity. We purposefully adopt a broad conceptual definition of public-private ties as any long-term contractual relationship between one or more private actors and public bodies that relies on private sector resources and competences for a direct provision of a public good or service.1 We likewise build on and acknowledge insights from prior studies, particularly in the field of economics and public policy, 1 We acknowledge that public-private collaboration may also occur through more specific research-based ties, such as firmuniversity partnerships geared towards scientific knowledge creation and sharing between public and private organizations. In the present study, we do not directly address this particular form of ties specifically, them representing a subject of a growing number of studies in research and innovation literature. 3 dedicated to public-private boundary decisions and their economic welfare implications (see, for example, Chong, Huet, & Saussier, 2006; Chong, Huet, Saussier, & Steiner, 2006; Guasch, 2004; Guasch, Laffont, & Straub, 2007, 2008; Zarco-Jasso, 2010). Our focus, nevertheless, is different and complementary by adopting a predominantly private actor’s perspective and investigating, specifically, the role of environmental uncertainty in the formation and longevity of public-private structures as hybrid governance forms. In doing so, we hope to bring to light the multi-faceted nature and effects of environmental uncertainty – not only market-based, but also broader institutional – affecting both the formation of public-private ties (Rangan, Samii, & Van Wassenhove, 2006), as well as their subsequent performance. Prior literature has tended to associate the presence of substantial environmental uncertainty with a restricted recourse to hybrid governance arrangements and strong preferences for vertical integration, particularly so, in mature industries (Folta, 1998; Williamson, 1991). Yet, large part of public-private interaction takes place in relatively mature, highly asset-specific infrastructure sectors (Kwak, Chih, & Ibbs, 2009), making hybrid forms of public-private interaction appear considerably more prevalent in these settings than a formal recourse to theory would suggest. Moreover, from political or nonmarket strategy viewpoint, the unpredictability stemming from institutional or political environment, in particular, has been argued to lead to significant impediment of private actor involvement in public domains of interest (Henisz, 2002; Henisz & Zelner, 2001; Levy & Spiller, 1996; Savedoff & Spiller, 1999). This view, however, contrasts with increasing evidence of extensive and diverse public-private contractual ties formed by private firms and public sector in environments characterized by substantial market or political volatility, such as the developing world (George, McGahan, & Prabhu, 2012; Lenssen & Van Wassenhove, 2012; Rangan et al., 2006). We address these opposing views by hypothesizing that, rather than limiting the engagement or internalizing exchange, organizational actors are able to respond to different facets of environmental uncertainty by “hybridizing” the governance, that is selectively adapting its key features, such as the degree of shared property rights or authority form, to at least partially mitigate the potential hazards. We build on a theoretical distinction between integrative versus autonomous public-private 4 governance forms – two conceptually different hybrid arrangements in terms of underlying operational and financial model, as well as features related to authority, property rights and strength of incentives (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012) - to illustrate how the likelihood of adopting these arrangements and their stability is likely to vary depending on the environmental contingencies surrounding the exchange, particularly so, from a private actor’s perspective. We, first, distinguish among market-based and institutional uncertainty as two fundamental types of exogenous environmental uncertainty affecting public-private governance choices. Furthermore, we theorize on two related, yet, distinct facets of institutional uncertainty – political uncertainty, a well established concept, referring to the feasibility of public policy or regime change (Fitzpatrick, 1983; Henisz, 2004; Henisz & Delios, 2004), and social uncertainty or volatility, a separate notion we develop to refer to the extent of variation and feasibility of social dispute or contestation arising and affecting the underlying exchange. Our core hypotheses rest on the argument that, from a private actor’s perspective, each of these different facets of exogenous environmental uncertainty is likely to lead to a choice of public-private governance structure with radically different features, deemed as better fit to cope with underlying contingencies. Hence, high political uncertainty (few political constraints) is expected to stimulate adoption of autonomous public-private governance choices, while high social and market-based volatility – integrative public-private arrangements. Moreover, we predict that the degree of structural alignment or fit between the selected public-private governance structure and the underlying environmental contingencies will be a critical determinant of underlying partnership duration or longevity. We investigate our hypotheses by examining long-term public-private contractual engagements in international water industry, covering fifty-four developing world countries. Our results illustrate that alternative hybrid forms of public-private governance co-exist with each form able to differentially address the type of contingencies surrounding the exchange. Based on the empirical context set in the developing world, our findings illustrate that organizational actors in these environments are able to economize and intentionally select public-private governance structures and features deemed as more fit in the light of underlying environmental hazards, particularly so, from the private actors 5 perspective. We find support for our hypotheses that high political uncertainty (low level of political constraints) may be associated with higher preferences for autonomous public-private governance alternatives, while high market-based volatility – with an inverse, opposing inclination towards integrative public-private arrangements. Moreover, our empirical findings suggest (even if mixed in evidence) the critical impact that initial structural alignment between governance features and the prevailing institutional, not just transaction-specific environment characteristics carries on the subsequent duration or longevity of observed public-private ties. From a broader theoretical perspective, our study contributes the emerging view on hybrid organizational forms as complex, multi-dimensional arrangements exhibiting divergent governance features, entailing a complex set of trade-offs and a differing ability to address the contingencies surrounding the exchange. It also contributes to clarify and expand the notion of exogenous environmental uncertainty by disentangling the underlying sources of uncertainty in governance choice and highlighting the role of structural alignment beyond market-based transaction characteristics to encompass contingencies from broader institutional environment. The paper is structured as follows: we start with an overview of theoretical background and develop a set of hypotheses related to governance choice under different facets of environmental uncertainty, as well as longevity implications under potential governance (mis)alignment to these environmental characteristics. We proceed with a review of methodology and empirical results. The paper concludes with a discussion on implications, limitations and future research directions. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND AND HYPOTHESES Uncertainty, as one of the central issues that organizations seek to cope with (March & Cyert, 1963; Podolny, 1994; Thompson, 1967), has long been acknowledged to play a key role in the formation and structure of alternative organizational forms, particularly, from comparative institutional analysis and transaction cost perspectives. Manifesting through a lack of information and predictability on future states of nature, given a specific decision-making scenario (Henisz & Delios, 2004; Milliken, 1987), uncertainty is argued to substantially alter and restrict the choice of organizational structures, particularly, in relation to a varying degree to which the underlying 6 structures are able to address the problem of costly adaptation to unforeseen disturbances surrounding the exchange (Geyskens, Steenkamp, & Kumar, 2006; Walker & Weber, 1984; Williamson, 1991). An exogenous environmental uncertainty in an exchange setting arises whenever the contingencies surrounding the exchange are perceived as too unpredictable to be determined ex ante and specified in the contract, and are generally outside the control of the organization facing it (Folta, 1998; Geyskens et al., 2006; Krishnan, Martin, & Noorderhaven, 2006). Yet, as a number of scholars point out, the exact effect of environmental uncertainty in the choice of hybrid governance structures remains unclear (Delmas & Tokat, 2005; Sutcliffe & Zaheer, 1998). While, on one hand, it calls for more hierarchical, independent forms of governance due to underlying costly adaptation problem (Williamson, 1991), on another - environmental uncertainty is also increasingly recognized to induce firms to engage in both market and hybrid forms of arrangements in order to sustain flexibility, particularly, in fast changing, knowledge-dependent environments (Folta, 1998; Geyskens et al., 2006). Environmental Uncertainty in the Context of Public-Private Interaction These opposing theoretical views on the effect of environmental uncertainty on hybrid governance structures are particularly evident in the analysis of public-private ties as a novel, discrete form of interorganizational engagements (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012). Prior literature has predominantly associated the presence of substantial environmental uncertainty with a limited recourse to hybrid governance arrangements and strong preferences for vertical integration, at least so, in mature industries (Folta, 1998; Williamson, 1991). Yet, in the context of public-private exchange, market-based environmental uncertainty or conditions where no odds can be placed on the future demand or the viability of the technological solution have been increasingly acknowledged to facilitate the collaboration between the two sectors (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012, Rangan et. al., 2006). A growing, even if dispersed empirical evidence illustrates how a range of industries, including relatively mature, highly asset-specific public infrastructure sectors, have witnessed a burgeoning rise in public-private governance arrangements (Henisz, 2006; Kwak et al., 2009) far beyond what a formal recourse to transaction cost theory would predict. 7 Furthermore, important theoretical concerns regarding the feasibility of public-private actor engagements have also been cast in relation to uncertainty stemming from the institutional or political environment, argued, typically, to represent a significant impediment to private actor entry into the domains of public interest (Henisz, 2002; Henisz & Zelner, 2001; Levy & Spiller, 1996; Savedoff & Spiller, 1999). Yet, public-private ties are paramount or, at least, strongly advocated in many settings characterized by substantial market and political volatility, such as, for example, public-private partnerships in the developing world (George et al., 2012; Lenssen & Van Wassenhove, 2012; Rangan et al., 2006). To address these contrasting perspectives, we build on nascent theoretical insights on the role of environmental uncertainty in the choice of public-private governances modes (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012; Rangan et al., 2006) to argue that they underscore the co-existence of different forms of publicprivate governance able to differentially address various facets of environmental uncertainty as the answer to the hybrid governance puzzle. From a theoretical perspective, we investigate governance under uncertainty by disentangling the notion of environmental uncertainty into a more fine-grained set of contingencies surrounding public-private ties as hybrid governance forms. More specifically, we differentiate between market-based and institutional uncertainty, decomposing the latter into two further, distinct categories. We focus not only on the effect of potential political or regime change (proxied through the level of political constraints), but, likewise, on a distinct set of contingencies arising from a variation and feasibility of social dispute or contestation in relation to underlying exchange – a notion we term as social volatility. Our approach, hence, exposes environmental uncertainty as a multilayered variable, carrying different implications for alternative public-private as hybrid governance choices. At last, we also predict different longevity implications for public-private arrangements in respect to the extent the selected organizational structures may be deemed as (mis)aligned with surrounding environmental contingencies. Public-Private Governance as A Hybrid Organizational Form As collaborative engagements or ventures between state or other public bodies and private organizations, public-private ties represent hybrid governance arrangements, in a sense of using the 8 resources and governance features of more than one independent organization (Borys & Jemison, 1989). However, in contrast to joint ventures and other types of private interorganizational forms, public-private arrangements as hybrid forms occupy a different location in the governance space, located between public and private hierarchies (Henisz, 2006; Williamson, 1999), and, as a result, feature a specific set of characteristics (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012). In Figure 1, we illustrate how this reasoning follows and extends Williamson’s (1999) classical governance spectrum. In it, public bureaucracies are recognized as an extreme form of organization, distinct from private hierarchy. Then, regulation is added as an intermediate form of organization, “akin to hybrid mode in the markets and hierarchies” but possessing “a syndrome of attributes that are located between polar modes of public and private bureaus” (Williamson, 1999: 335-336), such as intermediate strength of incentives, high degree of administrative controls, mediocre propensity toward probity, or compliance to public sector goals and a semi-legalistic dispute settlement regime. Public-private arrangements, we refer to, correspond to this governance space, yet, go beyond the regulation to encompass a broader set of direct interorganizational ties between public and private organizations. Following Makadok & Coff (2009), who delineate hybrid organizational forms as structures between the market and hierarchy that are „market-like” in some respects and „hierarchylike” in others (rather than as intermediate forms in unidimensional space à la Williamson (1991)), hybrid public-private arrangements are „public-like” in some respects and „private-like” in other, resulting in configurations that may exhibit radically different features in terms of fundamental governance dimensions. ------------------------------------------------Insert Figure 1 about here ------------------------------------------------In assessing this public-private as hybrid governance variation, we draw on the theoretical typology developed by Kivleniece & Quélin (2012), according to which public-private ties can be classified into two conceptual categories of contrasting hybrid public-private governance forms integrative versus autonomous – each featuring a distinct, internally consistent blend of operational model, financing or revenue model, and resulting in different fundamental governance features, such 9 as property rights, incentive structures and authority (Holmstrom & Milgrom, 1994; Makadok & Coff, 2009). Of these dimensions, we argue, at least three are directly observable and empirically identifiable – 1) operational model, referring to the underlying division of tasks and coordination among public and private actor, either predominantly private or shared jointly with the public partner, 2) financial or revenue model, either end-user or public payment based, and being a strong indicator of the type of efficiency incentives prevailing under each type or arrangement, and 3) ownership model, being either predominantly (or temporarily) private or predominantly public (shared) (see Figure 2 in Appendix for a graphical overview of the two conceptual public-private hybrid forms along these dimensions). According to this typology, autonomous forms of public-private ties, characterized by relatively independent set of operations run by private actor, an end-user based financing model, and limited, largely supervisory role of public actors, represent a hybrid form of governance featuring a mix of relatively high-powered incentives, extensive private authority and relatively broad private property rights (at least, temporarily). Integrative forms of public-private ties, by contrast, feature a more integrated set of operations between public and private counterparts, with public financing model and substantive control by public actors, resulting in effectively weaker productivity incentives, shared property rights and authority (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012). Both of these hybrid public-private governance forms, we argue, may represent theoretically viable organizational models, yet, from the perspective of organizational actors involved, as governance alternatives remain unclear. While in a number of public sectors the choice between these alternative structures may be predetermined by the nature of underlying services (e.g. hospital and incarceration facilities typically relying on integrative public-private engagements that retain a large degree of public sector involvement), in majority of public-private collaboration contexts the underlying choice between governance alternatives is not pre-determined (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012). Moreover, the performance or longevity implications associated with these ex ante governance choices are likewise not clear. We address these questions below by linking the selection between two conceptual public-private hybrid governance alternatives to different types of exogenous environmental uncertainty, and by predicting different longevity implications for public-private 10 arrangements in respect to the extent the adapted organizational structures may be (mis)aligned with underlying environmental contingencies. Public-Private Governance under Institutional Uncertainty We start by identifying and assessing the effects of two distinct facets of uncertainty stemming from the institutional environment – political uncertainty and social uncertainty (or volatility). Political Uncertainty. Because of their very nature, ties intersecting public and private organizational boundaries and interests are particularly susceptible to adverse development and lack of stability in the political landscape. Any form of political uncertainty – understood as difficult-toanticipate, important discontinuities in the business environment that may occur as a result of political change (Fitzpatrick, 1983), can substantially alter the effectiveness and outcomes of collaboration, particularly so from the private actor’s perspective. Henisz & Delios (2004) point out to at least two distinct sources of such uncertainty – political hazards and regime change – which both can impact significantly the continuity and past commitments made within public-private exchange, such as the level of investments, proprietary rights to assets or the degree of effort exercised by public counterparts. Political uncertainty is argued to stem from the structure of country’s existing political institutions, which may provide either substantial or limited discretion to policy-makers, depending on the extent to which there exist competing, independent political institutions that may constrain the arbitrary or even opportunistic behaviour by public actors (Henisz, 2004; Henisz, 2002). If such political constraints are limited, there is “a higher likelihood that status-quo policies that affect […] costs, revenues and asset value will change” (Henisz & Delios, 2004).2 In the context of public-private collaboration, as Holburn & Vander Bergh (2008: 531) point out, political uncertainty “creates challenges for firms and investors when the performance of marketbased investment strategies depends on long-term policy stability and predictability, as is particularly the case in infrastructure industries”. Because of the long-term, resource- and asset-specific 2 It is important to note, that from a theoretical perspective, the notion of „political uncertainty” is distinct from and not necessarily aligned with the level of democratic development in the respective environment. Hence, a democratic system with a high concentration of political power (e.g. in legislative and executive branches) may exhibit few political constraints and not necessarily be more certain (from a private actor’s perspective) than a more autocratic system. 11 investments characterizing most of public-private engagements, lack of ex ante predictability on policy environment raises concerns of costly ex post adaptation and rent redistribution. The effect of political uncertainty, from a private actor’s perspective, then, boils down to a problem of credible commitment on public actor’s side - if few political constraints exist to prevent the ex post policy change, few incentives exist for private actors to engage in relations with public actors that feature high dependence on public sector commitments. As an outcome of heightened political uncertainty, existing literature has tended to predict reduced or even absent private actor investment in public domains such as infrastructure services – at least from a privatization viewpoint (Henisz, 2002; Levy & Spiller, 1994; Spiller, 1993). The focus on privatization as (an extreme) form of vertical integration, however, has tended to obscure the view on more complex hybrid arrangements involving long-term contractual ties between public and private counterparts. As Kivleniece & Quélin (2012) point out, in the context of public-private ties, heightened political uncertainty is expected to lead towards preferences for governance arrangements that lessen the dependence of private actors on their public sector counterparts, while still retaining the underlying binding ties. In terms of autonomous versus integrative public-private governance choice, it implies increased preferences for autonomous forms of public-private ties, characterized by a higher degree of autonomy in which the private actor operates, less scope and opportunities for an interference of public authorities, and typically, an adaption of neoclassical institutional mechanisms, such as arbitration panels, for contract enforcement and renegotiation (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012). We refine this theoretical insight by associating the extent of political uncertainty with the feasibility of policy and regime change - dependant, in turn, on the extent of political constraints in the political environment (Henisz, 2000a, 2002; Henisz & Zelner, 2006). More specifically, we predict that in environments with fewer institutional “checks and balances”, and, hence, heightened likelihood of policy or regime change, public-private collaboration is expected to be organized in the form of autonomous structures with stronger private actor’s authority, more property rights assigned to private sector, yet, still retained public actor oversight and involvement. Such a governance setup, compared to more integrated forms, will serve to reduce the bargaining power asymmetries between public and 12 private counterparts, lessen the scope of public actor’s discretionary action within the collaboration, provide higher flexibility to private actors for ex post adjustments, while, simultaneously, still securing public actor engagement in a binding bilateral engagement. Hypothesis 1: The greater the feasibility of policy or regime change (i.e. the fewer the political constraints), the higher the likelihood of autonomous forms of public-private ties arising between private and public actors. Social Uncertainty. Adopting the notion of institutional environment as „a locus of parameters, changes in which parameters bring about shifts in the comparative costs of governance” (Williamson, 1991: 269), we note that uncertainty related to such „parameter shifts” cannot be restricted to unforeseeable changes in political institutions alone. Instead, it should, as we argue, likewise account for contingencies associated with uncertain behaviour of a broader set of institutional actors – not just government but also “community constituents in the organization's task environment” (Baum & Oliver, 1991: 187; Turk, 1973; Zucker, 1987), or, more broadly, any agency exercising social control (Rowan, 1982) – able, hence, to influence the underlying organizational structures. Non-governmental actor contestation and social pressures on corporations as organizational targets, in particular, have been increasingly demonstrated in the social movement literature (Davis, Morrill, Rao, & Soule, 2008; Eesley & Lenox, 2006; King & Soule, 2007; Weber, Rao, & Thomas, 2009). They have also been brought to attention through scholarly insights on private (as opposed to public) politics – processes through which certain non-public social agents or activists may attempt to change practices of market organizations for value redistribution purposes (Baron, 2001; Baron, 2003) Yet, while the influence and potential opposition by diverse social agents, forming part of the broader contestability in institutional environment, has become widely acknowledged, few studies exist that would identify social actor related contingencies as a separate, discrete source of environmental uncertainty. Instead, uncertainty of institutional environment has been overwhelmingly associated with political volatility, political hazards, or related notions, such as the degree of rule of law or corruption (Brunetti & Weder, 2000; Fladmoe-Lindquist & Jacque, 1995; Henisz, 2000a; Henisz, 2000b). Moreover, in the studies where external party or diverse interest group influences 13 have been explicitly recognized, scholars have predominantly viewed them as subordinate pressures, influencing the political environment and policy change through the demand for public policy or regulatory changes (Bonardi, Hillman, & Keim, 2005; Hillman & Keim, 1995; Levy & Spiller, 1994; Spiller, 1990) and, hence, treated them as part of political uncertainty equation. Whilst not denying the importance of these insights, this approach, we argue, falls short of embracing the multi-faceted nature of institutional environment uncertainty (Delios & Henisz, 2003) and multiple, discrete contingencies stemming from it. We argue that both political uncertainty and social uncertainty or social volatility (as a proxy to social uncertainty) – defining the latter as the extent of feasibility and variation in social dispute or contestation over the underlying exchange, may represent two interrelated, yet, independent contingencies in institutional environment. From this perspective, then, even if action by various social groups may deliberately affect and trigger unpredictable shifts in policy environment, both “public” and “private” politics effects represent two separate, distinct mechanisms affecting economic activity (Baron, 2001), and, hence, two distinct facets of environmental uncertainty. One important extension of this insight is that limited feasibility of policy change through formal political institutions need not curtail the possibility nor the potential effect of unforeseen social contestation by non-political actors. In public-private context, this insight is visible, for example, through one of the largest social revolts ever against public-private arrangement in water services worldwide – the “water war” of 2000 in Bolivia. An abrupt termination of the arrangement following a mass social uprising took place despite the relatively high level of political constraints in Bolivia, predicting an environment of policy continuity equivalent to that of Switzerland or Netherlands at the time (based on data by Henisz, POLCON (2010 edition)). In public-private governance context, social uncertainty raises significant ex ante concerns in terms of its potential impact on ex post governance costs and outcomes. Kivleniece & Quélin (2012) identify these ex post pressures as social activism and argue it to be substantially more likely to arise under autonomous public-private governance structures, given the weaker legitimacy of privateincentive based structures, higher stakeholder power as well as greater visibility and vulnerability of 14 these organizational modes as activist targets. We build on these insights, yet, complement the theory by arguing that social activism, as an ex post (endogenous) hazard, may also be present, in the form of social uncertainty or volatility, as an ex ante contingency - to the extent is may be exogenous or unrelated to underlying public-private engagement, and related, instead, to broader ideological shifts in the social control environment. Being conceptualized as the possibility of social dispute or contestation in a given exchange environment, one potential gauge of such ex ante social volatility could be, among others, the polarization of certain opinions in the society (DiMaggio, Evans, & Bryson, 1996), for instance - in regards to private enterprise engagement in public goods provision. In the environments that signal a potentially high ex ante social volatility, organizational actors would then alter and adjust the underlying (hybrid) governance structures to better fit and deal with anticipated contingencies. Applying the typology of dual public-private governance forms, we specifically hypothesize that the greater the social volatility in terms of the extent of feasibility and variation in social dispute or contestation of underlying exchange, the more likely public and private organizational actors are to engage in integrative governance structures. Such a choice, we argue, will be motivated by a number of features that integrative public-private governance arrangements embody. First, because of the strong, visible institutional linkages to public actors, a higher degree of legitimacy (Dacin, Oliver, & Roy, 2007) and reduced probity concerns (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012), integrative governance forms are expected to attenuate the escalation and utility of social contestation as such. Moreover, in the case of eventual rise in social pressures and ex post contestation, integrative public-private engagements are likely to be better adapted to sustain these pressures by having limited resource-based dependence on external constituents, and, instead, broader access to public resources and public financing-based compensatory mechanisms. Hypothesis 2: The greater the feasibility of social dispute or contestation (i.e. social volatility), the higher the likelihood of integrative forms of public-private ties arising between private and public actors. 15 Public-Private Governance under Market-Based Uncertainty Apart from uncertainty related to institutional environment, other, more traditionally emphasized facets of environmental uncertainty relate to market-based contingencies, such as volume or technological uncertainty (Folta, 1998; Walker & Weber, 1984) as critical factors affecting governance structures and costs (Geyskens et al., 2006). As such, market or demand-based uncertainty or volatility, i.e. the variation and unpredictability of change in future demand conditions, is likewise expected to play an important role in public-private governance choices. Here again, however, certain features of hybrid governance structures may allow actors to cope with this type of uncertainty better than others. We draw on Kivleniece & Quélin (2012), who, applying the notion of market-based uncertainty to public-private governance choices, highlight that, contrary to transaction costs predictions (Geyskens et al., 2006), increased demand or volume-based unpredictability in the context of public goods and services are likely to translate in preferences for integrative rather autonomous governance forms. From a private actor’s perspective, such preferences are likely to be motivated by a realization that the lack of possibility to establish reasonable odds regarding future demand may make the estimated payoff structure highly unclear and trigger costly ex post adjustments, particularly, in the case of highly asset-specific investments characterizing most of public-private exchanges. In such a case, unless public actors would participate with tax-based payments, guaranteed revenue or any other form of market-based volatility mitigating mechanisms, private actor engagement in the public area of interest would be substantially hampered or not viable at all. In line with these insights, we hypothesize that the greater the market-based (demand) volatility, the more likely both public and private actors are to incline towards integrative forms of public-private partnering, in efforts to secure the viability of underlying interorganizational engagement. In the presence of high market volatility, tight collaboration structure and compensation schemes based on public sector financing are expected to serve as a “safety net” against adverse market conditions, and sustain organizational relations between the two sectors better than governance structures that rely on a higher degree of private actor authority and market-driven compensation mechanisms. In comparison to the latter forms, integrative partnering is likely to secure more steady flow of revenues, 16 ease access to market (by modifying the competitive entry conditions), and establish more favourable pricing environment. Hypothesis 3: The greater the market-based (i.e. demand) volatility, the higher the likelihood of integrative forms of public-private ties arising between private and public actors. The Public-Private Governance (Mis)Fit and Longevity Implications The hypotheses above suggest that organizational actors engaged in public-private ties are likely to differentiate among alternative hybrid governance structures and adopt governance with features able to at least partially mitigate the type of contingencies prevailing in the external environment. Autonomous governance structures, characterized by predominantly private property rights, high degree of private managerial discretion and limited public-actor involvement in day-to-day activities, are likely to be preferred under the conditions of substantial political uncertainty, while integrative public-private governance structures, based on shared managerial authority, tight collaboration patterns and higher degree of public sector ownerships rights – under substantial social and marketbased (demand) uncertainty. Yet, due to both exchange-specific and actor-independent set of circumstances, on many instances the chosen governance arrangements may not be optimally aligned to underlying external environment characteristics. As our hypotheses and prior work suggest (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012), because of divergent governance preferences under different environmental and firm-specific contingencies, an optimal governance alignment may be hard to attain, and involve considerable tradeoffs. Path dependency and prior governance choices (Argyres & Liebeskind, 1998; Langlois, 2003) may drive less-than-optimal governance forms being selected over time. In the context of publicprivate collaboration, in particular, many governance alternatives may also be restricted by specific legislative, normative or regulatory requirements – leading, once again, to potential mismatch between the characteristics of external exchange environment and the adopted public-private governance features. For instance, as a prominent case in the water sector engagements, between 1995 and 2002, China prohibited foreign companies from being involved in the network operation, effectively eliminating, as a result, any possibility for concession-based contracts with foreign water operators. 17 The thrust of our theoretical argument is that potential governance misalignment, resulting from underlying path dependencies or external restrictions, are likely to carry adverse effects on the longevity, and, through it - indirectly, also on the performance of the underlying public-private arrangement, to the extent to which the duration of the partnership over initially preset timeframe allows for its full economic value to be garnered. As such, the notion of (mis)alignment (Williamson, 1988, 1991) and its effects on performance are well established in transaction cost economics literature. Structural alignment - defined as the extent to which the selected governance attributes match two main transaction characteristics, asset specificity and (behavioural) uncertainty – has been found a strong predictor of organizational profitability, technological performance and survival (Leiblein, Reuer, & Dalsace, 2002; Nickerson & Silverman, 2003; Silverman, Nickerson, & Freeman, 1997). Yet, almost all existing studies have been limited to internal, transaction-specific parameters of alignment without a further recognition of broader, multiple level alignment that may be required in the view of exogenous environmental uncertainty characterizing the exchange. Moreover, to our knowledge, none of the prior studies have explicitly accounted for the variation and governance (mis)alignment implications in hybrid governance forms (such as public-private ties), assuming these governance forms to be ill-suited to high-uncertainty environments (Williamson, 1991) and focusing, instead, on the classical “buy-ormake” dichotomies. We address the limited insights on hybrid governance alignment by arguing that public-private interorganizational ties, as distinct hybrid arrangements, may represent an inherent variation in governance structures leading to a different degree of fit with the key characteristics of underlying environment, such as political, social and market-based uncertainty. We predict that a greater misalignment or misfit is likely to be reflected in a reduced longevity of underlying ties, and, ultimately, a weaker performance of the partnership in terms of achieving its initially set public and private economic objectives. We, specifically, hypothesize that the greater the public-private governance misfit in relation to environmental contingencies, the shorter the duration of the underlying ties, based on the total time they persist from the moment of their conception to any major 18 distress event, such as litigation, cancellation or abrupt termination, at any subsequent point in time. Such an effect is expected to arise because, akin to purely private governance settings, some of the sources of uncertainty materializing over time will render misaligned governance forms less stable to withhold or adjust to underlying pressures, and, a result, prompt them to cease prematurely. In the public-private governance setting, specifically, any potential ex post adjustments to underlying governance arrangements are likely to be further complicated by the public-private contractual setting bearing a high degree of contractual rigidity. As Spiller (2008; 2010) highlights, such a rigidity would stem from the specific nature and accountability of public agencies, as well as the high degree of physical asset-specificity characterizing these engagements. As a result, in public-private settings, misaligned governance forms may be harder to correct and more likely to terminate prematurely without an adjustment. Moreover, under a public-private governance misfit, any potential ex post adjustments may suffer from underlying actor opportunism, and, in particular, from public actor’s superior institutional powers to change the underlying value distribution between public actors, private firm and external stakeholders. As private actor’s share of value may be threatened by ex post adjustments under misaligned governance form, its likelihood of premature exhibit will be substantially enhanced. Estache & Grifell-Tatje (2011), for example, in their study on the failure of a landmark public-private water partnership in Mali indicate how the premature private actor’s withdrawal from the underlying partnership (lasting only from 2001 to 2004) resulted from both ill-chosen initial financial governance structure, providing a poor fit to underlying market demand conditions and social contingencies, as well as from subsequent regulatory intervention reducing the private actor’s gains from the engagement. Our hypothesis, hence, extends the existing studies on governance and structural alignment by illustrating the longevity of public-private as strongly influenced by the degree to which the underlying organizational relationship is appropriately governed in the light of exogenous marketbased as well as institutional, i.e. political and social, contingencies. 19 Hypothesis 4: The higher the public-private governance misfit in relation to market-based, political and social contingencies characterizing the economic exchange, the shorter the longevity of underlying public-private ties. METHODOLOGY Empirical Setting and Data For the empirical setting of our study, we use the data on public-private infrastructure engagements in international water sector, focusing, in particular, on private actor participation in water projects in the developing world countries3. Our choice of this particular empirical setting, is motivated by a number of considerations. First, along with the economic and social significance attributed to water (and sanitation) sector in general, it represents a context with one of the longest standing track records of public-private collaboration, and a growing, even if divisive, role played in it by the private sector. It is estimated that about eighty per cent of developed countries and thirty-five percent of developing countries feature some form of private sector participation in water and sanitation service provision (Prasad, 2006). In developing countries alone, the total amount of private actor investment over the last two decades has amounted to 64 billion US dollars, according to the World Bank estimates (2012). Second, even if the role of private actors in the growth of the industry has been paramount, it has also been surrounded by important political and social debate, based on divergent ideological perspectives (water as an “economic good” or “basic human right”), and witnessed considerable controversy as regards the private actors’ performance (Barlow & Clarke, 2005; Budds & McGranahan, 2003). Moreover, the chosen setting serves particularly well to study the effects of environmental uncertainty on partnership governance, as it embodies a highly heterogeneous set of underlying institutional environments and governance arrangements. While on one hand, there is a high prevalence of traditional, autonomous forms of engagement, such as concessions; on another hand, integrative arrangements, based on shared activity, public sector revenue or joint public-private 3 Developing countries, in the context of this study, are understood to correspond to low- to middle-income countries, as classified by the World Bank (2012). 20 ownership, such as management contracts, are also increasingly common. In terms of external environment surrounding each public-private exchange, there is a considerable variation in both the degree of institutional uncertainty organizational actors face (see, for example, Savedoff & Spiller, 1999), as well as the degree of market development, allowing us to tackle different facets of environmental uncertainty in testing their effects on hybrid governance structures and their longevity. As our primary source of data, we use the World Bank Private Participation in Infrastructure database (The World Bank PPI Database, 2012) - one of the few authoritative public data sources available on public-private engagements in public infrastructure, such as energy, telecommunications, transport and water, worldwide. The data on the water sector, specifically, cover potable water treatment and distribution as well as sewage collection and treatment projects, with total records on more than seven hundred public-private water utility projects that have reached financial closure in sixty two low-to-middle income countries over the period of 1990-2011.4 The database covers infrastructure projects that meet the World Bank private participation criteria, i.e. where there is substantive private actor engagement in the project through private actor bearing a share in project’s operating risk, and private sector taking at least a certain minimum part in ownership or management (with a minimum private ownership threshold in the project company set at 25% for greenfield, and management and lease contracts, and 5% in the case of divestitures)5. Data on each observation include information on project identity, financial closure, type and structural form of private participation, sector and service details, key contract terms, status, details on main investors or private partners, government or development bank support, as well as overall project history. The database is updated every year via a review of secondary publicly available sources, such as specialized publications, private actor, public actor and multilateral agency websites (for more information, see "The World Bank PPI Database: Extended Methodology", 2007). 4 The World Bank PPI dataset has been use in prior studies on private participation in water industry, and the underlying contractual choices, albeit, from different theoretical perspectives (see Zarco-Jasso, 2010). 5 Projects that do not meet private participation criteria and, hence, are not part of data set include public procurement related activities such as supply, technical assistance and civil work contracts, subcontracting of individual activities, engineering or training service contracts, and turn-key or construction contracts (The World Bank PPI Database, 2012). 21 Even if comprehensive, the data on many instances are incomplete, hence, for the purposes of this study, we draw on various secondary information sources, such as company news reports and websites, as well as other public (e.g. World Bank) and private databases (such as Global Water Intelligence, Orbis, Factiva). More specific data sources used for different project and country-level variables are highlighted in the section below. The total set of records obtained from the dataset cover public-private partnerships in water management and supply in 62 developing countries over the period from 1991 to 2011. The twodecade time span covers both the nascent and principal period of global surge and saturation in private-public partnerships in the sector, which begun to be systematically implemented as a public policy tool from the early 1990s. For our final sample, however, we apply a number of restrictions on the full World Bank PPI dataset. We exclude public-private projects in China to avoid a bias due to their large overrepresentation in the total sample and very specific profile (almost half of projects reported in the World Bank PPI database are in China, and of those, 90% are on treatment plants). We likewise exclude projects that during the observation period underwent substantial changes in structural form and/or private ownership share, or for which substantial part of information on project is missing or incomplete. The final sample consists of 271 observations in 54 countries (further restricted depending on data availability, see the descriptive statistics later on), pooled across time (1991-2011), with the unit of analysis being each individual public-private partnership project. Dependent Variables Governance form. Public-private ties in international water industry are characterized by an array of structural arrangements, varying extensively along the ownership, financial and operational models as theoretical dimensions described earlier. Four broad types of empirical arrangements are identifiable in the World Bank PPI dataset (based on "The World Bank PPI Database: Extended Methodology 2007"): 1) management contacts, 2) affermage or lease contracts, 3) concessions and 4) divestitures (see Table 1 for more detailed overview of each type). ------------------------------------------------Insert Table 1 about here ------------------------------------------------22 Management contracts involve asset management and operations by private operator in return for a fee paid by the public actor, either fixed or variable, tied to the fulfilment of certain performance criteria. Investment responsibilities, operational and financing risks are under the realm of public authority, who is formally responsible for service provision. In Lease (or affermage) contracts private operator operates and manages service provision, including the revenue collection from end customers. In both affermage and lease contracts, however, it is the public authority, who is responsible for investments in infrastructure, and coordinates it in conjunction with a private operator. Because of their fundamentally similar features, both lease and affermage contracts are often classified together, the difference being a technical one – under lease contract, private operator collects the revenue and makes the lease payment to public authorities, while under affermage, the revenue collected by private operator is shared with public authorities and an affermage fee is paid on the basis of demand and customer tariffs ("The World Bank PPI Database: Extended Methodology 2007"):. Concessions are a broad category of public-private arrangements that provide private operator not only with full operational responsibilities, but also with investment management and financing duties. Concession type of contracts are often split in a further subset of technical categories, depending on the division of investment tasks and specific ownership rights characterizing each type of arrangement. Typically, in concession arrangements private actor is relatively autonomous in running the full set of operations, whilst public actor retains the legal title to underlying infrastructure asset ownership and supervision. Within the concession category, we also include greenfield arrangements, in which new infrastructure is built by private operator (as opposed to overtaking an existing public one), privately owned and operated on a temporary or permanent basis. At last, divestiture corresponds to arrangements that, instead of relying on specific contractual structures that split operational tasks or divide up property rights between public and private sector, transfer those fully to private sector. Partial divestiture corresponds to public sector retaining a stake in ownership, while full divestiture corresponds to a complete privatization. Because divestitures correspond to close-to-full privatization model and are a different type of arrangement than the public- 23 private contractual forms covered above (being close to the case of regulated utility privatization), we treat them as a separate type of arrangement and exclude the (relatively few) divestiture cases reported in the original dataset from the present analysis. For the purposes of the present study, we, first, identify and position each empirical partnership category - management contracts, lease or affermage agreements, and concessions - along the three dimensions of theoretical public-private governance forms (as identified earlier), depending on the extent to which the empirical category exhibits the features of two theoretical extremes - “integrative” versus “autonomous” governance forms. The overview of the theoretical forms as well as corresponding empirical arrangements are provided in Figure 2. ------------------------------------------------Insert Figure 2 about here ------------------------------------------------In terms of operational model, following the theoretical model prescriptions, public-private ties are integrative when they exhibit joint or shared operational responsibility and, as autonomous, when the operational and managerial responsibility is predominantly private. On the basis of this approach, concessions represent autonomous, while management and lease (as well as affermage) contracts – integrative public-private governance forms. In terms of financing model, following the theoretical model prescriptions, public-private ties take on an integrative form when the revenues are derived from public sector payments, and autonomous when they are end-user payment based. On the basis of observed empirical form characteristics, we, accordingly, identify concessions as well as lease (and affermage) contracts as representing autonomous governance form, while management contracts – integrative governance form. In terms of ownership, the empirical identification is more complex as the theoretical model does not explicitly discriminate among different types of property rights that can be associated with the use and exploitation of underlying core asset (such as the right to use the infrastructure or to alienate it), and the underlying rights to residual from this asset (i.e. rights to derive rents from the operations and asset use). As empirical evidence shows, these rights may often be split, for example, when a private 24 actor owns the equity to underlying project company exploiting the infrastructure asset, yet, is not the legal holder of the asset, not entitled to sell or modify it. We address this issue by identifying two forms of ownership – core asset and equity-based ownership (for the underlying project company). Public-private engagement is then assumed to be integrative, if core asset (infrastructure) ownership rights are predominantly public (or shared), while autonomous if those are predominantly or temporarily private. Applying this approach to our empirically observed partnership types, concessions fall under the autonomous form, while management, lease (and affermage) contracts – under integrative theoretical form. In terms of equity based ownership (in underlying project company), by contrast, we assume the higher the private equity stake in underlying project company, the more the engagement falls under autonomous public-private governance form. Adopting the approach above to map and classify the types of public-private arrangements that we observe in our empirical setting to matching theoretical governance forms (Figure 2), we arrive at two different constructs for public-private governance form as our dependent variable (for H1-H3): 1) an ordinal dependent variable, when coding all the governance arrangements on an ordinal scale, corresponding to 0 for integrative arrangements, 1 for “mixed” cases such as lease and affermage contracts - as in this case properties from two theoretical governance modes are present, and 2 for autonomous cases (see Figure 2 and Table 1); 2) a continuous variable (between 0.25 and 1), when coding the empirical arrangements on the basis of the share of private partner equity ownership in the project company (varying on the case-bycase basis), with lower private equity shares corresponding to integrative model and higher ones – to autonomous. In the light of data available, these two approaches allow us to capture different empirically observable dimensions of integrative versus autonomous governance modes. The ordinal variable allows us to capture the differences among the types of governance based on operational model, along with financing model (to the extent we can derive it from the generic contractual forms), and asset ownership model. The second, continuous variable specification, by contrast, looks at the variation in governance forms based on the overall distribution of private residual claimant rights in the project 25 company under each public-private arrangement. It, hence, provides us with an alternative property rights based measure of the variation in-between the integrative versus autonomous governance types. Longevity. To test Hypothesis 4, we operationalize our dependent variable – the longevity or duration of observed public-private ties as, first, a dummy variable (=1, if the relationship does not survive and goes under distress during the contractual/observation period). We define the project to be distressed when either of the following substantial changes to public-private project take place: 1) the project is cancelled or revoked with private actor selling, transferring or losing its stake before the intended end of contractual period and ceasing operations, or 2) one of the partners have requested (unexpected and major) renegotiation, termination or called in international arbitration. We obtain this information from the project status report in the World Bank PPI database (updated on the yearly basis). This approach, hence, regards the longevity as the extent to which the underlying pre-defined contractual length (being, on average, more than twenty years for the contracts in our sample) is respected. We also capture the actual duration term, that is the number of years between the formation of public-private engagement and 1) the moment it goes under distress or expires, or 2) the end of observation period (right-censoring), whichever happens first. The latter approach, used in the survival analysis, is commonly applied, for example, in the testing longevity in inter-firm relations literature (see, among others, Barkema, Bell, & Pennings, 1996; Barkema, Shenkar, Vermeulen, & Bell, 1997). Independent Variables Political Uncertainty. In measuring the degree of feasibility of policy change (i.e. the degree of political constraints) we rely on the political constraints index (POLCONIII), as developed by Henisz (2002), and made available in the POLCON database latest (2010) release.6 This measure, using an approach similar to the World Bank institutional “checks” index (Keefer & Stasavage, 2003), uses the number of veto players, i.e. the number of independent players in government (executive, lower and 6 The latest POLCON database release (2010), which we use (available from http://wwwmanagement.wharton.upenn.edu/henisz/) covers the data on political constraints for majority of world’s countries for the period from 1818 up to 2007 (including). For observations that fall within in the subsequent 2008-2011 period, we apply the latest POLCON value available (from 2007). 26 upper legislative chambers), to assess the likelihood of policy change of independent branches of government. It is estimated, as originally developed by Henisz (2002: 363), on the basis of data from political science databases, by identifying the number of independent branches of government (executive, lower and upper legislative chambers) with veto power over policy change in up to 160 countries (for every year since 1800). This measure is further modified to account for the alignment in party composition across these branches, and the degree of preference heterogeneity in legislative chambers, expecting these factors to drive up the costs of policy change. The resulting measure (varying between 0 and 1, with 0 characterizing political environment with virtually no constraints, hence, a high likelihood of policy change, and measures closer to 1 signifying high degree of constraints, i.e. low feasibility of policy change) provides similar results to World Bank political risk measures (Keefer & Stasavage, 2003) and has been repeatedly used as a measure of institutional environment uncertainty in previous political economy and firm strategy studies (see, for example, Henisz & Delios, 2004; Henisz & Zelner, 2006; Zelner, Henisz, & Holburn, 2009). Social Volatility. As a proxy to social uncertainty we define and use a notion of social volatility the feasibility and variation of social contestation or dispute in underlying (public-private) exchange context. We, first, note that to operationalize this variable, two different approaches can be applied. One is based on the event-study approach, commonly used in the studies of social movements, and consists of assessing the number of historical social contestation events in the industry, through recording, for example, events reported in newspaper records (Earl, Martin, McCarthy, & Soule, 2004; King & Soule, 2007). Unfortunately, this approach is not easily adaptable in the context of the present study as there are limited secondary data available on social contestation events in many developing country contexts, and, moreover, many of public-private arrangements observed represent one of the first private actor engagements in the given country’s water sector, limiting, hence, existence of prior events in industry to rely on in constructing this measure7. Another approach, that we rely on in the present study, is to gauge the degree of variation or polarization in opinions, such as the degree of 7 We do assess, as alternative measure of social volatility, also the effect of a certain key or landmark social contestation event on global industry worldwide – such as the „water war” in Cochabamba, Bolivia in 2000, which having obtained wide global publicity appears to have triggered many of the subsequent anti-private water movements and rise of anti-private water sentiments in developing country context, in particular. 27 “anti-private sentiment”, as a proxy or precursor condition to social volatility in a given public-private exchange context. This view is supported, for instance, by DiMaggio et al. (1996), who identify opinion polarization as a key causal mechanism to both political conflict and social volatility. To construct our country-level measure of social volatility we rely on the World Values Survey (WVS) – a unique global dataset tracking the beliefs and value statements of individuals, and changes in politico-social and economic attitudes in close to 100 world countries since 1981. Carried out through national surveys and based on a harmonized global questionnaire, it contains data in the form of repeated cross-sections on five consistent waves of surveys, corresponding to 1981-1984, 19891993, 1994-1999, 2000-2004 and 2005-2008. In constructing the exact measure on the basis of these data, we draw on the work by Landier, Thesmar, & Thoenig (2008), who construct a pro- or anticapitalism sentiment measure on a basis of selected questions in the WVS survey. We use the survey responses on the question on private ownership, specifically, to construct a variable reflecting the extent of “private participation/ownership” aversion in each country observed. In answering this question, respondents grade the merits of private versus public (government) ownership on a scale from 1 to 10, selecting their preferred statement between the two extremes: “Private ownership of business and industry should be increased” (1) and “Government ownership of business and industry should be increased” (10). We construct a variable on the basis of percentage of respondents selecting grade 5 and above (following Landier et al. 2008 methodology). The higher the score in the time period corresponding to the public-private engagement founding year, the higher, we deem, the antiprivate engagement sentiment prevailing in a given country, and the higher the likelihood of social protest following the private sector engagement in public infrastructure services.8 Unfortunately, as the World Values Survey is available only for 26 of 54 countries represented in our dataset, we, accordingly, use this subset of countries and a restricted sample of observations (n=148) in our estimations that rely on social volatility variable. Our sample is likewise restricted by a deliberate decision to minimize the possibility of a reverse causality, i.e. changes in the public opinion 8 We acknowledge that our measure represents an imperfect proxy for social volatility, able to capture the prevailing opinion polarization, yet, not the propensity of organized social action or movement to arise on the basis of these opinions. Developing a more elaborate measure to address this concern, particularly, in the developing country context, remains an important task for future research. 28 following the establishment of a given public-private arrangement in each country. To avoid this concern, we use for each observation only the survey data that corresponds to the last, lagged wave of survey (i.e. the year or maximum up to five years) before the date of project signing. Market-Based Volatility. Our measure of market-based volatility has to take into account the type of demand-related variation water and sanitation sector is likely to experience, particularly, in the developing market context. As such, the demand in volume terms can be argued to be relatively predictable (given the required base level of water consumption per capita that is expected to exhibit little variation). Yet, the actual chargeable and payment-based demand estimates may be hard to derive, in particular, as many of developing countries experience high proportions of population with low purchasing power and existing water infrastructure of low quality, resulting in large proportions of loss or leakage, high levels of non-payment, as well as measurement and control problems of the actual volumes consumed. In the light of these characteristics, we predict that market uncertainty (volatility) is likely to be substantially higher for water utility infrastructure rather for stand-alone engagements, such as treatment plants, due to underlying complexity and wide-spread service delivery network for former services, and their demand-based dependence on a wide base of end-users (rather than on a more limited range of utility buyers, as in the case of treatment plants). Accordingly, we introduce a dummy variable, taking the value of 0 for public-private engagements in treatment services, and 1 for utility (i.e. network-based) services. This measure, while relatively crude, nevertheless allows us to proxy for the extent of variance underlying the demand for water and sanitation services, absent a possibility to observe this variance directly. 9 It also follows the approach adopted in a number of prior studies that have applied industry subsector proxies to account for underlying transaction uncertainty (Kumar, 2005; Masten, Meehan, & Snyder, 1991). Governance Misfit. To measure the extent to which the actual governance form selected under each public-private engagement corresponds to the most optimal choice in the light of underlying market-based, political and social contingencies, we rely on a methodology of estimating the degree of 9 Because of the lack of relevant past demand data on each project level, we are not able to estimate market or demand-based uncertainty by a more commonly used method that measures the sum of squared errors from a regression of the relevant product-market’s historical unit demand over a certain number of years preceding the engagement (e.g. Leiblein et al. (2002)). 29 conformity or governance alignment used in prior studies in transaction cost economics (Leiblein et al., 2002; Nickerson & Silverman, 2003; Silverman et al., 1997). The approach, drawn from Anderson’s (1988) work on conformity, relies on estimating the probability that another governance form may be more appropriate given the contractual (or, in our case – broader environmental or institutional) hazards, and uses the residual between the actual governance structure and that predicted by the estimation as the measure of governance misfit for each individual observation. For this estimation, we rely on our first, operational governance model as the dependent variable specification, retaining the three ordered categories (integrative, mixed-case, and autonomous). The first step is to estimate the likelihood that a specific governance form (e.g. autonomous) will be chosen as a function of environmental contingencies identified earlier. We follow an approach similar to the one proposed by Leiblein et al. (2002), who in a binary case analysis, first, estimate the most likely value for autonomous governance choice by the following probit model: Prob (Yi = 1) = Φ (β'Xi) were Yi stands for the governance choice for the ith observation, Xi represents a vector of characteristics for the underlying relationship (corresponding to underlying contingencies, in our case), β is a vector of estimated coefficients for these characteristics, and Φ(.) stands for standard normal cumulative distribution function. Then, the governance misfit for each observation is estimated as the absolute value of 1 - Prob (Yi = 1) when governance choice equals 1, and Prob (Yi = 1) when it equals 0. We adjust this approach to our case of dependent variable with three ordered outcomes, by estimating an ordered probit model and measuring the governance misfit for each observation as Prob (Yi = 2) + Prob (Yi = 1) when governance choice equals 0 (i.e. integrative), 1 - Prob (Yi = 1) when it equals 1 (i.e. mixed) and 1- Prob (Yi = 2) when it equals 2 (i.e. autonomous). The higher the value, the higher the estimated degree of misfit of the adopted governance form. 30 The vector of characteristics that we keep in the ordered probit model are political constraints index, dummy for local project level and interaction term, the proxy for social volatility, dummy for water utilities, as well as two controls for size (capacity) and contract length.10 Controls We introduce two types of control variables: 1) country-level controls (particularly, as we cannot control for country fixed effects having instances of only one observation per country), and 2) projectlevel controls, corresponding to the specific characteristics and features surrounding each individual project. Country-level characteristics. We control for the overall demographic characteristics and economic development level of each project country by including GDP per capita and GDP annual growth rate measures, population size (in millions of inhabitants), and population density measures, all drawn from the World Bank Development Indicators database. We further account for the level of democratic development in each country, using the political liberties measure from the Freedom House, a nongovernmental research institute on worldwide democracy, political freedom and human rights development. To account for the degree of potential (positive) externalities surrounding the project, we include three measures corresponding to overall water sector development in the country, as reported by the World Health Organization/UNICEF Joint Monitoring Program for Water Supply and Sanitation – 1) the percentage of population with improved water source, 2) the percentage of population with improved sanitation access, and 3) the percentage of piped water to premises. These measures allow us to capture the degree to which public-private governance choices and stability of public-private engagements may be affected by the need to address underlying, potentially uncompensated deficiencies in the existing water provision system in a given country. We also account for at least two specific geographical country-level conditions likely to significantly affect water sector development, project complexity and infrastructure project viability – the degree of agricultural development (agricultural land as percentage of total land area) and the presence of extreme conditions, estimated as the average percentage of population affected by droughts, floods 10 We set and verify this specification after testing the ordered probit models for H1-H3 (see Table 3 and the discussion in the Results section). 31 and extreme temperature over the period of 1990-2009. Both of these measures are obtained from the World Bank Development Indicators database. Project-specific characteristics. We control for a number of individual project-specific characteristics expected to affect the governance choice and longevity of underlying public-private engagement, such as the contract length (in years), project re-award (a dummy), the number of independent infrastructure systems in each project (as a proxy for project complexity) and presence of related projects (a dummy). We likewise include a dummy variable for project subsector being related to potable water treatment, delivery or distribution. To control for the characteristics of each project in terms of administrative or politico-institutional level, we include a dummy for government partner being on the local level as opposed to state or federal level. We also account for the degree of governmental support and multilateral financing (such as development bank loans) provided to the project, by including an ordinal variable for government support, such as payments or guarantees, and an indicator of the size of multilateral support granted to project (in millions of USD). We include a number of control measures related to the private actor(s) engaged in the project. To control for potential “consortium” effects, we include a count of a number of private partners involved in the project (ranging from 1 to 5). To account for the potential effects of “liability of foreignness” and well as, conversely, advantages tied to having a local player on private actor side, we include a dummy variable for the presence of at least one foreign private partner among private actors engaged in each project, and a dummy variable for a presence of at least one local-country partner among the private actors engaged in each project. We control for project commitments and investment size by including data on the amount of financial resources committed by the project company to be invested in facilities at the time of project signing. We also devise a specific, ordinal scale based measure to control for the project capacity (size). Given that the capacity for all projects in the World Bank dataset is reported in three different terms, such as population served, number of connections or cubic meters per day of output, we cannot use a unified, single measure, and devise, instead, a three point scale to account for smaller, medium and large scale projects (a similar approach is applied in intrafirm studies, see, for example, Krishnan et al., 2006). 32 Unfortunately we have limited information on the competitive environment (such as the number of bidders) in each project and private partner selection process, except for an indication if the project was awarded through a competitive process, such as competitive bidding or negotiation, or other approach, such as direct negotiations or unsolicited proposal. To control for competitive intensity, we, hence, include a “competitive award” dummy, equal to 1 for projects where public-private contract was awarded through competitive bidding or competitive negotiations process. At last, we also introduce two controls to account for effects that may introduce changes in governance structures over time, measuring the industry-level average dominant governance choice, in both operational model and private equity participation terms, for each year of the study. As such, this approach is adopted from that of Guasch, Laffont & Straub (2007), who in their study on the likelihood of infrastructure contract renegotiations in Latin America used the prevailing governance choice in the industry in a given year as one of estimation variables, assuming it to influence the governance choice in each individual case. ------------------------------------------------Insert Table 2 about here ------------------------------------------------We provide an overview of summary statistics (means, standard deviations, minimum and maximum values, as well as correlations) on our dependent variables, explanatory variables and the full set of controls in Table 2. Estimation Methods The first part of our theoretical model (H1-H3) is based on the probability of public-private governance choice being influenced by different types of exogenous environmental uncertainty. We use an ordered probit model for our first dependent variable specification - the operational governance model set as three ordered categories (integrative, mixed and autonomous). The estimated coefficients capture the impact of three different types of environmental uncertainty or contingencies on the probability of increasingly autonomous governance choice. As such, our chosen estimation method follows previous studies on governance choice in inter-firm context (see, for example, Leiblein et al., 2002; Oxley, 1997; Pisano, 1989). 33 For our second dependent variable specification (again, to test H1-H3), based on the distribution of residual claimant rights (i.e. private equity share in the project company), we use a different estimation method. Given the proportional nature of this dependent variable and a non-trivial number of responses of 1 (i.e. full private ownership cases), we note that estimation methods, such as OLS regression or tobit, may not appropriate. We apply, instead, the approach recommended by Papke & Wooldridge (1996) on fractional response variables, and use a generalized linear model (GLM) with a logit link and the binomial family specification (with robust standard errors in case of misspecified distribution family) (STATA Corporation, 2004) for this estimation. To test the second part of our theoretical model (H4), focused on the impact of governance (mis)fit on partnership longevity, we apply, first, a probit regression, using as a proxy to longevity the dummy specification of our dependent variable (corresponding to 1, if the partnership undergoes distress during the observation/contractual period, 0 otherwise), and estimating, hence, a probability of public-private project going under distress as a function of governance misfit and a range of covariates. We note, however, that to assess the impact of governance on longevity or duration, several methodological concerns remain not addressed with this method, related to potential selfselection and omitted variable bias, as well as right-censoring of our data. As an alternative, additional robustness check we, hence, also apply a survival analysis based methodology, using an accelerated failure time regression method to estimate the effects of our independent variables and covariates on the expected duration of public-private ties. This approach, increasingly common in inter-firm collaboration and foreign entry survival studies (see, for example, Barkema et al., 1996; Barkema et al., 1997; Dussauge, Garrette, & Mitchell, 2000; Hoang & Rothaermel, 2010; Mitchell, Shaver, & Yeung, 1994), provides several advantages over logit (or probit) regressions as well as more traditional proportional hazard rate based survival methods (such as Cox regression). As Mitchell et al. (1994) argue, accelerated failure time technique is equivalent to an inverse measure of exit likelihood, however, compared to techniques such as logistic regression is able to account for different entry dates of observations and right-censoring. Moreover, compared to proportional hazard rate models (such as Cox regression), accelerated failure time models are more robust to omitted covariates, and hence 34 better fit to deal with endogeneity and unobserved heterogeneity concerns (Hoang & Rothaermel, 2010), even if selection problems may remain also in these models. Similar to a number of prior studies (Barkema et al., 1996; Barkema et al., 1997), we use an accelerated failure-time model with a Weibull distribution, which assumes a monotonic hazard rate (we come back later to this assumption in the Results section). At last, we note that the use of both types of approaches for longevity or duration studies are justified and supported by prior literature: logit or probit type of estimations represent widely used method focussing on the probability of a discrete outcome occurrence, while accelerated failure time techniques assess the effect of explanatory variables on the duration of time before an outcome (failure) takes place and take into account the right-censoring (Dussauge et al., 2000). RESULTS Environmental Uncertainty and Governance Choice Our first three hypotheses dealt with the effects of three different facets of environmental uncertainty – the degree of political constraints (H1), social volatility (H2) and market-based volatility (H3) – on the type of public-private governance structure selected by the involved actors. We estimate these effects by using two different measures of public-private governance form, first, a measure related to the operational model (with an ordering of integrative, mixed and autonomous forms) and, then, the proportional split of residual claimant rights among the public and private actors (i.e. the proportional share of private equity in the public-private project company – a higher proportion interpreted as a higher degree of autonomous governance). We first test Hypotheses 1-3 by focusing on the dependent variable specification based on the operational model, and performing an ordered probit analysis (see Table 3). We start by performing a more restricted test on control variables to assess the preliminary model specification (Model 1). We note several of the project-related characteristics as bearing a significant impact on the likelihood of adopting an autonomous governance structure – increasing contract length, re-awarded project, increasing government support augmenting the likelihood of more autonomous governance structures, 35 and by contrast, projects with potable water services, higher capacity and related projects bearing a lower probability of autonomous form selection. In Model 2, we introduce our explanatory variables, related to three different measures of environmental uncertainty, and find support for Hypothesis 3 on the negative association between market-based uncertainty and autonomous governance with the coefficient on utility services negative and significant (at 5% level). Neither political constraints nor social volatility measure, however, show a significant effect. In Model 3, we refine our approach by recognizing that the effect of political constraints on the public-private governance form is likely to be conditioned by the type of politico-institutional or administrative level on which the public-private collaboration takes place. We, accordingly, introduce an interaction term between the degree of political constraints and the project level (local versus state or federal), and obtain significant results for both main effects as well as the interaction term. Hypothesis 1, then, is indirectly supported (following an inverse logic) with a higher degree of political stability (more constraints) found to be associated with a reduced likelihood of selecting an autonomous governance structure (at 10% significance level). We also note that the local project level is associated with a reduced likelihood of autonomous governance choice, and that the interaction term is significant (its exact effect depending on the other covariates). ------------------------------------------------Insert Table 3 about here ------------------------------------------------We further refine the model (Model 4) by introducing our second, alternative governance measure (i.e. private equity share) as additional control to assess the robustness of the model. We also introduce an additional control for the time effects and potential governance mimicry effects by including the industry dominant governance choice (in a given year) as additional control. We observe that the results do not change – retaining the predicted signs and significant effect for political constraints (H1) and market-based uncertainty (H3). The effect of private equity share is not significant, while the implicit hypothesis on the influence of dominant industry governance form is supported – the more dominant are autonomous structures in industry in a given year, the higher the likelihood of 36 autonomous structure for a given project. At last, we note that Hypothesis 2 on the impact of social volatility on governance structures is not supported in any of the models. We proceed with our second dependent variable specification - a measure based on the private equity share, and estimate the effects of three explanatory variables on the degree of autonomous governance choice through a generalized linear model (see Table 4). We note that Models 1 and Models 2 (based, similarly as above, on restricted controls and main effects specification) represent rather weak specifications, with only re-awarded projects showing a significant association with a higher degree of private actor residual rights in the underlying project (i.e. higher share of private equity). Introducing the main effects and interaction effect between political constraints and the project level (Model 3), however, provides again an indirect support for Hypothesis 1, with a significant (at 5%) negative association between the level of political constraints (i.e. political stability) and the proportional share of equity in project company held by private actors. The effect of administrative level of project is, again, significant (at 1%) and negative, illustrating that the contracts signed on local level are likely to feature a smaller proportion of private equity (higher degree of public actor equity participation). ------------------------------------------------Insert Table 4 about here ------------------------------------------------Similar to the first dependent variable specification, the negative relationship implied in Hypothesis 1 (between the degree of political constraints and increasingly autonomous governance choice) is also supported in the extended model (Model 4), which controls for alternative (operational model) governance specification, and industry-dominant governance trend. However, neither Hypothesis 2 (on social volatility) nor Hypothesis 3 (on market-based volatility) are supported in any of the models that rely on private equity share-based governance specification.11 In terms of control variables, we observe that the positive and significant effect is retained for re-awarded projects. In addition, contract length is negatively and significantly associated with private equity share in Model 4 11 As an alternative proxy to social volatility we also test for any effect of potential landmark event (arrangement being signed pre or post the highly publicized Cachabamba „Water wars” in 2000), however, the effect is not significant. 37 (whilst found to be significant and positively associated with autonomous operational governance mode earlier). Governance Misfit and Longevity of Public-Private Ties Our last hypothesis (H4) suggests a potentially negative effect of public-private governance misalignment (misfit) on the longevity or duration of public-private ties. We hypothesize that the greater the governance misfit in relation to market-based, political and social contingencies characterizing the exchange environment, the shorted the public-private relationship lasts, from moment of establishment to a distress point (i.e. early “freeze” or premature termination) at any subsequent point in time. In the first set of tests, we assess this hypothesis through a probit regression analysis, with the longevity dummy as a dependent variable (see Table 5). Model 1 represents a base-line model with project-level controls and a selected number of country-level characteristics, which are expected to influence the longevity of public-private ties. In Model 2, we include the variable specifying the operational governance form to test if any operational model type is per se associated with a higher likelihood of distress affecting the duration of the underlying relationship. The effect of this variable, however, is not found as significant. In Model 3, we also test, if a mixed governance form, as opposed to “pure” (i.e. autonomous versus integrative) cases, may also feature any adverse effect of the longevity of underlying public-private ties. Interestingly, the coefficient is positive, even if the effect falls short of reaching a statistically significant level (at 11%), suggesting that intermediate forms between the autonomous and integrative structures may be inherently less viable. In Model 4, we introduce the degree of governance misfit as explanatory variable, and obtain a strong support for Hypothesis 4, with governance misfit positively and significantly (at 5%) linked to a higher likelihood of underlying public-private engagement facing earlier distress, termination or cancellation. ------------------------------------------------Insert Table 5 about here ------------------------------------------------- 38 We also highlight noteworthy results on several control variables, particularly in Model 4.12 Interestingly, while adopting an autonomous operational model (our first dependent variable specification) does not appear to impact the longevity of public-private relationship, an increasing private share of equity (i.e. increasingly private residual rights) is linked to a higher likelihood of partnership becoming distressed (at 1% in Model 4). As expected, the duration of the public-private relationship is negatively linked to the probability of distress. We find consistently significant and positive effect for multilateral financing (suggesting a financial leverage effect) and, in Model 4, also for a number of private actors (suggesting a consortium effect), with both of the factors appearing to adversely impact the likelihood of partnership longevity. The presence of a foreign private actor is not found to have a significant effect in Model 4, while the presence of local actor appears associated with a slightly reduced distress likelihood (at 10%) in Model 4. We also find larger capacity projects to be more likely to last longer (at 5%), again, however, in Model 4. And at last, in terms of country level effects – the results suggest a higher GDP growth rate is consistently linked to higher public-private tie longevity, while, inversely, the share of agricultural land area – to a greater likelihood of distress. To test our hypothesis on the effect of misfit on public-private tie duration, we also carry out, as an alternative robustness check, a survival methods based estimation, specified as an accelerated failure time model. As mentioned earlier, use of parametric models (i.e. accelerated failure time models) differs from more traditionally used methods in duration and survival analysis by implying a specific assumption about the shape and type of underlying hazard rate distribution function, and by estimating the effect of main variables and covariates on the latent survival time (hence, mandating an inverse interpretation to our previous model – with negative coefficients indicating negative effect on duration or survival time). Following a number of prior studies in alliance and foreign entry literature (Barkema et al., 1996; Barkema et al., 1997; Mitchell et al., 1994), we use an accelerated failure time (AFT) model with Weibull distribution that assumes a monotonic (declining or increasing) hazard rate over time. 12 We do acknowledge that results on certain variables in Models 1-3 require caution (change signs and significance), and retain Model 4 as a more relevant model specification. 39 The results of this regression model, however, prove to be substantially less conclusive than those of the previous estimation (see Table 6). Replicating Models 1-4 through AFT methods estimation, we find that governance misfit retains an adverse effect (signified by a negative coefficient in AFT model case) on the governance longevity or (survival duration), however, the effect is not statistically significant. Interestingly, presence of multilateral financing has a consistently negative significant effect on partnership duration, same as the foreign actor presence (except for Model 4). The intuitive insights on the role of host country growth rate impact on survival are also supported by GDP growth rate showing a consistently positive and significant effect on the underlying public-private tie duration. ------------------------------------------------Insert Table 6 about here ------------------------------------------------Recognizing that the estimation of a parametric model may be complicated by a need to make a correct assumption about the underlying distribution function, we do test alternative distribution specifications (such as log-logistic and lognormal – not reported in the paper), and find that Weibull specification may be retained on the basis of slightly smaller value of Akaike’s Information Criterion (AIC) - suggested in the literature as a measure to distinguish among different parametric models (Burnham & Anderson, 2002). We do note, however, that the differences in AIC scores are small, and that the generally small final sample may not provide sufficiently robust assessment of the fit with underlying tested distribution models. Likewise, due to relatively small number of observations, we are not able to use the generalized gamma distribution, which, as highlighted by Dussauge et al. (2000), represents a particularly useful, broader form of accelerated event-time regression by estimating both monotonic and nonmonotonic event rates (corresponding to a family of several distributions) as well the effect of omitted covariates. Overall, we conclude that to improve the validity and robustness of our estimates, particularly, in terms of survival analysis, increasing the sample of observations (currently limited to 244 observations in Models 1-3 and only 154 observations in Model 4, with 12-13% of failure rates among them)13 may be necessary. 13 This restriction in the final number of observations is driven by a number of missing data for our principal „governance misfit” variable, which itself is constructed by combining several underlying dimensions (and, as such, affected by a lack of data on all required dimensions for a number of observations). 40 DISCUSSION In the present study, we build on nascent theoretical insights on public-private ties as a novel type of hybrid governance arrangements, to examine how exogenous environmental uncertainty, in a form of distinct market and institutional environment based contingencies, affects the selection of publicprivate governance mechanisms and the longevity or duration of underlying ties. By differentiating between political, social and market–based facets of environmental uncertainty, we propose and find support for our core argument that alternative forms of public-private as hybrid governance arrangements co-exist with each alternative structure selected to differentially address the type of contingencies surrounding the underlying exchange. Based on the empirical context of public-private water sector engagements in the developing world, our findings illustrate that organizational actors – and private actors, specifically, operating in these environments, may be able to adjust and intentionally adapt public-private governance structures and individual features in the light of underlying environmental hazards. These insights counter more established views in organizational and strategy literature that generally recognize hybrid arrangements as ill suited for high-uncertainty environments (Folta, 1998; Williamson, 1991) – particularly, for politically hazardous ones (Henisz, 2002; Levy & Spiller, 1994; Spiller, 1993), and assume all hybrid arrangements to exhibit a uniform, intermediate variation in underlying governance features (Williamson, 1991; Williamson, 1999). Moreover, our empirical findings on the longevity of public-private ties (even if inconclusive in the second empirical specification), serve to illustrate the potential impact that a structural alignment with institutional environment characteristics, not just transactional features, may carry on the subsequent duration or survival of these engagements. Highlighting political uncertainty and social volatility as two distinct sources of contingencies stemming from broader institutional environment, we show that, along with market-base ones, they mandate a selection of divergent governance features, and through governance (mis)alignment affect the duration of underlying organizational arrangement. Overall, our work delivers three principal contributions. First, by investigating empirically the role of environmental uncertainty as a critical, multi-faceted factor affecting both ex ante public-private 41 governance preferences and ex post longevity of underlying relationships, we contribute to growing theoretical insights on the variation and viability of hybrid governance structures (Makadok & Coff, 2009). Our findings support the emerging view on hybrid organizational forms as complex, multidimensional arrangements exhibiting a high degree of variation in governance features, featuring important trade-offs (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012) and a divergent degree of ability to address the contingencies surrounding the exchange. Second, by distinguishing between two distinct types of institutional uncertainty – related to political, yet, also social constituency driven influences, we broaden the notion of (exogenous) environmental uncertainty, traditionally restricted to more traditional market (demand) and technology-based notions (Folta, 1998; Geyskens et al., 2006; Walker & Weber, 1984). In particular, but calling into attention not just the influence of state or public actors, but also of “community constituents in the organization's task environment” (Baum & Oliver, 1991: 187; Turk, 1973; Zucker, 1987), we suggest how a broader set of agencies exercising social control may be able to influence the organizational structures and governance selection, at least from a theoretical perspective. At last, by re-visiting the notion of governance misalignment from a broader political and social contingency context (rather than mere transactional view), we develop a theoretical distinction between transactional and broader institutional alignment as a potentially important predictor of underlying governance form sustainability and duration. Our results on public-private governance choice, specifically, suggest that organizational actors (private actors, in particular) may opt for structurally different public-private governance forms, i.e. autonomous versus integrative ones, depending on the degree of political constraints and market-based volatility in the underlying exchange environment. In line with our theoretical hypotheses, increasingly constrained political environments (and, hence, less uncertain) are shown to reduce the reliance on autonomous governance forms, while, by inverse logic, a high feasibility of policy change (i.e. few political constraints) appears to be enhance it. As mentioned, this insight calls into question a more common view that private actor participation may be severely limited in politically uncertain environments (Henisz, 2002; Henisz & Zelner, 2001; Levy & Spiller, 1996; Savedoff & Spiller, 1999). Moreover, based on developing country setting, the insights of our study suggest the “hybridization” 42 of governance forms – in a sense of selective adjustment and adoption of different underlying governance features to address political environment contingencies, as a powerful theoretical mechanism to explain the prevalence, fit and viability of these arrangement in emerging or “bottomof-the-pyramid” market contexts (George et al., 2012). Interestingly, however, our findings also point out to some crucial differences that may exist in governance structures depending on the politico-institutional level on which public-private interaction takes place. With private actors being able to collaborate with public actors on state, federal, as well as local (municipal or community-based) levels, the degree and impact of political uncertainty, in particular, as perceived on the state or national level, appears not homogeneous across these levels. Our results suggest that, while there is a strong association between country-level political uncertainty and a reduced reliance on integrative governance arrangements, ties formed on local level may be preferred to be governed in a more integrative way. An interesting further question to address would be to assess to which extent such an effect is driven by the nature of political uncertainty construct itself (measured on state or national level), or tied to more fundamental differences in how private actors perceive and engage with public actors on different administrative levels. In support of the latter view, one may argue that local political actors are likely to feature distinct, separate set of political constraints and stronger local, community-based ties, having, as a result, a different objective function and incentives vis-à-vis private sector partners. This, in turn, may modify the perceived nature of political uncertainties from private actor perspective, and render public-private ties formed on local level and their associated hazards much more relationship-specific and endogenously determined than public-private ties formed on higher politico-institutional levels. We likewise find that, as hypothesized, market-based uncertainty plays a critical role in publicprivate governance choice, in particular, shaping the type of operational form selected in each publicprivate engagement. Private actor participation in developing country water sector appears significantly more likely to take the form of integrative governance forms, such as management contracts, in the domains that feature high degree of market uncertainty, i.e. utility-based projects. As such, this insight runs counter the classical transaction cost based tenets in interfirm literature which 43 predict higher market uncertainty (and asset specificity) as associated with more vertically integrated engagements and limited recourse to hybrid governance forms – at least, from a private actor’s perspective. Our results suggest that in the context of public-private collaboration, the opposite may be true – a higher degree of market uncertainty may facilitate the emergence of tightly integrated, shared authority governance structures between public and private counterparts. In such cases, the public counterpart is able to share and mitigate part of the adverse effects for the private actor, such as unpredictable demand fluctuations, associated with market-based contingencies. In terms of public-private governance typology, our study also sheds important light on the need to distinguish between separate governance dimensions, relevant for understanding why different hybrid governance forms emerge and are adopted by organizational actors. Two of these dimensions relate to what we term the “operational model” or the degree and scope of authority that a private partner may exercise in a specific collaboration context, as well as the ownership (control) rights over the physical assets (such as infrastructure). Both of these dimensions appear strongly intertwined – with on one side, integrative arrangements, such as management contracts, featuring considerably restricted scope for private actor’s authority and asset control rights and, on another side, concession type of arrangements, granting most of the decision and (at least temporarily) asset ownership rights to private actors. Our empirical analysis, however, also highlights another critical ownership dimension related to the sharing of residual claimant rights among public and private players – with autonomous engagements featuring a close-to-full private sector ownership in underlying project companies, and more integrative arrangements involving an increasing public equity stake. What our results illustrate is that both asset control and residual claimant rights, rather than being overlapping or substitutes, may be complementary dimensions of governance, able to address the underlying environmental contingencies to an unequal, varying degree. For example, while we find that both a high degree of private equity ownership and high degree of operational autonomy may be sought for in public-private arrangements that feature high degree of political uncertainty, under a high degree of market-based 44 uncertainty or volatility, only the governance structures based on shared operational model appear to be systematically selected. From a broader theoretical perspective, we believe, these insights highlight the need to look beyond the implicit assumption of uniform distribution of property rights in analyzing hybrid governance arrangements, and embrace a broader set of dimensions in the analysis of ownership rights underlying novel organizational structures. As Schlager & Ostrom (1992) point out, one such approach would be to recognize property rights as a broader bundle of discrete decision rights, each of which may be distributed in a different manner, especially in the context of collective or public exchange. As illustrated by the variety of public-private arrangements in the empirical context of the present study, governance structures that rely on shared residual rights (and hence assume an equivalent partitioning of underlying decision rights) tell only part of the story. Certain rights may be given away entirely (such as the rights to private actors to manage the underlying public asset) while others held or retained (such as the rights to derive revenue, exclude the users or alienate the asset – often retained by the public sector). Developing and deepening these insights would provide a promising and important direction for future research. At last, our empirical results, even if only partially conclusive, also help to shed light on the longevity or duration of public-private ties, particularly, in the developing country context. Based on our discrete-event based (probit) analysis, we find that, as predicted, the initial structural alignment between the governance form and the type and degree of institutional and market-based contingencies characterizing the exchange is an important predictor of the subsequent duration of underlying ties. If confirmed in further research, this insight calls for enlarging the established, predominantly transaction-specific analysis on the impact of misalignment on organizational survival or performance (Leiblein et al., 2002; Nickerson & Silverman, 2003; Williamson, 1991). More specifically, it calls for conceptualizing the governance misalignment on a broader level – relating it to the (mis)fit between the underlying governance structures and a multi-faceted set of contingencies characterizing the exogenous institutional environment of a given exchange, rather than internal transaction-specific hazards alone. Through development and testing of an enlarged governance (mis)alignment notion, we 45 also point out the inherent fragility of public-private ties, resulting from organizational actor preferences being pulled in opposing directions (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012). In other words, recognizing that simultaneous presence of, for example, high degree of market uncertainty may warrant one type (i.e. integrative) of public-private engagement, while the simultaneous presence of weak political constraints, for example, mandates an alternative (i.e. autonomous) structure, may explain why a certain degree of governance misfit may be unavoidable in public-private as hybrid governance context. Limitations and Future Research Work Notwithstanding the insights described above, the present study also features several limitations and conceptual questions to be addressed in future research work. From a theoretical perspective, exogenous environmental uncertainty may account for only part of the factors shaping governance structures and their selection in public-private interaction. As prior theoretical studies highlight (Kivleniece & Quélin, 2012; Rangan et al., 2006), internal, organizational actor-specific factors, such as the presence (or lack) of idiosyncratic organizational resources and capabilities on both public and private actors’ side, as well as relationship-specific hazards may introduce important modifications in the actor preferences and public-private engagement choices. From a public policy perspective, likewise, in many empirical contexts public-private governance alternatives may be considerably restrained by legislative or regulatory means (requesting, for example, mandatory local partner participation or limiting the range of operational models available for private actor engagements in public service provision). Such restrictions do not necessarily invalidate our insights, however, they do draw attention to an even broader set of factors likely to shape public-private governance choices in diverse empirical settings. From the perspective of institutional environment analysis, we also note that other mechanisms and agents are likely to play a role in public-private as a hybrid governance structure selection and longevity. More specifically, our work does not explicitly cover the role and presence of potential regulatory bodies surrounding public-private actor interaction. While previous studies on the infrastructure engagements in developing country context have provided important insights on the role 46 of regulatory presence and its features, such as price cap regulation, on the likelihood of terminations or renegotiations (Guasch, 2004; Guasch et al., 2007), we recognize that more insights and future work may be called for to join the insights on the influence of regulatory environment and the broader institutional environment contingencies that are investigated in the present study. We likewise recognize the potential effects related to other institutional norms or practices, and strategic influences, such as the feasibility and degree of political decision-maker capture, collusion between private and political interests, and corruption. While not captured in our present analysis, they are likely to be particularly relevant in the public-private interaction, particularly, in the developing country settings and, as such, represent important avenues for future inquiries.14 It is also important to emphasize that in our study we deliberately limit our attention to a predominantly private actor–based perspective on governance preferences, choices, and longevity outcomes in public-private interaction. This particular focus is motivated by an observation that most of existing literature and studies on public-private collaboration have treated public-private interaction phenomenon principally from a public actor’s (or public policy) perspective, with private actors implicitly assumed as passive in the underlying organizational structures and choices. In our study, we aim to correct this view by providing one of the first firm-centric empirical analyses of public-private governance choices and longevity implications, by illustrating how private actor governance preferences may be systematically reflected in the selection and fit of underlying organizational structures. In our study we likewise deliberately focus on the longevity or duration of public-private ties as an implicit measure reflecting the underlying performance of the relationship. Yet, as a number of scholars in alliance literature suggest, longevity as a construct, even if still widely used, may not provide enough information about the effectiveness of collaboration (Kale, Dyer, & Singh, 2002), blur the important distinction between outcome and process performance (Ariño, 2003) and ignore other 14 Unfortunately, very limited systematic and (across-time) comparable data are available on the levels of corruption in the developing market context, which represents the empirical setting of our study. For the purposes of the present study, we collected internationally recognized measures and data, such as Corruption Perception Index (estimated from 1995 by Transparency International); however, due to changes in the index estimation methods and a limited number of relevant country observations were not able to use it in our present data sample. 47 sources of value that may arise even in prematurely terminated interorganizational engagements. In our case, we believe it reasonable to assume that the longer the public-private engagement is operational, the higher the potential pool of public or total value it creates, and, hence, the higher its overall performance (while short-lived alliances may provide one-off shot of private benefits and collapse thereafter). Yet, refining and testing alternative, more direct measures of public-private tie performance, such as the extent of public and private goal fulfilment, represents an important avenue for future research. At last, certain limitations relate to the empirical setting and data sample of the present study. First of all, we acknowledge that focusing our analysis on the developing country context may be restrictive as we are not able to compare the governance choices and stability of public-private arrangements observed in these settings with those present in more inherently stable market and institutional environment conditions, i.e. developed countries. We intend to address this limitation in future research work by adding the original data (in collection) on public-private governance arrangements in the water sector in the developed country context, for the equivalent period of 1991-2011. Importantly, this would also allow us to enlarge substantially the sample size and increase the validity and reliability of results. We also recognize that our reliance on the World Bank dataset implies that several limitations that characterize this dataset are also present in our study. Two key issues can be raised – the underrepresentation of small public-private projects in this dataset (The World Bank PPI Database: Extended Methodology 2007), as well as the potential underreporting of distressed projects (with project distress rates as reported by the World Bank of 12-17% being lower than estimates from other sources). None of these methodological limitations, however, in our opinion, raise sufficiently high concerns as to invalidate our analysis. At last we also note certain limitations and future research work with regards to the specification of certain variables and additional robustness checks in our empirical models. Most notably, further work is required to devise a measure able to reflect to a sufficiently robust degree our social volatility construct. While we do use a theoretically relevant proxy, based on the anti-private ownership 48 sentiment measure, it may not entirely capture the potential likelihood or feasibility of social protests or contestation. Other factors, such as, for example, the degree of restrictions on the protest or free speech rights in developing countries may influence and alter significantly the link between antiprivate sentiments and the expression of those sentiments through various (e.g. protest, boycott etc.) means. We also recognize that further work may be required to test the robustness and enhance estimation methods applied in our analysis. More specifically, for testing the governance choice a more complex approach may be envisaged, based on simultaneous equation models, as one could argue that governance choices, such as operational model and ownership share (as well as other contractual features), may be determined simultaneously. A further, more complex estimation method may also be called for testing partnership longevity. Since organizational actors are able to self-select into a particular form of governance, and, the relative misfit of the governance may be driven by other variables, such as the level of adaptive capabilities, which are, in turn, strongly tied to performance, hence, potential endogeneity and selection concerns may need to be addressed further. Conclusion By exploring public-private governance choice and longevity in the context of public-private water sector engagements in the developing world, our analysis represents one of the first systematic empirical accounts of the environmental determinants likely to shape the structural preferences and outcomes in public-private ties as novel hybrid organizational forms. By focusing on the multi-faceted nature of environmental uncertainty, specifically, our analysis uncovers both market-based and broader institutional environment related contingencies likely to significantly shape public-private governance selection and longevity. By differentiating between political, social and market–based facets of environmental uncertainty, we propose and find support for an argument that alternative, hybrid forms of public-private governance may co-exist with each alternative structure able to differentially address the type of contingencies surrounding the underlying exchange. Our findings illustrate that organizational actors in developing country environments are able to selectively adjust and intentionally adopt public-private governance structures and features to ones 49 deemed as more fit in the light of underlying environmental hazards, particularly, from the private actor’s perspective. Failure to do so is suggested to be a significant predictor of a premature distress or termination of underlying relationship. Moreover, our study highlights the critical impact that institutional, not mere transactional, alignment between adopted governance and the ex ante external environment conditions plays in the formation and duration of underlying organizational ties. From a broader theoretical perspective, the insights presented in this paper contribute to the emerging view on hybrid organizational forms as exhibiting a high degree of variation in governance features, a divergent degree of ability to mitigate or address the hazards surrounding the exchange, and facing a range of governance trade-offs likely to affect the longevity or duration of underlying engagements. 50 FIGURES AND TABLES FIGURE 1: Expanding the Governance Spectrum: Public-Private Ties as Distinct Hybrid Governance Forms Unassisted market h =0 Unrelieved hazard s=0 Private hybrid contracting h >0 Private hierarchy s>0 Public-private hybrid contracting (and regulation) Public agency Note: k is an index of contractual hazard and s denotes contractual safeguards Source: Adapted from Williamson,1999 FIGURE 2: Public-Private Arrangements: From Theoretical to Empirical Forms Autonomous Integrative Predominantly private Operational model End-user payment based Financial or revenue model Predominantly (or temporarily) private Legend: Ownership model* Management contracts Lease or affermage contracts Concessions * On the basis of core asset (infrastructure) ownership Source: Adapted from Kivleniece & Quelin (2012) 51 Joint (shared) Public actor payment based Predominantly public (or shared) TABLE 1: Overview of Empirical Public-Private Arrangement Types in Water Infrastructure and Services Sector Empirical arrangement Management contract Lease or affermage contract Concession (incl. greenfield) Divestiture4 Operator duties Provides management services to the utility in return for a fee Manages the operations, retains a fee from customers based on volume sold, but does not invest in infrastructure Manages the operations, including the investment in infrastructure yet rarely is the permanent owner of infrastructure assets2 Manages operations, finances investment and owns infrastructure assets Operator’s profit function Sub type Operational model Revenue model Ownership Core asset Equity1 Matching theoretical governance form Integrative Fixed fee + bonus – staff cost and related expense Revenue from customers (fee x volume) – operating and maintenance costs - Joint Public payment Public Casebased - Joint End-user payment Public Casebased Mixed features Revenue from customers – operating and maintenance costs, investment costs, and any concession fee BOT Private Private Temporarily private Private BROT Private RLT Private ROT Private Partial Joint Temporarily private Temporarily private Temporarily private Mixed Casebased Casebased Casebased Casebased Casebased Mixed Autonomous BOO End-user payment3 End-user payment3 End-user payment3 End-user payment3 End-user payment3 End-user payment Full Private End-user payment Private Private - Revenue from customers – operating and maintenance costs, investment, any license fee Autonomous Autonomous Autonomous Autonomous - 1 Note that in public-private contractual arrangements equity (i.e. project company) ownership is not equivalent to core asset (i.e. infrastructure) ownership, and varies on case-by-case basis. We, accordingly, devise a separate measure to classify observed arrangements into “autonomous vs. integrative” forms on the basis of private actor’s equity stake in public-private project company. 2 In certain forms of greenfield investment, such as Build-Own-Operate (BOO) schemes, private operator may retain the eventual ownership to infrastructure assets. 3 For several concession projects, such as treatment plants, sales may be directly derived from utilities or public actors, e.g. municipalities. Hence, the coding above, in terms of revenue model, may be strictly applied only to utilities. 4 Note that the divestiture of public equity stake in utilities operator may be partial or full (i.e. 100%). Subtype abbreviations correspond to: BOO: Build-own-operate BOT: Build-own-transfer BROT: Build-rehabilitate-operate-transfer RLT: Rehabilitate-lease-or-rent-transfer ROT: Rehabilitate-operate-transfer Source: Adapted on the basis of “Private Participation in Infrastructure (PPI) Database: Extended Methodology”, The World Bank, June 2007. 52 TABLE 2: Summary Statistics Nr 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 Variable Operational governance form Private equity share Governance misfit Mixed governance, dummy Dom. industry governance (oper.) Dom. industry governance (equity) Political constraints (POLCON) Social volatility (proxy) Utility, dummy Local level, dummy Potable water services, dummy Stability, dummy Duration, years Contract length Reawarded project, dummy Related project, dummy Nb of systems Government support Multilateral financing Nb of private actors Foreign actor involvement, dummy Local actor involvement, dummy Initial investment Capacity (level) Competitive award, dummy GDP GDP growth Population Population density Political freedom Water access Water infrastructure, piped Sanitation access Agricultural land Extreme conditions Obs 271 271 158 271 271 271 250 240 271 204 271 271 271 267 271 271 271 271 271 265 264 265 260 261 271 268 268 268 268 266 270 270 270 268 268 Mean 1.579336 0.947085 0.261713 0.118081 1.579428 0.931956 0.41028 63.36625 0.760148 0.470588 0.848709 0.118081 8.99262 21.42322 0.055351 0.073801 1.04059 0.317343 12.05535 1.562264 0.560606 0.596226 107.5613 0.509579 0.512915 3944.297 2.507933 1.26E+08 63.1067 3.06391 89.70741 73.21852 72.52222 38.17654 0.780431 Std. Dev. 0.740481 0.144804 0.291109 0.323301 0.23216 0.035091 0.195159 9.833688 0.427783 0.500362 0.358996 0.323301 4.69041 9.252753 0.229086 0.26193 0.289018 0.706343 59.24513 0.877373 0.497256 0.491582 341.8524 0.767679 0.500758 2483.054 3.359204 2.23E+08 96.50196 1.458758 8.924276 22.58796 18.58642 16.2635 1.233303 Min 0 0.3 0.000094 0 0.667 0.87 0 34.6 0 0 0 0 0 2 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 172.0287 -8.56462 257300 2.352026 1 40 3 7 2.124277 0 Max 2 1 0.995715 1 2 1 0.69 86.7 1 1 1 1 20 50 1 1 4 2 781 5 1 1 4000 2 1 10710.07 13.74159 1.21E+09 625.0512 7 100 99 100 82.04402 7.525066 1 1 0.0542 -0.52 -0.3111 0.301 0.0076 0.0235 0.1457 -0.2684 -0.0065 -0.1865 -0.06 0.036 0.5899 -0.1403 -0.1328 -0.0677 0.2038 0.0186 0.0707 -0.2078 0.1293 0.1363 -0.2325 -0.0551 0.3021 0.0084 -0.0956 -0.1543 -0.257 0.2088 0.189 0.1151 -0.0948 -0.2675 53 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 1 -0.137 -0.1448 0.0196 0.1892 -0.0531 -0.0591 0.1267 0.0568 -0.0818 0.0604 0.0652 -0.0866 0.1018 -0.0102 0.0366 0.0084 -0.0103 0.1588 -0.2039 0.3171 -0.0512 -0.0569 -0.061 0.1389 -0.0186 -0.134 -0.1257 -0.0468 0.0612 0.0936 0.0099 0.0981 -0.0361 1 0.6754 -0.232 0.0466 0.0054 0.0582 0.419 0.1017 0.2591 0.0596 0.0017 -0.2716 0.1125 0.1695 0.0874 -0.0804 0.1029 -0.1342 0.0618 -0.0038 0.0442 0.1892 -0.0003 -0.2141 0.0682 0.0745 0.0988 0.1478 -0.0868 -0.0861 -0.1363 0.0549 0.0998 1 -0.1693 0.1766 -0.0121 0.1104 0.208 0.049 0.1585 0.0605 0.0011 -0.0132 -0.003 0.1599 -0.0144 -0.1804 0.0579 -0.1257 0.0336 0.0101 -0.0418 0.1302 -0.0791 -0.122 0.114 -0.1132 -0.0682 0.1911 -0.0889 0.0068 -0.0213 -0.1137 -0.0904 1 -0.18 0.1434 -0.1262 -0.1604 -0.028 -0.122 0.0378 0.0191 0.1648 0.0109 -0.0353 -0.0972 0.003 0.1269 0.2362 0.1019 -0.0262 0.1884 0.0464 -0.1611 0.2572 0.1063 0.052 0.0299 -0.1803 0.0937 0.069 0.0526 0.156 -0.1039 1 -0.1196 -0.0034 0.0139 0.0015 0.0543 0.1098 0.342 -0.1066 -0.0411 0.0214 0.089 0.0016 0.1806 -0.0336 -0.0416 0.0604 0.0647 -0.0489 -0.2275 -0.2402 -0.0554 -0.2541 -0.2066 0.3067 -0.129 0.0882 0.0104 -0.1117 -0.0701 1 -0.0961 0.2044 -0.0753 0.0768 0.0553 0.2272 0.157 -0.1373 -0.0526 -0.0087 -0.2408 0.0636 -0.0232 -0.0285 0.0065 0.1167 0.0398 0.0842 0.2771 -0.1289 0.0494 -0.0718 -0.4946 0.288 0.1761 0.2251 0.0433 0.0316 1 -0.0338 -0.0317 0.0478 -0.1521 -0.268 0.0705 0.0739 0.1567 0.147 0.173 -0.1658 -0.0601 -0.2156 0.1029 -0.0737 -0.0066 0.0293 -0.1424 -0.006 0.1177 0.0964 -0.015 0.1765 0.0894 -0.074 -0.4266 -0.1534 1 0.0078 0.508 0.0239 0.0858 0.0539 0.0816 0.0905 0.0705 -0.234 0.071 -0.0664 -0.1833 0.1341 0.0607 0.2192 0.081 -0.0238 -0.0532 -0.1416 -0.1077 -0.1314 0.1266 0.0891 0.1458 0.0134 0.0022 1 -0.1289 -0.0979 0.0729 -0.0765 -0.0386 -0.1257 0.0097 -0.1585 -0.0945 -0.1603 -0.1189 0.1307 -0.1861 -0.2698 -0.2221 -0.1519 0.0574 0.0083 -0.0192 0.042 -0.0384 -0.0167 -0.1709 0.1083 0.0007 1 0.0515 -0.0674 0.0663 0.1119 0.1477 0.0371 -0.091 0.0718 0.0211 -0.0212 -0.0451 0.0708 0.1164 0.0854 -0.2399 -0.0145 -0.0247 0.0992 0.0736 -0.0894 -0.1678 0.0404 -0.0259 0.1133 1 -0.2828 -0.0618 -0.0082 0.012 -0.0714 -0.0587 0.2971 0.089 0.2185 -0.0977 0.2134 0.1655 -0.0615 0.0434 -0.3122 -0.13 -0.0412 -0.0267 -0.0687 -0.0617 0.028 0.1106 -0.007 TABLE 2: Summary Statistics (cont.) Nr 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 Variable Duration, years Contract length Reawarded project, dummy Related project, dummy Nb of systems Government support Multilateral financing Nb of private actors Foreign actor involvement, dummy Local actor involvement, dummy Initial investment Capacity (level) Competitive award, dummy GDP GDP growth Population Population density Political freedom Water access Water infrastructure, piped Sanitation access Agricultural land Extreme conditions 13 1 0.1 -0.04 -0.049 -0.037 -0.272 0.077 0.132 0.069 0.05 0.12 0.024 -0.283 -0.033 -0.113 -0.217 -0.216 -0.014 -0.026 0.069 0.128 0.157 -0.183 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 1 -0.184 0.032 -0.169 -0.076 0.061 0.096 -0.166 0.072 0.175 -0.006 0.026 0.31 -0.028 -0.063 -0.129 -0.332 0.246 0.125 0.184 -0.162 -0.168 1 0.664 -0.049 -0.005 0.037 0.13 -0.024 0.048 0.155 0.185 0.134 -0.19 0.096 -0.092 0.176 0.176 -0.113 -0.162 -0.043 0.06 -0.022 1 -0.065 -0.081 -0.023 -0.074 -0.047 -0.028 -0.015 0.197 0.069 -0.11 0.138 -0.124 0.069 0.14 -0.039 -0.044 0.068 -0.124 -0.067 1 0.13 -0.04 -0.051 -0.129 0.059 -0.056 -0.133 0.073 -0.18 0.048 0.274 0.231 0.013 -0.067 -0.123 -0.235 0.086 0.232 1 -0.085 0.087 -0.153 0.204 -0.047 -0.245 0.242 0.092 0.019 0.129 0.04 0.02 0.052 0.126 -0.119 0.037 0.049 1 0.112 0.132 -0.107 0.811 0.283 0.063 0.02 0.09 -0.061 -0.025 -0.007 -0.008 -0.055 0.039 0.019 -0.066 1 0.139 0.326 0.238 0.068 0.092 0.017 -0.01 0.015 0.143 -0.149 -0.092 -0.155 -0.069 0.167 0.046 1 -0.701 0.155 0.262 0.071 -0.17 -0.092 -0.056 0.132 0.053 -0.289 -0.246 -0.003 0.197 0.078 1 -0.116 -0.261 -0.056 0.079 0.042 0.12 0.024 -0.107 0.091 0.062 -0.188 0.01 0.016 1 0.363 0.08 0.114 -0.014 -0.075 0.009 -0.111 0.095 -0.043 0.122 -0.014 -0.1 1 0.165 -0.008 0.048 -0.157 -0.036 0.08 0.034 -0.026 0.211 -0.076 -0.174 1 0.14 0.094 0.106 0.131 -0.197 0.076 -0.01 0.081 0.039 0.11 1 -0.144 -0.28 -0.523 -0.437 0.539 0.549 0.547 -0.05 -0.452 1 0.302 0.329 0.091 -0.023 -0.209 -0.21 -0.029 0.209 1 0.819 -0.189 -0.162 -0.577 -0.734 0.269 0.711 1 -0.071 -0.322 -0.776 -0.728 0.345 0.736 1 -0.287 -0.049 -0.028 -0.268 -0.148 54 31 32 33 34 35 1 0.699 1 0.648 0.778 1 -0.263 -0.322 -0.308 1 -0.206 -0.551 -0.594 0.373 1 TABLE 3: Results of Ordered Probit Analysis on Governance Choice (Operational Form) VARIABLES Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Controls W/Expl.var. W/Interaction Full -0.349 (0.34) -0.915 (1.43) -0.840* (0.49) -6.025* (3.32) -3.518** (1.60) 6.352* (3.33) 0.021 (0.03) -1.800** (0.90) -6.658* (3.78) -3.804** (1.85) 6.827* (3.84) 0.038 (0.03) -1.742* (1.03) 1.214 (1.40) 2.175** (1.00) -1.266** -1.252 -1.008 (0.52) (1.18) (1.01) Contract length 0.117*** 0.100*** 0.112*** (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) Reawarded project 2.276*** 1.056 1.018 (0.80) (0.97) (1.02) Related projects -1.780*** -1.709** -1.716** (0.61) (0.69) (0.73) Nb of systems 0.184 0.094 0.088 (0.35) (0.40) (0.37) Government support 0.742*** 0.379 0.293 (0.26) (0.33) (0.34) Multilateral financing 0.0004 0.001 0.001 (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) Nb of private actors 0.073 0.516 0.339 (0.26) (0.46) (0.46) Foreign actor involvement -0.358 -1.593* -1.227 (0.60) (0.95) (0.99) Local actor involvement -0.034 -0.693 -0.597 (0.50) (0.78) (0.81) Initial investment 0.003** 0.003* 0.003* (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) Capacity -0.591*** -0.749** -0.837** (0.23) (0.35) (0.36) Competitive award -0.435 -0.087 -0.088 (0.34) (0.50) (0.52) Country-level controls yes yes yes Constant/cut1 -3.894* -4.573 -2.75 (2.19) (4.95) (5.02) Constant/cut2 -2.819 -3.472 -1.596 (2.18) (4.94) (5.01) McFadden's R2 0.494 0.529 0.549 Log likelihood -71.833 -51.233 -49.003 Observations (n) 179 148 148 Standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 -1.36 (1.27) 0.108*** (0.03) 0.438 (1.11) -1.536** (0.75) -0.063 (0.37) 0.173 (0.36) 0.000 (0.01) 0.084 (0.48) -1.43 (1.06) -0.633 (0.87) 0.004* (0.00) -0.925** (0.40) 0.457 (0.61) yes 2.302 (5.62) 3.529 (5.63) 0.582 -45.461 148 Political constaints (POLCON) Local level POLCON X Local level Social volatility (proxy) -0.008 (0.03) -1.943** (0.93) Utility, dummy Private equity share Dominant industry governance (operational) Project-level controls Potable water services 55 Model 4 TABLE 4: Results of GLM Regression Analysis on Governance Choice (Equity-Based) VARIABLES Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Controls W/Expl.var. W/Interaction Full 0.142 (0.47) -0.72 (1.61) -0.178 (0.77) -7.784** (3.14) -4.769*** (1.73) 11.382*** (4.20) 0.019 (0.06) 0.711 (0.66) -6.365* (3.43) -3.517** (1.78) 8.360** (3.97) -0.025 (0.07) 0.757 (0.65) 0.618 (0.71) 16.416* (9.74) Political constaints (POLCON) Local level POLCON X Local level Social volatility (proxy) -0.015 (0.05) 0.551 (0.76) Utility, dummy Operational governance form Dominant industry governance (equity-based) Project-level controls Potable water services -0.566 -0.309 -0.022 (0.74) (1.19) (1.51) Contract length -0.054 -0.06 -0.069 (0.04) (0.05) (0.05) Reawarded project 1.735* 14.303*** 15.167*** (1.04) (1.50) (1.73) Related projects -0.409 -0.351 0.358 (0.71) (0.66) (0.76) Nb of systems 0.794 0.695 0.735 (0.55) (0.61) (0.74) Government support 0.183 0.073 -0.223 (0.31) (0.45) (0.46) Multilateral financing 0.006 0.003 0.004 (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) Nb of private actors 0.621 0.439 0.341 (0.43) (0.44) (0.42) Foreign actor involvement 0.27 0.435 1.124 (1.34) (1.47) (1.54) Local actor involvement 2.048 2.072 2.206 (1.44) (1.63) (1.51) Initial investment -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) Capacity 0.174 0.213 0.222 (0.30) (0.33) (0.28) Competitive award -0.45 -0.443 -0.196 (0.43) (0.56) (0.57) Country-level controls yes yes yes Constant -0.869 -1.247 1.724 (2.80) (6.79) (6.16) Log pseudolikelihood -26.942 -20.68 -19.317 Observations (n) 179 148 148 Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 56 0.469 (1.25) -0.103*** (0.04) 16.359*** (1.38) 0.575 (0.56) 0.591 (0.85) -0.296 (0.37) 0.003 (0.01) 0.338 (0.36) 1.334 (1.81) 2.243 (1.55) -0.002 (0.00) 0.306 (0.36) 0.193 (0.58) yes -14.892 (13.72) -18.64 148 TABLE 5: Results of Probit Regression Analysis on Longevity (inversed measure, dummy) VARIABLES Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Controls Gov form M ixed form Governance misfit M isfit 1.456** (0.72) Mixed governance 0.573 (0.37) Operational governance form Project-level controls Private equity share Model 4 -0.114 (0.24) 0.733 (0.85) 0.047*** (0.02) -0.213*** (0.04) -1.108 (1.11) 0.558 (0.52) -0.093 (0.19) 0.005** (0.00) -0.196 (0.18) 1.563*** (0.41) 0.914** (0.45) -0.024 (0.20) -0.708** (0.34) 5.602*** (1.93) -0.02 (0.02) -0.548*** (0.15) -3.719*** (0.95) 4.778*** (1.05) -0.58 (0.41) 0.037*** (0.01) 1.588*** (0.40) 0.444 (0.80) -1.236* (0.73) -0.972** (0.47) -1.163 (0.82) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.00 0.00 0.00 GDP growth -0.173*** -0.172*** -0.178*** (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) Water access -0.047** -0.048** -0.047** (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) Water infrastructure, piped 0.015 0.016 0.017 (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) Agricultural land 0.015* 0.015* 0.016* (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) Extreme conditions -0.157 -0.161 -0.141 (0.16) (0.17) (0.16) Constant 1.31 1.333 0.729 (1.73) (1.72) (1.70) McFadden's R2 0.402 0.403 0.414 Log likelihood (full model) -53.170 -53.092 -52.179 Observations (n) 244 244 244 Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 0.000 0.00 -0.603*** (0.16) 0.021 (0.05) 0.026 (0.02) 0.054*** (0.02) -0.003 (0.29) -9.38 (5.82) 0.800 -11.096 154 Contract length Duration Reawarded project Related projects Government support Multilateral financing Nb of private actors Foreign actor involvement Local actor involvement Capacity Competitive award 0.498 (0.83) 0.043*** (0.02) -0.207*** (0.04) -1.056 (0.99) 0.674 (0.45) -0.134 (0.19) 0.005** (0.00) -0.208 (0.17) 1.534*** (0.41) 0.966** (0.45) -0.009 (0.19) -0.699** (0.33) Country-level controls GDP 57 0.557 (0.83) 0.048** (0.02) -0.206*** (0.04) -0.968 (1.00) 0.627 (0.49) -0.113 (0.19) 0.005** (0.00) -0.206 (0.17) 1.550*** (0.41) 0.964** (0.45) -0.021 (0.19) -0.710** (0.33) TABLE 6: Results of Survival Analysis - Accelerated Failure Time Regression, Weibull distribution (negative coefficients indicate shorter survival time) VARIABLES Model 1 Model 2 Controls Gov form M ixed form Model 3 Governance misfit -0.608 (0.52) Operational governance form Contract length Reawarded project Related projects Government support Multilateral financing Nb of private actors Foreign actor involvement Local actor involvement Capacity Competitive award M isfit -0.033 (0.81) Mixed governance Project-level controls Private equity share Model 4 0.128 (0.29) -0.84 -0.893 -1.601 (1.42) (1.39) (1.95) -0.017 -0.022 -0.021 (0.02) (0.03) (0.03) 1.222 1.132 1.258 (1.13) (1.15) (1.15) -0.801 -0.714 -0.561 (0.62) (0.72) (0.73) -0.1 -0.12 -0.114 (0.24) (0.23) (0.23) -0.002** -0.002** -0.002** (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) 0.155 0.148 0.124 (0.19) (0.19) (0.19) -1.336*** -1.314*** -1.351*** (0.48) (0.48) (0.52) -0.511 -0.47 -0.438 (0.41) (0.42) (0.39) -0.203 -0.189 -0.191 (0.18) (0.19) (0.18) 0.095 0.14 0.079 (0.30) (0.33) (0.31) Country-level controls GDP -1.338 (3.11) 0.038 (0.03) 1.659 (1.50) -1.475 (1.00) -0.396 (0.33) -0.003** (0.00) -0.167 (0.32) -0.879 (0.75) 0.049 (0.63) -0.205 (0.25) 0.271 (0.42) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 GDP growth 0.085* 0.081* 0.080* 0.198** (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.08) Water access -0.005 -0.004 -0.008 0.002 (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.04) Water infrastructure, piped 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.019 (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) Agricultural land -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 0.005 (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) Extreme conditions 0.075 0.095 0.103 -0.146 (0.16) (0.18) (0.18) (0.37) Constant 5.831** 5.667** 6.958** 4.366 (2.34) (2.50) (2.83) (5.65) Log pseudo-likelihood -67.047 -66.923 -65.920 -33.745 Observations 244 244 244 154 Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 58 REFERENCES 2007. The World Bank PPI database: Extended methodology: The World Bank, http://ppi.worldbank.org/documents/methodology_expanded_May_2007.pdf. 2012. The World Bank PPI Database: The World Bank, http://ppi.worldbank.org/. Anderson, E. 1988. Strategic implications of Darwinian economics for selling efficiency and choice of integrated or independent sales forces. Management Science, 34(5): 599618. Argyres, N. S., & Liebeskind, J. P. 1998. Contractual commitments, bargaining power, and governance inseparability: Incorporating history into transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 24(1): 49-63. Ariño, A. 2003. Measures of strategic alliance performance: An analysis of construct validity. Journal of International Business Studies, 34(1): 66-79. Barkema, H. G., Bell, J. H. J., & Pennings, J. 1996. Foreign entry, cultural barriers and learning. Strategic Management Journal, 17(2): 151-166. Barkema, H. G., Shenkar, O., Vermeulen, F., & Bell, J. H. J. 1997. Working abroad, working with others: How firms learn to operate international joint ventures. Academy of Management Journal, 40(2): 426-442. Barlow, M., & Clarke, T. 2005. Blue gold: The fight to stop the corporate theft of the world's water. New York: The New Press. Baron, D. P. 2001. Private politics, corporate social responsibility, and integrated strategy. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 10(1): 7-45. Baron, D. P. 2003. Private politics. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 12(1): 31-66. Baum, J. A. C., & Oliver, C. 1991. Institutional linkages and organizational mortality. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(2): 187-218. Bonardi, J.-P., Hillman, A. J., & Keim, G. D. 2005. The attractiveness of political markets: Implications for firm strategy. Academy of Management Review, 30(2): 397-413. Borys, B., & Jemison, D. B. 1989. Hybrid arrangements as strategic alliances: Theoretical issues in organizational combinations. Academy of Management Review, 14(2): 234249. Brunetti, A., & Weder, B. 2000. Investment and institutional uncertainty: A comparative study of different uncertainty measures: International Finance Corporation, Department of Economics Working Paper No. 4. Budds, J., & McGranahan, G. 2003. Are the debates on water privatization missing the point? Experiences from Africa, Asia and Latin America. Environment and Urbanization, 15(2): 87-114. Burnham, K. P., & Anderson, D. R. 2002. Model Selection and Multi-Model Inference. New York: Springer. Chong, E., Huet, F., & Saussier, S. 2006. Auctions, ex post competition and prices: The efficiency of public-private partnerships. Annals of Public & Cooperative Economics, 77(4): 521-554. Chong, E., Huet, F., Saussier, S., & Steiner, F. 2006. Public-private partnerships and prices: Evidence from water distribution in France. Review of Industrial Organization, 29(1): 149-169. 59 Dacin, M. T., Oliver, C., & Roy, J.-P. 2007. The legitimacy of strategic alliances: An institutional perspective. Strategic Management Journal, 28(2): 169-187. Davis, G. F., Morrill, C., Rao, H., & Soule, S. A. 2008. Introduction: Social movements in organizations and markets. Administrative Science Quarterly, 53(3): 389-394. Delios, A., & Henisz, W. J. 2003. Polical hazards, experience, and sequential entry strategies: The international expansion of Japanese firms, 1980-1998. Strategic Management Journal, 24(11): 1153-1164. Delmas, M., & Tokat, Y. 2005. Deregulation, governance structures, and efficiency: The US electric utility sector. Strategic Management Journal, 26(5): 441-460. Demil, B., & Lecocq, X. 2006. Neither market nor hierarchy nor network: The emergence of bazaar governance. Organization Studies, 27(10): 1447-1466. DiMaggio, P., Evans, J., & Bryson, B. 1996. Have American's social attitudes become more polarized? American Journal of Sociology, 102(3): 690-755. Dussauge, P., Garrette, B., & Mitchell, W. 2000. Learning from competing partners: outcomes and durations of scale and link alliances in Europe, North America and Asia. Strategic Management Journal, 21(2): 99-126. Earl, J., Martin, A., McCarthy, J. D., & Soule, S. A. 2004. The use of newspaper data in the study of collective action. Annual Review of Sociology, 30(1): 65-80. Eesley, C., & Lenox, M. J. 2006. Firm responses to secondary stakeholder action. Strategic Management Journal, 27(8): 765-781. Estache, A., & Grifell-Tatje, E. 2011. Assessing the impact of Mali's water privatization across stakeholders: CEPR Discussion Papers. Fitzpatrick, M. 1983. The definition and assessment of political risk in international business: A review of the literature. The Academy of Management Review, 8(2): 249-254. Fladmoe-Lindquist, K., & Jacque, L. L. 1995. Control modes in international service operations: The propensity to franchise. Management Science, 41(7): 1238-1250. Folta, T. B. 1998. Governance and uncertainty: The tradeoff between administrative control and commitment. Strategic Management Journal, 19(11): 1007-1028. George, G., McGahan, A. M., & Prabhu, J. 2012. Innovation for inclusive growth: Towards a theoretical framework and a research agenda. Journal of Management Studies, 49(4): 661-683. Geyskens, I., Steenkamp, J.-B. E. M., & Kumar, N. 2006. Make, buy or ally: A transaction cost theory meta-analysis. Academy of Management Journal, 49(3): 519-543. Guasch, J. L. 2004. Granting and renegotiating infrastructure concessions: Doing it right: Washington D.C.: The World Bank, WBI Development Studies. Guasch, J. L., Laffont, J.-J., & Straub, S. 2007. Concessions of infrastructure in Latin America: Government-led renegotiation. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 22(7): 1267-1294. Guasch, J. L., Laffont, J.-J., & Straub, S. 2008. Renegotiation of concession contracts in Latin America: Evidence from the water and transport sectors. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 26(2): 421-442. Gulati, R. 1998. Alliances and networks. Strategic Management Journal, 19(4): 293. Hagedoorn, J., & Hesen, G. 2007. Contract law and the governance of inter-firm technology partnerships: An analysis of different modes of partnering and their contractual implications. Journal of Management Studies, 44(3): 342-366. 60 Henisz, W. 2004. Political institutions and policy volatility. Economics and Politics, 16: 127. Henisz, W. 2006. Governance issues in public private partnerships. International Journal of Project Management, 24: 537-538. Henisz, W. 2010. POLCON Database: management.wharton.upenn.edu/henisz/. Available at http://www- Henisz, W. J. 2000a. The institutional environment for economic growth. Economics & Politics, 12(1): 1. Henisz, W. J. 2000b. The institutional environment for multinational investment. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 16(2): 334-364. Henisz, W. J. 2002. The institutional environment for infrastructure investment. Industrial & Corporate Change, 11(2): 355-389. Henisz, W. J., & Delios, A. 2004. Information or influence? The benefits of experience for managing political uncertainty. Strategic Organization, 2(4): 389-421. Henisz, W. J., & Zelner, B. A. 2001. The institutional environment for telecommunications investment. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 10(1): 123-147. Henisz, W. J., & Zelner, B. A. 2006. Interest groups, veto points, and electricity infrastructure deployment. International Organization, 60(1): 263-286. Hennart, J.-F. 1988. A transaction costs theory of equity joint ventures. Strategic Management Journal, 9(4): 361–374. Hillman, A., & Keim, G. 1995. International variation in the business-government interface: Institutional and organizational considerations. The Academy of Management Review, 20(1): 193-214. Hoang, H., & Rothaermel, F. T. 2010. Leveraging internal and external experience: Exploration, exploitation, and R&D project performance. Strategic Management Journal, 31(7): 734-758. Holburn, G. L. F., & Vanden Bergh, R. G. 2008. Making friends in hostile environments: Political strategy in regulated industries. Academy of Management Review, 33(2): 521-540. Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. 1994. The firm as an incentive system. American Economic Review, 84(4): 972-991. Kale, P., Dyer, J. H., & Singh, H. 2002. Alliance capability, stock market response, and longterm alliance success: the role of the alliance function. Strategic Management Journal, 23(8): 747-767. Keefer, P., & Stasavage, D. 2003. The limits of delegation: Veto players, central bank independence, and the credibility of monetary policy. The American Political Science Review, 97(3): 407-423. King, B. G., & Soule, S. A. 2007. Social movements as extra-institutional entrepreneurs: The effect of protests on stock price returns. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52(3): 413-442. Kivleniece, I., & Quélin, B. 2012. Creating and capturing value in public-private ties: A private actor's perspective. Academy of Management Review, 37(2): 272-299. Krishnan, R., Martin, X., & Noorderhaven, N. G. 2006. When does trust matter to alliance performance? Academy of Management Journal, 49(5): 894-917. Kumar, S. 2005. The value from acquiring and divesting a joint venture: A real options approach. Strategic Management Journal, 26(4): 321-331. 61 Kwak, Y. H., Chih, Y., & Ibbs, C. W. 2009. Towards a comprehensive understanding of public-private partnerships for infrastructure development. California Management Review, 51(2): 51-78. Landier, A., Thesmar, D., & Thoenig, M. 2008. Investigating capitalism aversion. Economic Policy, 23(55): 465-497. Langlois, R. N. 2003. The vanishing hand: The changing dynamics of industrial capitalism. Industrial and Corporate Change, 12(2): 351-385. Leiblein, M. J., Reuer, J. J., & Dalsace, F. 2002. Do make or buy decisions matter? The influence of organizational governance on technological performance. Strategic Management Journal, 23(9): 817–833. Lenssen, J. J., & Van Wassenhove, L. N. 2012. A new era of development: the changing role and responsibility of business in developing countries. Corporate Governance, 12(4): 403-413. Levy, B., & Spiller, P. T. 1994. The institutional foundations of regulatory commitment: A comparative analysis of telecommunications regulation. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 10(2): 201-246. Levy, B., & Spiller, P. T. 1996. Regulations, institutions and commitment.: Cambridge University Press: Cambridge. Lunnan, R., & Haugland, S. A. 2008. Predicting and measuring alliance performance: A multidimensional analysis. Strategic Management Journal, 29(5): 545-556. Makadok, R., & Coff, R. 2009. Both market and hierarchy: An incentive-system theory of hybrid governance forms. Academy of Management Review, 34(2): 297-319. March, J. G., & Cyert, R. M. 1963. A behavorial theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice Hall. Masten, S. E., Meehan, J. W., & Snyder, E. A. 1991. The costs of organization. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 7(1): 1-25. Milliken, F. J. 1987. Three types of perceived uncertainty about the environment: State, effect, and response uncertainty. Academy of Management Review, 12(1): 133-143. Mitchell, W., Shaver, J. M., & Yeung, B. 1994. Foreign entrant survival and foreign market share: Canadian companies' experience in United States medical sector markets. Strategic Management Journal, 15(7): 555-567. Nickerson, J. A., & Silverman, B. S. 2003. Why firms want to organize efficiently and what keeps them from doing so: Inappropriate governance, performance, and adaptation in a deregulated industry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 48(3): 433-465. Oxley, J. E. 1997. Appropriability hazards and governance in strategic alliances: A transaction cost approach. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 13(2): 387-409. Papke, L. E., & Wooldridge, J. M. 1996. Econometric methods for fractional response variables with an application to 401(k) plan participation rates. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 11(6): 619-632. Pisano, G. P. 1989. Using equity participation to support exchange: Evidence from the biotechnology industry. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 5(1): 109-126. Podolny, J. M. 1994. Market uncertainty and the social character of economic exchange. Administrative Science Quarterly, 39(3): 458-483. Prasad, N. 2006. Privatisation results: Private sector participation in water services after 15 years. Development Policy Review, 24(6): 669-692. 62 Rangan, S., Samii, R., & Van Wassenhove, L. N. 2006. Constructive partnerships: When alliances between private firms and public actors can enable creative strategies. Academy of Management Review, 31(3): 738-751. Rowan, B. 1982. Organizational structure and the institutional environment: The case of public schools. Administrative Science Quarterly, 27: 259-279. Rufin, C., & Rivera-Santos, M. 2010. Between commonweal and competition: Understanding the governance of public-private partnerships. Journal of Management: 1-21. Savedoff, W. D., & Spiller, P. T. 1999. Spilled water: Institutional commitment in the provision of water services. Washington D.C.: Inter-American Development Bank. Schlager, E., & Ostrom, E. 1992. Property-rights regimes and natural resources: A conceptual analysis. Land Economics, 68(3): 249. Silverman, B. S., Nickerson, J. A., & Freeman, J. 1997. Profitability, transactional alignment, and organizational mortality in the US trucking industry. Strategic Management Journal, 18(1): 31-52 Spiller, P. T. 1990. Politicians, interest groups, and regulators: A multiple-principals agency theory of regulation, or "let them be bribed". Journal of Law & Economics, 33(1): 65-101. Spiller, P. T. 1993. Institutions and regulatory commitment in utilities' privatization. Industrial & Corporate Change, 2: 387-450. Sutcliffe, K. M., & Zaheer, A. 1998. Uncertainty in the transaction environment: An empirical test. Strategic Management Journal, 19(1): 1-23. Thompson, J. D. 1967. Organizations in action: Social science bases of administrative theory McGraw-Hill. Turk, H. 1973. Comparative urban structure from an interorganizational perspective. Administrative Science Quarterly, 18(1): 37-55. Walker, G., & Weber, D. 1984. A transaction cost approach to make-or-buy decisions. Administrative Science Quarterly, 29(3): 373-391. Weber, K., Rao, H., & Thomas, L. G. 2009. From streets to suites: How the anti-biotech movement affected German pharmaceutical firms. American Sociological Review, 74(1): 106-127. Williamson, O. E. 1988. The logic of economic organization. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 4(1): 65-93. Williamson, O. E. 1991. Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(2): 269-296. Williamson, O. E. 1999. Public and private bureaucracies: A transaction cost economics perspectives. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 15(1): 306-342. Zarco-Jasso, H. 2010. Determinants of contract choices in public-private partnerships: An application to the water industry. Saarbrucken, Germany: LAP LAMBERT Academic Publishing. Zelner, B. A., Henisz, W. J., & Holburn, G. L. 2009. Contentious implementation and retrenchment in neoliberal policy reform: The global electric power industry, 19892001. Administrative Science Quarterly, 54(3): 379-412. Zollo, M., Reuer, J. J., & Singh, H. 2002. Interorganizational routines and performance in strategic alliances. Organization Science, 13(6): 701-713. Zucker, L. G. 1987. Institutional theories of organization. Annual Review of Sociology, 13: 443-464. 63