Modeling and Cost Analysis of Global Logistics and Manufacturing System by Te-San Liao B. S., Naval Architecture Engineering National Taiwan University, 1991 Submitted to the Department of Ocean Engineering in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degrees of Master of Science in Operations Research and Master of Science in Ocean Systems Management at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology June, 1997 C 1997 Massachusetts Institute of Technology All rights reserved ............. ........................ ......... Department of Ocean Engineering Signature of Author ...... S Certified by ......................... May 20 t , 1997 • .. • ... ..... .on ' . . . ........ Don 'B. Rosenfield Director, Leaders for Manufacturing Fellows Program S _ Thesis Supervisor Certified by ........................... t.;+16. ý .. ........ . ..... .............. Henry S. Marcus Professor, Ocean Systems Thesis Supervisor Accepted by ......................................................... . ... ............ :- s sThomas L. Magnanti or,_j.. , :t"ov George Eastman Professor of Management Science JUL 15 1997 LIBRARIES Eng. Professor of Electrical Engineering and Computer Science ., Accepted by .................................. Codirector, OpprationiS Research Center ............... . . . . . . . . . . . . ... ........... Professor, J. Kim Vandiver Chairman, Departmental Committee on Graduate Studies Modeling and Cost Analysis of Global Logistics and Manufacturing System by Te-San Liao Submitted to the Department of Ocean Engineering on May 21st, 1997 in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degrees of Master of Science in Ocean Systems Management and Master of Science in Operations Research ABSTRACT Three major transportation modes, sea shipping, railroad shipping, and trucking, are explored in terms of the factors that affect pricing policy. This thesis explores the factors and the pricing policy for each transportation mode, develops the cost model of each mode, and uses their cost models to examine the accuracy of an approximate total cost model. These cost models are also applied in estimating total distribution and operational costs in automobile industries. The effects of number of plants and their locations on total operational costs in global markets are inspected. Thesis Supervisor : Donald B., Rosenfield Title : Director, Leaders for Manufacturing Fellows Program Thesis Supervisor : Henry S., Marcus Title : Professor, Ocean Systems Acknowledgments Supports for this thesis came in many forms, technical, emotional and financial. Without undue exaggeration, the greatest contributor in all three areas was my advisor, Donald Rosenfield. He spent so much time and effort, especially in the late stages of the thesis, to read my thesis and give me advice. The entire process has been a valuable learning experience for me. Thanks for all his patience, advice and generous financial support during my thesis preparation. I would like to thank Professor Henry Marcus who served as academic advisor and thesis reader. Thanks for his help and advice during my study at MIT. I would like to thank Chia-Ming and Yu-Hsuan, my best friends at MIT. Thanks for their supports and friendship over years. To my friends at MIT and in Boston, being with them made my life at MIT full of fun and easier. Sincerest thanks to my girlfriend, Jasmine Hsing Chao, for her love, encouragement, and companionship. Finally, I would like to express my deepest appreciation to my family, my parents and sisters, for everything. Contents Page 5 List of Tables and Figures Chapter 1 Introduction Chapter 2 Transportation Costs and Models Chapter 3 7 11 2.1 Introduction and Basic Theory for Pricing ........................ 11 2.2 Sea Shipping ....................................... 2.3 Railroad Shipping .................................................... 25 2.4 Trucking .................................................... 29 ......... 14 Total Cost Model of Global System and Case Analysis 3.1 36 Case I: Comparison of the Results of the Geographic Distance Model and the U.S. Automobile Market ............................. 39 3.2 Case II: Analysis for the projected demand in the world from 1997 to 2002 ..................................................... 44 3.3 The Limitations of the Application of the Geographic Distance M odel ...................................... Chapter 4 .... ................ 51 53 Summary and Conclusion Bibliography Appendix 58 Appendix I ...................................... ................. Appendix II ...................................... ..... 58 ................. 65 List of Tables and Figures Tables Chapter 2 2.2.1 Factors of Determining Freight Structure 15 2.2.2 Detailed Cost Per 20 Feet Container (Per TEU) of 2,800 TEU ships 16 2.2.3 Layout of 'Article Matrix' of a Cost-Based Tariff of Freight Rates 19 2.2.4 Costs per Ship (2,800 TEU) on Annual Basis in Cross-Pacific Trade 22 2.2.5 Costs per Ship (1,600 TEU) on Annual Basis in Cross-Atlantic Trade 24 2.3.1 U.S. Railroad Revenue Per Carload 25 2.3.2 Railroad Freight Rate Data for 1988 27 2.4.1 Weighted Average Used in the Trucking Cost Function 33 2.4.2 Coefficient Estimates for Cost Functions of Official, South-West and Interregional Carriers 2.4.3 Elasticity of Costs with Respect to Output and Operating Characteristics at the Point of Approximation, Carrier of Specialized Commodities Chapter 3 3.1.1 The Results of Geographic Distance Model and Direct Calculation 3.1.2 Total Shipping Costs for One Plant System with Different Plant Locations 3.2.1 Annual sales of Ford Taurus in major regions in the world 3.2.2 Demand Distribution in Western Europe 3.2.3 Demand Distribution in the Far East 3.2.4 Plant Locations in the Systems with Different Numbers of Plants 3.2.5 Costs for 1-Plant & 2-Plant System 3.2.6 Costs for Two Alternatives in 3-Plant System Chapter 4 4.1 33 Change of Plants, Fixed Production Costs, and Distribution Costs 35 Appendix A.1.1 Transportation Cost in the U.S. with One Plant A.1.2 Transportation Cost in the U.S. with Two Plants A.1.3 Transportation Cost in the U.S. with Three Plants A.1.4 Transportation Cost for Alternative Plant Locations in the U.S. in One Plant Case A.2.1 Distribution Costs in Global Systems with 1 Plant A.2.2 Distribution Costs in Global Systems with 2 Plants A.2.3 Distribution Costs in Global Systems with 3 Plants (Taiwan) A.2.4 Distribution Costs in Global Systems with 3 Plants (Salt Lake City) Figure 3.1.1 Geographical Distribution of Projected Demand for Ford Taurus in the U.S Chapter 1 Introduction Transportation and information technology have developed rapidly in past years. It is now easier for companies to respond to demands for their products and to distribute their products to their clients. In addition, competitive pressures are requiring more companies to go global. In the past several years, many corporations have substantially increased the magnitude of global operations, including both manufacturing and distribution. When a company plans to set up a global manufacturing and distribution network, it must consider two major alternative systems: (1) a centralized production system building a big plant to finish the production process, and then using its distribution and logistics channels to ship its products to its clients; (2) a decentralized production system - building several plants in different places, and using the products of these plants to meet the demand in the local market or nearby markets. For example, if the company chooses the decentralized system, it may build one plant in the U.S. to meet the demands in the U.S. market, and another plant in Western Europe to meet the demands in Western Europe, Eastern Europe, and Africa. Both of these systems have their own advantages and disadvantages. According to its situation, a company will carefully choose between these two alternatives in order to reduce total operational costs and increase profits. In these two systems, the number and the locations of factories are the key factors in determining total operational costs. There are many factors that will affect decisions about the number of plants and their locations: transportation costs, manufacturing costs, taxes and duties, local issues and local restrictions, exchange-rate uncertainty, etc. These factors make a global system more complex and difficult to be analyzed. Global operations have become more important in recent years. For this reason, several authors have explored this area. Arntzen, Brown, Harrison, and Trafton (1995) used global supply chain model to analyze the manufacturing and distribution strategy of Digital Equipment Corporation'. They modeled the important issues in global system, such as, demand, production, inventory, shipping, duty drawback and duty relief. Huchzermeier and Cohen (1996) discussed the issues of valuing operational flexibility under exchange rate risk in global system 2. Rosenfield (1996) analyzed multi-regional operations and used stochastics models to simulate exchange rate uncertainty3 . Rosenfield used three major costs to compose the majority of total operational costs: production costs, distribution and handling costs, and taxes. For most products, these costs consist more than 80% of operational costs. They used a geographic distance model to model distribution and handling costs in local system4 . This model states that the average distance over which the products are shipped is proportional to the square root of the area served by the plant. Total transportation costs are also proportional to demand. The total transportation costs can be expressed as: Total Transportation Costs = A * D * r12 Here, A is a constant coefficient, D is the total demand in the whole market, and r is the average area served by each facility. Because r=R/M Therefore, Total Transportation Costs = A * D * r 2=A * D * (R / M )12 = C * D * M(112) R is the total market area served. M is number of total plants in the whole market. C is a constant and equal to A * R 12 . SArntzen, Bruce C., Brown, Gerald G., Harrison, Terry P., and Trafton, Linda L. (1995), Global Supply Chain management at DigitalEquipment Corporation,Interfaces 25, Jan.-Feb., 1995 2Huchzermeier, Arnd, and Cohen, Morris A. (1996), Valuing OperationalFlexibility UnderExchange Rate Risk, OperationsResearch, Vol. 44, No. 1, Jan. Feb., 1996 3Donald B. Rosenfield (1996), Global and Variable Cost ManufacturingSystems, European Journal of Operational Research, 1996 4Magee, John F., Copacino, William C., and Rosenfield, Donald B. (1985), Modern Logistics Management, Chapter 10, John Wiley & Sons, N.Y One of the purposes of this thesis is to test such simple approaches in estimating transportation costs. In global systems, there are four major transportation modes: sea shipping, railroad shipping, trucking and air shipping. The costs of these four models constitute total transportation costs. Every shipping mode has its specific characteristics and supply-and-demand relationship. Carriers of different shipping modes will have their specific considerations and procedures to determine their freight rates. Even though there are common factors needed to be considered in all shipping modes, these factors will have different weights in different modes. For example, distance is a critical factor in determining the freight rate of trucking. However, because facility, capacity and accessibility of seaports are very important in determining sea shipping costs, compared to these factors, distance becomes less important for sea shipping. Therefore, each shipping mode should have its unique model for freight rates. On the other hand, for different products, transportation costs are responsible for different portion of total costs. In some cases, transportation costs account for just 10% or less of total costs. However, in some other cases, the portion may be more than half of the total costs, for instance, raw material transportation. Therefore, applying oversimplified models to estimate total transportation will induce a different scale of errors in total operational costs. In the automobile industry, because many components are required to assemble a car, and it is difficult to produce all components at a same plant, automobile companies have to ship some components from other plants or component suppliers. Transportation and shipping costs become more important in the automobile industry than those in other industries. We thus explore the automobile industry because first, it is one of the largest industries in the world, and second, transportation costs are critical in the automobile industry. The objectives of this thesis are: 1. To realize the characteristics and important factors of different transportation modes, with a major product of the automobile industry. 2. To develop cost models for different transportation modes. 3. To check the accuracy of simplified models such as the Geographic Distance Model by using the freight rate models of these transportation modes. 4. To analyze and estimate global operational costs in the automobile industry. Aircraft cannot carry very heavy cargoes, because of its characteristics. For this reason, automobile companies rarely use this mode to ship their products. Therefore, the mode of air shipping is not discussed in this thesis. In Chapter Two, the general pricing theory in shipping industries is introduced. Total transportation costs are divided into three parts: sea shipping cost, railroad shipping cost and trucking cost. For each mode cost, I will analyze its specific characteristics, find the important factors in determining its freight rate, and develop its individual pricing model. Chapter Three includes two major parts. In the first part, the cost models of the three modes are combined together as the total transportation cost model. This model and the Geographic Distance Model are used to analyze the U.S. automobile market. By comparing their results, the accuracy of the Geographic Distance Model is examined. In the second part, the total transportation cost model is associated into total operational cost model. The case of a global automobile market is analyzed by using the total operational cost model. Chapter Four concludes the thesis. Chapter 2 Transportation Costs and Models 2.1 Introduction and Basic Theory for Pricing Because of the deregulation in most major modes of transportation, it is difficult to realize the pricing behavior of them by a regulated formula. The reasons are: first, there are too many factors involving in determining freight rates. Some of the factors are related to shippers, such as shipped commodity characteristics and total shipped amount. Some factors are related to carriers, such as total capacity of the individual carrier and all carriers. There are also some other factors that are unrelated to both of them, such as shipping season. Second, for different transportation modes, there are different factors resulting in total operation cost for carriers. Even when different modes have common determinants, these determinants have different weights in determining freight rates. For example, fixed cost or equipment cost is not so important for trucking, but it covers a big part for sea-shipping. Therefore, economists spent a lot of time and energy to determine a proper policy to determine freight rates. The theoretical way to approach pricing strategies for different modes of transportation is through a well-known theorem in economics. It states that a competitive equilibrium is Pareto optimal and therefore efficient in the sense that no industry can increase its output without decreasing that of another, and no individual's welfare can increase without decreasing that of another. Economists analyzing the efficiency of the surface freight industry have generally focused on competitive equilibrium as the norm.' Economists also suggest that it is a reasonable pricing policy for carriers to charge shippers the marginal shipping cost in order to get maximum profit for the whole commodity. 1 See Meyer et al. (1959) and Moore (1975) In following two examples, one in the competitive market and the other one in joint profit maximizing market, we can see what this economic theorem means, how it works, and why it is reasonable for carriers to charge marginal cost. In a competitive market, if price is less than marginal cost, price should be required to increase and then be equal to marginal cost, because of over-utilization of resources and increasing demand in that sector. If price is greater than marginal cost, then through the function of supply-and-demand in economic market, then the normative price should be forced to decrease to attract demand and then be equal to marginal cost. Here, demand is estimated on an industry level and is postulated to be a function of rates, trip attributes, non-transportation output, etc., and cost is estimated on a firm level and is postulated to be a function of output, factor prices, and trip characteristics. On the other hand, in joint profit maximizing market, if one firm, through ownership, or a group of firms, through collusion, were to gain monopoly power in an industry, it has enough power to affect market price. Neoclassical economic theory states that the industry will produce where marginal cost equals marginal revenue in order to maximize profits for the whole community. It is obvious that the firm will not allow a market price less than marginal cost, otherwise it will lose money. Moreover, the firm will tend to set the price as high as it can in order to get more profit. However, when the market price is greater than marginal cost, even though the firm can get more profit, there is a "deadweight loss" in the whole community. "Deadweight loss" is not characteristics of customers or the firm, but lost in the whole system. From the viewpoint of resource efficiency for the whole system, because a resource is used and no benefit is produced, this is not an efficiently economic system. Therefore, in an industry that produces many outputs, profit will be maximized where marginal cost equals marginal revenue for each commodity. From the previous two examples, apparently, charging marginal cost is reasonable and efficient for carriers, shippers and the whole system. Therefore, the policy of charging marginal shipping cost is generally accepted and used as the basic rule in current freight rate structure for most transportation modes. I also use a marginal cost model to approach freight rate in this thesis. In addition to economic forces, federal transportation policy is another important determinant of transportation activity. This includes not only the equilibrium quantity of service, but also its quality and cost. It is fairly easy to visualize how transportation regulation, through restrictions on entry, rates and routes, can affect the equilibrium service and costs of a particular mode. What should be realized is that because the various modes are in competition, the relative service levels of all modes have been affected. It should be noted that there are many modes competing for freight, for instance, railroad, trucking, barge, pipeline and air freight. However, tractability calls for the problem to be segmented. Pipelines mainly carry natural gas and petroleum products in large volumes. Barge competes mainly with rail for bulk commodities. Air freight makes up a very small share of the transportation market. Trucking is both a substitute and complement for railroad transportation. Full truckload truck transportation competes directly with rail, and less than truckload lot truck transportation offers a service complementary to that of rail. In this thesis, my focused commodity is motor vehicle. Because of the high freight rate and the capacity constraint of air shipping, most of these commodities are not shipped through air. So I will not discuss the freight structure of air shipping. In this chapter, I focus on the pricing behavior of three shipping modes: sea shipping (Section II), railroad shipping (Section 111), and trucking (Section IV). In each section, I will generally discuss the important factors in determining marginal cost and freight rate of this mode, and the effect of these factors on the pricing behavior. Finally, I will use the existing data to develop an individual mathematical model for this mode. 2.2 Sea Shipping The most conspicuous feature of the sea-shipping tariff has been its size: practically every one of hundreds or more different articles are separately identified so that each can, in principle, carry an individual freight rate. When, as is common, a separate rate is quoted for each specific commodity, one speaks about 'commodity rates'. A single tariff may include several thousands of commodity rates. In some tariffs, freight rates are divided into ten to twenty classes, and the commodities are assigned to different classes. These quotations also apply to containerized cargo. For a less-than-full container load, commodity rates as published for conventional cargo normally apply. For a full container load, a simplified tariff which may include twenty or thirty commodity classes normally used. Based on the principle of economic theory described in Section 2.1, the freight rate structure can be approached by marginal costs. There are many factors that participate in shaping the level and structure of freight rates, and which makes it very difficult to compare individual freight rates. For example, the following rather exhaustive list (Table 2.2.1) of twenty-seven factors was suggested by the US delegates in the Inter-American Maritime Conference in 1941. Table 2.2.1 Factors of Determining Freight Structure (Source: Inter-American Maritime Conference, Report of Delegates of the United States, Washington, Government printing Office, 1941) 1. Character of cargo 23. Port regulations 2. Volume of cargo 24. Port charges and dues 3. Availability of cargo 25. Canal tolls 4. Susceptibility to damage 26. Port location 5. Susceptibility to pilferage 27. Possibility of securing return cargo 6. Value of goods 7. Packing 8. Direct cost of operation 9. Distance 10. Cost of handling 11. Lighterage 12. Special deliveries or devices 13. Fixed charges 14. Insurance 15. Package 16. Stowage 17. Heavy lifts 18. Extra length 19. Goods from other sources of supply 20. Goods via competitive gateways 21. Competition from other carriers 22. Port facilities For costing purposes, the marginal cost of the kth cargo can conveniently be divided into three parts: (1) Fixed cost component, (2) Direct cargo cost component, (3) Indirect cost component. We can see more detailed components in these three groups and their percentage of total cost in Table 2.2.2 Table 2.2.2 Detailed Cost Per 20 Feet Container (Per TEU) of 2,800 container ships (Source: Container Market Profitability to 1997) 1. Fixed Costs $ Per Teu Bunkers 61 3.5 Ports 62 3.6 Capital 168 9.7 Operating 133 7.7 Administration 281 16.2 Subtotal 707 40.8 Terminals 286 16.5 Transport 470 27.1 Depots 7 0.4 Refrigeration 7 0.4 Subtotal 769 44.4 Empty Containers 85 4.9 Equipment Provision 88 5.1 Maintain & Repair 68 3.9 Cargo Insurance 16 0.9 Subtotal 256 14.8 1733 100 2. Direct costs 3. Indirect Costs Total Costs Explanation: Fixed costs: the cost irrelative to shipping quantity * Bunkers - Fuel for the ship's engines. * Ports - Pilotage, towage, dockage fees, port dues, etc. * Capital - Payments toward equity in the vessel, including interest charges. * Operating - Stores and lubes, ship repairs and maintenance, insurance and managing the ship * Administration - Managing the movement of cargo through the service network Direct Costs: the cost relative to shipping quantity and induced in the shipping process directly * Terminals - Moving containers on and off the vessel, including terminal gate charges, crane usage, transfers, removal of hatch covers and all other interminal cargo expenses * Transport - Cargo movement by rail, truck or barge from the port to an inland destination * Depots - Costs for consolidating cargo into full container loads (stuffing/stripping) at container freight stations * Refrigeration - Cost for provision of refrigeration facilities and monitoring the temperature of frozen cargo Indirect Costs: the cost relative to shipping quantity and induced indirectly * Empty Containers - Cost for restowage, transportation and loading of empties. Does not include opportunity cost of not carrying full containers * Equipment Provision - Cost for containers and trailers, includes both leasing and purchasing costs * Maintenance & Repair - Costs for maintaining containers and trailers * Cargo Insurance - Covers the cargo on both the land and sea portions of the trip The investigation of the structure of break-bulk cargo handling costs 2 indicates that a very substantial proportion of the variations in both the direct and indirect handling costs are explained by the package type, the package weight, and the "stowage factor". Here, the definition of "stowage factor" is the ratio of package measurement (including broken stowage) to package weight. Alternatively, we can use package measurement as a substitute for the stowage factor to describe characteristics of cargo and this does not reduce the explanatory power by much3 . By the suggestion of Jansson and Shneerson 4,the marginal costs of different cargoes and the cargo characteristics can be describe by: MCijk = (aijk * m)+(bijk * w)+ Cij k Where MCijk : the marginal cost of shipping from the ith port to the jth port an article of the kth package type m : package measurement w : package weight aijk * m : measurement-proportional cost component bijk * w : weight-proportional cost component cijk : fixed cost per package unit (independent of package size) In the common case where more than one port is called in each service range, the tariff construction will be somewhat involved, in view of the likely possibility that some of the coefficients, aijk, bijk, and cijk take different values for different ports for each given package type. 2 Jansson J. 0., and Shneerson D. (1982), PortEconomics 3Jansson J. 0., and Shneerson D. (1986), Liner Shipping Economics, Chapter11 4 Jansson J. 0., and Shneerson D. (1986), Liner Shipping Economics, Chapter11 The technically most suitable tariff format would be a number of "article matrices" of the kind shown by Fig. 2.2.3 with three entries for each pair of ports. One entry gives the charge per m 3 , a second entry gives the charge per ton (1000kg), and a third entry gives the fixed charge per package unit, which consequently is independent of the package size. Table 2.2.3 Layout of 'Article Matrix' of a Cost-Based Tariff of Freight Rates Port of loading First port Second port Port of unloading 3 a21 per m First port X b2 1 per ton C21 a12 per m 3 Second port bl 2 per ton X C12 There have to be as many article matrices as there are package types. The most insignificant package types could perhaps be grouped together under a heading like 'general cargo, not otherwise specified'. The previous example suggests that a range of package weights be specified. An additional charge could be levied on exceptional units, both on unusually small and unusually big units, if there are good cost reasons for this. More important is a peak and off-peak differential. The basic freight rates should be specified to apply to a period of time, i.e. the slack season. Outside this period, one or more extra peak charges should be levied on top of the basic freight rates. However, Table 2.2.3 does not show this kind of modification for this issue. Finally, a quantity rebate may be justified. If this is the case, a simple way of making the freight rate of a given article taper off with increases in the size of shipments is to levy a fixed charge per shipment. This may also be justified on account of clerical work required in connection with the documentation, etc. which is largely independent of the size of the shipment. The logical extension of the pricing principles to containers is immediate. Containers represent one class of package type. Only one 'article matrix' of the kind described in the previous paragraph may be required. Freight rates for modules other than 20-foot containers should either be a multiple of the basic freight rates for 20 footers, or the other modules could be defined as separate articles. In fact, for container shipping, the tariff might be further simplified, without great loss in efficiency. The fixed charge, cij, and even the charge per ton, bij, could be superfluous; the former because it would practically be identical to all containers, and the latter because for containerizable cargo, the effect of weight will be nil in most cases. The tariff would then have a single charge per cubic meter that will vary according to the ports of loading and unloading. For example, company A is an automobile company and plans to use containers to ship its cars from Yokohama, Japan to Long Beach, California. Company B is a lumber company and also plans to use containers to ship its lumber from the same origin to same destination. Because of the volume constraint of containers and because of safety reasons, company A just can use a 20-feet container to hold one car and nothing else. Company B also uses 20-feet containers to ship its lumber. Because both of them use the same size of containers, even though the size, the weight and the value of their cargoes are different, the fixed cost for one container of these two kinds of cargoes will be similar. On the other hand, compared to the total shipping tonnage of a ship, the difference between the weights of a container of these two kinds of cargoes is still very small. The weight factor of cargoes can be neglected. Therefore, the critical determinant factor is the volume of containers. The distance between loading and unloading ports is the most important factor in determining coefficient aj. When the distance is longer, aj will become larger. The other factors which will affect coefficient ai are the conditions of the ports. These conditions include geographical conditions, facility conditions, etc. However, cost-based tariffs outlined above will look very different from the present liner conference tariffs. The radical difference is the type of commodity. Commodity type is chief determinant in the current freight rate system, but is not so important in the proposed tariff system. It is mainly in cases where commodities are handled in loose form that the commodity type is a principal cost factor. Packaged cargo is very dominating so far as liner shipping is concerned. Indirectly the type of commodity will play a role for the freight rates, in so far that the measurement and weight of packages are influenced by the content. There may be some other intrinsic commodity qualities affecting the freight-rate structure. In fact, it is difficult to construct the proposed tariff tables. The reason is that some factors discussed before are difficult to quantify, such as conditions of ports. On the other hand, the data of the these factors fluctuate frequently and is difficult to collect. Therefore, it is really difficult to include these factors and obtain a precise mathematical model, even for the cost matrix mentioned before, for marginal cost or freight rate of all commodities. In this thesis, because the focused commodity is containerized motor vehicles as noted previously, the model can be simplified and just related to shipping distance and number of containers. That is Total cost = Unit container shipping cost (20-foot or 40-foot) * Total number of containers ( 20-foot or 40-foot) * Shipping distance The unit container shipping cost is calculated by Drewry Shipping Consultants. Drewry derived this coefficient by analyzing annual cost of a ship in Pacific trade and Atlantic trade. The results of these two cases are listed in Exhibit 2.2.4 and 2.2.5 Table 2.2.4 Costs per Ship (2,800 TEU) on Annual Basis in Cross-Pacific Trade (Derived by Drewry Shipping Consultants, 1992) tons per teu cost per teu-mile ($) cost per ton-mile ($) 5 0.208 0.042 6 0.208 0.035 7 0.208 0.030 8 0.208 0.026 9 0.208 0.023 10 0.208 0.021 11 0.208 0.019 12 0.208 0.017 13 0.208 0.016 14 0.208 0.015 15 0.208 0.014 In Pacific trade case shown in Exhibit 2.2.4, the data are based on a six ship service, traveling a 42-day route and calling once per week at each port. The exhibit shows the expenses for one ship traveling a complete cycle, stopping at a total of 8 ports between Singapore and Los Angeles. The port rotation is as follows: Singapore, Hong Kong, Kaohsiung, Busan, Kobe, Tokyo, Los Angeles, Oakland, Tokyo, Kobe, Busan, Kaohsiung, Hong Kong, Singapore. The ship moves eastbound with 2288 teu and westbound with 1806 teu. Therefore, the average of shipped containers per round trip is 4094. The total mile per Pacific crossing is 8275. Drewry uses the following equation to get cost per teu-mile and cost per ton-mile in Exhibit 2.2.4: $60,469,000 /year $0.208 /teu-mile = (4094 teu /round trip)*(8.57 round trips /year)*(8275 miles) Here, 1 teu-mile represents that one 20-foot container is shipped in one nautical mile. For Atlantic trade, Drewry uses an example with four vessels of 1600 teu, sailing on a 28 round-trip cycle and calling once a week at each port in the service. The port rotation for each individual ship is Antwerp, Felixstowe, Bremerhaven, Rotterdam, Le Havre, New York, Baltimore, Norfolk, Charleston, New York and Antwerp. Each ship moves westbound with 780 teu and eastbound with 1200 teu. With the same methodology, Drewry can calculate cost per teu-mile in Atlantic trade. From Exhibit 2.2.4 and 2.2.5, given the total weight of cargoes or total amount of containers, origin and destination, we can get total cost for sea shipping. For example, a car company wants to ship 1,000 cars from Yokohama to Los Angeles. One container can hold just one car. The distance between these two ports is 4,385 nautical miles. From the Exhibit 2.2.4, the shipping cost per teu-mile is $0.208. The total shipping cost will be $912,080. (= 1,000*4,385*0.208 ) Table 2.2.5 Costs per ship (1,600 TEU) on annual basis in Cross-Atlantic Trade (Derived by Drewry Shipping Consultants, 1992) teu per round trips cost per yearly cost miles per round trip per year round trip per ship crossing 1980 12.9 $3,023,000 $38,867,143 4625 tons per teu cost per teu-mile ($) cost per ton-mile ($) 5 0.330 0.066 6 0.330 0.055 7 0.330 0.047 8 0.330 0.041 9 0.330 0.037 10 0.330 0.033 11 0.330 0.030 12 0.330 0.028 13 0.330 0.025 14 0.330 0.024 15 0.330 0.022 2.3 Railroad Shipping In rail shipping industry, because (1) different commodities require different shipping equipment and cars, (2) the operation costs for different equipment and cars are different, and (3) the demand elasticity of different commodities is different, there is price-discrimination among shippers of different commodities. In fact, such discrimination was officially sanctioned under the value-of-service pricing philosophy that the Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC) adopted shortly after its founding in 1887. Every year, ICC collects data of pricing policy and performance of railroad shipping. The objectives of ICC are: (1) prohibit personal price discrimination (2) guarantee value-of-service pricing (3) maintain carriers' profitability. Though there was a deregulation in rail shipping industry in 1980, the phenomenon of discrimination continued. We can see this pattern by Table 2.3.1. Table 2.3.1 U.S. Railroad Revenue Per Carload (in 1982 dollars) (Source: AAR, Analysis of Class 1 Railroads, 1980-1990. ) Year 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 Grain 1821 1531 1353 1120 1088 1101 Coal 1039 1143 1106 1023 967 900 Stone gravel 809 889 722 596 516 503 Food Products 2358 2280 2033 1797 1596 1454 Primary Forest 545 579 571 526 530 547 Lumber wood 3086 3215 3040 2553 2465 2187 Pulp paper 2101 2326 2289 2133 2015 1863 Chemicals 2572 2722 2465 2370 2157 1955 Metal Products 2114 2196 1858 1816 1759 1539 Motor vehicles 2587 2711 2518 2445 2409 2243 All carloads 1470 1477 1372 1266 1156 1064 The table reports real revenue per carload by commodity type for Class 1 railroads during the period 1980-1990. These are proxies for real rates, since they do not reflect distance traveled that does vary among commodities. Nevertheless, the revenue per carload data do provide a broad indicator of relative rates, because they are based on gross industry revenue by category and total carloads by category. The data show that while real rates on most commodities have been falling since deregulation, the structure of rates has remained fairly constant. Shippers of high-value products such as automobiles and lumber continue to pay premium prices for freight service, while bulk shippers pay lower rates. Grain and coal shippers are in the middle. To calculate these railroad rates more precisely, we begin with revenue observations from the ICC Waybill Sample. Each year, railroads are required to submit to the ICC a stratified sampling of the documents which accompany rail freight movements. (The stratification controls for multi-car movements.) This Waybill Sample, used by officials at the ICC, provides details on about 400,000 movements including commodity shipped, distance, equipment, and rate. The focus of the STL is car-type miles, specifically, the miles of seven car-types which where aggregated from the detailed information in the AAR Analysis. The Waybill reports nominal revenue per movement along with equipment in the AAR Analysis. The Waybill reports nominal revenue per movement along with equipment identification, commodity identification and mileage. These are translated into real rates (in 1982 dollars) per car-type-mile using the Producer Price Index; these are reported in the first row of table 2.3.2 as RRATE. The distribution of these per-mile rates conforms to the distribution of carload rates reported in table 2.3.1. Chemical and automotive shipments command the highest rates. Coal and grain are in the middle range. Stone and gravel are lowest. The rates recorded here are for loaded car-miles. In fact, the railroad must absorb the costs of the loaded and empty portions of each movement. Methodologically, too, the marginal cost estimated to which these rates will be compared are calculated on an overall mileage basis, because the expenditure data (the left hand side in the cost regression) cannot be segregated to reflect empty and loaded movements. To reflect these facts, we calculate for each car-type an "effective rate", i.e., an estimate of the distributed rate the railroad typically receives for moving a particular car-type one mile. Table 2.3.2 Railroad Freight Rate Data for 1988 ($/car-miles) Base Rate Load/Empty Adjustment Efficient Ratio Coefficient Rate RRATE L/E FACTOR FRATE Closed hopper 2.3110 1.0310 0.5080 1.1730 Open hopper 2.2738 1.1040 0.5250 1.1930 TOFC/COFC flat cars 1.1302 15.940 0.9410 1.0630 Multilevel flat cars 2.4014 1.3350 0.5720 1.3730 Tank cars 3.0349 0.9420 0.4850 1.4720 Equipped gondola 1.5988 1.0180 0.5040 0.8057 Box cars 1.9489 1.112 0.527 1.026 We begin by calculating the ratio of loaded to empty miles by car-type and year based on data in the Analysis. These ratios are reported in the second line of table 2.3.2. The very high utilization for TOFC/COFC flat cars reflects two facts: (1) railroads often receive payments for moving empty containers, and (2) there is a national fleet of intermodal cars that is jointly utilized. Utilization of multi-level flat cars also is relatively high because of national pooling arrangements. Tank cars have low utilization, because they are highly specialized and frequently owned by individual chemical manufacturers. We use the UL/E ratio to form a "payment factor" (FACTOR) which converts the loaded car-mile rate into an effective (i.e., distributed) car-mile rate. The formula for the payment factor is simply: FACTOR = L/(L+E) The payment factors are reported in line 3 of table 2.3.2, and effective rates (FRATE), the product of FACTOR times RRATE, are given in line 4. The adjustment from RRATE to FRATE causes some rate compression (rates of tank cars move closer to rate of multilevel flat cars) and a change in ordering (closed hopper drops below open hopper), but the basic rate structure is the same. The structure is such that auto and chemical shippers, on average, pay 20-25 percent more per car-mile than coal or grain shippers, while box-car and intermodal shippers pay 20 percent less. The question, of course, is whether the cost of providing service differs in the same way and to the same extent. 2.4 Trucking The regulated trucking market can be segmented into two distinct groups: common carriers of general commodities and common carriers of specialized commodities. General commodity carriers tend to specialize in relatively small shipments and hence are characterized by less-than-truck-load (LTL) carriage and terminal consolidation. As LTL carriers of general commodities, their traffic encompasses the spectrum of manufactured and related goods that are suitable for truck transport, and their customers tend to be relatively small shippers who do not generate a sufficient volume to support rail or full-truckload operations. In contrast, the carriers of specialized commodities utilize full-truckload (TL) operations and perform few, if any, consolidation functions. While their traffic also includes the spectrum of manufactured goods, these carriers tend to compete directly with the railroads and hence concentrate on large-load, long-haul traffic. The difference in technologies between the two sectors results primarily from differences in operating authorities. While operating authorities for specialized carriers are more restrictive in specifying commodities for transport than are common general freight operating authorities, specialized carrier authorities are less restrictive in routing entitlements. Carriers of specialized commodities have authorities to carry products from one region to another region. Thus, if a specialized product is manufactured, processed, or distributed at one plant, an operating authority for a specialized carrier might enable the carrier to distribute the product to all major consumers in a given region. This type of operating authority does not require the capital-intensive consolidated terminal distribution systems that are necessitated by operating authorities for carriers of general freight, because operating authorities of special commodity carriers allow for direct delivery to large consumers. At the same time, without consolidated terminal distribution systems, small shipments of less-than-truckload freight become quite costly. In contrast, carriers of general freight have operating authorities that allow service to a mapping of specific points, but not to entire regions. Pointwise authorities encourage consolidated pickup and distribution centers at each point of operating authority. Consolidation terminals permit carriers of general freight inasmuch as more than one shipment can be made per haul. The expenses of terminal usage, both in overhead and delay of delivery, make general freight carriers more expensive than specialized freight carriers for large truckload shipments. For large shipments, particularly for medium or long distances, rail carriers and trucking carriers of specialized commodities compete for the same market. Because regulated trucking firms are typically limited in the commodities which they can carry or the routes they can cover, by acquiring firms with different operating rights, regulated trucking firms can obtain longer hauls, higher load factors, fewer empty backhauls, and thus lower operating costs. Consequently, larger firms may be more profitable not because their costs are inherently lower, but because they can obtain higher utilization of equipment through diversified operating rights. Since many of the recent mergers have been characterized by the extension of operating rights and authorities, this indicates that if economies of scale do in fact exist, they may be of a regulatory rather than a technological nature. This implies, of course, that economies of scale would not exist if any carrier were free to carry any commodity to any place along any route. According to Friedlander and Spady 5 , the general specification used to describe trucking costs and technology is C=C( where , w, t) w : factor prices (labor, fuel, capital and purchased transportation) t : operating characteristics V- : transportation output The assumptions of the general model are: 5 Friedlaender, Ann F. and Spady, Richard H. (1980), Freight TransportRegulation, Appendix C, E. 1. Firms are able to make optimal adjustments in capacity. 2. The general cost function is the linear combination of logarithm of its factor prices. The cost function for specialized commodity carriers can be described in more specific form: InTC(V,w,t) = a 0 + Y. a i In wi + + V2 * f jIntj + y InW Aij In wi In wj + I I Bij In wi In tj + E Ci In wi In W + V2 1 Dijln ti In tj + E Ei In ti In V +V2Fln V In VF where: TC : total cost for the firm wl : the price of labor w2 : the price of fuel w3 : the price of capital w4 : the price of purchased transportation tI : average load (tons/truck) t 2 : average length of haul t3 : insurance per ton-mile V/ : output in ton-miles a i j, ," Aij, Bij, Ci, Dij, Ei, F:coefficients ( i= 1,2,3,4, j=1,2,3) From total cost function, the functions of marginal cost and average cost can be derived: MC = TC/O =TC*w I4 and AC=TC*w 4 / I/ *[ y +XCinwi+EEjlntj+Fln iY ] From this point, it would be simple to calculate the total, average and marginal costs for any firm in the sample. All one need to do is to substitute that firm's output, factor prices, and technology variables into the above equations. The values of all the factors and coefficients are shown in Table 2.4.1 and 2.4.26 Friedlander and Spady segmented trucking market as fully as possible on a regional basis and thus analyze geographic differences in trucking technology on a relatively desegregate scale. Because of limitations in the number of observations, all the factors and coefficients were settled on a somewhat more aggregate breakdown for econometric analysis: regional carriers in the Official Territory, which comprises the New England, Middle Atlantic, and Central Regions; all other regional carriers, which comprise carriers in the Southern, South-Western, and Western Regions, and which we refer to as carriers in the South-West Region for notational simplicity. Although it was recognized that this lever of aggregation may introduce some bias, this bias is minimal. According to Table 2.4.3, the result of marginal cost is equal to $ 1.1654 per tonmile in official region, and $ 1.1358 per ton-mile in south-west region. 6 Data Source: Friedlaender, Ann F. and Spady, Richard H. (1980), Freight TransportRegulation, Appendix C, E. Table 2.4.1 Weighted Average Used in the Trucking Cost Function Variable Units Official Region South-West Region w] w2 w3 w4 1/ Manufactures Output $(000)/man-year $/standardized vehicle-mile Index $/standardized vehicle-mile ton-miles (000) 31.868068 0.064234 6.229777 0.357404 48,632.005 30.956642 0.116276 5.753408 0.345916 79,118.917 tons/vehicle miles $(000)/ton-mile 14.3419 329.4268 0.000539 14.773176 457.31263 0.000417 tons/vehicle miles $(000)/ton-mile 20.795576 146.75698 0.000539 21.996293 218.21319 0.000417 tI t2 t3 Bulk Output tI t2 t3 Table 2.4.2 Coefficient Estimates for Cost Functions of Official, South-West and Interregional Carriers Coefficient Variable Official South-West Constant 8.8839 9.5417 a I In w, 0.3485 0.2675 a 2 In w2 0.0423 0.0498 a In w3 0.2925 0.3003 In w4 0.3167 0.3841 fl In t1 -0.8441 -0.5346 f6 2 In t2 -0.1767 -0.1769 fl In t3 0.0319 0.2679 a a 4 Y, In 9J 0.7873 0.9362 All /2*( In W)2 0.1223 0.0781 A 12 In w 1 In w 2 -0.0099 0.0136 A 13 In w1 In w 3 -0.0136 -0.0035 A14 In w 1 In w4 -0.099 -0.0882 A22 /2( In W2) 2 -0.0178 -0.0122 A23 In w 2 In w3 -0.0258 -0.0192 A 24 In w 2 In w 4 0.0535 0.0178 2 A 33 1/2*( In w3) -0.0343 -0.0386 A3 4 In w3 In w 4 0.0737 0.0613 A44 /2( In w 4) 2 -0.0282 0.009 Bll In wI In t1 -0.0059 -0.0311 B12 In w1 In t2 -0.0046 -0.0244 B13 In w3 In t3 0.0055 -0.0103 B21 In w2 In t1 -0.0054 -0.0046 B2 2 In w2 In t2 0.0096 0.0073 B2 3 In w2 In t3 -0.0086 -0.0067 B3 1 In w 3 In t1 0.0184 -0.0199 B32 In w3 In t2 0.0079 -0.0123 B33 In w 3 In t3 -0.0016 0.0036 B41 In w4 In t1 -0.0071 0.0158 B42 In w4 In t 2 -0.0129 0.0293 B43 In w4 In t3 0.0046 0.0134 Cly In wI In VJ -0.0238 -0.0316 C2y In w 2 In 5V -0.0081 -0.0091 C3y In w3 In VJ -0.0396 -0.0336 C4y In w 4 In Y' 0.0715 0.0743 0.3563 -0.1427 -0.1116 -0.0423 Dl D12 1/2*( In t) 2 In t, In t2 D13 In t In t3 -0.053 0.0562 D22 /2*( In t2 )2 0.0646 0.133 D23 Int2 Int3 -0.0203 -0.0559 D33 1/2*( Int3)2 0.0088 0.0793 El In t, In V -0.2007 0 -0.0457 E2 in t2 In V -0.0135 -0.0144 E3 Int3 In V -0.0635 0.0155 ( In 0.0273 0.0874 F 1/2* T Table 2.4.3 )2 Elasticity of Costs with Respect to Output and Operating Characteristics at the Point of Approximation, Carrier of Specialized Commodities Elasticity of cost with respect to Official South-West Output( ( In C / In / ) 1.1654 1.3858 Average load ( a In C/ a In tl) -0.8841 -0.5346 Average length of haul ( a In C/ a In t2) -0.1767 -0.1769 Insurance ( a In C/ a In t3) 0.0319 0.2679 Chapter 3 Total Cost Model of Global System and Case Analysis In total cost model in global system, there are three major parts: (1) manufacturing costs (2) shipping and handling costs (3) taxes and duties. According to Rosenfield1 (1995), a simple model for total cost function can be written as: M N TotalCost= 1F(Y)+C*D+(C2-C1) * (D j=1 min( ZYi,Di)) i=1 (3.1) jemarket..i where: : production at plant j ) : production function : total demand : size of market i, i = 1,N : number of plants : unit cost for distribution, handling, taxes, and duties within the same market C2 : unit cost for distribution, handling, taxes, and duties to other markets In Equation 3.1, the first term is the term for total production costs. The second term is the term for minimum possible costs of transportation, handling, taxes and duties that are incurred by the demands located in the same market as plant's location. The final term is the term for extra costs of transportation, handling, taxes and duties that are incurred by the demands located outside the market where plants locate. If we assume that taxes are constant for all the countries in the world and that there are no duties for delivering to a different country, then this term basically is constituted by the extra 1Donald B. Rosenfield (1996), Global and Variable Cost ManufacturingSystems, European Journal of Operational Research, 1996 transportation and handling costs for shipping the products out of the region where plants locate. This model is a very simplified model, particularly in the approach for transportation costs. This chapter explores building up the total costs from the various components and thus expands section 3.1. If the assumptions 2 of a more general model, which is referred to as the Geographic Distance Model, are accepted, transportation and distribution costs are assumed to decrease with an increasing number of plants as markets that are closer to their nearest plants. Therefore, for a geographic area with distance proportional transportation costs, the total costs are proportional to M(-1/ 2 ). These costs can be separated from the second term in Equation 3.1. Then, Equation 3.1 can be written as: M N F(Y) + [C3 + C4 * M-1/2] * D + (C2 - C1) * (D - TotalCost = j=1 in( i=1 Yj,Di)) jemarket..i (3.2) C3 : unit costs for taxes and duties C4 : unit costs for distribution and handling with the market which has only one plant However, the assumptions of the Geographic Distance Model are not always valid in most markets. In order to check how accurate this model is and to gain some insight for global models, two cases are discussed. In these cases, I use Ford Taurus as the target product. In Case One, according to demand in the continental U.S., I will compare the results of the Geographic Distance Model and the real pricing policy of shipping industry from chapter two, and check the estimation accuracy of this model. Because the target market is in continental U.S., trucking is the only shipping mode used in this case 2Magee, John F., Copacino, William C., and Rosenfield, Donald B. (1985), Modern Logistics Management, Chapter 10, John Wiley & Sons, N.Y analysis. The reasons for the errors of this model are discussed. In Case Two, a global automobile market is analyzed according to the data of demand in all countries worldwide. The models of sea-shipping, trucking and railroad shipping in chapter 2 are used to estimate total distribution costs and total operational costs. Thus we expand the model implicit in equation 3.2. These costs in the global systems with one, two, and three plants are estimated. The effects of number of plants on total distribution costs and total operational costs are shown and discussed. In the last section, the limitations of the Geographic Distance Model are discussed. 3.1 Case I: Comparison of the Results of the Geographic Distance Model and the U.S. Automobile Market There are three major assumptions of the Geographic Distance Model: (1) Demand density should be constant in the whole area. That is, demand in unit geographic area should be equal. (2) Transportation costs are proportional to distance. (3) Plants should be located in the geographic center of their response area in order to minimize total transportation costs. Therefore, total transportation costs can be expressed as Total Transportation Costs = C4 * D * M(-m) Here, C4 is the total transportation costs for the system which has only one plant in the center of the area. Table A. 1.1 shows Ford Taurus 1995 annual sales in each state of the U.S. Its total sales for U.S. market are 642,997 cars. If the company ships all of its cars by trucking, its total shipping costs are about $1,356 millions dollars. If we regard the U.S. as a big system that has one big plant in Kansas City, the geographic center of the U.S., we can get value of C4 equal to $2109 dollars*(no. of plants) 1/2 /car. Then, by using the Geographic Distance Model, total shipping costs for two-plant system and three-plant system can be evaluated. Table 3.1.1 shows the results. More detailed assumptions and calculations are shown in Appendix I. In Table 3.1.1, plant locations are chosen according to the rule that each plant has nearly equally large response area. Total distribution costs for 1-plant system in the Geographic Distance Model are equal to that calculated directly from the practical shipping pricing policy. Table 3.1.1 The Results of Geographic Distance Model and Direct Calculation No. of Plants Location Costs by Model Costs by Difference Calculation ($) Direct ($) (%) Calculation ($) 1 Kansas City 1,355,928,187 1,355,928,187 2 Denver 958,786,016 882,859,618 75,926,398 8.6 782,845,504 706,230,614 76,614,890 10.8 Cincinnati Kansas City 3 Salt Lake City Charleston, WV According to Table 3.1.1, the difference between the results of the Geographic Distance Model and direct calculation is quite large. That is, there are errors which cannot be neglected when we use the Geographic Distance Model to analyze the cases in the real world. We can understand the reasons for the errors of the Geographic Distance Model from the following two analyses: a. The assumptions of even distributed demands throughout the whole region are not satisfied in the U.S. market. We observe this in Figure 3.1.1 and Table A. 1.1. In Figure 3.1.1, most of the demands are located on the east part of the U.S. In fact, more than 55% of demands are located in East Coast and Great Lake areas. However, the area of this region just consists about 25% of total area in the U.S. It means that the demand densities of these regions are about four times higher than the rest regions in the U.S. Figure 3.1.1 Geographical Distribution of Projected Demand for Ford Taurus in the U.S. Projected Demand N -E We can also see the errors in a different way. In Table 3.1.2, we can see the total shipping costs for one plant system which has some alternative plant locations. More detailed calculations are shown in Table A. 1.1 & Table A. 1.4. Table 3.1.2 Total Shipping Costs for One Plant System with Different Plant Locations Plant Location Kansas City St. Louis Cincinnati Detroit Total Shipping Cost ($) 1,355,928,187 1,250,205,890 1,217,690,711 1,342,549,260 From Table 3.1.2, we can observe that the plant location for minimum shipping costs among these four alternatives is Cincinnati, not Kansas City, even though Kansas City is close to the U.S. geographical center. Cincinnati is located around the midpoint between the U.S. geographical center and the East Coast. This result conflicts with the assumptions of the Geographic Distance Model. In the model, the supplier location for minimum shipping costs is in the geographical center of the system area. The conflicts are also caused by unevenly distributed demand. The movement of plant location in one direction will decrease the shipping costs for the demand in the same direction, and increase the costs in the opposite direction. Because most of the demands are in the east side of the U.S., if the plant location moves from the geographical center to east side, the reduced costs on the east side are greater than increased costs on the west side. Therefore, total shipping costs for the whole system will decrease. Demand is not equally distributed even in each state. For each state, most of the demands are found in the metropolitan area or the region closer to big cities or its capital. This also induces the errors about the model estimation. b. Shipping rates are different in different regions. From Chapter 2, trucking rates are not constant throughout the U.S., and are the functions of factor prices (fuel, labor, etc.). Different factor prices induce different freight rates. On average, the freight rates in New England, Middle Atlantic, and Central Regions, are lower than other regions in the U.S.3 On the other hand, the freight rates between big cities are lower than those in rural regions. The reasons are, (1) the freight suppliers serving metropolitan regions are more numerous than those in rural regions, and (2) it is easier for trucking companies between big cities to cooperate with other trucking companies in order to increase equipment utilization and reduce operation costs. 3 In New England, Middle Atlantic, and Central Regions, the freight rate for trucking is 1.1654 ton-mile. In the rest regions, Southern, South-Western, and Western Regions, the rate is 1.3858 ton-mile. 3.2 Case II: Analysis for the projected demand in the world from 1997 to 2002 This case analyzes the global car market by using the following equation: Total Costs = Production Costs + Distribution Costs + Tax Appendix II4 shows Ford Automobile 1995 annual sales in the U.S. and other countries. Because a global system is complex and some data are inaccessible, the following assumptions are made to simplify this system: a. Assumptions of annual projected demands: 1. The lifetime of target type of automobile is 5 years. Other new type of automobiles will totally take over the market. The demand of target automobile is zero after 5 years. 2. The annual demand in every region will not change during 5 years. 3. Ford's market shares are identical in geographically close countries. Therefore, for some countries which only have data of annual sale of all brands of cars, the specified annul sales for Ford can be calculated according to the market share in a nearby country which has available information of market share. 4. For the countries where the geographic distribution of demand is unknown, all the demands in this country are located close to its capital, especially in undeveloped countries. Therefore, Ford needs to be responsible for the costs of shipping its cars only to the capital. However, because the demands in all the U.S. states are known, the demands are located in the geographical center of each state. 5. The sale of the target type of automobile accounts for a fixed percentage of total sales in all regions. For example, the sale of Taurus is 30% of Ford total sales in all states in the U.S. and all countries. 4 World Road Statistics, 97' Edition, International Road Federation Ward's automotive Yearbook, 1993, Ward's Communications InternationalMotor Business, 1995, The Economist Intelligence Unit, U. K. According to the previous assumptions for sales, sales for all regions in the world are estimated as shown in Table 3.2.1. More detailed information about sales in each country is shown in Appendix II. Table 3.2.1 Annual sales of Ford Taurus in major regions in the world Region Sales (cars) %of total sales Africa 13,405 1.16 Caribbean America 3,175 0.27 Central & South America 54,108 4.67 North America 545,335 47.10 Far East 68,321 5.90 Middle East 11,555 1 East Europe 17,100 1.48 West Europe 406,150 35.08 Pacific 38,569 3.33 Total 1,157,718 100 b. Assumptions of production model: The production model is Production Costs = Fixed Costs Per Plant * Number of Plants + Variable Costs Per Unit * Total Demand According to the data 5 , the setup cost for a plant with annual capacity of 250,000 cars is about $ 150 million dollars. I assume that the setup cost is constant and unrelated to the production capacity of the plant. On the other hand, I assume that yearly 1993-1994 World Automotive Market Report, Auto & Truck International 5 Ashoka Mody & David Wheeler, Automation and World Competition depreciation is 15%. After 5 years, the surplus value of the plant is only 25% (=100% 5*15%) of the setup cost. Therefore, fixed cost for one plant to operate 5 years is $112,500,000 dollars. Variable cost is equal to $5,500 dollars per car. These costs are constant during these 5 years. The other assumption is that the capacity of each plant is infinite. c. Assumptions of shipping: 1. Containers can be shipped only to some certain seaports. For each region, a certain seaport is chosen according to its annual container traffic. 2. All the countries choose the closest seaport which is already determined according to previous condition to import or export their cars. 3. For the country which has its own seaport, it will use the feeder system to transfer the products from the regional seaport to its own seaport with no additional costs. 4. The distance between the country's capital and seaport is straight line distance. 5. All factors' prices are fixed during production period. Therefore, the coefficients in the models will not change. 6. The models, factor prices, and coefficients of sea-shipping, railroad shipping and trucking for all countries are same as those for the U.S. That is, Trucking : (1.1654+1.3858)/2 = $1.2756 dollars/ton-mile Railroad: $1.373 dollars/ton-mile Sea Shipping: Cross-Pacific : $0.208 dollars/teu6-mile Cross-Atlantic : $0.33 dollars/teu-mile 6Teu is the unit for one 20-feet container. 1 teu = 1 20-feet container. d. Assumptions of taxes: The tax rate is a constant and equal to 35%, the current U.S. corporate tax rate, in all countries. Net profit of a car is close to its variable production cost. Therefore, Unit Tax Costs = 35% * Unit Variable Production Costs = 0.35 * $5,500 dollars/car = $1,925 dollars/car Analysis for plant locations: 1. From Table 3.2.1, about half of the total demands of the target cars in the world are located in North America, and about 35% are located in Western Europe. According to the total cost model, in order to avoid additional costs for shipping and handling, if the company just wants to set up one plant, it should be located in North America. If the company wants to set up two plants, the first plant should be in North America, and the second one should be in Western Europe. 2. There are two alternative locations for the third plant: Far East or North America. 3. In case one, if the company just sets up a plant in the U.S., we can see that the plant location for minimum shipping costs in the U.S. is Cincinnati. However, if the defined system is North American, which includes the U.S., Canada, and Mexico, the optimal location will change. The annual sales of target car are 38,269 in Canada and 8,661 in Mexico. Because the annual sales in Canada are more than that in Mexico, the optimal location will move to the region around Detroit in the north.. 4. Table 3.2.2 shows the demand distribution in Western Europe. Following the similar analysis in the U.S., if the second plant is located in Western Europe, it should be located in the middle of France. Table 3.2.2 Demand Distribution in Western Europe Country U. K. Spain Germany France Italy % of total sales in W. Europe 30.92 9.51 24.12 11.19 11.53 5. Table 3.2.3 shows the demand distribution in Far East. If the third plant is located in the Far East, it should be in Taiwan. Table 3.2.3 Demand Distribution in the Far East 6. If the third plant is located in North America, according to the demand distribution in the U.S., Canada, and Mexico, these two plants should be in Detroit and Salt Lake City. 7. According to the previous conclusions, I used the projected demand of all countries in the world to calculate total costs for the systems with one, two and three plants. Table 3.2.4 summarizes these results.. Table 3.2.4 Plant Locations in the Systems with Different Numbers of Plants System 1 Plant 2 Plants Plant Locations Detroit, U.S. (1) Detroit, U.S. (2) Paris, France 3 Plants - Alternative 1 (1) Detroit, U.S. (2) Paris, France (3) Taiwan 3 Plants - Alternative 2 (1) Detroit, U.S. (2) Salt Lake City, U.S. (3) Paris, France * Results of analysis The cost components and their percentage ratios are shown in Table 3.2.5 & 3.2.6 Table 3.2.5 Costs for 1-Plant & 2-Plant System (for 5 years ) One Plant System $ Costs % Two Plant System $ % 112,500 K 0.19 225,000 K 0.41 Production (variable) 31,837,245 K 52.93 31,837,245 K 57.35 Distribution 17,052,400 K 28.35 12,310,122 K 22.17 Taxes 11,143,035 K 18.53 11,143,035 K 20.07 Total 60,145,180 K 100 55,515,402 K 100 Production (fixed) Table 3.2.6 Costs for Two Alternatives in 3-Plant System (for 5 years) Location : Taiwan Costs $ % Location : U.S. $ % 337,500 K 0.63 337,500 K 0.64 Production (variable) 31,837,245 K 59.72 31,837,245 K 60.41 Distribution 9,990,267 K 18.74 9,388,126 K 17.81 Taxes 11,143,035 K 20.91 11,143,035 K 21.14 Total 53,308,047 K 100 52,705,906 K 100 Production (fixed) * Observations 1. From Table 3.2.5: * Under the previous assumptions, because total demands for 5 years are fixed, variable production costs and taxes are unrelated to the numbers of the plants in the systems. * Fixed production cost is increased by $112,500,000 dollars from one-plant system to a two-plant system * Distribution and Handling costs are decreased by $4,742,278,000 dollars 2. Because variable production costs and taxes are constant, the optimal number of plants depends on the fixed production costs and distribution costs. 3. In a one-plant system, building the second plant reduces distribution costs. The reduced parts are more than the induced extra fixed production costs of the second plant. Therefore, total operational costs in a two-plant system are less than those in a one-plant system. 4. Table 3.2.6 shows that the system with the third plant in Salt Lake City, U.S. has less operational costs than the other alternative with the third plant in Taiwan. The reason is that most of the demands are located in North America. Building an additional plant in Taiwan reduces much distribution costs for unit demand in the Far East and the Middle East; because the demands in these regions consist just 6.9% of total demands in the world, the total distribution costs are not reduced so much as the amount reduced by building an additional plant in Salt Lake City. 3.3 The Limitations of the Application of the Geographic Distance Model Based on previous analysis, we know that there are limitations of application of the Geographic Distance Model. Any application would have to satisfy the following two conditions to avoid estimation errors: 1. Transportation costs would have to be proportional to shipping distances. 2. Demand would have to be equally distributed throughout the whole geographic regions. In practice, most global markets do not satisfy these conditions. Only regional markets with small areas might satisfy these assumptions. The reasons are: 1. Transportation Costs are more likely to be proportional to shipping distances in regional markets. In regional markets, the choices of transportation modes are limited. For example, for the cargo shipment with a small country, such as Switzerland, trucking and railroad shipping are the only economic choices. In addition, the freight rates are more likely to stay constant, because the factors which determine freight rates are more likely to stay constant in a small region. On the other hand, in global systems, four different transportation modes are available. Each of them has its individual pricing. Also, there are more factors which will affect freight rates. These make the transportation costs in global systems more complex and not proportional to shipping distances. 2. Demands are more likely to be equally distributed throughout the whole geographic regions. In regional markets, two conditions are more likely to be satisfied in the whole regions: (1) evenly distributed populations (2) evenly distributed incomes. These two conditions cause equally distributed demand throughout the whole regions. In section 3.1, although the income of each person is similar in the U.S., because of unequally distributed population in the U.S., the demand distribution is still uneven in the U.S. market. It induces 10.8% error as shown in Table 3.1.1. The markets outside of the U.S. are even more complex and heterogeneous than those in the U.S.. It is more difficult for them to satisfy the conditions of the Geographic Distance Model. For example, there are big income and population gaps between the countries in Western Europe and Eastern Europe, even though these countries are geographically close. Therefore, applications of the Geographic Distance Model in European market will yield greater errors than those in the U.S. market. In global markets, these gaps of population and income are larger between different locations, and the estimation accuracy of the model will be much lower. In conclusion, we can use a model such as the Geographic Distance Model only as an approximation to part of a total cost model. Chapter 4 Summary and Conclusion The major objective of the thesis has been to understand the characteristics of the pricing behavior in different transportation modes and try to develop cost models for them. Simplified models, such as the Geographic Distance Model, are evaluated by comparing the results of these cost models. The major results of this research are the pricing models in Chapter Two. Such models are effective tools in tabulating total system costs, as shown by the examples in Chapter Three. Based on the analysis in Chapter 2 and Chapter 3, we know that there are limits to the Geographic Distance Model. One possible way to mitigate estimation errors is through market segmentation. We need to divide the large markets into several submarkets in order to create homogenous conditions within the markets. Such market segmentation is an area of future research. The applications of the cost models showed the following: 1. In the example for the automobile industry, a decentralized system has less operational costs than a centralized system. From Tables 3.2.5 & 3.2.6, we get the following results: Table 4.1 Change of Plants, Fixed Production Costs, and Distribution Costs Change of total plants in the system Increased fixed Production Costs Decreased Distribution Costs 1- 2 24 3 $ 112.5 M $112.5 M $4,727.3 M $2,922.0 M Under the assumptions in section 3.2, variable production costs and taxes are unrelated to the total number of plants in the system. From Table 4.1, when the number of total plants increases by one, increased fixed production costs are much less than decreased distribution costs. As such increasing, the total number of plants will decrease total operational costs, and the decreased distribution costs will also decrease. When there are sufficient plants in the system, the decreased distribution costs will be equal to the increased fixed production costs, and the company will get the minimum total operational costs. If the number of plants in the system is more than the optimal number, the decreased distribution costs will be less than the increased fixed production costs, and the total operational costs will increase. 2. Because of the characteristics and freight rates of railroad shipping and trucking are quite similar, these two transportation modes compete with each other. The biggest differences between these two modes are the convenience and reliability. Because trucking has more flexibility than railroad shipping, it is easy for trucking carriers to offer door-to-door service. On the other hand, railroad shipping schedule is less affected by uncontrolled factors, such as, weather, traffic congestion, etc.. Railroad shipping thus has higher reliability than trucking. The shippers choose between these two modes according to the characteristics of their products and their requirements for the shipment. 3. The freight rates for sea shipping are about 1/6 of those for trucking and railroad shipping. A company can have lower distribution costs by avoiding shipment via trucking and railroad. Locating plants close to seaports will, therefore, provide economic advantages. Any conclusions need to be subject to the following qualifications: 1. Different countries have their specific pricing policy and structures for their shipping modes. Some of them are similar to those in the U.S., but some of them are quite different. Because of unavailable freight rate data in many countries, it is difficult to precisely estimate all the coefficients for the shipping modes in different countries. Using the models in the U.S. for other countries will induce some error. 2. In the production model, I assume that production costs consist of a fixed and a variable component, and the plants have unlimited capacity. However, this assumption is only an approximation. When plant capacity increases, the production costs should vary in a nonlinear manner that is more complex than a fixed and a variable cost. 3. From previous results, we can know that demand locations are very important factors in determining unit distribution costs and total costs. Accurate estimation of costs requires geographical distribution of demands. 4. In railroad shipping and trucking industries, especially in railroad shipping industry, the carriers offer discounts on their freight rates for long distance shippers. Because the calculations of these discounts are complex and different in different cases, I just assume that there is no discount on the freight rats in this thesis. In fact, the longdistance shipping costs for railroad shipping and trucking are lower than the results of Chapter 3. Bibliography * Chapter 1: 1. Arntzen, Bruce C., and Brown, Gerald G. (1995), Global Supply ChainManagement at DigitalEquipment Corporation,Interfaces 25, January-February 1995. 2. Huchzermeier, Arnd, and Cohen, Morris A. (1996), Valuing OperationalFlexibility Under Exchange Rate Risk, Operations Research, Vol. 44, No. 1, January-February 1996. 3. Rosenfield, Donald B. (1996), Global And Variable Cost ManufacturingSystems, European Journal of Operational Research, 1996 * Chapter 2: 1. Bryan, A.I. (1974) Regression analysis of oceanfreight rates on some Canadian export routes. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, May. 2. Drewry Shipping Consultants, LTD, ContainerMarket Profitabilityto 1997: Will stabilizationagreements save carriersfrom checkmate?, London, 1992 3. Evans, J.J. (1977) Liner FreightRates Discriminationand Cross-subsidization, Maritime Policy and Management, 4, 41 4. Friedlaender, Ann F. (1969), The Dilemma of Freight TransportRegulation, Washington DC: The Brookings Institution 5. Friedlaender, Ann F. and Spady, Richard H. (1980), FreightTransportRegulation, The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts 6. Gerard J. McCullough (1993), Essays on the Economic Performance of U.S. Freight Railroads UnderDeregulation,Massachusetts Institute of Technology Thesis. 7. Gerald, Thomas M. (1980), Market Structure and the Industry Behavior of the General Commodity Carriers,Thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge 8. Jansson, J.O. and Shneerson, D. (1982), PortEconomics, MIT Press, Chicago 9. Jansson, J.O., and Shneerson, D. (1986), Liner Shipping Economics, Chapman and Hall, Chapter 3, 4, 11 10. Keeler, Theodore E. (1974), Railroad Costs, Returns to Scale, and Excess Capacity, Review of Economics and Statistics. 61:201-208 11. Lewis, Dale B. (1995), FreightMode Choice: Air TransportVersus Ocean Transport in the 1990s, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, M. S. Thesis 12. Lipsey, R. G. and K. Lancaster (1956), The General Theory of Second Best, Review of Economic Studies 24. 13. MacAvoy, Paul W. and Snow, John W. (1977), Regulation of Entry and Pricingin Truck Transportation,American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, D. C. 14. Meyer, J. R., M. J. Peck, J. Stenason, and C. Zwick (1959), The Economics of Competition in the TransportationIndustries,Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts 15. Moore, T. G. (1975), DeregulatingSurface Freight Transportation,in A. Phillips (ed.), Promoting Competition in Regulated Markets, The Brookings Institution (Washington DC) 16. Roy Pearson (1985) ContainerShips and Shipping, Chapter 8 17. Tye, William B. (1987), Encouraging CooperationAmong Competitor, Greenwood Press, Inc., Connecticut Chapter 3: 1. Ashoka Mody & David Wheeler (1990), Automation and World Competition, New Technologies, IndustrialLocation and Trade, St. Martin's Press, New York 2. InternationalMotor Business, 1995, The Economist Intelligence Unit, U. K. 3. Rosenfield, Donald B. (1996), Global And Variable Cost ManufacturingSystems, European Journal of Operational Research, 1996 4. World Road Statistics, 1997 Edition, International Road Federation 5. Ward's automotive Yearbook, 1993, Ward's Communications. 6. 1993-1994 World Automotive Market Report, Auto & Truck International Appendix I The following numbers and formulas are used in the calculation procedure. Weight of 4-door Taurus : 3326 lb. = 1.66 tons Freight rate for trucking : Official : $1.1654 ton-mile South-West: $1.3858 ton-mile Transportation Cost = State Annual Sales (cars/year) * Weight of Unit Car ( tons/car ) * Distance between Plants and Demand ( miles ) * Freight Rate by truck ( $/ton-mile ) Note: 1. In the calculation of Table A. 1.2 & Table A. 1.3, each state will get cars from the closest plant. 2. The distance for each state is measured from the geographic center of the state to the supply plant location. 3. There is no limitation on the capacity of the plant production. Data source: 1. World Road Statistics, 1997 Edition, International Road Federation 2. The Automotive News, 1996, Crain Communications, Inc. 3. Ward's automotive Yearbook, 1993, Ward's Communications 4. Chapter 2 Table A.1.1 Transportation Cost in the U.S. with One Plant (Plant Location : Kansas City) State Alabama Arizona Arkansas California Colorado Connecticut Delaware Dist. of Columbia Federal Government Florida Georgia Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Maine Maryland Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Mississippi Missouri Montana Nebraska Nevada New Hampshire New Jersey New Mexico New York North Carolina North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania Rhode Island South Carolina Sales 8210 10244 4247 70164 9791 8576 2001 610 1410 47653 22145 1612 33123 11586 4584 4789 7957 10659 2873 18736 14197 37361 12439 5259 15961 1308 2780 3729 3543 23805 3583 28118 18237 909 32801 5297 6995 27151 2045 10506 % of total Taurus in US 1.277 1.593 0.660 10.912 1.523 1.334 0.311 0.095 0.219 7.411 3.444 0.251 5.151 1.802 0.713 0.745 1.237 1.658 0.447 2.914 2.208 5.810 1.934 0.818 2.482 0.203 0.432 0.580 0.551 3.702 0.557 4.373 2.836 0.141 5.101 0.824 1.088 4.222 0.318 1.634 Distance to Kansas City 692 1250 391 1750 616 1204 1134 1067 1067 1231 792 1482 500 487 197 245 500 842 1600 1041 1529 777 443 637 100 1117 492 1450 1550 1228 769 1250 1036 965 663 350 1852 1000 1250 1221 $ by truck 13069468 29455543 3819588 282462653 13874470 19974184 4389785 1259150 2909461 134945046 40346839 5495686 32038798 10915078 1747004 2699104 9152253 20646061 8892804 37732077 41993993 56158668 12675946 7705662 3671598 3361008 3146433 12438529 10622449 56552220 6338431 67993879 36550747 2016791 42071085 4264878 29799316 52524380 4944020 24815069 South Dakota Tennessee Texas Utah Vermont Virginia Washington W. Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming Total Table A.1.2 1046 12043 44257 3868 1546 18198 10691 3523 10135 708 0.163 1.873 6.883 0.601 0.240 2.830 1.663 0.548 1.576 0.110 642997 100.000 694 538 652 1137 1300 1086 1906 739 562 853 1669138 14904162 66379397 10115781 3888087 38231792 46873735 5989157 11018481 1388303 1355928187 Transportation Cost in the U.S. with Two Plant (Plant Location : Denver & Cincinnati) State Alabama Arizona Arkansas California Colorado Connecticut Delaware Dis of Columbia Federal Government Florida Georgia Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Maine Maryland Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Mississippi Missouri Sales 8210 10244 4247 70164 9791 8576 2001 610 1410 47653 22145 1612 33123 11586 4584 4789 7957 10659 2873 18736 14197 37361 12439 5259 15961 Distance to Distance to Denver Cincinnati $ by truck 1297 455 8593364 790 1856 18615903 1006 601 5871029 1100 2280 177547953 250 1208 5630873 1936 778 12906906 1759 581 2249087 1681 515 607743 1681 515 1404285 1848 885 97015732 1406 453 23077169 831 1930 3081589 980 290 18582503 987 109 2443005 676 591 5241012 455 803 5012621 1106 100 1830451 1341 806 19763331 1460 991 5507980 1685 516 18702931 1990 820 22521304 1281 268 19370043 926 1214 745 697 687 490 19943870 8310502 17990831 Montana Nebraska Nevada New Hampshire New Jersey New Mexico New York North Carolina North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania Rhode Island South Carolina South Dakota Tennessee Texas Utah Vermont Virginia Washington W. Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming 1308 2780 3729 3543 23805 3583 28118 18237 909 32801 5297 6995 27151 2045 10506 1046 12043 44257 3868 1546 18198 10691 3523 10135 708 Total Table A.1.3 553 290 900 1990 1785 457 1700 1685 768 1277 697 1249 1600 2089 1734 554 1155 1036 537 1900 1666 1313 1375 1050 248 1602 1021 2050 875 675 1508 600 509 1094 109 843 2370 437 853 618 1096 277 1061 1727 750 535 2395 205 391 1392 642997 1663955 1854605 7720466 5996544 31085300 3766792 32637062 17957848 1605073 6916664 8493201 20096839 22953154 3373799 12559961 1332424 7673704 105474012 4777638 2243127 18834262 32290249 1661404 7665883 403633 882859618 Transportation Cost in the U.S. with Three Plant (Plant Location : Kansas City, Salt Lake City & Charleston in W. Vagina) State Alabama Arizona Arkansas California Colorado Connecticut Delaware Dis of Columbia Federal Government Sales 8210 10244 4247 70164 9791 8576 2001 610 1410 Distance to Distance to Distance to Kansas City Salt Lake Charleston $ by truck 692 1250 391 1750 616 1204 1134 1067 1067 1673 655 1532 720 537 2284 2152 2205 2205 535 2076 733 2420 1375 509 476 359 359 10104285 15434704 3819588 116213206 12095114 8444235 1842626 423650 978910 Florida Georgia Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Maine Maryland Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Mississippi Missouri Montana Nebraska Nevada New Hampshire New Jersey New Mexico New York North Carolina North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania Rhode Island South Carolina South Dakota Tennessee Texas Utah Vermont Virginia Washington W. Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming Total 47653 22145 1612 33123 11586 4584 4789 7957 10659 2873 18736 14197 37361 12439 5259 15961 1308 2780 3729 3543 23805 3583 28118 18237 909 32801 5297 6995 27151 2045 10506 1046 12043 44257 3868 1546 18198 10691 3523 10135 708 642997 1231 792 1482 500 487 197 245 500 842 1600 1041 1529 777 443 637 100 1117 492 1450 1550 1228 769 1250 1036 965 663 350 1852 1000 1250 1221 694 538 652 1137 1300 1086 1906 739 562 853 2337 1920 336 1380 1545 1068 1062 1666 1856 2507 2092 2328 1649 1318 1794 1287 566 606 470 2378 2193 623 2100 2022 1049 1727 1206 757 2000 2358 2222 904 1669 1400 180 2270 2185 800 1781 1436 310 794 515 2160 483 307 757 645 247 870 941 363 720 368 937 852 620 1820 1204 2200 772 547 1527 470 299 1297 153 999 2572 350 738 489 1336 395 1199 1781 720 310 2449 150 580 1661 87040103 26235634 1245985 30949479 6880758 1747004 2699104 4521213 20646061 5230080 13157295 19774804 26597670 12675946 7705662 3671598 1703071 3146433 4031799 5290665 25190606 5135036 25565699 10548912 2016791 9708712 4264878 12180390 18383533 2918949 9938222 1669138 10942647 66379397 1601443 2153402 10913311 19674180 1215661 11018481 504541 706230614 Table A.1.4 State Alabama Arizona Arkansas California Colorado Connecticut Delaware Dist. of Columbia Federal Government Florida Georgia Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Maine Maryland Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Mississippi Missouri Montana Nebraska Nevada Transportation Cost for Alternative Plant Locations in the U.S. in One Plant Case Taurus Sales 8210 10244 4247 70164 9791 8576 2001 610 1410 47653 22145 1612 33123 11586 4584 4789 7957 10659 2873 18736 14197 37361 12439 5259 15961 1308 2780 3729 Plant Location: distance (mile) 527 1503 405 2000 860 1103 904 830 830 992 560 1675 180 257 372 445 275 677 1332 834 1100 540 608 492 125 1396 723 1750 St. Louis cost ($) 9953193 35417345 3956351 322814460 19370202 18298609 3499441 979470 2263217 108745317 28528068 6211386 11533967 5760113 3298911 4902454 5033739 16600217 7403259 30229157 30211506 39029190 17397235 5951626 4589498 4200508 4623722 15012018 Plant Location: distance (mile) 455 1856 601 2280 1208 778 581 515 515 885 453 1930 290 109 591 803 100 806 991 516 820 268 697 687 490 1602 1021 2050 Cincinnati cost ($) 8593364 43735590 5871029 368008485 27208377 12906906 2249087 607743 1404285 97015732 23077169 7157000 18582503 2443005 5241012 8846450 1830451 19763331 5507980 18702931 22521304 19370043 19943870 8310502 17990831 4820354 6529489 17585507 Plant Location: distance (mile) 734 2041 896 2300 1282 645 597 527 527 1210 727 1965 350 286 614 992 366 1071 780 532 650 70 674 1000 660 1573 1025 2000 Detroit cost ($) 13862701 48095010 8752816 371236629 28875115 10700456 2311024 621904 1437007 132642978 37035545 7286790 22427159 6410087 5444977 10928616 6699449 26261201 4335242 19282867 17852253 5059339 19285751 12096801 24232548 4733094 6555070 17156592 New Hampshire New Jersey New Mexico New York North Carolina North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania Rhode Island South Carolina South Dakota Tennessee Texas Utah Vermont Virginia Washington W. Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming Total 3543 23805 3583 28118 18237 909 32801 5297 6995 27151 2045 10506 1046 12043 44257 3868 1546 18198 10691 3523 10135 708 642997 1100 999 1034 1000 747 975 433 491 2095 800 1153 889 775 324 845 1380 1060 836 2139 520 377 1084 7538512 46006244 8522676 54395103 26354641 2037690 27476289 5983015 33709270 42019504 4560364 18067647 1863951 8975741 86028514 12277729 3170286 29430735 52603840 4214292 7391401 1764267 1250205890 875 675 1508 600 509 1094 109 843 2370 437 853 618 1096 277 1061 1727 750 535 2395 205 391 1392 5996544 31085300 12429590 32637062 17957848 2286393 6916664 10272264 38134114 22953154 3373799 12559961 2635987 7673704 108019234 15364955 2243127 18834262 58899578 1661404 7665883 2265554 1217690711 716 649 1564 550 656 1105 206 1036 2364 450 694 830 1073 542 1349 1649 600 631 2230 368 367 1386 4906886 29887940 12891166 29917307 23144102 2309382 13071861 12624040 38037572 23635971 2744920 16868557 2580670 15014974 137340195 14670997 1794502 22213868 54841778 2982422 7195343 2255788 1342549260 Appendix II The following numbers and formulas are used in the calculation procedure. Weight of 4-door Taurus : 3326 lb. = 1.66 tons Freight rate: trucking in US: Official : $1.1654 ton-mile South-West: $1.3858 ton-mile in other countries : (1.1654+1.3858)/2 = $1.2756 dollars/ton-mile railroad: $1.373 dollars/ton-mile sea Shipping: Cross-Pacific : $0.208 dollars/teul-mile Cross-Atlantic : $0.33 dollars/teu-mile Transportation Cost = State Annual Sales( cars/year) * Weight of Unit Car ( tons/car ) * Distance between Plants and Demand ( miles ) * Freight Rate by truck ( $/ton-mile ) Note: 1. The distance for each state is measured from the geographic center of the state to the supply plant location. 2. In U.S., Canada, and Mexico, the products are shipped directly by trucking to the location of demand. 3. The demand location in Canada is equally divided into Vancouver, Ottawa, Toronto, and Montreal. 4. The total distribution costs in U.S. is calculated from Appendix I. 5. There is no limitation on the capacity of the plant production. Teu is the unit for one 20-feet container. 1 teu = 1 20-feet container. Data source: 1. World Road Statistics, 1997 Edition, International Road Federation 2. The Automotive News, 1996, Crain Communications, Inc. 3. Ward's automotive Yearbook, 1993, Ward's Communications 4. InternationalMotor Business, 1995, The Economist Intelligence Unit, U. K. 5. 1993-1994 World Automotive Market Report, Auto & Truck International 6. Ashoka Mody & David Wheeler (1990), Automation and World Competition, New Technologies, IndustrialLocation and Trade, St. Martin's Press, New York 7. Distances Between Ports, 1965, U.S. Naval Oceanographic Office 8. Chapter 2 Table A.2.1 Country Sales for Import Port Taurus Distribution Cost in Global System with 1 Plant Plant Location : Detroit, U.S. Unit Cost from Unit Cost from Detroit to export Port Export to Import Ports Import Port to Capital Distance Total Cost Unit Cost Africa Algeria Angola Benin Botswana Burkina Faso Burundi Cameroon Cape Verde Central African Republic Chad Comoros Congo Djibouti Equatorial Guinea Eritrea Ethiopia Gambia Ghana Guinea Guinea-Bissau Ivory Coast Kenya Liberia Libya Madagascar Malawi 428 121 176 55 50 61 134 13 18 2 12 17 12 2 13 13 20 127 8 21 504 129 5 857 4 43 Casablanca Durban Abidjan Durban Abidjan Durban Abidjan Durban Abidjan Abidjan Durban Durban Mombasa Durban Mombasa Mombasa Durban Abidjan Abidjan Durban Abidjan Mombasa Abidjan Casablanca Durban Durban $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,001 $2,254 $1,628 $2,254 $1,628 $2,254 $1,628 $2,254 $1,628 $1,628 $2,254 $2,254 $4,564 $2,254 $4,564 $4,564 $2,254 $1,628 $1,628 $2,254 $1,628 $4,564 $1,628 $1,001 $2,254 $2,254 560 1488 352 432 400 1472 848 1120 1200 1120 1280 1664 1040 800 800 688 1040 192 800 800 0 0 352 1104 0 928 $1,186 $3,151 $745 $915 $847 $3,117 $1,796 $2,372 $2,541 $2,372 $2,710 $3,524 $2,202 $1,694 $1,694 $1,457 $2,202 $407 $1,694 $1,694 $0 $0 $745 $2,338 $0 $1,965 $1,474,847 $804,284 $639,369 $243,445 $185,589 $402,184 $624,945 $78,430 $95,688 $12,139 $77,723 $117,423 $93,493 $10,491 $98,615 $95,502 $113,956 $418,693 $35,087 $108,735 $1,453,284 $751,588 $16,384 $3,936,658 $14,299 $235,696 Mali Mauritania Mauritius Morocco Mozambique Namibia Niger Nigeria Rwanda Saint Lucia Sao Tome & Principe Senegal Seychelles Sierra Leone Somalia South Africa Sudan Swaziland Tanzania Togo Tunisia Uganda Zaire Zambia Zimbabwe Subtotal 23 40 63 1991 40 12 110 953 23 16 5 47 15 47 0 4161 630 42 174 68 67 48 210 252 1525 13405 Casablanca Casablanca Durban Casablanca Durban Durban Abidjan Abidjan Durban Durban Durban Abidjan Durban Durban Mombasa Durban Mombasa Durban Mombasa Abidjan Casablanca Mombasa Durban Durban Durban $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,001 $1,001 $2,254 $1,001 $2,254 $2,254 $1,628 $1,628 $2,254 $2,254 $2,254 $1,628 $2,254 $2,254 $4,564 $2,254 $4,564 $2,254 $4,564 $1,628 $1,001 $1,628 $2,254 $2,254 $2,254 1232 1040 0 0 224 848 576 352 800 800 800 832 1120 1120 448 0 1088 San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 192 288 896 448 1632 912 640 $2,609 $2,202 $0 $0 $474 $1,796 $1,220 $745 $1,694 $1,694 $1,694 $1,762 $2,372 $2,372 $949 $0 $2,304 $0 $407 $610 $1,897 $949 $3,456 $1,931 $1,355 $109,638 $176,981 $219,576 $4,493,017 $157,715 $66,293 $450,652 $3,459,830 $120,210 $81,852 $25,681 $220,561 $86,458 $275,430 $0 $14,605,747 $5,117,701 $148,890 $1,082,587 $236,733 $277,415 $184,288 $1,462,787 $1,371,146 $7,417,328 $53,987,063 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $59,454 $47,081 $50,931 $16,327 $369,252 $431,273 $12,168 Caribbean America Bahamas Barbados Bermuda Cuba Dominican Republic Guadeloupe Haiti 35 28 30 10 216 252 7 Jamaica Martinique Netherlands Antilles Puerto Rico Trinidad & Tobago Virgin Islands Other Subtotal 114 0 194 1806 108 15 363 3175 San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $195,100 $0 $331,156 $3,090,326 $184,164 $26,492 $620,417 $5,434,140 Buenos Aires Cristobal Callao Santo's Valparaso Cristobal Limon-Moin Callao Cristobal Cristobal Limon-Moin Cristobal Limon-Moin Limon-Moin Cristobal Santo's Callao Cristobal Santo's Cristobal $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,400 $666 $1,111 $1,636 $1,542 $666 $666 $1,111 $666 $666 $666 $666 $666 $666 $666 $1,636 $1,111 $666 $1,636 $666 0 672 512 0 0 352 0 560 960 1424 480 1120 320 208 0 624 0 1280 832 640 $0 $1,423 $1,084 $0 $0 $745 $0 $1,186 $2,033 $3,015 $1,016 $2,372 $678 $440 $0 $1,321 $0 $2,710 $1,762 $1,355 $24,890,438 $1,505 $310,644 $102,438,610 $5,344,674 $3,233,246 $1,078,208 $4,050,691 $562,245 $344,818 $767,700 $61,827 $70,889 $425,937 $1,109,574 $736,623 $781,894 $1,459,185 $2,916,809 $5,504,903 $156,090,422 C. & S. America Argentina Belize Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Costa Rica Ecuador El Salvador French Guiana Guatemala Guyana Honduras Nicaragua Panama Paraguay Peru Suriname Uruguay Venezuela Subtotal 9371 0 90 35424 1910 1212 561 1140 142 70 261 14 27 180 577 175 330 315 627 1680 54108 North America Canada 38269 $0 Mexico United States 8661 498405 $0 $0 - Subtotal Far East Afghanistan Bangladesh Brunei Burma Cambodia China Hong Kong India Indonesia Japan Laos S. Korea Malaysia Maldives Mongolia Pakistan Philippines Singapore Sri Lanka Taiwan Thailand Vietnam Subtotal $0 $0 $0 $3,356 $128,442,845 $6,503 $56,327,119 $1,040,647,567 $1,225,417,530 545335 I 1 19 52 0 134 6314 1099 4350 98 23404 306 3421 600 0 84 1465 2681 1565 381 19986 2340 19 68321 Singapore Singapore Singapore Singapore Singapore Shanghai Hong Kong Madras Singapore Yokohama Singapore Pusan Singapore Singapore Shanghai Madras Marila Singapore Madras Kaoshung Singapore Singapore $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $1,636 $1,636 $1,636 $1,636 $1,636 $1,208 $1,327 $1,966 $1,636 $1,966 $1,636 $1,966 $1,636 $1,636 $1,208 $1,966 $1,360 $1,636 $1,966 $1,360 $1,636 $1,636 0 0 0 0 0 592 0 560 0 0 0 160 0 0 1344 1280 0 0 0 0 80 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $1,254 $0 $1,186 $0 $0 $0 $339 $0 $0 $2,846 $2,710 $0 $0 $0 $0 $169 $0 $7,973 $132,709 $355,433 $1,502 $922,336 $48,516,841 $7,197,526 $36,424,280 $674,786 $168,218,238 $2,097,005 $25,749,295 $4,112,944 $3,210 $781,443 $14,500,167 $17,645,124 $10,734,447 $2,741,279 $131,543,751 $16,444,901 $126,948 $488,932,138 Mid East Subtotal 11555 Jeddah $1,256 $3,785 560 $1,186 $71,948,240 318 631 411 176 4563 188 741 948 40 1272 385 883 71 1454 3200 972 641 206 17100 Piraeus Hamburg Piraeus Piraeus Hamburg Limassol Hamburg Hamburg Piraeus Hamburg Hamburg Hamburg Piraeus Hamburg Piraeus Hamburg Piraeus Piraeus $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,323 $1,254 $1,323 $1,323 $1,254 $1,523 $1,254 $1,254 $1,323 $1,254 $1,254 $1,254 $1,323 $1,254 $1,323 $1,254 $1,323 $1,323 1120 928 320 0 640 0 384 944 1168 704 848 640 0 608 480 512 0 0 $2,372 $1,965 $678 $0 $1,355 $0 $813 $1,999 $2,473 $1,491 $1,796 $1,355 $0 $1,287 $1,016 $1,084 $0 $0 $1,575,573 $2,822,965 $1,339,920 $453,292 $17,636,896 $523,419 $2,462,431 $4,272,352 $202,324 $5,087,712 $1,656,428 $3,411,597 $184,085 $5,520,715 $11,506,875 $3,493,522 $1,653,883 $532,499 $64,336,487 7348 9332 3739 1510 45432 97952 Rotterdam Antwerp Copenhagen Copenhagen Le Havre Hamburg $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,155 $1,096 $1,264 $1,264 $1,040 $1,254 736 160 0 816 208 240 $1,558 $339 $0 $1,728 $440 $508 $29,167,128 $25,107,883 $9,422,861 $6,413,173 $124,315,002 $295,638,029 East Europe Armenia Byelarus Bulgaria Com. of Indep. Sta Croatia Cyprus Czechoslovakia Estonia Georgia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Macedonia Poland Romania Slovenia Yugoslavia Ukraine Subtotal West Europe Austria Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Iceland Ireland Italy Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland UK Subtotal 3374 145 3278 46843 691 218 1344 2452 7437 38634 3686 7139 125597 406150 Piraeus Felixstowe Felixstowe La Spezid Antwerp Algeciras Rotterdam Copenhagen Algeciras Algeciras Copenhagen Rotterdam Felixstowe $1,256 $1,256 $1,2 5 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,323 $1,013 $1,013 $1,238 $1,096 $963 $1,155 $1,264 $963 $963 $1,264 $1,155 $1,013 0 1680 0 310 160 0 20 0 0 0 544 496 0 $0 $3,557 $0 $656 $339 $0 $42 $0 $0 $0 $1,152 $1,050 $0 $8,701,752 $843,328 $7,438,004 $147,551,564 $1,859,910 $482,574 $3,296,659 $6,179,052 $16,499,448 $85,713,113 $13,536,462 $24,710,757 $284,950,933 $1,091,827,630 31716 39 68 195 124 6341 39 6 5 35 Sydney Port Sydney Port Sydney Port Sydney Port Sydney Port Auckland Sydney Port Auckland Sydney Port Auckland $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $5,222 $1,354 $1,354 $1,354 $1,354 $1,354 $1,177 $1,354 $1,177 $1,354 $1,177 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $208,573,550 $258,023 $447,036 $1,283,819 $817,903 $40,575,261 $259,108 $35,475 $31,032 $225,099 $252,506,307 Pacific Australia Fiji French Pacific Ocean Guam New Caledonia New Zealand Papua New Guinea Samoa Vanuatu W. Samoa tl Qbt., L3UIJLULa Total( for 1 year) Total ( for 5 year) 3ODDY 1157718 5788590 $3,410,479,956 $17,052,399,781 Table A.2.2 i I~1^ UUI y Iaes orl Taurus _____ - ~ - ~ - unit Cost from Plant to Export Port Africa Algeria Angola Benin Botswana Burkina Faso Burundi Cameroon Cape Verde Central African Republic Chad Comoros Congo Djibouti Equatorial Guinea Eritrea Ethiopia Gambia Ghana Guinea Guinea-Bissau Ivory Coast Kenya Liberia Libya Madagascar Malawi - import ror Distribution Cost in Global System with 2 Plants Plant Location : Detroit, U.S. & Paris, France Supply Plant : Paris Paris to Le Havre 428 121 176 55 50 61 134 13 18 2 12 17 12 2 13 13 20 127 8 21 504 129 5 857 4 43 Casablanca Durban Abidjan Durban Abidjan Durban Abidjan Durban Abidjan Abidjan Durban Durban Mombasa Durban Mombasa Mombasa Durban Abidjan Abidjan Durban Abidjan Mombasa Abidjan Casablanca Durban Durban I Unit Cost from ImportPort to Capital -- Export to Import Ports I Distance Total Cost I Unit Cost Le Havre to Import Ports $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $338 $2,237 $1,190 $2,237 $1,190 $2,237 $1,190 $2,237 $1,190 $1,190 $2,237 $2,237 $2,800 $2,237 $2,800 $2,800 $2,237 $1,190 $1,190 $2,237 $1,190 $2,800 $1,190 $338 $2,237 $2,237 560 1488 352 432 400 1472 848 1120 1200 1120 1280 1664 1040 800 800 688 1040 192 800 800 0 0 352 1104 0 928 $1,186 $3,151 $745 $915 $847 $3,117 $1,796 $2,372 $2,541 $2,372 $2,710 $3,524 $2,202 $1,694 $1,694 $1,457 $2,202 $407 $1,694 $1,694 $0 $0 $745 $2,338 $0 $1,965 $739,867 $675,062 $376,754 $184,564 $111,437 $337,236 $425,872 $64,159 $69,395 $8,696 $64,351 $99,557 $60,671 $8,334 $61,653 $58,540 $92,607 $229,009 $23,662 $86,374 $702,062 $387,887 $9,655 $2,466,698 $9,940 $189,626 Mali Mauritania Mauritius Morocco Mozambique Namibia Niger Nigeria Rwanda Saint Lucia Sao Tome & Principe Senegal Seychelles Sierra Leone Somalia South Africa Sudan Swaziland Tanzania Togo Tunisia Uganda Zaire Zambia Zimbabwe Subtotal 23 40 63 1991 40 12 110 953 23 16 5 47 15 47 0 4161 630 42 174 68 67 48 210 252 1525 13405 Casablanca Casablanca Durban Casablanca Durban Durban Abidjan Abidjan Durban Durban Durban Abidjan Durban Durban Mombasa Durban Mombasa Durban Mombasa Abidjan Casablanca Mombasa Durban Durban Durban Caribbean America Bahamas Barbados Bermuda Cuba Dominican Republic Guadeloupe Haiti 35 28 30 10 216 252 7 San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 Supply Plant : Detroit Detroit to N.Y. N.Y. to San Juan $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $338 $338 $2,237 $338 $2,237 $2,237 $1,190 $1,190 $2,237 $2,237 $2,237 $1,190 $2,237 $2,237 $2,800 $2,237 $2,800 $2,237 $2,800 $1,190 $338 $2,800 $2,237 $2,237 $2,237 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 1232 1040 0 0 224 848 576 352 800 800 800 832 1120 1120 448 0 1088 0 192 288 896 448 1632 912 640 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 $2,609 $2,202 $0 $0 $474 $1,796 $1,220 $745 $1,694 $1,694 $1,694 $1,762 $2,372 $2,372 $949 $0 $2,304 $0 $407 $610 $1,897 $949 $3,456 $1,931 $1,355 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $70,979 $108,887 $152,628 $1,077,521 $115,353 $52,921 $286,948 $2,038,737 $95,489 $65,020 $20,400 $149,790 $70,727 $225,315 $0 $10,152,490 $3,343,546 $103,494 $592,920 $135,725 $162,845 $190,053 $1,238,054 $1,101,466 $5,785,762 $34,880,733 $59,454 $47,081 $50,931 $16,327 $369,252 $431,273 $12,168 Jamaica Martinique Netherlands Antilles Puerto Rico Trinidad & Tobago Virgin Islands Other Subtotal 114 San Juan $1,256 $455 0 $0 0 San Juan $1,256 $455 0 $0 $0 194 1806 108 15 363 3175 San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 0 0 0 0 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $331,156 $3,090,326 $184,164 $26,492 $620,417 $5,434,140 $1,400 $666 $1,111 $1,636 $1,542 $666 $666 $1,111 $666 $666 $666 $666 $666 $666 $666 $1,636 $1,111 $666 $1,636 $666 0 672 512 0 0 352 0 560 960 1424 480 1120 320 208 0 624 0 1280 832 640 $0 $1,423 $1,084 $0 $0 $745 $0 $1,186 $2,033 $3,015 $1,016 $2,372 $678 $440 $0 $1,321 $0 $2,710 $1,762 $1,355 $24,890,438 $1,505 $310,644 $102,438,610 $5,344,674 $3,233,246 $1,078,208 $4,050,691 $562,245 $344,818 $767,700 $61,827 $70,889 $425,937 $1,109,574 $736,623 $781,894 $1,459,185 $2,916,809 $5,504,903 $156,090,422 C. & S. America Argentina Belize Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Costa Rica Ecuador El Salvador French Guiana Guatemala Guyana Honduras Nicaragua Panama Paraguay Peru Suriname Uruguay Venezuela Subtotal 9371 0 90 35424 1910 1212 561 1140 142 70 261 14 27 180 577 175 330 315 627 1680 54108 Buenos Aires Cristobal Callao Santo's Valparaso Cristobal Limon-Moin Callao Cristobal Cristobal Limon-Moin Cristobal Limon-Moin Limon-Moin Cristobal Santo's Callao Cristobal Santo's Cristobal Supply Plant: Detroit Detroit to N.Y. N.Y. to Import Ports $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $195,100 North America Canada Mexico United States Subtotal Supply Plant : Detroit 1 382691 8661 498405 545335 Far East $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 QS11 u tota 1P $128,442,845 $56,327,119 $1,040,647,567 $1,225,417,530 Supply Plant : Paris Paris to Le Havre Afghanistan Bangladesh Brunei Burma Cambodia China Hong Kong India Indonesia Japan Laos S. Korea Malaysia Maldives Mongolia Pakistan Philippines Singapore Sri Lanka Taiwan Thailand Vietnam $3,356 $6,503 1 19 52 0 134 6314 1099 4350 98 23404 306 3421 600 0 84 1465 2681 1565 381 19986 2340 19 6O3L1 Singapore Singapore Singapore Singapore Singapore Shanghai Hong Kong Madras Singapore Yokohama Singapore Pusan Singapore Singapore Shanghai Madras Marila Singapore Madras Kaoshung Singapore Singapore Le Havre to Import Ports $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $3,848 $3,848 $3,848 $3,848 $3,848 0 0 0 0 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $4,709 $78,389 $209,950 $887 $544,812 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $4,576 $4,328 $3,148 $3,848 592 0 560 0 $1,254 $0 $1,186 $0 $38,092,212 $4,979,605 $19,735,940 $398,587 $4,802 $3,848 $4,802 $3,848 $3,848 $4,576 $3,148 $4,287 $3,848 $3,148 $4,287 $3,848 0 0 160 0 0 1344 1280 0 0 0 $0 $0 $339 $0 $0 $2,846 $2,710 $0 $0 $0 $117,125,073 $1,238,674 $18,280,480 $2,429,463 $1,896 $642,360 $8,879,994 $12,037,495 $6,340,698 $1,278,114 0 80 $0 $169 $89,739,087 $9,876,039 $3,848 0 $0 $74,986 $ 74•1 $331,989,451 Mid East Subtotal Supply Plant : Paris Paris to Le Havre 11555 East Europe Armenia Byelarus Bulgaria Com. of Indep. Sta Croatia Cyprus Czechoslovakia Estonia Georgia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Macedonia Poland Romania Slovenia Yugoslavia Ukraine Subtotal 318 631 411 176 4563 188 741 948 40 1272 385 883 71 1454 3200 972 641 206 17100 560 $1,186 $57,683,543 By Land Directly $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 2320 1424 1216 900 736 1920 656 $4,913 $3,015 $2,575 $1,906 $1,558 $4,066 $1,389 $1,563,383 $1,902,136 $1,059,329 $334,920 $7,111,331 $765,745 $1,029,306 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 1520 2304 880 1376 1328 1120 $3,219 $4,879 $1,863 $2,914 $2,812 $2,372 $3,049,727 $195,363 $2,369,681 $1,120,924 $2,482,028 $169,261 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 1024 1328 832 1008 1488 $2,168 $2,812 $1,762 $2,134 $3,151 $3,152,298 $8,999,012 $1,712,427 $1,368,630 $650,493 $39,035,996 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 752 208 768 1600 0 752 $1,592 $440 $1,626 $3,388 $0 $1,592 $11,700,403 $4,110,354 $6,080,320 $5,114,699 $0 $155,974,234 Supply Plant : Paris 7348 9332 3739 1510 45432 97952 $3,603 $203) ( Supply Plant : Paris West Europe Austria Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany Jeddah By Land Directly $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 Greece Iceland Ireland Italy Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland UK Subtotal 3374 145 3278 46843 691 218 1344 2452 7437 38634 3686 7139 125597 406150 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 Pacific Australia Fiji French Pacific Ocean Guam New Caledonia New Zealand Papua New Guinea Samoa Vanuatu W. Samoa $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 1376 1952 624 752 224 1152 368 1120 960 768 1280 288 272 $2,914 $4,133 $1,321 $1,592 $474 $2,439 $779 $2,372 $2,033 $1,626 $2,710 $610 $576 $9,829,827 $598,296 $4,331,847 $74,590,619 $327,903 $530,589 $1,047,092 $5,814,633 $15,117,581 $62,827,550 $9,991,198 $4,353,762 $72,338,769 $444,679,675 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $135,037,530 $167,060 $289,439 $831,224 $529,561 $29,580,368 $167,762 $25,862 $20,092 $164,103 $166,813,002 Supply Plant : Paris Paris to Le Havre 31716 39 68 195 124 6341 39 6 5 35 Subtotal 385•Y Total ( for 1 year ) Total ( for 5 year ) 1157718 5788590 Sydney Port Sydney Port Sydney Port Sydney Port Sydney Port Auckland Sydney Port Auckland Sydney Port Auckland $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $4,055 $4,055 $4,055 $4,055 $4,055 $4,462 $4,055 $4,462 $4,055 $4,462 $2,462,024,493 $12,310,122,465 Table A.2.3 Distribution Cost in Global System with 3 Plants Plant Location : Detroit, U.S. & Paris, France Taiwan Country Sales for Import Port Taurus S Africa Algeria Angola Benin Botswana Burkina Faso Burundi Cameroon Cape Verde Central African Republic Chad Comoros Congo Djibouti Equatorial Guinea Eritrea Ethiopia Gambia Ghana Guinea Guinea-Bissau Ivory Coast Kenya Liberia Libya Madagascar Malawi Mali Unit Cost from Unit Cost from Plant to Export Port Export to Import Ports Supply Plant : Paris Paris to Le Havre 428 121 176 55 50 61 134 13 18 2 12 17 12 2 13 13 20 127 8 21 504 129 5 857 4 43 23 Casablanca Durban Abidjan Durban Abidjan Durban Abidjan Durban Abidjan Abidjan Durban Durban Mombasa Durban Mombasa Mombasa Durban Abidjan Abidjan Durban Abidjan Mombasa Abidjan Casablanca Durban Durban Casablanca Import Port to Capital Distance Total Cost Unit Cost Le Havre to Import Ports $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $338 $2,237 $1,190 $2,237 $1,190 $2,237 $1,190 $2,237 $1,190 $1,190 $2,237 $2,237 $2,800 $2,237 $2,800 $2,800 $2,237 $1,190 $1,190 $2,237 $1,190 $2,800 $1,190 $338 $2,237 $2,237 $338 560 1488 352 432 400 1472 848 1120 1200 1120 1280 1664 1040 800 800 688 1040 192 800 800 0 0 352 1104 0 928 1232 $1,186 $3,151 $745 $915 $847 $3,117 $1,796 $2,372 $2,541 $2,372 $2,710 $3,524 $2,202 $1,694 $1,694 $1,457 $2,202 $407 $1,694 $1,694 $0 $0 $745 $2,338 $0 $1,965 $2,609 $739,867 $675,062 $376,754 $184,564 $111,437 $337,236 $425,872 $64,159 $69,395 $8,696 $64,351 $99,557 $60,671 $8,334 $61,653 $58,540 $92,607 $229,009 $23,662 $86,374 $702,062 $387,887 $9,655 $2,466,698 $9,940 $189,626 $70,979 Mauritania Mauritius Morocco Mozambique Namibia Niger Nigeria Rwanda Saint Lucia Sao Tome & Principe Senegal Seychelles Sierra Leone Somalia South Africa Sudan Swaziland Tanzania Togo Tunisia Uganda Zaire Zambia Zimbabwe Subtotal 40 Casablanca $203 $338 1040 $2,202 63 1991 40 12 110 953 23 16 5 47 15 47 0 4161 630 42 174 68 67 48 210 252 1525 13405 $108,887 Durban Casablanca Durban Durban Abidjan Abidjan Durban Durban Durban Abidjan Durban Durban Mombasa Durban Mombasa Durban Mombasa Abidjan Casablanca Mombasa Durban Durban Durban $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $2,237 $338 $2,237 $2,237 $1,190 $1,190 $2,237 $2,237 $2,237 $1,190 $2,237 $2,237 $2,800 $2,237 $2,800 $2,237 $2,800 $1,190 $338 $2,800 $2,237 $2,237 $2,237 0 0 224 848 576 352 800 800 800 832 1120 1120 448 0 1088 0 192 288 896 448 1632 912 640 $0 $0 $474 $1,796 $1,220 $745 $1,694 $1,694 $1,694 $1,762 $2,372 $2,372 $949 $0 $2,304 $0 $407 $610 $1,897 $949 $3,456 $1,931 $1,355 $152,628 $1,077,521 $115,353 $52,921 $286,948 $2,038,737 $95,489 $65,020 $20,400 $149,790 $70,727 $225,315 $0 $10,152,490 $3,343,546 $103,494 $592,920 $135,725 $162,845 $190,053 $1,238,054 $1,101,466 $5,785,762 $34,880,733 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 Caribbean America Bahamas Barbados Bermuda Cuba Dominican Republic Guadeloupe Haiti Jamaica 35 28 30 10 216 252 7 114 San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan Supply Plant : Detroit Detroit to N.Y. N.Y. to San Juan $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $59,454 $47,081 $50,931 $16,327 $369,252 $431,273 $12,168 $195,100 Martinique Netherlands Antilles Puerto Rico Trinidad & Tobago Virgin Islands Other Subtotal 0 194 1806 108 San San San San Juan Juan Juan Juan $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $455 $455 $455 $455 0 0 0 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 15 San Juan $1,256 $455 363 3175 0 San Juan $0 $26,492 $1,256 $455 0 $0 $620,417 $5,434,140 0 672 512 0 0 352 0 560 960 1424 480 1120 320 208 0 624 0 1280 832 640 $0 $1,423 $1,084 $0 $0 $745 $0 $1,186 $2,033 $3,015 $1,016 $2,372 $678 $440 $0 $1,321 $0 $2,710 $1,762 $1,355 $0 $1,506 $276,519 $102,778,040 $4,098,899 $3,235,743 $1,061,861 $3,618,440 $562,538 $344,962 $760,086 $61,857 $70,095 $420,683 $1,110,764 $738,299 $656,667 $1,459,834 $2,922,815 $5,508,363 $129,687,968 $0 $331,156 $3,090,326 $184,164 1948.96 C. & S. America Supply Plant : Taiwan Taiwan to Import Ports Argentina Belize Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Costa Rica Ecuador El Salvador French Guiana Guatemala Guyana Honduras Nicaragua Panama Paraguay Peru Suriname Uruguay Venezuela QI- ULU tLal 9371 0 90 35424 1910 1212 561 1140 142 70 261 14 27 180 577 175 330 315 627 1680 5410U Buenos Aires Cristobal Callao Santo's Valparaso Cristobal Limon-Moin Callao Cristobal Cristobal Limon-Moin Cristobal Limon-Moin Limon-Moin Cristobal Santo's Callao Cristobal Santo's Cristobal $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $1,924 $1,988 $2,901 $2,146 $1,924 $1,893 $1,988 $1,924 $1,924 $1,893 $1,924 $1,893 $1,893 $1,924 $2,901 $1,988 $1,924 $2,901 $1,924 North America Supply Plant : Detroit Canada Mexico 38269 8661 $0 $0 $0 $0 United States 498405 $0 $0 Subtotal 545335 1 · $3,356 $6,503 · $128,442,845 $56,327,119 $1,040,647,567 $1,225,417,530 Far East Supply Plant : Taiwan Taiwan to Import Ports Afghanistan Bangladesh Brunei Burma Cambodia China Hong Kong India Indonesia Japan Laos S. Korea Malaysia Maldives Mongolia Pakistan Philippines Singapore Sri Lanka Taiwan Thailand Vietnam Subtotal 1 19 52 0 134 6314 1099 4350 98 23404 306 3421 600 0 84 1465 2681 1565 381 19986 2340 19 68321 Singapore Singapore Singapore Singapore Singapore Shanghai Hong Kong Madras Singapore Yokohama Singapore Pusan Singapore Singapore Shanghai Madras Marila Singapore Madras Kaoshung Singapore Singapore $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $374 $374 $374 $374 $374 $127 $92 $704 $374 $325 $374 $325 $374 $374 $127 $704 $19 $374 $704 $0 $374 $374 0 0 0 0 0 592 0 560 0 0 0 160 0 0 1344 1280 0 0 0 0 80 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $1,254 $0 $1,186 $0 $0 $0 $339 $0 $0 $2,846 $2,710 $0 $0 $0 $0 $169 $0 $435 $7,245 $19,403 $82 $50,351 $8,718,679 $100,582 $8,219,159 $36,837 $7,608,718 $114,477 $2,271,344 $224,528 $175 $250,463 $5,001,460 $50,187 $585,999 $268,370 $0 $1,272,491 $6,930 $34,807,915 · Mid East Subtotal Supply Plant : Taiwan Taiwan to Import Ports 11555 East Europe Jeddah $1,310 Supply Plant : Paris 560 $1,186 $28,843,665 By Land Directly Armenia Byelarus Bulgaria Com. of Indep. Sta Croatia Cyprus Czechoslovakia Estonia Georgia Hungary 318 631 411 176 4563 188 741 948 40 1272 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 2320 1424 1216 900 736 1920 656 1520 2304 880 $4,913 $3,015 $2,575 $1,906 $1,558 $4,066 $1,389 $3,219 $4,879 $1,863 $1,563,383 $1,902,136 $1,059,329 $334,920 $7,111,331 $765,745 $1,029,306 $3,049,727 $195,363 $2,369,681 Latvia Lithuania Macedonia Poland Romania 385 883 71 1454 3200 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 1376 1328 1120 1024 1328 $2,914 $2,812 $2,372 $2,168 $2,812 $1,120,924 $2,482,028 $169,261 $3,152,298 $8,999,012 Slovenia Yugoslavia 972 641 $0 $0 $0 $0 832 1008 $1,762 $2,134 $1,712,427 $1,368,630 206 17100 $0 $0 1488 $3,151 $650,493 $39,035,996 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 752 208 768 1600 0 752 $1,592 $440 $1,626 $3,388 $0 $1,592 $11,700,403 $4,110,354 $6,080,320 $5,114,699 $0 $155,974,234 Ukraine Subtotal West Europe Austria Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany Supply Plant : Paris 7348 9332 3739 1510 45432 97952 By Land Directly $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 Greece Iceland Ireland Italy Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland UK Subtotal 3374 145 3278 46843 691 218 1344 2452 7437 38634 3686 7139 125597 406150 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 Pacific $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 1376 1952 624 752 224 1152 368 1120 960 768 1280 288 272 $2,914 $4,133 $1,321 $1,592 $474 $2,439 $779 $2,372 $2,033 $1,626 $2,710 $610 $576 $9,829,827 $598,296 $4,331,847 $74,590,619 $327,903 $530,589 $1,047,092 $5,814,633 $15,117,581 $62,827,550 $9,991,198 $4,353,762 $72,338,769 $444,679,675 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $43,309,467 $53,580 $92,829 $266,592 $169,842 $11,241,089 $53,805 $9,828 $6,444 $62,362 $55,265,837 Supply Plant : Taiwan Taiwan to Import Ports Australia Fiji French Pacific Ocean Guam New Caledonia New Zealand Papua New Guinea Samoa Vanuatu W. Samoa S kUUbt cl oLIall Total ( for 1 year ) Total ( for 5 year ) 31716 39 68 195 124 6341 39 6 5 35 300Y0 1157718 5788590 Sydney Port Sydney Port Sydney Port Sydney Port Sydney Port Auckland Sydney Port Auckland Sydney Port Auckland $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $1,366 $1,366 $1,366 $1,366 $1,366 $1,773 $1,366 $1,773 $1,366 $1,773 $1,998,053,461 $9,990,267,306 Table A.2.4 Country mI Sales for Import Port Taurus Africa Algeria Angola Benin Botswana Burkina Faso Burundi Cameroon Cape Verde Central African Republic Chad Comoros Congo Djibouti Equatorial Guinea Eritrea Ethiopia Gambia Ghana Guinea Guinea-Bissau Ivory Coast Kenya Liberia Libya Madagascar Malawi Distribution Cost in Global System with 3 Plants Plant Location : Detroit, & Salt Lake City, U.S. Paris, France Unit Cost from Unit Cost from Plant to Export Port Export to Import Ports Supply Plant : Paris Paris to Le Havre 428 121 176 55 50 61 134 13 18 2 12 17 12 2 13 13 20 127 8 21 504 129 5 857 4 43 Casablanca Durban Abidjan Durban Abidjan Durban Abidjan Durban Abidjan Abidjan Durban Durban Mombasa Durban Mombasa Mombasa Durban Abidjan Abidjan Durban Abidjan Mombasa Abidjan Casablanca Durban Durban Import Port to Capital Total Cost Distance m Unit Cost Le Havre to Import Ports $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $338 $2,237 $1,190 $2,237 $1,190 $2,237 $1,190 $2,237 $1,190 $1,190 $2,237 $2,237 $2,800 $2,237 $2,800 $2,800 $2,237 $1,190 $1,190 $2,237 $1,190 $2,800 $1,190 $338 $2,237 $2,237 560 1488 352 432 400 1472 848 1120 1200 1120 1280 1664 1040 800 800 688 1040 192 800 800 0 0 352 1104 0 928 $1,186 $3,151 $745 $915 $847 $3,117 $1,796 $2,372 $2,541 $2,372 $2,710 $3,524 $2,202 $1,694 $1,694 $1,457 $2,202 $407 $1,694 $1,694 $0 $0 $745 $2,338 $0 $1,965 $739,867 $675,062 $376,754 $184,564 $111,437 $337,236 $425,872 $64,159 $69,395 $8,696 $64,351 $99,557 $60,671 $8,334 $61,653 $58,540 $92,607 $229,009 $23,662 $86,374 $702,062 $387,887 $9,655 $2,466,698 $9,940 $189,626 Mali Mauritania Mauritius Morocco Mozambique Namibia Niger Nigeria Rwanda Saint Lucia Sao Tome & Principe Senegal Seychelles Sierra Leone Somalia South Africa Sudan Swaziland Tanzania Togo Tunisia Uganda Zaire Zambia Zimbabwe Subtotal 23 40 63 1991 40 12 110 953 23 16 5 47 15 47 0 4161 630 42 174 68 67 48 210 252 1525 13405 Casablanca Casablanca Durban Casablanca Durban Durban Abidjan Abidjan Durban Durban Durban Abidjan Durban Durban Mombasa Durban Mombasa Durban Mombasa Abidjan Casablanca Mombasa Durban Durban Durban Caribbean America Bahamas Barbados Bermuda Cuba Dominican Republic Guadeloupe Haiti 35 28 30 10 216 252 7 San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan San Juan $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 $203 Supply Plant : Detroit Detroit to N.Y. N.Y. to San Juan $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $338 $338 $2,237 $338 $2,237 $2,237 $1,190 $1,190 $2,237 $2,237 $2,237 $1,190 $2,237 $2,237 $2,800 $2,237 $2,800 $2,237 $2,800 $1,190 $338 $2,800 $2,237 $2,237 $2,237 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 1232 1040 0 0 224 848 576 352 800 800 800 832 1120 1120 448 0 1088 0 192 288 896 448 1632 912 640 $2,609 $2,202 $0 $0 $474 $1,796 $1,220 $745 $1,694 $1,694 $1,694 $1,762 $2,372 $2,372 $949 $0 $2,304 $0 $407 $610 $1,897 $949 $3,456 $1,931 $1,355 $70,979 $108,887 $152,628 $1,077,521 $115,353 $52,921 $286,948 $2,038,737 $95,489 $65,020 $20,400 $149,790 $70,727 $225,315 $0 $10,152,490 $3,343,546 $103,494 $592,920 $135,725 $162,845 $190,053 $1,238,054 $1,101,466 $5,785,762 $34,880,733 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $59,454 $47,081 $50,931 $16,327 $369,252 $431,273 $12,168 Jamaica Martinique Netherlands Antilles Puerto Rico Trinidad & Tobago Virgin Islands Other Subtotal 114 0 194 1806 108 15 363 3175 San San San San San San San Juan Juan Juan Juan Juan Juan Juan C. & S. America Argentina Belize Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Costa Rica Ecuador El Salvador French Guiana Guatemala Guyana Honduras Nicaragua Panama Paraguay Peru Suriname Uruguay Venezuela Subtotal 9371 0 90 35424 1910 1212 561 1140 142 70 261 14 27 180 577 175 330 315 627 1680 54108 Buenos Aires Cristobal Callao Santo's Valparaso Cristobal Limon-Moin Callao Cristobal Cristobal Limon-Moin Cristobal Limon-Moin Limon-Moin Cristobal Santo's Callao Cristobal Santo's Cristobal $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 Supply Plant : Detroit Detroit to N.Y. N.Y. to Import Ports $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $1,256 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 $455 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $195,100 $0 $331,156 $3,090,326 $184,164 $26,492 $620,417 $5,434,140 $1,400 $666 $1,111 $1,636 $1,542 $666 $666 $1,111 $666 $666 $666 $666 $666 $666 $666 $1,636 $1,111 $666 $1,636 $666 0 672 512 0 0 352 0 560 960 1424 480 1120 320 208 0 624 0 1280 832 640 $0 $1,423 $1,084 $0 $0 $745 $0 $1,186 $2,033 $3,015 $1,016 $2,372 $678 $440 $0 $1,321 $0 $2,710 $1,762 $1,355 $24,890,438 $1,505 $310,644 $102,438,610 $5,344,674 $3,233,246 $1,078,208 $4,050,691 $562,245 $344,818 $767,700 $61,827 $70,889 $425,937 $1,109,574 $736,623 $781,894 $1,459,185 $2,916,809 $5,504,903 $156,090,422 North America Canada Mexico United States Subtotal I Supply Plant : Detroit and Salt Lake City by land directly $0 $0 $0 38269 8661 498405 545335 Far East $0 $0 $0 $1,804 $6,503 $69,019,322 $56,324,434 $684,329,239 $809,672,995 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $1,254 $0 $1,186 $0 $0 $0 $339 $0 $0 $2,846 $2,710 $0 $0 $0 $0 $169 $0 $3,777 $62,867 $168,376 $712 $436,930 $25,727,171 $3,230,723 $20,723,390 $319,660 $61,297,570 $993,395 $10,397,125 $1,948,387 $1,521 $477,388 $9,212,540 $7,964,640 $5,085,130 $1,364,690 $59,376,100 $7,998,906 $60,138 $216,851,134 Supply Plant : Salt Lake City Afghanistan Bangladesh Brunei Burma Cambodia China Hong Kong India Indonesia Japan Laos S. Korea Malaysia Maldives Mongolia Pakistan Philippines Singapore Sri Lanka Taiwan Thailand Vietnam 1 19 52 0 134 6314 1099 4350 98 23404 306 3421 600 0 84 1465 2681 1565 381 19986 2340 19 LSubtotal 68321 Singapore Singapore Singapore Singapore Singapore Shanghai Hong Kong Madras Singapore Yokohama Singapore Pusan Singapore Singapore Shanghai Madras Marila Singapore Madras Kaoshung Singapore Singapore Salt Lake City to L.A. L.A. to Import Ports $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,636 $1,636 $1,636 $1,636 $1,636 $1,208 $1,327 $1,966 $1,636 $1,007 $1,636 $1,088 $1,636 $1,636 $1,208 $1,966 $1,358 $1,636 $1,966 $1,358 $1,636 $1,636 0 0 0 0 0 592 0 560 0 0 0 160 0 0 1344 1280 0 0 0 0 80 0 I Mid East Subtotal I Supply Plant : Paris Paris to Le Havre 11555 East Europe Armenia Byelarus Bulgaria Com. of Indep. Sta Croatia Cyprus Czechoslovakia Estonia Georgia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Macedonia Poland Romania Slovenia Yugoslavia Ukraine Subtotal $203 Supply Plant : Paris 318 631 411 176 4563 188 741 948 40 1272 385 883 71 1454 3200 972 641 206 17100 West Europe Austria Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany Jeddah 560 $1,186 $57,683,543 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 2320 1424 1216 900 736 1920 656 1520 2304 880 1376 1328 1120 1024 1328 832 1008 1488 $4,913 $3,015 $2,575 $1,906 $1,558 $4,066 $1,389 $3,219 $4,879 $1,863 $2,914 $2,812 $2,372 $2,168 $2,812 $1,762 $2,134 $3,151 $1,563,383 $1,902,136 $1,059,329 $334,920 $7,111,331 $765,745 $1,029,306 $3,049,727 $195,363 $2,369,681 $1,120,924 $2,482,028 $169,261 $3,152,298 $8,999,012 $1,712,427 $1,368,630 $650,493 $39,035,996 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 752 208 768 1600 0 752 $1,592 $440 $1,626 $3,388 $0 $1,592 $11,700,403 $4,110,354 $6,080,320 $5,114,699 $0 $155,974,234 By Land Directly $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 Supply Plant : Paris 7348 9332 3739 1510 45432 97952 $3,603 By Land Directly $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 Greece Iceland Ireland Italy Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland UK Subtotal 3374 145 3278 46843 691 218 1344 2452 7437 38634 3686 7139 125597 406150 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 Pacific Australia Fiji French Pacific Ocean Guam New Caledonia New Zealand Papua New Guinea Samoa Vanuatu W. Samoa Subtotal Total ( for 1 year) Total ( for 5 year ) 31716 39 68 195 124 6341 39 6 5 35 38569 1157718 5788590 Sydney Port Sydney Port Sydney Port Sydney Port Sydney Port Auckland Sydney Port Auckland Sydney Port Auckland Supply Plant : Salt Lake City Salt Lake City to L.A. L.A. to Import Ports $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $1,613 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $1,354 $1,354 $1,354 $1,354 $1,354 $1,177 $1,354 $1,177 $1,354 $1,177 1376 1952 624 752 224 1152 368 1120 960 768 1280 288 272 $2,914 $4,133 $1,321 $1,592 $474 $2,439 $779 $2,372 $2,033 $1,626 $2,710 $610 $576 $9,829,827 $598,296 $4,331,847 $74,590,619 $327,903 $530,589 $1,047,092 $5,814,633 $15,117,581 $62,827,550 $9,991,198 $4,353,762 $72,338,769 $444,679,675 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $94,097,821 $116,412 $201,689 $579,220 $369,013 $17,688,019 $116,901 $15,465 $14,001 $98,128 $113,296,668 $1,877,625,306 $9,388,126,528