Essays on Prescription Drug Benefits in Medicare Managed Care by Anne Elizabeth Hall B. A., Linguistics (1993), Yale University M.Phil., General Linguistics and Comparative Philology (1995), University of Oxford Submitted to the Department of Economics in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology iNS OF TEHOO E Y June 2005 JUN 06 LIB ( 2005 Anne E. Hall RIES All rights reserved The author hereby grants to MIT permission to reproduce and to distribute publicly paper and electronic copies of this thesis document in whole or in part. x Signature of Author....y ..........-. ......... .................................................... x\ ~~~~~~~~\>~~ ~ Departmentof Economics ~May 17, 2005 Certified by........................................................ Jonathan Gruber Professor of Economics Thesis Supervisor Certified by ....... .i .... Jerry Hausman John and Jennie S. MacDonald Professor of Economics Thesis Supervisor Accepted by................ ............................................................................. Peter Temin Elisha Gray II Professor of Economics Chairman, Departmental Committee on Graduate Studies -ARCHIVES 05 Essays on Prescription Drug Benefits in Medicare Managed Care by Anne Elizabeth Hall Submitted to the Department of Economics in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy of Economics ABSTRACT In this thesis, I estimate a structural demand model for prescription drug benefits by Medicare beneficiaries using data from the Medicare HMO program. I then use the utility parameter estimates to explore other questions of interest relating to the elderly's demand for prescription drug benefits. In Chapter 1, I study the question of how much Medicare beneficiaries value prescription drug benefits. Using data from the Medicare HMO program, I find that Medicare beneficiaries are willing to pay $33 to increase their brand-name coverage limit by $100. I also estimate marginal cost for each HMO and regress it on prescription drug benefits. I find that raising brand-name coverage by $100 costs $30. These estimates suggest that Medicare HMO enrollees are less than average prescription drug users and the results give a lower bound for the welfare derived by the elderly from prescription drug benefits. Chapter 2 addresses the question of how Medicare HMOs' choices of premiums and benefits affect selection. Changes in demographic factors (a measure of risk based on beneficiaries' characteristics) and risk scores (a measure based on beneficiaries' inpatient diagnoses) in the fee-for-service sector are regressed on changes in premiums and benefits in the HMO sector. The results show that increasing premiums and lowering benefits raise the demographic factor but have no effect on the risk score, suggesting that beneficiaries in more expensive demographic categories switch out of HMOs when premiums rise and benefits fall but these beneficiaries are healthy for their demographic category. Chapter 3 measures the welfare loss from the withdrawals from the HMO program following the Balanced Budget Act of 1997, using the utility parameter estimates from Chapter 1. The changes to the Medicare HMO program in the Balanced Budget Act triggered many plan withdrawals from the program. The welfare and costs are calculated under two counterfactual scenarios. The results show that the Medicare HMO program generates more welfare than costs and that the withdrawals resulted in a net loss for society. The estimates of the loss range from $4.3 billion to $16.6 billion. Thesis Supervisor: Jonathan Gruber Title: Professor of Economics Thesis Supervisor: Jerry Hausman Title: John and Jennie S. MacDonald Professor of Economics 3 4 Acknowledgments This thesis would not have been possible without the support and contributions of many people and I would like to take this opportunity to acknowledge them in print. My advisors, Jon Gruber and Jerry Hausman, both gave helpful advice and feedback throughout all stages of researching and writing this thesis. I am deeply appreciative of the time and effort they both put into advising me. In addition, their constant support and enthusiasm kept my spirits up, and I never came out of a discussion with either of them without feeling more inspired and hopeful about my work than when I came in. Both of my parents gave me an enormous amount of support throughout graduate school, even when I abandoned one Ph.D. and took up another. Not many parents would have been as sympathetic to their children's career crises as mine were and I will always be grateful. Their biggest contribution, however, was in raising me to enjoy learning and appreciate scholarly work. My mother also contributed by reading drafts and providing feedback. Ernie Berndt has always gone beyond the call of duty in giving me support and advice all throughout graduate school, and by giving me the opportunity to teach and helping with my job search. David Cutler and Jim Poterba were also particularly helpful with this thesis and throughout my graduate career. Glenn Ellison and Joe Newhouse also gave helpful feedback for Chapter 1. My classmates at MIT and my graduate student colleagues at the NBER provided tons of companionship, support and feedback. I'd particularly like to thank Melissa Boyle, Lesley Chiou, Norma Coe, Dan Hungerman, Srikanth Kadiyala, Patricia Keenan, Joanna Lahey, Ha Yan Lee, Byron Lutz, Grant Miller, Erich Muehlegger, and Cindy Perry. Their friendship has been invaluable; they made graduate school bearable, and even occasionally fun. The support staff at the NBER were amazingly helpful, particularly Donna Hicks and Janet Stein, who administered my fellowship, and Dan Feenberg and Mohan Ramanujan, who provided excellent computer support. Gary King at MIT was also incredibly helpful and always shared his vast knowledge of how things work at MIT. My brothers Chris, Jonathan, and Andrew, my stepmother Susan, my stepsister Sonja, and her husband Evan, were all tremendously supportive throughout. My extended family was also, particularly those who live in the Boston area: my cousin Cathy and her husband Johan, my aunt Betty and uncle Pat, and my cousin Ch'uya and her husband Dave, all provided advice, support, and endless free dinners. My non-economist friends (and I'm amazed I still have some) have been incredibly supportive and patient, even when I disappeared for months on end to study for generals or work on my job-market paper. Thanks especially to Lois and Timur, Kasey, Chris, Mike, Renate, Stephanie, Maria, and Ron. Thanks also to the other members of Chorus pro Musica for giving me a life outside economics. Finally, it would be species-ist of me not to recognize Persephone and Ulysses for relieving stress, for getting me up in the morning, and for generally helping out, especially with the important tasks of sleeping on my desk and walking across the computer keyboard when I am trying to work. Funding from the National Institute on Aging, through Grant Number T32-AG 00186 to the National Bureau of Economic Research, is gratefully acknowledged. 5 6 Table of Contents Chapter 1: Estimating the Demand for Prescription Drug Benefits by Medicare Beneficiaries I. Introduction 9 II. Background: The Medicare HMO Program III. A model of demand for Medicare HMO coverage and prescription drug 11 coverage 12 IV. Data on the Medicare HMO program 14 V. Data on prescription drug benefits 17 VI. Empirical strategy 20 VII. Demand parameter estimates VIII. Welfare estimates IX. The cost of supplying prescription drug benefits 23 27 32 X. Conclusion References Table 1a Table 1b Table 2a Table 2b Table 3 Table 4 Table 5 Table 6 36 38 40 41 42 43 45 45 46 49 Table 7 51 Table 8 52 Table 9 53 Table 10 54 Chapter 2: Medicare HMOs, Prescription Drug Benefits, and Selection I. Introduction II. Previous work 56 59 III. A model of plan choice by Medicare beneficiaries IV. Data on Medicare HMOs and risk in the Medicare FFS sector 60 63 V. Empirical specification VI. Results VII. Discussion VIII. Conclusion References Figure 1 65 68 74 75 77 79 7 Figure 2 Figure 3 80 80 Table 1 81 Table 2 82 Table 3 83 Table 4 84 Table 5 85 Table 6 86 Table 7 87 88 Table 8 Chapter 3: The Welfare Loss from Medicare+Choice I. Introduction II. Background: The Medicare HMO Program and the Balanced Budget Act of 1997 III. My approach to estimating welfare IV. Estimating welfare in nested logit models V. Applying welfare estimates to the Medicare HMO market VI. Results of welfare and cost calculations VII. Conclusion References Table 1 Table 2 Table 3 89 92 96 100 101 103 106 108 109 109 110 Table 4 113 Figure 1 117 Figure 2 118 8 Chapter 1: Estimating the Demand for Prescription Drug Benefits by Medicare Beneficiaries I. Introduction Medicare, when it was passed in 1965, did not include an outpatient prescription drug benefit. Adding such a benefit has been under debate almost since the inception of Medicare and the debate intensified during the 1990s. Medical spending during this decade rose more quickly than GDP and prescription drug spending rose even more quickly than overall medical spending. In 1999, for example, GDP rose 4.8%, medical spending rose 7.1% and prescription drug spending rose 18.4% (Strunk and Ginsburg 2004). Medicare beneficiaries who do not have prescription drug coverage, however, as part of their supplemental coverage have no protection against prescription drug costs, even though prescription drugs have become a larger part of medical treatment. In December 2003, Congress passed the Medicare Prescription Drug Improvement and Modernization Act, which provides a partial, voluntary drug benefit for Medicare beneficiaries starting in 2006. Much of the debate around passing this act centered on the costs. Estimates of the cost of this benefit over the next decade are uncertain and range from $395 billion (from the Congressional Budget Office) to $534 billion (from the Department of Health and Human Services). There has however been very little discussion of the potential value of the benefit; while there appears to be a consensus that providing such a benefit is good policy, without quantification of the welfare derived from it, there is no way of knowing what the rate of return of spending on the drug benefit will be. 9 In this paper, I will address the question of how much value Medicare beneficiaries derive from having prescription drug benefits by using data from the Medicare HMO program to estimate the demand for, costs of, and welfare implications of prescription drug benefits for Medicare beneficiaries who enroll in Medicare HMOs. I will be employing methods developed for estimating demand for differentiated products using market share data used previously by Berry (1994) and Town and Liu (2003), among others. I find that Medicare beneficiaries, on average, are willing to pay $20 a month for Medicare HMO prescription drug benefits, $28 a month to have their brandname drug coverage raised by $100, about $0.07 a month to lower their brand-name drug co-payment by $1 and $8 a month to have coverage outside a plan's formulary, or list of favored drugs. The benefits cost on average $146 per person per month to provide and it costs plans $100 to raise brand-name coverage by $100, $129 to provide non-formulary coverage, and $0.56 to lower the brand-name co-payment by $1. The discrepancy between valuation and cost probably arises from either adverse selection or moral hazard combined with regulation of HMOs that constrains their profit levels and causes them to supply benefits at a cost higher than their value to beneficiaries. While there have been previous studies on the plan choices of Medicare beneficiaries using data from the Medicare HMO program (Dowd et al. 2003, Town and Liu 2003 and Atherly et al. 2004), my paper is the first to examine the welfare and cost implications of providing different levels of drug benefits. Town and Liu discuss welfare but they consider the welfare only from having or not having a benefit, not from different levels of benefits, nor do they consider the costs of benefits. To predict the consequences 10 of providing such a benefit however, it is necessary to understand beneficiaries' response to different levels of benefits and the associated costs. Section II gives some background on the Medicare HMO program, Section III presents a model of demand for Medicare HMOs and their drug benefits, Section IV and Section V discuss the data, Section VI presents the empirical strategy, Section VII presents the demand parameter estimates, Section VIII the welfare estimates and Section IX the cost estimates. Section X concludes. II. Background: The Medicare HMO Program Traditional Medicare has high requirements for patient cost sharing relative to most modern private insurance plans. Currently, Medicare requires 20% co-insurance on most outpatient services, a high deductible ($876) on hospital stays and only covers the first 150 days of hospitalization per year. To cover the remaining costs, a large proportion (87% in 1999 [Medicare Chartbook 2001]) of beneficiaries have some kind of supplemental insurance. In 1999, about a third had employer-sponsored had private Medigap insurance, coverage, 24% 11% were on Medicaid and 17% were enrolled in a Medicare HMO. The Medicare HMO program was created to take advantage of the supposedly greater efficiency of managed care plans in caring for Medicare beneficiaries. Commercial HMOs contract with the Center for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS), the agency that runs Medicare, to provide health care for Medicare beneficiaries within a defined service area (usually a county or group of contiguous counties). The contract, which is revised and renewed each year, specifies benefits to be provided and possibly a 11 premium that will be charged by the HMO to the beneficiary. The government reimburses the HMO at a flat rate that is set at a base level by county and then adjusted for the individual beneficiary's age, sex, Medicaid eligibility status and employment status. The flat rate passes on the financial risk of the beneficiary's medical care to the HMO. Beneficiaries are allowed to enroll in HMOs or remain in traditional Medicare as they choose and are currently allowed to switch in and out or among HMOs whenever they want. The HMOs must either accept all enrollees or close the plan completely. From the beneficiary's point of view, the advantage of the HMOs is that they require less cost-sharing for the beneficiary; co-payments for doctor visits, for example, are usually about $10-$15 per visit which is less than traditional Medicare's 20% co- insurance. Medicare HMOs also often cover benefits that are not covered by traditional Medicare such as preventive care and outpatient prescription drugs. On the other hand, they are managed-care plans and therefore usually place constraints on which providers patients can see, which traditional Medicare does not. III. A model of demand for Medicare HMO coverage and prescription drug coverage To estimate the value of drug benefits to Medicare beneficiaries, I will first estimate a model of demand for HMOs and their associated benefits. To do this, I will use methods for estimating the demand for differentiated products that have been developed and used by Berry (1994) and Town and Liu (2003). Berry, following Cardell (1997), lays out how to estimate logit and nested logit models of demand using data on market shares and on prices and choice characteristics. 12 I will focus on the nested logit specification but will also present results from the logit. In the nested logit model, plans are grouped into nests, within which utility is correlated across plans. Similar to Town and Liu, I group the choices of Medicare beneficiaries into HMOs with drug benefits, HMOs without drug benefit and traditional Medicare. Utility for person i in plan j in county m at time t in this model is given as: Uijmt m, jmt, +jmt jmt + igmt +(1 )£ijmt (1) Pjm,is the premium paid by the beneficiary, Xjm, is a vector of observed characteristics of the plan, j,,, is the unobserved quality of plan j and ejmt (distributed extreme value) is an indclividual-specificshock. igmt +( - )£uijm, is the random component of utility and is also distributed extreme value. Cardell derives the distribution of individual-specific ,igmt'another shock that is the same for each individual across all plans in the same group g (HMO with prescription drug benefits or HMO without prescription drug benefits). are [0,1) measures the correlation of within-group utility. In the simple logit, both and Cigequal 0, so ijmtis the only individual-specific shock. This specification has the prediction that, if a plan exits the market, the plan's members move to the plan with the largest market share. This prediction holds even if the plan that they originally chose offered drug coverage and the plan that they are predicted to move to does not. In the nested logit model, this prediction only holds within nests and we will see that the nested logit model fits the data better. 13 Berry shows that if utility has the specification in (1), the parameters of the utility function can be estimated with a linear regression (omitting the subscripts m and t for clarity): (2) lns -Ins0 =apj +Xj,8+lnsjlg + :j where sj is plan j's market share and so is the market share of the outside choice, which is defined as the choice whose utility is normalized to zero. I define the outside choice as choosing to remain in traditional Medicare. sjig is the plan's share within its nest and the plan quality ~j is unobserved and comprises the error term. Data on the Medicare HMO program IV. Data were collected for the years 1999-2002. Market shares for Medicare HMOs come from the Medicare Managed Care Market Penetration State/County/Plan Data files, which contain enrollment Reimbursement in Medicare managed care plans by plan and county. levels come from the Medicare+Choice base reimbursement Payment Rate files; I use the rate for the aged in each county. Benefit and premium data come from the Medicare Compare database, which is the source of information for the online plan chooser for Medicare beneficiaries. All of these data sources were obtained from the Center for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS), the government agency that runs Medicare. I had to overcome a few difficulties with the data in order to use it. First, the enrollment data do not report enrollment by county of service area of the HMO but rather by county of residence for the beneficiary. While beneficiaries can only enroll in an HMO if they live in that HMO's service area, they are usually allowed to retain coverage 14 if they subsequently move outside the plan's service area. The result is that there appear to be many more HMOs in a county than there actually are HMOs available for beneficiaries to enroll in. Most of the HMOs have very small enrollment, however. Like other researchers who have used these data, therefore, I have only counted an HMO as competing in a county if its enrollment is above a certain level (25 enrollees) and I have also only included it if the Medicare Compare database shows the HMO as being in that county since otherwise there is no benefit or premium data for it. The enrollment data also only give enrollment by contract number within a county. One contract may, however, cover more than one package of benefits since HMOs are allowed to offer more than one within a county. Usually, the offerings consist of a "basic" plan with an optional supplement for an extra premium. Since enrollment is not split up by packages however, I attribute all of the enrollment to the HMO's "basic" plan (the plan with the lowest premium). (Atherly et al. [2004] report that 87% of Medicare HMO enrollees with prescription drug coverage receive it through the plan's basic benefit package.) The market share was calculated by dividing the HMO's enrollment by the number of Medicare eligibles, adjusted to reflect state-level rates of Medicaid and employer-sponsored plan participation. These rates were calculated by pooling the March demographic supplements for the four years, identifying respondents reporting being covered by Medicare and then tabulating the rates at which these respondents also report being covered by Medicaid and employer-sponsored insurance by state. It was necessary to use state-level rates since the sample sizes for MSAs would not have been large enough. 15 Table 1a shows, for each year, the number of contracts, the number of counties with at least one Medicare HMO, the number of county-contract combinations (observations) and total enrollment in the Medicare HMO program. All of these variables decline sharply during the period of interest. Between 1999 and 2002, the number of contracts drops from 290 to 143, the number of counties with at least one HMO drops from 808 to 540, the number of observations drops from 1,964 to 962 and the number of enrollees drops from 6.1 million to 4.8 million, a drop of 21%. The drop in overall participation in the Medicare HMO program is due to the large number of plan withdrawals during this period. These were in turn triggered by the Balanced Budget Act of 1997, which went into effect in 1999. The Balanced Budget Act adjusted the formula for the base reimbursement rates so that reimbursement did not grow as fast for many areas and, as a result, many plans dropped out. Table lb shows summary statistics for Medicare HMOs and counties by year. The average Medicare HMO market share in a county climbed from 6.1% to 8.1% between 1999 and 2002; this increase is due to the greater likelihood of a plan withdrawing if it had a smaller market share. Similarly, the average enrollment in a plan climbs from 3,107 to 5,033. The HMOs with the largest shares each year have shares from 47-48% and the plans with the greatest enrollment have enrollments of 130,000-144,000. Traditional Medicare's market share is on average about 85% in counties where there are HMOs and only ever drops as low as 47%, so even in counties with high HMO enrollment, traditional Medicare is still a dominant presence. The average number of plans in a county, conditional on there being at least one plan in the county, is about 2.5 16 in 1999 and drops to 1.8 by 2002 and the number of plans in a county ranges from to 12. In addition to many HMOs dropping out of the program during this period, a further effect of reducing the reimbursement was that the HMOs who stayed in raised premiums faster than the rate of inflation and reduced coverage. Table 2a shows the average premium and percent of plans offering drug benefits by year. The average premium nearly tripled between 1999 and 2002 while at the same time the percent of plans offering prescription drug benefits dropped from 70% in 1999 to 60% in 2001 and then rose again to 66% in 2002. V. Data on prescription drug benefits Medicare HMOs vary the generosity of their drug benefits along several axes. They can vary in what categories of drugs they cover, the coverage limits, the number of tiers, the amount of the co-payments, the presence of a formulary (or list of drugs favored by the plan), and whether the formulary is open or closed. The main distinction in pricing among drugs is whether a drug is brand-name or generic. Brand-name drugs are still under patent and are therefore priced much higher than generic drugs. Table 4 contains national average drug prices for both the generic and brand-name categories for 1999-2002, and, as it shows, brand-name drugs were typically more than three times as expensive as generic drugs during this period. In the data, plans fall into one of five categories with regard to what classes of drugs they cover and whether or not there is a limit on coverage. Plans can have: * Limited generic coverage and no brand-name coverage; 17 * Unlimited generic coverage and no brand-name coverage; * Limited generic and brand-name coverage; * Unlimited generic coverage and limited brand-name coverage; * Unlimited generic and brand-name coverage. Table 2b shows the distribution of plans across the categories. The main way in which plans reduced their generosity during this period was by removing brand-name drug coverage. Between 1999 and 2002, there was a marked shift from the last three categories into the second and the percent of plans with drug benefits offering brandname coverage dropped from almost 97% to 59%. Nominal coverage amounts within the categories remained stable over the period although the real value of the coverage declined since prescription drug prices were rising 5-10% a year. The co-payment is the amount per prescription paid by the plan enrollee. Drugs are grouped by co-payment into tiers, which are usually defined by the drugs' patent status (brand-name or generic) and whether or not the drug is in the plan's formulary. The formulary is a list of drugs that the plan obtains at lower prices and drugs on the formulary have lower co-payments. In the 1999-2000 data, a plan can have up to four tiers: generic non-formulary, brand-name non-formulary, generic formulary and brand-name formulary. In the 20012002 data, a plan can also have a fifth tier: preferred brand-name formulary, and can also specify different co-payments for when prescription drugs are mail-ordered. Few plans have the maximum number of tiers, however, since plans do not always cover all categories of drugs, and often formularies apply only to brand-name drugs. 18 Plans also vary in whether or not they have a formulary and whether the formulary is open or closed. A formulary is open if drugs not on the formulary are covered (at a higher co-payment). The formulary is closed if drugs not on it are not covered at all. I group plans without formularies and plans with open formularies together into plans offering non-formulary coverage. There is no information in the data about what drugs are included in the formulary; rather, the beneficiary is advised to contact the plan directly about the formulary. For the purposes of this study, since co-payments for the different tiers are highly correlated, I only use one generic co-payment and one brand-name co-payment from each plan. For each category, I use the lowest co-payment available (usually the generic formulary co-payment and the preferred brand-name co-payment). Co-payments remained more or less stable throughout this period, as Table 2a shows; the average generic co-payment only rises slightly from $6.70 to $8.72 while the average brand-name co-payment remains more or less constant at $15-$16. The bottom rows of Table 2a report averages of measure of drug expenditure covered by insurance and out-of-pocket spending for each plan; how I calculated these will be discussed below. Table 3 shows the average base rate for reimbursement by year for all counties and counties containing HMOs. These range from about $400-500 a month to $700-800 across counties and over the period in question. The average rate for counties with HMOs is about $40 higher than the average rate for all counties. This difference is not surprising since studies of entry and exit in the Medicare HMO industry indicate that the level of 19 reimbursement is the most important factor in HMOs' decision to offer a Medicare plan in a county (GAO 1999, Abraham 2000, Ellis and Gurol 2002, Pai 1999, Penrod 2001). Empirical strategy VI. As discussed in Section III, the regression to be estimated is: lnSjmt -Ilnsomt = Pjmt+ X jmt, + alnSjlgmt + jt (3) where s is the market share, j is the plan, m is the county and t is the year (1999-2002). Xjmt is a vector of drug benefit characteristics, the exact specification of which will be discussed below. 5jmt contains unobserved characteristics of the plan that are unobserved by the econometrician but are observed by the beneficiaries and affect their valuation of the plan. In this case, among other things, it might take the form of the extensiveness and quality of the HMO's provider network, which we cannot observe. Unobserved quality is correlated with both premium and the log of the nest share. In order to overcome this problem, I use a strategy very similar to Hausman (1996), Nevo (2001) and Town and Liu (2003). I use plan-county fixed effects, which capture the plancounty mean quality jm leaving the time-specific deviation in plan quality Ajm, as the error term. The only potential bias therefore would arise from factors that change over time for a given plan in a given county that affect both their premium and demand for their product. To deal with this remaining concern, I instrument for both premium and the log of the nest share. I use two instruments for premiums. The first is created by calculating the mean of the premiums charged by the plan's competitors for each of the other counties in 20 the plan's service area, and then calculating the mean of these means, weighted by the number of Medicare eligibles in each county. The weighting takes into account the relative importance of the other markets to the plans' pricing decisions. For example, in 2002, Harvard Pilgrim Health Care offered a Medicare HMO plan in Essex, Middlesex, Suffolk and Norfolk counties in Massachusetts (see Figure 1). The instrument for the Harvard Pilgrim Health Care-Essex county-2002 observation would be calculated by taking the means of Tufts and Blue Cross Blue Shield's premiums in Middlesex county, of the same two plans' premiums in Suffolk county and of Tufts, Blue Cross Blue Shield and Fallon in Norfolk county and then calculating the mean of these three numbers weighted by the number of Medicare eligibles in each of the three counties. In using competitors' premiums, I differ from most previous work in this area which use the firm's own prices in other geographic regions as instruments rather than competitors' prices. The assumption behind using own premiums is that shocks to marginal cost will be reflected in the firms' prices across counties. Their strategy requires, however, the assumption that the different regions' deviations from the mean valuation of the same good be independent of each other. This assumption can be justified in the case where regions are geographically separated from each other and the good that is being sold is the same across regions (as in the case of ready-to-eat cereal being sold in different cities across the US). Medicare HMOs, however, tend to operate in a group of counties that are contiguous and beneficiaries are likely to be crossing over county boundaries to receive their medical care. In this case, a plan's time-specific deviations from the means of quality for each county are not going to be independent of 21 each other in adjacent counties, limiting the applicability of the type of instrument used in previous work. For example, if Harvard Pilgrim Health Care adds a Boston hospital to its network, the time-specific deviation from its county means of quality will be correlated across Suffolk, Middlesex and Norfolk counties since many residents of Middlesex and Norfolk counties go into Boston in Suffolk county to receive hospital care. Using competitors' premiums in other counties overcomes this problem. Competitors' premiums are correlated with the premium because of the component of marginal cost common to the region. They are, on the other hand, unlikely to be correlated with the time-specific deviation from quality Ajm, because it is plausible to assume that Medicare HMOs' pricing decisions in a county are based on factors specific to that county, such as marginal cost and reimbursement. Marginal cost is derived from exogenous supply-side factors such as the level of competition among providers and the average health status of the elderly in the county while reimbursement is set according to a formula. A more explicit model of pricing will be laid out in Section IX. I also instrument for premiums with the county reimbursement rate since that is an exogenous determinant of price. To instrument for log of the nest share, Berry recommends using functions of the characteristics of other firms in the same market. These variables will capture the part of the firm's nest share that is determined by other firms' behavior but not the part that is set by the firm's own characteristics. I use the mean of the drug expenditure covered by each competing plan, weighted by each plan's market share. Finally, to control for yearly shifts in demand for HMOs and their associated medical care, I add year effects, where the omitted year is 1999. 22 VII. Demand parameter estimates Table 5 reports the results of estimating the demand equation for different specifications of plan benefits. As mentioned above, no one has ever done a study of plan choice with this level of detail in the drug benefit data. It is therefore not obvious how to specify plan benefits. While theory can make a prediction about the sign of the effect of plan benefits (that co-payments have a negative effect on demand, for example), there is no theory on what functional form to use for benefits such as co-payments, coverage amounts and non-formulary coverage. I will therefore employ three specifications. The first one I use is a dummy for prescription drug benefits alone. The second is a measure of how much prescription drug expenditure is covered by the plan and the third has features of the plan, such as co- payments and coverage limits, entering directly into the regression. As canr be seen from Table 5, which specification I use does not significantly affect the coefficients on premium or on the year dummies. The coefficient on premium ranges from -. 007 to -0.005 (with a standard error of about 0.001) across specifications. The year effects are significantly positive and rise over time, suggesting that demand for Medicare HMOs rose steadily during this period. The coefficient on the log of the nest share varies slightly more across specifications and is always significantly positive, suggesting that the nested logit fits the data better then the ordinary logit. The OLS and IV estimates tend to be quite similar. The coefficients in these regressions report the percent change in the ratio of the plan market share to the outside choice's market share resulting from a one unit change in 23 the right-hand-side variable. Since this measure is not very easily interpretable, I will x translate them into elasticities: jmt imi where Xjmtis the variable of interest. In the jmt ordinary logit model, the elasticity is given by on X jmt. In the nested -[1-&jlgmt -(1- 6)Sjmt]X jmt logit (l - Sjmt )X jmtwhere model, the elasticity is the coefficient is given by where a is the coefficient on the log of the nest share. In both cases, the elasticity is only defined if X jmt is greater than 0. Since about half of the observations have a premium of zero, I calculate the semi-elasticity jmlx aXim I for S jmt the premium. I also calculate the semi-elasticity when calculating the effect of dummy variables. Table 6 shows the median elasticities and semi-elasticities. The premium elasticity estimate of -0.18 to -0.31 means that doubling the premium is predicted to cause the HMO's market share to drop by 18-31% and the semi-elasticity estimate of 0.005 to -0.008 that adding $10 to the premium causes the market share to drop by 5-8%. These estimates are similar to Town and Liu's (2003) estimates of the median elasticity at -0.29 and of the semi-elasticity at -0.009 and are higher in magnitude than Dowd et al.'s estimate of -0.13. Columns (1)-(4) of table 5 report the results from using only a dummy variable for whether or not the plan offers prescription drug benefits. As expected, the effect of a prescription drug benefit is significant and positive and the coefficient is estimated to be 0.108 in the IV nested logit specification. 24 Town and Liu estimate a significantly higher coefficient at 0.35 for the years 1997-2000. The difference may be due to several factors. First, plan generosity was slightly higher on average in 1997-98 than in the period of my study as the Balanced Budget Act did not take effect until 1999. Second, Town and Liu use the plan's own premium in other counties as instruments. For reasons I discussed above, own premiums may not be exogenous and using them as instruments will therefore not entirely remove the upward bias of the coefficient on the indicator for drug benefits. As the elasticity estimate in Table 6 shows, this coefficient is equivalent to the addition of a prescription drug benefit raising the HMO's market share by 10.8%. The second specification reported is a measure of drug expenditure for an average prescription drug user covered by the plan. To calculate average drug utilization, I use information from two sources. Moeller et al. (2004), using the Medical Expenditure Panel Survey, find that the average elderly person filled 28.4 prescriptions annually in 2001 while Thomas et al. (2001) report that 34.3% of prescriptions written for elderly prescription drug users were generic. I calculate the average price of a prescription as being a weighted average of average generic and brand-name prices, weighting the generic price with .343 and the brand-name price with .657. Table 4 gives the weighted average price for each year. Using these average prices, I calculate the cost of 2.4 prescriptions per month. I then apply the rules of the plan to the total annual cost of the prescriptions and split this amount into out-of-pocket expenditure and expenditure covered by the plan. For example, in 2001, the average prescription drug user is expected to spend 28.6 times $54.65 or $1,563.05 annually. Tufts HMO's Medicare HMO plan in Middlesex 25 County, Massachusetts, offered drug coverage in 2001 with an annual limit of $600. The expenditure covered by this plan is therefore calculated to be $600 (since an average drug user would use it all up) and the out-of-pocket expenditure for this plan is calculated to be $1,563.05-$600=$963.05. Another example is given by California Physicians' Service in San Bernardino County, California, in 2001, whose plan offers drug coverage with an annual limit of $2000 and co-payments of $7 for generic drugs and $25 for brand-name drugs. In this case, the out-of-pocket expenditure is calculated to be $538.42, or 28.6 times a weighted average of the co-payments, where the weight for generic is .343 and that for brand-name is .657. The expenditure covered by the plan is calculated to be $1,563.05-$538.42, or $1,024.63 since, in this plan, the average drug user does not use up all the coverage. Table 2a reports summary statistics on out-of-pocket and covered expenditure. Average out-of-pocket expenditure rises from about $553 in 1999 to $1,079 in 2002, a rise of 95% over three years. Average expenditure covered by the plan drops from $781 in 1999 to $567 in 2002, a drop of 27%. Columns (5)-(8) of table 5 report the results for covered expenditure. As expected, the effect on market share of increasing covered expenditure is significant and positive. As Table 6 shows, when translated into an elasticity, the coefficient of .002 implies that doubling the amount of covered expenditure is predicted to raise the HMO's market share by 17.0%. In the third specification, I allow the co-payments and coverage amounts to enter directly into the regression. For plans that have unlimited coverage for brand-name drugs, I set their coverage at the cost of 20 brand-name prescriptions a month. This puts the 26 coverage amount above the highest amount given in the data. I also deflate the coverage amount using the Consumer Price Index for prescription drugs to 1999 levels. Since there is a large amount of information in the Medicare Compare data, I had to simplify it. As described above, I have already reduced the number of co-payment tiers to two. I also found, through trial-and-error, that generic co-payments and coverage do nriotseem to matter to plan choice at all so I only include brand-name co-payments and coverage amounts if brand-name drugs are covered. Because the distribution of coverage amounts is skewed, I allow it to enter in as a quadratic. Columns (9)-(12) of Table 5 report the results of regressions using the brandname co-payment, the brand-name coverage amount and coverage amount squared, and a dummy for non-formulary coverage. The parameters on brand-name co-payment and non-formulary coverage have the expected signs but only the parameter on nonformulary coverage is significant. The parameter on coverage amount is significantly positive and that on coverage amount squared is significantly negative. Columns (9)-(12) of Table 6 convert these coefficients into elasticities and semielasticities. Doubling the coverage amount is predicted to increase the market share by 14.7% and adding non-formulary coverage is predicted to increase the market share by 7.1%. Doubling the brand-name co-payment lowers the market share by 0.4%. VIII. Welfare estimates The utility parameter estimates allow the estimation of welfare derived from having different levels of prescription drug benefits. Welfare measures translate changes in utility resulting from changes in benefits into monetary terms. These valuations 27 provide the benefit side for a cost-benefit analysis of adding a prescription drug benefit of different levels of generosity. Adding or changing the level of a drug benefit represents a change in the quality of the plan. Small and Rosen (1981) give two ways of measuring welfare from such a quality change in discrete-choice models. The first is to integrate over the change in the share function resulting from a benefit to find compensated variation. Compensated variation is the income change it would be necessary to give or take away to compensate for the change. The second way is to measure the price change necessary to keep the beneficiary at the same level of utility after a benefit change; this measure is usually referred to as the I will report both measures and they turn out to be very similar. "willingness-to-pay". The compensating variation for a change in benefits is given by: - fr Sjmt (Ujmt)dU (4) Intuitively, this result is analogous to the result for continuous choice that compensating variation is found by integrating over the compensated demand function. Small and Rosen give the details of derivation for this result for the discrete-choice case. In the case of the nested logit model, the compensating variation of a quality change is given by: 1 .. , ... rUj (5) = IIn I A -Ag Eexp( Uk -) kEg I- I-C 28 This formula is derived by McFadden (1984). It is evaluated from Uto Uwhere U is the utility of plan j before a change in plan j's benefits and U'I is the utility after the change. g is the group or nest (HMOs offering drug benefits, HMOs not offering drug benefits or traditional Medicare). The utility of traditional Medicare is normalized to zero. This result holds for more than one quality or price change made simultaneously; U J is evaluated at the starting point before the changes and U'J is evaluated with all the changes made. To find the predicted welfare effect of a benefit change, such as adding a drug benefit or raising the brand-name coverage amount, I calculate (5) for a hypothesized market containing one HMO that offers drug benefits and traditional Medicare. The HMO has the average characteristics (premium and unobserved quality) of all HMOs offering drugs in the data. It is important to note that equation (5) gives the average compensating variation across all beneficiaries in the county. Benefit changes in HMOs will only affect a small number of beneficiaries however: those beneficiaries in the plan and those that switch into the plan because of the benefit change. (The benefit changes I consider are all improvements so the change in enrollment will always be positive.) The average welfare impact across these beneficiaries will be much larger. To calculate this welfare impact, I find the total welfare change in the county using equation (5) and also calculate the predicted share for the HMO before and after the change. When there is only one HMO in the county, the share is given by: 29 exp(Uj) (6) j= 1+ exp(Uj) I then divide the total welfare change by the predicted share after the change to find the average impact on those actually affected by the change. Table 7 provides estimates of welfare changes from adding a drug benefit and a number of hypothetical benefit improvements. The average compensating variation across all beneficiaries in the market from adding a prescription drug benefit is calculated to be $1.95 but, when divided by the market share, the compensating variation per enrollee is found to be $16.09. In other words, enrollees would have to have $16.09 taken away from them to compensate for adding the benefits. The compensating variation of adding brand-name coverage, at $25.26, is higher than that of a prescription drug benefit. The hypothetical coverage added has the average characteristics of brand-name coverage in the data: a premium of $18, a brand-name co- payment of $17 and a monthly brand-name coverage limit of $72. Raising brand-name coverage by $100 from a base of $72 is estimated to have a welfare effect of $25.49 and therefore has as much effect as adding the drug benefit. Adding non-formulary coverage brings $8.60 per month in welfare. Doubling the expenditure covered by the plan (from a base of $62, the mean value in the data) is estimated to increase welfare by $19.36. Lowering the brand-name co-payment by $10 from $17 has an insignificant effect. The willingness-to-pay measure gives an alternative measure of value for the benefits. This measure gives the change in premium necessary to bring the beneficiary 30 down to the previous level of utility before the benefit change. To see this, assume that before the change, utility is given by: Uo =+ap+0 + 0 +o +o If we assume a benefit change along with a compensatory price change, utility after the change is given by: U, = (p0 + Ap)+,8(X o +AX) + o + £o Setting U0 equal to Ul gives: Ap= -fAX -- (7) a The change in p equals a8 if X changes by one unit. Table 8 reports estimates for willingness-to-pay for drug benefits based on the coefficient estimates in Table 5. According to the IV nested logit parameter estimates, on average, beneficiaries are willing to pay $18.00 per month for a prescription drug of average value. They are willing to pay $28.60 for an additional $100 of covered expenditure, $32.96 to raise monthly brand-name coverage by $100, $8.86 per month to have non-formulary coverage and effectively zero to lower the brand-name co-payment. Because brand-name coverage enters the regression as a quadratic, the willingness-to-pay for this variable is given by ,am + Ja2 X amt and is evaluated at the median monthly a coverage amount of $27.50. These estimates are all qualitatively similar to the estimates of compensated variation. 31 IX. The cost of supplying prescription drug benefits Using the parameters of the demand regression, it is possible to estimate marginal cost for each HMO-county. To see this, consider equation (4), which gives the firm's profit equation for a particular county: rj = (pj +R)Msj ()-mcjMsj(mt) (10) where R is the county reimbursement rate, M is the number of Medicare eligibles in the county and j5 is the vector of premiums in the county. If we assume a constant marginal cost, the firm's first-order condition for profit maximization is: Sj pj pj = McJ =mcj asi /' pj R (9) In the nested logit model: Si1 as / pj I- a - (10) a(l- jig- ( - )Sj) so we can invert equation (9) to give an expression for marginal cost in terms of the price, the share, the reimbursement and the demand parameters: mcj = pj +R+ (-, 1-ff (11) -(-)j) Table 9 reports the summary statistics of the results of this calculation for each HMOcounty in the data. Estimated average monthly marginal cost rises from $360 in 1999 to $457 in 2002 and the HMOs' estimated profit margin drops from 31% in 1999 to 27% in 2002. 32 In order to estimate how much it costs to supply prescription drug benefits, I assume marginal cost is a function of benefits provided, county supply-side characteristics, year effects and unobserved plan quality: MCjm,= (Rx benefits) , + (County characteristics) y+ (Year effects) 6+ jmt (12) Regressing marginal cost on these variables will therefore give an estimate of the cost of providing prescription drug benefits. Correlation between the benefits and plan quality may be an issue however. While I argued in Section V. that the benefits were uncorrelated with the time-specific deviation J4jmt, it is possible they are correlated with jm t. While this problem could be fixed with plan-county fixed effects as in the demand regressions, I am unable to use them in this regression because identification of the effect of benefits on marginal cost would only come from plans that change their benefits over time and the decision to change benefits may be endogenous to the level and cost of benefits. To deal with the endogeneity problem therefore, I instrument for the level of benefits with the average level of benefits offered by other plans in the county, the average premium offered by other plans in the county and the Herfindahl index for Medicare HMOs in the county. These variables all proxy for the level of competitiveness in the county. Gurol and Ellis (2004) have demonstrated that competitiveness in the market is a determinant of whether or not HMOs offer prescription drug benefits, and it is therefore probably also a determinant of the level of benefits. Table 10 reports the results of regressing marginal cost on prescription drug benefits, county characteristics and year dummies for both OLS and IV and for all three of the specifications of drug benefits used in the demand regressions. Since marginal cost 33 is estimated using parameters from the demand regressions, the regressions are weighted with the inverse of the standard deviation of that estimate. A probit was run for the first stage of the binary endogenous variables (the dummy for drug benefits, the dummy for non-formulary coverage and the dummy for generic-only coverage). For county characteristics affecting marginal cost, I used the number of short-term acute care hospitals, the number of beds in such hospitals, the number of doctors, the number of medical and dental residents, the number of doctors engaged in teaching and the number of doctors engaged in research as proxies for provider density and quality. These variables are all divided by the number of Medicare eligibles in the county. As Table 10 shows, the coefficients on these variables and on the year dummies differ slightly between OLS and IV but do not differ significantly across drug benefit specifications, suggesting that they are robust. Columns (1) and (2) show the results when the drug benefits are specified with a single dummy variable. The average cost of a drug benefit is estimated to be $21 with OLS and $31 with IV. The increase in the cost of a drug benefit from OLS to IV suggests that, conditional on the medical provider variables and year, the presence of prescription drug benefits is negatively correlated with unobserved plan quality. This relationship may be due to plans deciding to substitute prescription drug benefits for other plan benefits, either to keep total costs down or to encourage favorable selection. Columns (3) and (4) show the effect on marginal cost of raising the amount of expenditure incurred by an average prescription drug user covered by the plan. Again, the effect rises from OLS to IV and the effect is measured to be $0.28 with OLS and $0.43 with IV. 34 Columns (5) and (6) report the results for the specification using benefit characteristics. Most coefficients have the expected sign and are significant. The effect of raising the monthly brand-name coverage amount by $100 is estimated to be $32.33$2.58, or $29.75, while the effect on marginal cost of raising the brand-name co-payment by $1 is estimated to be $1.31. The average cost of providing non-formulary coverage is estimated to be $65 per month while the estimated cost of providing a generic-only benefit is insignificantly different from zero. These estimates of the effect of marginal cost of offering prescription drug benefits allow us to make inferences about the level of prescription drug usage by enrollees in HMOs and the estimates show the enrollees make extensive usage of them. As discussed previously, the average elderly person fills about 2.4 prescriptions per month, of which 34% are generic and 66% are brand-name. HMOs offering drug coverage cover, on average, about $60 of this average person's spending. If HMO enrollees were average prescription drug users, the effect of offering drug coverage on the plan's marginal cost would be about $60. Instead, as column (2) shows, the effect is $31; HMOs with drug coverage are therefore covering $31 of drug spending per enrollee per month. Similarly, in column (4), if HMO enrollees were average drug users, the coefficient on covered expenditure would be 1. Instead, it is about .44, implying that HMO enrollees with drug coverage spend 44% much as the average prescription drug user. The results in column (6) have similar implications. The cost of raising monthly brand-name coverage by $100 costs about $30, implying that, in general, enrollees do not 35 take full advantage of the drug coverage. Non-formulary drug coverage, however, is estimated to cost $65 on average, suggesting that enrollees in these plans are taking advantage of the open formulary. X. Conclusion In summary, then, beneficiaries are willing to pay on average $18 for a prescription drug benefit and the benefit costs $31 to provide. Beneficiaries are willing to pay $0.29 to increase the amount of expenditure of an average-level drug user by $1 and increasing that amount by $1 costs the plan $0.44. It is important to remember when comparing welfare and cost estimates that the welfare estimates give the average welfare across the entire market, while the cost estimates only apply to the enrollees who actually enroll in plans offering prescription drugs. It is not surprising therefore that the cost estimates are slightly higher than the welfare estimates. While we normally would not expect to see benefits being provided at a higher cost than they are worth to consumers in the market, beneficiaries who actually choose plans offering prescription drug benefits will value the benefits more than the average beneficiary. The welfare estimate, however, implies that the market the HMOs are drawing upon seems to consist of less-than-average prescription drug users. If the average beneficiary is only willing to pay $0.29 to raise the amount of expenditure of an average user by $1, then the average beneficiary in the market HMOs are drawing upon uses prescription drugs considerably less than average. 36 There are several factors that could give rise to this result. First, the Medicaideligible are excluded from the market definition and they are sicker than the average Medicare beneficiary. Second, Medicare HMOs are known for deliberately targeting healthier beneficiaries because they are paid with a flat reimbursement rate and therefore have an incentive to enroll the beneficiaries who are expected to be less costly (Neuman 1998). Third, the market may appear to value prescription drugs less because while we observe managed care without prescription drug benefits, we never observe prescription drug benefits without managed care. A higher demand for prescription drug benefits, however, is correlated with a lower demand for managed care, since people who are ill both take more drugs and have a lower tolerance for the constraints of managed care. As the demand for prescription drugs tends to be skewed, those beneficiaries in the tail of the distribution, who are very ill, may also have a very great distaste for managed care and would not choose to enroll in an HMO under almost any circumstances. The loss of the tail of the distribution may explain why the welfare estimate implies that the value of prescription drugs is so much lower than we would expect if the market represented a random cross-section of Medicare beneficiaries. The results presented here, however, are applicable to those Medicare beneficiaries who did not have drug coverage before. This population is interesting because they will be the ones to acquire prescription drug coverage when the Medicare Modernization Act (MMA) comes into effect at the beginning of 2006. These estimates provide a lower bound of the welfare effects of providing prescription drug coverage to Medicare beneficiaries. 37 References (1999). Medicare Managed Care Plans: Many Factors Contribute to Recent Withdrawals; Plan Interest Continues, United States General Accounting Office: 69. (2001). Medicare Chart Book, The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation. Abraham, J., A. Arora, et al. (2000). "Enter at Your Own Risk: HMO Participation and Enrollment in the Medicare Risk Market." Economic Inquiry 38(3): 385-401. Arellano, M. (1987). "Computing Robust Standard Errors for Within-groups Estimators." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 49(4): 431-434. Atherly, A., B. E. Dowd, et al. (2004). "The Effect of Benefits, Premiums, and Health Risk on Health Plan Choice in the Medicare Program." Health Services Research 39(4, Part I): 847-864. Berry, S. (1994). "Estimating Discrete-Choice Models of Product Differentiation." The RAND Journal of Economics 25(2): 242-262. Cardell, N. (1997). "Variance Components Structures for the Extreme Value and Logistic Distribution with Applications to Models of Heterogeneity." Econometric Theory 13: 185-213. Dowd, B. E., R. Feldman, et al. (2003). "The Effect of Health Plan Characteristics on Medicare+Choice Enrollment." Health Services Research 38(1, Part I): 113-135. Ellis, R. P. and I. Gurol (2002). Health Plan Entry and Exit in the Medicare Managed Care Market. Boston University working paper 28. Gurol, I. and R. P. Ellis (2004). Medicare Managed Care Choice of Benefits and Premiums: Competition and Selection Incentives Really Matter. Boston University working paper 27. Hausman, J. (1997). Valuation of New Goods under Perfect and Imperfect Competition. The Economics of New Goods, NBER Studies in Income and Wealth. T. F. Bresnahan. Chicago, University of Chicago Press. Hellinger, F. J. and H. S. Wong (2000). "Selection Bias in HMOs: A Review of the Evidence." Medical Care Research and Review 57(4): 405-439. McFadden, D. (1984). Econometric Analysis of Qualitative Response Models. Handbook of Econometrics. Z. Griliches and M. D. Intriligator, Elsevier Science Publishers BV. II: 1395-1457. 38 Moeller, J. F., G. E. Miller, et al. (2004). "Looking Inside The Nation's Medicine Cabinet: Trends in Outpatient Drug Spending By Medicare Beneficiaries, 1997 And 2001." Health Affairs 23(5): 217-225. Neuman, P., E. Maibach, et al. (1998). "Marketing HMOs To Medicare Beneficiaries." Health Affairs 17(4): 132-139. Nevo, A. (2001). "Measuring Market Power in the Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry." Econometrica 69(2): 307-342. Pai, C.-W. and D. G. Clement (1999). "Recent Determinants of New Entry of HMOs into a Medicare Risk Contract: A Diversification Strategy." Inquiry 36: 78-89. Pauly, M. V. and Y. Zeng (2003). Adverse Selection and the Challenges to Stand-Alone Prescription Drug Insurance. NBER WP 9919. Penrod, J. D., T. D. McBride, et al. (2001). "Geographic Variation in Determinants of Medicare Managed Care Enrollment." Health Services Research 36(4): 733-750. Small, K. A. and H. S. Rosen (1981). "Applied Welfare Economics with Discrete Choice Models." Econometrica 49(1): 105-130. Strunk, B. C. and P. B. Ginsburg (2004). "Tracking Health Care Costs: Trends Turn Downward In 2003." Health Affairs(Web Exclusive): W4-354-W4-362. Thomas, C. P., G. Ritter, et al. (2001). "Growth In Prescription Drug Spending Among Insured Elders." Health Affairs 20(3): 265-277. Town, R. and S. Liu (2003). "The welfare impact of Medicare HMOs." The RAND Journal of Economics 34(4): 719-736. 39 . *CE =E ILM o Ct' OC'4) -a0 0I I~- CD-CO - Co 0)) oOD (D U0 I- 6 0 0 0 I- 41) E U) 4.- co 04) 0 z 0 t-(ON-C' ) E O LO I cO .r (C (, lCU o 'B O II aQ CO LO t - 4) CL co 4) 0) E, 0.4 4) 0. z 4)0 '0 *o ) .- 0 CO (D - CO ,It It o CooCM oC )LO ) I' CC)r-w u' 0.1: E E C,) o) o C C) m U) C C00 Ez m 0o0o _D CD CD CD E o o 0S 0 X 0O C\! 7q CO 0 C) O0 r-.L~ c O, U) U- o o 0 C~lIt ,O~ O a E 0c)0) 0)0 It C CO ') - C) CO LO 0 a) 0)0a)0) o) - Ct 0 cJn .It 1-- C\jO O ,IO ([: 'I~ 0)jco O 00 ._ C0 C) C O C Oo O'O O x CM . CO 0 m E _Oq CO L0U) U) C C'l Cj C\j Cj CC0r- O ,t It LO LO - - -oo -)0)- (I) .O mB I) ._ 0 (U o (a - a ac (D O N-i- 'C oS oS0 C") o 'Ittr-Cco (D Itt ) cot t ~CV)0)M C6 C 'i O U 13 Iq CV) Ui CD o o co C", U C 0 Om ~-t co m t,IdC0co ) om N -co 0 o6 3 o oo CO 0) 0) cO 4- E E z t o '.(0 cs M r o L) ,t r- cm (O r 0 0) r- - -. H o 00 O 0)CD0o NC 0 O0 O O (U ) (U O) - N C C cm CO C - o C00 -0 00 O, ,-CD O CO0 CO 0It o C o0It O L)O - ',t g) oCLO coN CO ' -Coi OJ N- O ') co -( o U) O0 C C\ - - CD O _ N M) - _) ) 0C0 N0 _CN 0) ) 00 0 00 0) 00C00 -0)000 0O O O )0 00 0)000 OC C C -- CM N NC I- C" 0 0 I .1. C 0 0 0 0 o(U C.) 4O E 0 C.) 0 0 m e-, C. -r I.E co 0 E o0 (U) m (U 0) C.) (U O 620 Ic '1- c ._. (U E .5 w co UJI (A 4) ._ a- 0 (L) 0 0 O o I-(_ O . (U C U) ao.0 c 0 > 0C) .'~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~. c O. 0 I- 0 E Z O '4. 0(U .0 0C. aE Z 0 C. 0 W.. .0 E E Z z CO ,t CO ) w cO o o o LO LO cO O C 1 ) 0 ) Ocoo 'tcoO' C)O cO co ;; COLO I'l LO CO c - CO O CO 1G1G G- N 'ct (O COD N 69 6 G G 6 f 69 . 000 6 69 -: G~ G- GG 6e G ;; ;9 ;; E O E 61g6) E ,t > i, a) 0 0 0 0 0 0 0O 0OOt V.6 0 O00 0 CO U) 0) OO1 69. V: 6g- 6G~ G~ 6 6 6 6. 60 t0 ft 0 OOOO1:~61.61: 6g) 69 ) 9 - - E CO C CM a) o 0 o co - (O 0 LO 0 o (D O) CO (D O - )C CO '-NC e 6 Oi1C N) Z CO LO t CO CO L) t O r CO -CO ' t CO CO ,'* ' C C) C) 0o Cl) 0N 'T CO N CO C CO N t O C - CN . )O0 co N C C) C OD 6 69 * o 61) 0 ) 0 t 0 0) 0 C CM0N C N CM C 0 C C C C C C CM CM CO CM CM Cl N 69.: C O Co) N CMO- -co 0) O CO CD CD co ' r r 6LO o;6;.e 61 6 6 LO 69 0) 0 T 0 0) 0 'T 0 CO C C C 0 CJ N C'J C C N NC CMco N CM z 000- 0 0)Oi0 - 0 0) - "4 0) 000 0)000 0)0 000 0 CM0) 0' 0) 0 e) 0 00 00 o) 0 00 0) 00 0 0) 0) 0)000 aa. o4 oI o 0) 000 ) 00 00 0 0)0 0 0 0 00 03000 OMO O irC N - CNN 04 0 - C - (0 C.) 4.' CoM CN4 C 0,. a- a) a) 0) a) a) .0 a- .0 cco 'a G) i_ >a ') O 0 . *0 . 0 00 i- a) ca) .0 cm 0. a.c -0) a) Ia) 0 0. w U) c 0) O a) a) a) cm w ._- m 0) 0. CL a) 0) a) C) a) .r 00. (n aC) a) zO I- ac) 0ta) m a) 0) m 0 0) *0 ol L0 .o ca) 6a) cm 0. 0I- 0 a) c CD 0. a) a) E E .E E 0) a.E a.. a) a) L- 4) a- a) E so m .0 C 0 >a Q E m 0 0 g. 0 ._ ._ L- 0m ._ c O 3 E 0 0. cm a- a) 0. I- a) .10. X 0t m 0a) 00 a) 0 m Q ca) 0OL ;aa 0 4 0 2ca) 0f (D a) . x w Table 2b Coverage amount by category of plan Year % of total plans with prescription drug coverage Mean coverage amount Minimum coverage amount 8 2.8% $600 $250 $1,000 1 0.3% n/a 169 58.5% $942 $50 $3,600 87 30.1% $1,359 $300 $4,500 24 8.3% n/a $500 $500 Types of plans Maximum coverage amount Lim. Gen. covge, 1999 no BN covge Unlim. Gen. covge, no BN covge. Lim. Gen. and BN covge Unlim. Gen. covge, lim. BN covge Unlim. Gen. and BN covge Total 289 % offering BN covge. 96.9% Lim. Gen. covge, 2000 no BN covge 2 0.6% $500 12 3.8% n/a 149 46.6% $802 $50 $3,600 113 35.3% $1,199 $100 $4,000 44 13.8% n/a Unlim. Gen. covge, no BN covge. Lim. Gen. and BN covge Unlim. Gen. covge, lim. BN covge Unlim. Gen. and BN covge Total 320 % offering BN covge. 95.6% 43 Table 2b (con.) Coverage amount by category of plan Year Mean Minimum Maximum % of total plans with RX coverage coverage amount coverage amount coverage amount 6 2.7% $383 $200 $500 33 14.7% n/a 115 51.3% $997 $200 $3,000 61 27.2% $1,283 $250 $12,000 9 4.0% n/a $200 $1,000 Types of plans Lim. Gen. covge, 2001 no BN covge Unlim. Gen. covge, no BN covge. Lim. Gen. and BN covge Unlim. Gen. covge, lim. BN covge Unlim. Gen. and BN covge Total 224 % offering BN covge. 82.6% Lim. Gen. covge, 2002 no BN covge 16 7.3% $583 75 34.1% n/a 75 34.1% $939 $200 $4,000 49 22.3% $1,107 $250 $3,000 5 2.3% n/a Unlim. Gen. covge, no BN covge. Lim. Gen. and BN covge Unlim. Gen. covge, lim. BN covge Unlim. Gen. and BN covge Total 220 % offering BN covge. 58.6% 44 E C\I L :3Cl C ,E co *R ) Lo) o Lo Cl L ao eNr-9 ,-1!09CO '3~6 m 0 0 E 0 E 02 '. (0) U g m( E .0 0n 0C @'o OD CDO C) N CO ) ._ o t t U) .C )-O 61 6 6 0. 9 Io) 0a-a c) OD U) CM C (D O It C's Cl, Cl, 1 a)0 0 ) Co 0 (0 a) F) ' 0 CO Co U) Nr C, 0 U CO -COl .- a a) E 0 ., '~''' °C) M OO 6 O,C1 (D m)t(D E C 0 O C O ) ZOcoc U-) o 1- (D '§a0. . -. 4-- E n m.- 0" 0 0* 0E I a)(l I L L ,E w '~ E._ ~~ C\ O, C) C L) a C Nt O) oo 0 a a) ., 5 a) 3E roi o .0 ,E E a) a) 0) a- u-) r- CD C 6qL09 I-Cl? t0 C?,) a- Cl, CM C CM )OOiC-e (I9 6 6 649 a)t It0 00 0O' 0 0 O a) a) U) CO 0 U) t r U) L(DO LO ) 2 C? rlO=0. a)CL 4' E E qa) 0 0 0 0 0*-L- .- Q Q) a- 0)E . Q4 o) a)C . CD LO (D CY)LO cq 03 FQ C') c 0) c) 9 _ 8U o 0. o o Q 0) 0 _. 0 C co wo co co 4)a- oN1 oCml oN- > O)'-X .. O. o a) C)0)000 0)000 C son o0 Cl. 0a) C 0 Cl) Zt i t CO ao X ._C Q O ZC ~ It t s6s U) 69 6s a) C O a ,. o- . C 0) Cl , -,, raCo 0 0o C CO 10CLO ,t It U) LO a) .2 w a).~ Q-0 om r C\ C D0s) C (D U .- 0) o o.0 - 0) 04 0 .c oa) Q0D 0a 0 a- >) C CQ< 0 0) 0 (0 CMOD)GO a) 0 OO O)C)m C) 0m 0) 0 _ 0 0) 0 <~ C: o rC) C) r N CD U) O O O 0 OO C) 0 -o~ OOO OO_ O OOO6 SO0 O ECD /) COa) Z .2 CZ * '4- U 0) .0 00r, 0 o o C O1 O) 0)~cn] ',- O 00 COj a) O' O COCO I O C C) C) Coo v5C oo O 'r- O Ck · o. oo qc)c3 .. 4- .-E C < rco) C) nO C LO 0 C] I- z > (0) L I- V C L.- ._. qI) 0 0 E 4-W 0 C a)c I00 ~c C0 CZa r - 0l0 -j0 9oc0-0woc\Jc °. C) _C) 0° Joo'o v0 v3)o o cLO O0 O0s O0 T- O- ?- O. Ck O0 C v v v v E E CD) -i 0 0 ·a)0 ~) - 0_ -- OCQ xlEn)El._ (D CO _ O I'. oO- 0CO oo r,.FO oCD-,el C o oo C U) Ckl 00 0 o o - r cm Ckl CM CN No O w CO o o o. o,-. oCD. C o CO o , *9C>. C) C) m. C) mC . LO x 0 in0E a) a)- 0 O. .0 Q O) 0 0 0) 0) 0. 0) 'CO .C C LO0 0.I- 0) .,E--, _ ) 0) aC E 0) t a) 10 a) cn 0 m 0) 0- .-tC - a) 0) c'o, V 2ncE ( -j0 OC0 0 c CI 0 m C 4..d 0. a- a a- E c-) C '-- O) 0) E 0) 0) E. CDC eC w .0 0 0 zU) C 0 2L U) a _ 0)) _n U) > 0 a) (n 4. 0. .-0 0 oo o C) CD o-0 CM 00 CJ CD CDJ C) L- a.. L 0) 0) 0) m 0 0 U') 0) 4- .o ?U 0 0= 0 -1 V CL a) a -- 0 a 0 0MNcc 0)0 CLZ. 0) : z U 4D o _CCa) a) -nr._C0 o - CZ 0 _ c a) (U C 0 m LO 0 0 a ( L 00O ~ C L CM C\J0C\C~9l c00O66666 Ooo_ O oQ) cTs C0 0q C _ C- ) _U0 z 0 C/) E U :C 0 0 OE O C a) .- L.. Lo C) -J 0 0c. 0y-0C'J0C Q ) F:ZF U) C\00 O) . D O). 0 O Q O- r-- O c 0 '-- CO 0O -0 U') *0 a 0) o ,C) U) ) E x (1)s 0 a a) 0 0 N- O' - CJ (0 0)0 0 C, o.C0 oo COC °) CD O - - o_ '6_ 00s0 C !. CD LO Cm "t Cj C O) O C .) c _ O) - CO 0 _U-)° z c C/) E .0H 0 0 N- o- .'i 2 'U) E.' U O CO a) -i 0 . 0 >) LO 0 -J OJ R0 0 o.0o6O 0 o--L-)o. CD Co ooooo -o CJ CN00wC)- C9 Cc C OOLCU) ca 6 CM U) a) 0(D, x 0)) On D .0 0C E do)L-m) 0- - _ECz - >- inE 0 y Q "o >1 U U) cn m (U a) O oU) a) O·a (/O) cn a) a1) .U) n 0 > _ ) -o n ._ a) 0 X 0) 0O .t E o a) (_ 0) cn ¢D a) U I.- *0 *_- o -~ E 0) 0 -j Ca) O O I.. a) aL. U) ) Q) .E 1.--) E'- a; oU) -0 C (U (o -i_ i. 0 n E &- CO SN~ L. '- N (UD s NIIl CS I- ED N~ II a- a) 0 a a 0 (U 0. .U m >1 s_ x 0 O C v Q 0 ¢DcU ... J ._ >m a a) ¢ D a).4-. a) .0 N ¢D O (U O c: CZZ ._n a) .-- CZ 0ta) o a) ._0 "r O0 [OCZ E-i-- cm 0 _ ) CZ -oc-: 0j o 9oooZ . 0"ooCoo)o oo&C\ _0C co 4) 4) 4- z 0) 0. 0.-) 966666o666666669?666m( C)(. CC CM t C) C> ) o°. CO t a C) C LO U-) OOC O C) U-) O C) O LCD CoU) M O C) °.°) C) C) S0D O0) s0'It W w c) -nOC\I P_ - CA _j ° . C) O. O 0 C0 CDCO )C t 0 C) 0 C)lrtO- O °. O O O cCL a) -O .2 . Us C 0/).- W Q cn~ :)0)- I op 4) '4M 4) <D" rO(. ia CMjC Co :;"o C) CD C) UML t o M vO N CO) 0 C 0 0 0 900cj-5J0\ 4) E - a)E a) M CD © >~ C _D 4- 0 0) ° O6OOO O O O6O ~0C\J ;, 4- C a) _,.0..J o _o o'o o cV, 0 .000_ SC)0 o C) cvcccc U) CM C cv C) a) :- 4_ 'cn - E 0-- O 0 *e Q 0 ) a) a -U r- co^0 "t ia cm :;: , a O w M U.) oqooCo U-)sNM 69 6666666 -_ C oM co :;: P_ a r, R 0 0Cccoo 66 - C) N r COCm · Cc _c9 co 96OO00O c) C a). 02- u-E = - 3C oC.)_=a ZI- o 0)c)C co U) ) o CL 0 Ua w 11--' C E U) 0 CD a) "0 cn E U) oE O 0) 0C E o .._ ._ 1, , o U) .oo 44) C 4) E m 00C .0 0 4. . C.) E 0 E E 0 =3 Mi ob L.., E 0?.) 0) 0o v,.. co 4) H 00 E 0 4) 4) O 00C 04) a- E s- 0 ·~ oD o CDJ I- 4) o co 4) _ _ 4) 0() !_ _ - O s'_ O 0"O tn E C. > E .0 = < *0 E (D _ < W. 0 - E E 0 U) m-> ) J,C a S) v 4) E o a0)!) (1) 0 0) n0)S (1) 0 ch.. 4) o I_ IZ 4) "0 4)0 C nCo a) 0) C aC w E a) o c -)~0) >- 0 0) F U) cmo Ci2 a,o -4)U)o )C CZ a) CDEC cn co a: o E 00 v z4) .6- 0 Lo~C C Ci- co 0 o ocI 0~ ) = C0 c96 06C= o-) ioU);z- 66 C) 0 a) R- *- o) o 9oo -j .o oo6 06 0 a. CMj co- . x a) *0 a) CD 0) .- z ) a 0 U,'C.D CO C'J (O 0) CM C'J tOo- q 65 0 coN doo -0 - -o 0 , a) n- 00 a In. a ._ 0 -i 'r 6 -0 o'0 C 96 66C O - ) CM m( z I E 0 wI cn i 0 C.) a) 0q U __ *0-* .- .) (I! ) z 9o 0 -O . 0 (0 a, 0 C'j OC) O0 .q 00 O 9o 00 0 d70 CO O C) Cf C) E (D 0 'a,~ a0) .0 0. C 06 0 U) -J 0, o 9o 00 9 00 o.06 (ON- 0 C 3- 3w M. 0 Z ml ,0 C' .0 m 0) e C |' m v a 0 .. 0 E E - 0) -J 0 -0 o o 0) 0) cr 0,) CV) 0 a) 0 c'J 0 o. O C 00:Z z U, a) I- c) o CZ C Un C -i0 906~ o° 69o (DC'J 00 CM a) E o C) cn 0 0 '- >6 >, > ._- .o .. 0 U) Li C . 0a) C CE ) w ._ q_.0 o E :: X a) SO 0 >6 E 'm--m m .. . a). a4a) '0- ,m... m o . _- o 0a) . 0Q) w w ._ ._ (D a) > 'O .__ 0 H :- a) 0¢t-a)2Q ._ - 0a.) D > >, . _- I- a - > 0 6 ) O 0 C)> >0 am Q 'a) E 0 *._ 0 C a) I..- a n C a C) E CU a) Q a) E 0 OCZ a) a) > CZ >6 .0 0),a)am ma-a 00a) U) a) Un a) E 0D nn ! 0) U) .. a) E a) CU._ En E *0- am COn 0a) a) _ cn -00 .6m 4) 0) z oo0 q q 9o 9 oo C0 CO 0) 0, , 00 00 ) ) - 1- _- It-c\J t 00~ 0m co C. A! a4) C.) (U (D (. 0) 0, _ ? t t 6 C ~.dd~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ t Or- Ow~ 000 0 . vv- q q CO 76666 o~~~~~I CDC CC -J )C cm. 0) in) _ C.) C e) 04) 0 Co) CO -J 0 0 CM, O 06C 00 o-00 O~O0 O O0 0 - O vIt C - CM OO0Z3 cooC o~ 0 ~ ~~ 66 0 Oo 9v~ z P-Lo 0oO:00 0*, ~~ C 0 o'o -0) I= coZ 00 O) -i0 - - q 0 00 10:)C I- OCO .~ O O . 000 . .~C 0 v0000o 4) o0 0 Cu1 4) Cuw :50 4).( ._~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~u o ._ 0 0 W 0 0 >1 >. > 0 0 0 w w a) :5 ._ _ E 0) com - 0 C ._ .- E .0 C t._~ Q 0 ~~~~L 0) :n ._ cm -oP 0) a) o.2 n a) 0) E a) c ._ 0) 4) 0 C 'a- 0._ 0 0) (A E co :-I 0 0 :5C C 'IO6- x 4) >' E I- 0. 0 4) 0 CU aQ a- C 4) E s/)W C Cu C 00 o0. 0 m L. 4) c) 4) E w mF C *. C m E co C E °C a) 0 4) CZ C l a)E 4.I a C 0 0 cn 0- U) a co1 C iU a- C U . ) - 0 O )O .Em -- Q3.2 a E O N- CO v _ °6 -S .- ~ ON '-(0 cEI CLO CMj 6§ (D C\n (O o o. c6 C)O 0o 6, r_ C! cnO r C 6J v P00 CMj co 69 69 0 0- a) L. C :F C o6 L. C E a L- Lf °9go o o6 o 6o (A) '0. aL) -C CO -00:: -F .. CO Itc co C\J gU) CMO · a) aC E im ii 0 a C (0 O O. t OCO3 vi~ · O~ -cxM 'a. 4x 0 O L C &W t co '-- *0 L- C m( 00 a )- m gc E 00 CD = (L C 0 C o\ 0)0 (4 'cm C 6c8 io M. 4a O 00 7i CX CO s._ 0a2 C.) *-E C, ) 0 -E >0 . C ccm 6g -4 _ LO OO C) oCO too,o- cn ci ur c5Cm (0 a == co O C) a 6. 6cl .C0 0M 69C C'J o~ 69 C')C' vNco r-~ C 61 -CM C w NJ 6 =1 - 69 a) -o CZ (O0 ICD U) CM- CM- o~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~69 e469n6# GG 69 .. a) uC.- '0- L C E 0. a- C\!s a c6 6 c)R t ~0 00 ,cl '5 C 0 C ;C C) C\ CJ r- L0 CMI 6g 6) (D CLO -l *' G- CM ;- 6 603. _ 6 6g 1_CJ _ E Q a a, a. a) a m 0) 0) E 0 O a0 a1) E a) .0 0 C. SD E aa) a) - 0 Ct .°~~~~~~~0 .'-'I U) E .2 r a) 4 '-- 0 0a-) )D Ua) 0'*M E)E . a.) 'O I. IO (D oU) L) 0 0 0" ._ a) n E E a0 E U 0 X6 O.s f *0E- o 1 . Q0 0a),- o = 0 0) W. 0 _ -'~ x(L)E I-o D C 0) CJ C (O < 0.> 0 a) 2Ž WE 0 °E In w 00 a) 0 X 0 a) a) -j C a1) 0C.) (L) L. .0 0 .r 0 *o 4, L. 0 oC/) -J 0 a) 0. x w 'o6 o o .5, a) C -4 (D C CO C 'a a 00 . C) C) za) (x o " Co 00 4-, 0 Le) 00 .A § a1) * - C .0 . C 0 0 0 '6- z ) (0 (.0 a) 0. C C I o _ *T.' 4d C c)(O rs C In N.. :66 Cl 0 Coc o10 o,- za) a) a) co o C a am '-a t 0 a1) C 0 .6C.) C-) a) a) £- 0. 0 'I- E E a ) -j0 a- -j 0 c) z '- 0 v) C) a0 o CD CM 0 OO11 0Cv,I I o i C;CSotc 1r- ) I.- .- Ui a) a) C F co a) - D* -4 Co -O s 0 N 10 ,N -jC C~icv, z ) C 0rc _ .o( LOC -r (: a) C) cS I'4c6 C;) cn Ca c\ U E .-. oo 0c C: L6 aO CO 6 C)co U) 'a a) @a 4 ~ 0 I- C 0. 0 a) 0. U) Qa) mE o W- a) 6a) c . a) 0 a)a C) >1 E a- cn '0 L, N C (D - LO C *-, U -0 ECZ a) 0 CD w a) cO o C a E m C -6 C E > 9P 6 O 0a). .0 - E c C -6 C a 'o CD aECCD CZO Q -0 a) >E _ Co °- ' Zo o - 6#Ira C co C. a) 0) a) a)Ea) U ) Cn .0 U) IIC >j 0 , c 0 0 c 4)C C(12 C)C L._ (0 I- 0.02(D 0.C CM Co r- C,) *a- (0 cOCL I'Iq oR Lq LO 00 LO r- L. Cu (D OD rl r_ 69. 6A.69- 69 E E P-'t - t E E C O CO 0 I0 0 CO CD C0 C q(O cV) (D C s2 cMl ( (U CM C\J 4) I- 'E C 'CML OCF) U) r CO It It 0 CU 0m 000 0_-CC000 0 0CC0 a) I- ,I.) c Cf0 0 LO~O..C a q a Cy r0s c ICC) .Cia (sCJ) a).) tcI b- a) (o c- e0 -. N co ,t Lo ,'co r- Lo co co 0. x a) ,(<c t )00 O0 a) La) 0 O cn - r- CO 0 O V Cf - I c w -C C ocqLm O cr O -NCIO r a) O(OOc O 't O rs u C CV) LO u= (DN Ino CO *- °O t cor o Cr 6t LO (. o C\i9CJ E 0C 0 , ._ '~- 03 U)C 0(C) C 0 0 co 'D IN a) CO ^ 1L OON., cL 0I OCSN C) O O L FIL0 .o . O C 6 o 0o ^ ^ ) ^-- ^O ~--M ^1 -C I- CC ') 0 ON ) 00--(DV)Oc '0t C rN C U) 6 C 6 o C\ CJ N C) j .0 00 C; - 0 x c a) CO CU a) 0 C (~CO CO --:. 0--- LOC o 0 0C0 ._ E E Co -i a 0 1- CM c C\.O W -Wt Co t 0 D't U-)v CI I' Q !. co LO r'ls~s O t0 0 Cf) O O - C> -c t ' -C OI 't C) o ov I t ) Co O0 O U) O CM O U) C I .- - O - -- 0 o C q 1 t C r , o U) C E a) 0C(I) LO 0). 2 oYcVO . LL _""E.' CIO co E a) ) Cc E) E w . Csa - on oE00> I 01 4) ao OU '-a c"*;oAI nC 3 -a) c'- o co C L- C C E~ *5 c E~~~~~~~-t- C .~a ,x e" 0 ._ C a) 0 . a) 0) a_ a,n 0 0 .0 0 .2 C C._ a) o 0 0 0. .. a00. E a) 0 1- 20 a 0. C. 0a) a a1, x 0 -j 0 a) 'a 0- . E a) 0a CCD a) 2 o o~ 0 CJ 0mJ coO c0> o 0. . 0 .mEn a)a)> (D ) a)~> LC, o~~~~c x a) 0 a) -J 0 4) 0 >) a I, N1 oD O CD O CD cal 11 cml 11 cal 11 &. &. a, G) a) m >. >- 0 &. 0a, ,I- 0 0 . C OcE 0U 0 0 2 CO C >1 C ~in ° -oo o) a, a) 4) 0 ~0 1 00'a)a.._ 0 E o .@ a, 0. sa) a)m, z -I)--a@o2 a 20a) 0~~~~0 0 C.. 0cnC1) C( Ua)>C U) C 0 a) um 0 N Oci: U) Table 10 (con.) Marginal cost regressions Benefit characteristics OLS IV (5) (6) -70.734 -68.445 (0.923) (0.985) Log(Beds per 1000 Medicare eligibles) 40.166 38.949 Log(MDs per 1000 Medicare eligibles) (0.550) 3.715 (0.798) (0.595) 3.851 (0.834) Log(Hospitals per 1000 Medicare eligibles) Log(Residents per 1000 Medicare eligibles) Log(MDs teaching per 1000 Medicare eligibles) -0.872 -1.187 (0.342) (0.345) -5.649 -5.576 (0.465) (0.462) -2.042 (0.459) -1.810 (0.460) Year=2000 45.666 51.147 Year=2001 (2.496) 101.021 (2.648) 103.633 Year=2002 132.818 142.883 (2.842) 7.261 (3.992) 16.630 (2.422) 10.078 (2.037) (3.238) -4.341 (7.916) Log(MDs doing research per 1000 Medicare eligibles) Dummy for generic-only benefit Dummy for non-formulary coverage Monthly brand-name coverage amount (2.761) (2.816) 65.364 (11.456) 32.329 (4.206) Monthly brand-namecoverage amount squared -0.694 -2.577 Brand-name co-payment (0.141) -0.051 (0.081) (0.324) -1.313 Constant Observations R2 0.783 (0.292) 0.778 (0.110) (0.109) 5317 0.95 5317 Dependent variable: marginal cost derived from parameters in Column (12) of Table 5. Notes: Regressions weighted by inverse of standard deviation of marginal cost estimates. First stage of binary endogenous variables estimated with probit. Benefit variables are instrumented in IV regressions. Instruments include the average benefits of competing plans in county, the average premium charged by competing plans in county and the Herfindahl index for Medicare HMOs in county. 55 Chapter 2: Medicare HMOs, Prescription Drug Benefits, and Selection I. Introduction Much of the literature on Medicare HMOs has focused on the question of whether Medicare HMOs experience favorable selection and if so, how much (Atherly et al. 2004, Ellis and Garcia-Goii 2004, Greenwald et al. 2000, Mello et al. 2002, Mello et al. 2003; for a review of the pre-2000 literature, see Hellinger and Wong 2000). The consensus is that Medicare HMOs do enroll beneficiaries who are on average significantly healthier than the average Medicare beneficiary. A related question that has not been very well explored, however, is how Medicare HMOs' choices of their premiums and benefits affects selection differentially. This is an interesting question because, in the past, policies have had a strong impact on Medicare HMOs' behavior that was not predicted beforehand due to misunderstanding of the market in which they operated. A key example is the exit of HMOs from Medicare following the passage of the Balanced Budget Act of 1997. Starting in 1999, when the act took effect, a large number of HMOs left the program or reduced their service areas, and the exits continued for several years following. From 1999 to 2002, the number of HMOs in the program declined from 290 in 1999 to 143 in 2002, the number of counties served by the program declined from 808 to 540, and the number of enrollees declined from 6.1 million to 4.8 million. It is not very well understood why the HMOs exited in such large numbers. The primary reason HMO executives gave for exiting was that their reimbursement was not 56 high enough (Draper et al. 2002). The reimbursement level does not explain however why many HMOs chose to exit rather than raise their premiums and lower their benefits. Most HMOs that stayed in the program did raise their premiums and lower their benefits but a large number chose to exit instead. Lake and Brown (2002) examined the factors contributing to HMOs' exit decisions. They found that the most significant factors were reimbursement level, the profit status of the HMO (for-profit plans were more likely to leave) and whether the plan was national (national plans were more likely to leave). They do not explore why the HMOs that chose to exit did so instead of raising the cost sharing borne by enrollees. A possible explanation for the HMOs' decision to exit is that raising premiums and/or lowering benefits would have different effects on healthy and sick enrollees' decisions, causing adverse selection. The risk of adverse selection could cause the HMOs to exit since it might reduce their profit enough that offering a Medicare product would no longer be profitable, given the fixed costs. As evidence of this hypothesis, HMO executives of national plans cite adverse selection as a concern when discussing their decisions to exit (Draper et al. 2002, Hurley et al. 2003). On the face of it, it seems surprising that HMO executives should be concerned about adverse selection when Medicare HMOs in general enjoy favorable selection. Medicare HMOs do have features, however, that might make them attractive to sicker beneficiaries. First, many of them offer prescription drug benefits, which would be demanded more by beneficiaries with conditions requiring prescription drugs. Second, while patients in general prefer fee-for-service when they are sick, Medicare HMOs are sometimes the only supplementary plan available for beneficiaries who are neither 57 eligible for Medicaid nor have employer-sponsored retiree benefits. Murgolo (2002) finds that the income distribution of Medicare HMO enrollees is more weighted towards the lower middle, while the income distribution of fee-for-service (FFS) enrollees is more weighted towards the extremes. Among beneficiaries not eligible for Medicaid therefore, Medicare HMO enrollees will generally have lower incomes than FFS enrollees and therefore both might find the supplementary benefits of HMOs more attractive and might be in poorer health. Theory therefore makes an ambiguous prediction about what enrollees will leave Medicare HMOs first if the HMOs raise premiums or lower benefits. If the HMOs raise premiums, the healthy could leave first because they are richer and do not value extra benefits as much, or the sick could leave first because they have a higher disutility from being in managed care. Similarly, if the HMOs lower benefits, the healthy could leave first because the HMO has overall become less attractive or the sick could leave first because the value of the benefits is no longer higher than the disutility of being in managed care. In this paper, I will address the question of how changing premiums and benefits affects selection by looking at the effect of Medicare HMO premiums and benefits on the level of risk in the FFS sector of each county. If a change in premiums or benefits causes favorable selection in the HMO, we should observe an increase in the risk level of FFS beneficiaries but if it causes adverse selection in the HMO, we should observe a decrease in the risk level of FFS beneficiaries. 58 II. Previous work There have been two previous papers that addressed this question. Feldman et al. (2003) study the effect of HMOs changing their drug benefits on the average risk level of other HMOs in the market and find some evidence that higher benefits cause adverse selection. Their study is limited in two ways, however. First, they take the total enrollment in HMOs in a county as exogenous and only look at the change in relative risk levels among the HMOs. Their analysis therefore precludes the possibility that HMOs' benefits and premiums affects the overall level of selection in the HMO sector. Their risk measures are also made at the plan level, not the plan-county level, and they are forced to assume that average risk in a plan is equal across all counties in its service area. The second paper, by Atherly et al. (2004), studies the choice of Medicare HMOs at an individual level, using data from the Medicare Current Beneficiary Survey. With individual data, they are able to interact beneficiary characteristics with plan choice to find the effect of health status on plan choice and find some evidence that beneficiaries with chronic illnesses choose an HMO with prescription drug benefits, conditional on choosing an HMO. They only control for the presence of prescription drug benefits, however, not the level. With regard to the choice of sector, they find that beneficiaries choosing HMOs rate their health higher on average. Neither paper addresses the question of how the level of drug benefits and premiums offered by HMOs affects selection in the HMO sector relative to the FFS sector. 59 III. A model of plan choice by Medicare beneficiaries The following section outlines a model of selection bias showing why the direction of selection when Medicare HMOs raise their premiums or reduce their benefits cannot be predicted. Intuitively, this result comes from the unusual structure of Medicare beneficiaries' choices. In conventional models of selection in health insurance (Cutler and Reber 1998, Cutler and Zeckhauser 2000), it is assumed that choosers are choosing between two plans, one that is more generous for all benefits and one that is less generous. Medicare beneficiaries, however, are choosing between being in traditional Medicare (possibly combined with a Medigap supplementary plan) and enrolling in a Medicare HMO. Traditional Medicare has no constraints on utilization of services, which is attractive to beneficiaries with health problems, but has high-cost sharing and does not cover outpatient prescription drugs, which may drive away sicker beneficiaries. Medicare HMOs, as managed care plans, have lower cost-sharing and often cover prescription drugs but put constraints on utilization. The two choices therefore each have features that will tend to influence selection in opposite directions and it is ambiguous exactly how beneficiaries will respond when HMO premiums and benefits are changed. To put the argument more formally, assume a market similar to that presented in Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) and Cutler and Zeckhauser (2000) where there are two individuals, one high-risk and one low-risk. These individuals each derive utility from their Medicare choices which is a function of the benefits provided, the premium paid, and the level of strictness in management by the health plan: U = U(b, p) - (1) 60 where b = benefits, p = premium and is a scalar measuring the disutility derived from being in managed care. U(b, p) is a concave function that is increasing in b and decreasing in p. Figure graphs the utility function against the level of benefits, holding the premium and disutility for managed care constant. If we normalize the level of utility derived from being in traditional Medicare to zero, as benefits drop, the beneficiary will switch to traditional Medicare when benefits pass point A, since that is when her total utility from being in an HMO drops below zero. The high-risk and low-risk types can be assumed to have different relative valuations of the HMO's benefits and of being in managed care. Let us assume that highrisk people value the HMO's benefits at a higher level but also have a higher disutility of being in managed care. These assumptions alone do not predict which type will leave managed care first when managed care benefits drop. To see this, consider Figures 2 and 3. Figure 2 graphs the utility functions of the high-risk and the low-risk types against each other under the scenario where lowering the benefits causes favorable selection for the HMO. The utility function for the high-risk type is given by Us(b,p)-4s and that for the low-risk type is given by UH(b,p)-OH. In Figure 2, as b drops, the high-risk types switch first to FFS, at B, and the low-risk types follow when b drops below A. Figure 3 shows how the reverse can hold under the same assumptions. If the highrisk types' utility from drug benefits is higher relative to that of the low-risks, or their disutility from being in managed care is less, the low-risk types will drop out first as b drops, at A, and the high-risks follow when b drops below B, causing adverse selection in the HMOs. 61 This model illustrates how which case holds can be tested by looking at the change in the average risk levels of those enrolled in FFS Medicare. As benefits in HMOs drop, there will be a shift from HMOs to FFS, and whether the HMOs experience favorable or adverse selection will be shown by the effect on the risk level of those in FFS, holding everything else equal. In a simple model, where HMOs and FFS may be assumed to have the same average risk level initially, the direction of selection can be directly inferred by the sign of the change in average risk level in the FFS sector. If average risk in the FFS sector rises as a result of benefit changes in the HMO sector, the beneficiaries switching into FFS are sicker than average and that implies that the HMOs are experiencing favorable selection as a result of the change. On the other hand, if average risk in the FFS sector falls, the beneficiaries switching into FFS are healthier than average and the HMOs are therefore experiencing adverse selection as a result of the change. As mentioned above, however, HMOs in general experience favorable selection and the initial average risk level in HMOs will be lower than that in the FFS sector. The interpretation of a falling risk level in the FFS sector can therefore be ambiguous for the direction of selection in HMOs, since beneficiaries who are healthy enough to be lowering the average risk level in the FFS sector may still be high-risk in the HMO sector. The correct interpretation will therefore depend on the magnitude of the effect that changing benefits and premiums has on the average risk level in FFS. If the changes cause a drop in the risk level larger than the average difference between the managed care and FFS sectors, that implies that the HMOs are experiencing adverse selection. If, however, the changes cause either an increase in the risk level or a drop in the risk level 62 smaller than the average difference between the managed care and FFS sectors, that implies that the HMOs are experiencing favorable selection. IV. Data on Medicare HMOs and risk in the Medicare FFS sector The data for this study consist of Medicare HMO premiums and prescription drug benefits by plan-county and average demographic factors and market shares for the FFS sector by county for the year 1999-2002. There are also average risk scores for the FFS sector by county for the years 2000-2001. These data were all obtained from CMS. The data for the premiums and benefits of Medicare HMOs came from the Medicare Compare database, the online tool that allows Medicare beneficiaries to compare Medicare HMOs available in their county. The FFS risk score data come from the FFS expenditure data on CMS's website (http://www.cms.hhs.gov/healthplans/rates/default.asp). The prescription drug benefit data consists of co-payments for brand-name and generic drugs, and drug coverage limits and are measured in three ways. The first is a simple indicator for whether or not the plan offered prescription drug benefits. About one-third of HMOs do not offer prescription drug benefits at all. The second is the brandname coverage limit and the third is a measure of expenditure incurred by an average prescription drug user that would be covered by the plan. (For details of how this variable is calculated, see Chapter 1). To get a county-level measure of generosity in the HMO sector, the premiums and benefits are averaged across HMOs within in the county. As discussed in the introduction, the Balanced Budget Act caused both exit from the Medicare HMO program and a reduction in benefits and increase in premiums for the plans that stayed in. Table 1 reports summary statistics for each year, showing the 63 changes in the program. The average premium increased from about $13 to $38 and the average expenditure of an average prescription drug user covered by the plan decreased from $781 to $567. Risk in the FFS sector is measured in two ways. First, it is measured by the average demographic factor among FFS beneficiaries in the county. The demographic factor is an adjustment made by CMS to the Medicare HMO county base reimbursement rate for each Medicare HMO enrollee based on their observed demographic characteristics. The adjustment is the ratio of the expected cost for that demographic category to the expected cost of an average Medicare enrollee. The demographics used are gender, age, institutionalization status, Medicaid status and employment status and the factors range from .35 (for a 65- to 69-year-old female who is employed) to 2.6 (for an 85+-year-old male who is on Medicaid and not working). In other words, if a 65- to 69-year-old female who is employed enrolled in a Medicare HMO, the HMO received 35% of the county base reimbursement rate (previous to the Balanced Budget Act, when the formula was changed). Table 2 reports the demographic cost factors used by CMS from 1997 to 2005. As part of the base rate calculation process, CMS calculates the average demographic factor for all FFS enrollees in the county and reports it in the FFS sector expenditure data for the county. The demographic factors are for aged enrollees only and are reported separately for Part A and Part B. Risk is also measured using the average risk scores for FFS enrollees in the county. In 2000, CMS began partially risk-adjusting reimbursements to Medicare HMOs based on demographics and enrollees' inpatient diagnoses from the previous year (for 64 details, see Ingber 2000). The risk score is also reported as the ratio of the expected cost for the enrollee to the average cost of an enrollee. Again, as part of the rate calculation process, CMS reports average risk scores for the FFS sector for each county. Since risk adjustment did not start until 2000 and the risk scores are missing in the 2002 expenditure data for unknown reasons, the data are only available for 2000-2001. In 2000, the average county risk scores ranged from .74 to 1.42 and in 2001, from .73 to 1.27. V. Empirical specification The equation to be estimated is: Average FFS riskmt= a*avg premiumm, + ,3*avgdrug benefitsmt+ mm + tt + £mt (2) where m is the county and t is the year. The county effects will be captured with county fixed effects and the year effects will be captured with year dummy variables. Since county fixed effects and year dummies demean the variables both cross-sectionally and over time, (2) is equivalent to regressing the county-year specific change to average FFS risk on the county-year specific changes to the HMO premiums and drug benefits. The coefficients will therefore be estimates of the effect of variation in the HMO premiums and benefits on variation in the average FFS risk that is not explained by the county or the year. Since the dependent variable is a county-level mean, the variance of the error term is proportional to the population over which the mean is calculated. To correct for this heteroskedasticity, the regressions are weighted by the square root of the relevant population variable for the measure of risk being used: Part A enrollment for the Part A demographic factor, Part B enrollment for the Part B demographic factor, and the aged 65 and disabled population together for the risk score. To correct for any remaining heteroskedasticity or serial correlation, robust standard errors are calculated by the formula for fixed effects models given by Arellano (1987). If we were considering this problem with conventional HMOs, a concern might arise that HMO premiums and risk in the FFS sector are jointly determined because the premiums are determined by the risk level of the HMO beneficiaries. The identifying assumption will therefore be that the risk level of enrollees does not determine Medicare HMO premiums and benefits in the plan. This assumption is plausible because Medicare HMOs derive most of their revenue from the reimbursement they receive from the government, not from the premium. In 1999 for example, the average base reimbursement rate in counties that contained HMOs was $469.23, while the average premium charged by HMOs was $10.87 and two-thirds of Medicare HMOs did not charge a premium at all. The size of the premium relative to the reimbursement is relevant because it shows that the HMOs did not rely on the premium for very much of their revenue. They were therefore free to adjust it and the benefits to influence selection. There is empirical evidence that Medicare HMOs set their benefits and premiums to attract healthier beneficiaries. Cao and McGuire (2003) show that average FFS costs for inpatient and mental health services are higher when the HMO penetration rate is higher, suggesting that the HMOs are under-providing those services, while the reverse is true for primary care and general surgery. Gurol and Ellis (2004) show that there is little relation between payment rates and the premiums Medicare HMOs charge. They also show that payment rates have no effect on whether HMOs offer benefits that are attractive to healthy 66 enrollees (such as physicals) but payment rates combined with the level of competition strongly affect whether or not HMOs offer benefits that attract sicker enrollees (such as prescription drug benefits and foot care). It is therefore plausible to assume that benefits and premiums are exogenous to selection in the FFS sector since they are often deliberately set to influence selection in the HMO sector. While the HMOs' power to affect selection might suggest that we would only ever observe them experiencing favorable selection, it is still possible we would observe adverse selection because the decisions of the HMOs remaining in the program are not solely based on the potential effect on selection but on other factors as well, including a desire to serve the community of Medicare beneficiaries as well as a desire to maintain their reputation. As discussed above, some HMOs exited after the Balanced Budget Act passed, and Lake and Brown (2002) show that the HMOs were more likely to exit during this period if they were for-profit. These HMOs may have therefore exited to avoid adverse selection because they were primarily motivated by profit while the HMOs that remained may have undergone adverse selection rather than exit because of their other motivations. The only requirement for exogeneity is that their other motivations do not affect the risk level of who is enrolled in their plan. In order to interpret the results, I will also have to make assumptions about the direction of movement between FFS and HMOs that result from premium and benefit changes. Both Chapter and several other studies (Town and Liu 2003, Dowd et al. 2003, Atherly et al. 2004) have shown that HMO enrollees are sensitive to premiums and benefits and that HMO market shares respond negatively to premium increases and positively to benefit increases. I will assume therefore that, if HMOs raise their premiums 67 or decrease their benefits, these changes will cause movement from the HMO sector into the FFS sector and conversely, if HMOs lower their premiums or increase their benefits, these changes will cause movement from the FFS sector into the HMO sector. The changes that HMOs made during this period were largely of the first type, however, and I will focus on the effect of those. VI. Results Table 3 shows results for the regressions with Part A and Part B demographic factors as the dependent variable. As it shows, the coefficient on premium is positive and significant across all specifications of the drug benefits, implying that raising the premium in HMOs raises the average risk level in the FFS sector. Since I assume that an increase in premiums causes a movement from the HMO sector into the FFS sector, a rise in risk in the FFS sector implies that the beneficiaries switching into the FFS sector are less healthy than the average beneficiary already enrolled in FFS Medicare. Since HMO enrollees are, on average, healthier than FFS enrollees, the beneficiaries that are switching must be much sicker than the average HMO enrollee and the positive coefficient therefore indicates unambiguously that raising premiums increases the HMOs' favorable selection. The coefficient of .017 in column (1) implies that an increase of $10 in the average premium in a county raises the average Part A demographic factor in the FFS sector by .0017. (The demographic factors have been multiplied by 100 in the regressions so that an average beneficiary has a demographic factor of 100.) This change appears to be small but if the FFS share is large and the number of beneficiaries moving is relatively 68 small, a small change in average risk level can imply that the beneficiaries moving have much higher risk. It is impossible to know the risk level of beneficiaries moving without directly observing those beneficiaries that move as a result of the change. It is possible to make an estimate, however, using the regression coefficients and by making other assumptions about the size of the market shares of FFS and the HMOs, about the number of people moving in response to the change, and about the risk level in HMOs. To see this, consider the following result from equation (2): 'IRiskFFS,+l = RiskFFS,+i- RiskFFSt =/ * average premiumt+l (3) The change in risk that results from a change in premiums is equal to the coefficient multiplied by that change. The change in risk occurs because there has been movement from the HMC) sector to the FFS sector so we also know that the risk in FFS in period t+l is a weighted average of the risk in FFS in period t and the risk of the beneficiaries that moved into FFS: RiskFFSt+l= %FFS * RiskFFSt + %Movers* Riskmovers (FFS+4) %FFSt+i (4 Note that: %FFSt+ 1 = %FFSt + %Movers (5) Combining (3) with (4) and solving for Riskmovers, we find that: Riskmovers= (6) To solve this equation, we must make assumptions about %FFS, RiskFFSt, and 7%Movers.For %FFSt and RiskFFS, it seems natural to take the observed average of these variables in the data in the first year of the period observed. The average FFS 69 market share in 1999 in counties that have an HMO is 84.9%, the average Part A demographic factor is .972, the average Part B demographic factor is .991 and the average risk score in 2000 is .979. It is less clear how to make assumptions about the number of people who move since we do not directly observe the number of people who move because of the change, but only observe the net movement of people in and out of the FFS sector. Other studies, however, have made estimates of the effect on HMO market shares of changes in their premiums and benefits, which can be used here. Both Chapter 1 and Town and Liu (2003) estimate the effect of a $10 premium increase on that HMO's market share; Town and Liu estimate that the increase lowers the market share by 9% and Chapter 1 estimates that the increase lowers the market share by 5-8%. Table 5 shows the calculation of the risk level of people moving in response to a $10 premium increase in a market where the initial FFS market share is 84.9% and the initial FFS risk levels are the averages, as described above. To test the sensitivity of the calculation to assumptions about the number of people moving, the calculation was performed for different values of the effect of the change on the HMO market share in the neighborhood of Town and Liu's estimates and the estimates presented in Chapter 1. The results show that, for a 5 percent drop in the HMO's market share, the beneficiaries that move have an average risk level of 1.17, and for a 9 percent drop in the HMO's market share, the beneficiaries that move have an average risk level of 1.08. The results are very similar for the Part B demographic factor; for a 5 percent drop, the beneficiaries that move have an average risk level of 1.16 and for a 9 percent drop, the beneficiaries that move have an average risk level of 1.09. The beneficiaries that are 70 moving therefore belong to demographic categories that have a somewhat higher predicted level of spending than average. Table 4 reports the results for the regressions with the risk score as the dependent variable. As it shows, changes in HMO premiums have no significant effect on the average risk score in the FFS sector. In Table 5, we see that, for a 5 percent drop in the HNMO'smarket share, the risk level of the beneficiaries moving is calculated to be .922 and, for a 9 percent drop, it is calculated to be .947. The difference in results between the demographic factors and the risk score suggest that, while the people who leave HMOs when premiums rise belong to demographic categories with higher predicted spending (such as male, older, subsequently enrolling in Medicaid or being in a nursing home), in fact, these people are no sicker than the average FFS beneficiary. The results for the benefits have a similar interpretation. Columns (1) and (2) of Table 3 show that dropping drug benefits increases the average FFS risk level by .014. In Chapter 1, it was estimated that dropping a prescription drug benefit lowers an HMO's market share by 10.8% so Table 6 shows the average risk level of beneficiaries moving uLinder the same assumptions as Table 5 and for values of the decrease in the HMO market share in the neighborhood of 10.8%. The results show that dropping prescription drug benefits triggers the movement of beneficiaries belonging to demographic categories that are predicted to have very high spending; the average Part A demographic factor of these movers is 1.73 and the average Part B demographic factor is 1.69. As Table 2 shows, these averages are so high as to imply that the average beneficiary moving as a result of prescription drug benefits dropping must be either institutionalized or on Medicaid. The risk score results show, however, that the beneficiaries moving are not actually sicker 71 than the average FFS beneficiary since, as column (1) of Table 4 shows, dropping drug benefits has no significant effect on the average risk score in the FFS sector. The beneficiaries moving as a result of the change, while belonging to demographic categories predicted to have high spending, are therefore not actually sicker than average, as measured by their inpatient diagnoses of the previous year. (HMOs were required to report the inpatient diagnoses of their enrollees to CMS so it is not the case that enrollees moving into FFS had understated risk scores because of missing information.) Since FFS enrollees are on average sicker than HMO enrollees, however, the risk score in the HMO sector must have dropped as a result of losing these beneficiaries, so the change caused favorable selection for the HMOs. Columns (5) through (8) of Table 3 and columns (2) and (3) of Table 4 show similar results when controlling for the level of drug benefits. Reducing the average level of drug benefits in the HMO sector causes a significant rise in the FFS demographic factors. Specifically, reducing the monthly brand-name coverage amount by $100 raises the average Part A demographic factor by .0074 and the average Part B demographic factor by .0081. Again, these estimates seem small but Table 7 shows the risk level of the beneficiaries who move in response to reducing the monthly brand-name coverage amount. In Chapter 1, it was found that halving brand-name coverage lowered the market share of HMOs by 14.7% so the effect of the change is considered in the neighborhood of this value. Since the average brand-name coverage amount in 1999 is $140, the hypothesized change is a $70 drop in brand-name coverage. The results show that the beneficiaries moving were above average in risk level as measured by their demographic factor; beneficiaries moving had an average Part A demographic factor of 1.21 and an 72 average Part B demographic factor of 1.23. Changing the amount of brand-name coverage has no significant effect, however, on the average risk score in the FFS sector and the average risk score of beneficiaries changing sectors is .994. As in the case of dropping drug benefits entirely, therefore, we find that the people who are moving in response to the change fall into demographic categories predicted to have higher spending but are not sicker than average as measured by their inpatient diagnoses in the previous year. The results are similar for the level of benefits as measured by the amount of expenditure for an average prescription drug user covered by the plan. (For details on the construction of this variable, see Chapter 1.) This measure differs from the amount of brand-name coverage by including the generosity of the generic coverage and taking into account the co-payments and which categories of drugs (generic or brand-name) the coverage limit applies to. The results in Table 3 show that lowering the monthly covered expenditure by $1 raises both the Part A and Part B demographic factors by .0003. Translating these amounts into the implied risk level of the beneficiaries changing sectors, we find in Table 8 that a drop in the average monthly covered expenditure among HMOs of $27 causes beneficiaries with an average Part A demographic factor of 1.25 and an average Part B demographic factor of 1.29 to move to the FFS sector. This result assumes a 17.3% drop in the initial HMO market share of 15.1%, following Chapter 1 where it was shown that halving the monthly expenditure covered by the plan caused an HMO's share to drop by 17.3%. Again, the lowering of benefits has an insignificant effect on the risk score and the beneficiaries moving are predicted to have an average risk score of 1.01. 73 VII. Discussion The results presented show that raising premiums and lowering benefits increases HMOs' favorable selection. The beneficiaries predicted to move as a result of the changes have average to above-average risk among FFS enrollees, so must be considerably sicker than the average HMO enrollee. Greenwald et al. (2000) compare risk scores of the FFS and HMO sectors on a county-by-county basis and find that in the median county, the average risk score for HMO enrollees differs from the average risk score for FFS enrollees by 13.6%. If FFS enrollees have an average risk score of .98, this implies that HMO enrollees have an average risk score of .85 in the median county, so enrollees with a risk factor equal to the FFS average are significantly less healthy than the average HMO enrollee. In the context of the model presented in Section III, therefore, the case presented in Figure 2 holds. Either the sicker beneficiaries' valuation of the drug benefits is not that great compared to the healthy's valuation or the sick have a great disutility of managed care relative to the healthy. As discussed in the previous section, there is a noticeable difference in the effect of HMOs changing their premiums and benefits on the average demographic scores and the average risk scores in the FFS sector. Increasing premiums and reducing benefits significantly raised the average demographic factor in the FFS sector but had no significant effect on the average risk score. There are two ways to interpret this difference. First, it is possible that HMO enrollees are not just healthier unconditionally but that, conditional on demographics, they are healthier, and so the enrollees leaving 74 HMOs are among the healthier in their demographic category. Even though enrollees may belong tlo categories with above average predicted spending (that is, they are male, older, institutionalized, or enroll in Medicaid), they may still be relatively healthy for those categories and that is why they chose the HMO in the first place. The other possibility is that the risk score does not entirely capture the beneficiaries' predicted spending. The risk adjustment model used by CMS during this period reflected only inpatient diagnoses (see Ingber 2000). Since HMOs controlled inpatient utilization more than FFS Medicare, HMO enrollees may therefore have appeared healthier than they would have if they had been enrolled in the FFS sector. There is evidence that the HMOs were successful in lowering inpatient utilization, even after controlling for the favorable selection they had (Dhanani et al. 2004, Mello et al. 2002). The risk score would also have not reflected any chronic illnesses the beneficiary had and Atherly et al. (2004) showed that having a chronic illness made a beneficiary slightly more likely to enroll in an HMO offering a drug benefit. The beneficiaries moving out of HMOs as a result of benefit cuts may therefore have been sicker than they appear by the risk score. The risk score that is observed, however, is still a lower bound on their true level of sickness and the results still point towards HMOs experiencing increased favorable selection as a result of the changes. VIII. Conclusion This paper showed that the increases in premiums and cuts in prescription drug benefits undertaken by Medicare HMOs during the period immediately following the passage of the Balanced Budget Act caused significant rises in the average demographic 75 factors in the FFS sector but did not affect average risk scores in FFS Medicare. These results imply that the risk levels of the beneficiaries that moved as a result of the changes were at least as sick as the average beneficiary already enrolled in FFS and therefore sicker than the average HMO beneficiary. Increasing premiums and lowering drug benefits therefore increased favorable selection for the HMOs. As discussed in the introduction, a motivation for exploring this question was to see if raising premiums and lowering drug benefits caused adverse selection in the HMOs, as some of the HMO executive claimed. The results presented here show that, rather, these changes increased the HMOs' favorable selection. The results, however, are necessarily limited by the endogeneity of exit; we can only observe those HMOs that remained in the market and it is still possible that HMOs who, for idiosyncratic reasons, would have experienced adverse selection as a consequence of raising premiums and cutting benefits, chose to leave the market instead. 76 References Arellano, M. (1987). "Computing Robust Standard Errors for Within-groups Estimators." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 49(4): 431-434. Atherly, A., B. E. Dowd, et al. (2004). "The Effect of Benefits, Premiums, and Health Risk on Health Plan Choice in the Medicare Program." Health Services Research 39(4, Part I): 847-864. Cao, Z. and T. G. McGuire (2003). "Service-level selection by HMOs in Medicare." Journal of Health Economics 22: 915-931. Cutler, D. M. and S. J. Reber (1998). "Paying for Health Insurance: The Trade-off Between Competition and Adverse Selection." Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(2): 433-467. Cutler, D. M. and R. J. Zeckhauser (2000). The Anatomy of Health Insurance. Handbook of Health Economics. A. J. Culyer and J. P. Newhouse, Elsevier Science B. V. 1: 563-643. I)hanani, N., J. F. O'Leary, et al. (2004). "The Effect of HMOs on the Inpatient Utilization of Medicare Beneficiaries." Health Services Research 39(5): 16071627. I)owd, B. E., R. Feldman, et al. (2003). "The Effect of Health Plan Characteristics on Medicare+Choice Enrollment." Health Services Research 38(1, Part I): 113-135. D)raper, D., M. Gold, et al. (2002). The Role of National Firms in Medicare+Choice, The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation: 58. Ellis, R. P. and M. Garcia-Goni (2004). Selection in Medicare HMOs: Absence of Evidence from Aged versus Disabled Payment Rates: 19. Feldman, R., B. Dowd, et al. (2003). "Risk Selection and Benefits in the Medicare+Choice Program." Health Care Financing Review 25(1): 23-36. Greenwald, L. M., J. M. Levy, et al. (2000). "Favorable Selection in the Medicare+Choice Program: New Evidence." Health Care Financing Review 21(3): 127-134. Gurol, I. and R. P. Ellis (2004). Medicare Managed Care Choice of Benefits and Premiums: Competition and Selection Incentives Really Matter: 27. Hellinger, F. J. and H. S. Wong (2000). "Selection Bias in HMOs: A Review of the Evidence." Medical Care Research and Review 57(4): 405-439. Hurley, R. E., J. M. Grossman, et al. (2003). "Medicare Contracting Risk/Medicare Risk Contracting: A Life-Cycle View from Twelve Markets." Health Services 77 Research 38(1): 395-417. Ingber, M. J. (2000). "Implementation of Risk Adjustment for Medicare." Health Care Financing Review 21(3): 119-126. Lake, T. and R. Brown (2002). Medicare+Choice Withdrawals: Understanding Key Factors, The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation: 41. Mello, M. M., S. C. Stearns, et al. (2002). "Do Medicare HMOs still reduce health services use after controlling for selection bias?" Health Economics 11: 323-340. Mello, M. M., S. C. Stearns, et al. (2003). "Understanding Biased Selection in Medicare HMOs." Health Services Research 38(3): 961-992. Murgolo, M. S. (2002). "Comparison of Medicare Risk HMO and FFS Enrollees." Health Care Financing Review 24(1): 177-185. Rothschild, M. and J. Stiglitz (1976). "Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information." Quarterly Journal of Economics 90(4): 629-649. Town, R. and S. Liu (2003). "The welfare impact of Medicare HMOs." The RAND Journal of Economics 34(4): 719-736. 78 U 0 A Figure 1 79 Us(b,p)-os -] A B Figure 2 [ "UHs(b,p)-oH UH(b,p)-qOH w -$H S i ( r t BA Figure 3 80 b E 0000 O C C)O - - O E 6116 6 6) w-- ._ - -- (0 u CO ('tLO (0 LOLO 00oCM 'COUO) UD o Lo -- wJ co 1,y). - - - 6 6 6 6 6k6 I- U') C 0 0 C\l (.0 6021,69. 619- f 6 C 6 69 69f 9 69 69l Ot - It 0 Co ) C co -(D b--CO 0 - (O ci L6 oi r: 0) C\i rC- c6S oo 6 C\ C Ct) CMCM r'- ( L o 6 6 60 69 6 6 6. 4) 61) Sl) O 00 a z 00 CM CO LO( t CO Ir I' C0 CO LO ' Ct)O- D CO CO ,t t CO CO C 060 C CO CMl r,~ LO N- 60 600 CMj - LI 6 696-- O ) 0 0C0 0 'C) 0o C\J CM CM c0 C\j CM CM o00C\ C C '0t C)w C] Cj Cj C\j CO CM C\j CM O C~ CM of 0d O0O0 O0O 0 0 6 *ft 6 co r- CM r. U- C) CMjC: U' f.0 6 MC)OIt co OD T- V -N C C C C Ci C _ C1l C T 0 C CM ,-ONNN C) CM CM CMj CM co - CM 0- C 0)0 000 0) 000 )0)0 000 0)00 0 0) 0o) 000 M 0)0 o 0 0 0 00 0) 000 0)000 O C - o CO 0o LO w O CD Lo (o Q') c) 0000 0000 000 E 00 I 0) o O0 ft 0) ft (n NcO0N-rOJOLO 6969. 61; 69d 0 NC CM CM 0 ! 0) o 0) CM CD oDCM C14 04 0) - 0 co 'a)= c00 1-4-* - 0 a) e' 000 .Q 0 a) U0 0 a 0) O Q~ .) 0)0 t O0 O. C 0a) 0 a. 0. *0 a) 0) a.. E Q 0M. Cu 0 'O 'C 0 0. ._M 0 C M M 0 .4. .0d 0 C.) 0~ 0 0) M .C. E I0E I. 0a) E C Q O a) M a- M IF 0 a M 4- C CQ E .E a) 0 a 6 0 ._. a.. 'o o c.o E M '6. 0) M a) C D Cu a) 0 0C.) _00) 0. a) .Q 0 0 - ,.. C. 0 0 a) E M 9u 0. L.) 0. 0 I.. a) 0. 0) CL I- x 0 O) 0Q. . X w Table 2 Demographic Cost Factors for Aged 1997-2005 Part A B Sex Male Ag e Non-lnstitutionalized Medicaid Non-Medicaid Institutionalized Working 65-69 1.75 1.15 0.65 0.40 70-74 75-79 80-84 85+ 2.25 2.25 2.25 2.25 1.50 1.95 2.35 2.60 0.85 1.05 1.20 1.35 0.45 0.70 0.80 0.90 Female 65-69 1.45 0.80 0.55 0.35 70-74 75-79 80-84 85+ 1.80 2.10 2.10 2.10 1.05 1.45 1.70 2.10 0.70 0.85 1.05 1.20 0.45 0.55 0.70 0.80 65-69 1.60 1.10 0.80 0.45 70-74 1.80 1.35 0.95 0.65 75-79 80-84 85+ 1.95 1.95 1.95 1.55 1.70 1.70 1.10 1.15 1.15 0.80 0.90 1.00 1.50 1.65 1.65 1.65 1.05 1.15 1.25 1.25 0.70 0.85 0.95 0.95 0.40 0.55 0.70 0.75 1.65 1.25 1.00 0.85 Male Female 65-69 70-74 75-79 80-84 85+ Source: http://www.cms.hhs.gov/healthplans/rates/2005/demofac.asp 82 CD cO( . (O 0 O.o. ¢ Io o 00 C-' O a' C; o C 04 aC0 fU) CD orv9o) t (0 00 - a 00 9 66C O C co r- r- c C~- fIQ 6 o"- o- co 0~ E ., C/o 34 L) 00 t LOCo U) LO oocs o9r)o 0 0oo0c OD.0 o0o 0 U) o _o 1. 9o, a4-C C ._ .C C a -n .- cc) - 6 6C 6 ct) O0 (0l O0 v- rp- co a-, a 6 co 00 00 O0 o? Io 7 o LC r- CO 'O 0 0 ._ G) c C )r 0 a7"t Lo 06 6ooOro odd - Ct (U) C CM- C CD 0C _ C--cm -- 13. r ) CM CO - C E Co 0 L 0 CD-OdC . gcn o.(D W> 't, C v .4 NC) C-n ')O a M IC : .0 >4 C Co 0 o o o oi .o ,3-0 c5 cw c, t :cul o &I Ms W r_- ( (.0 r C: CD00 C . -). C0cm C 6 00 a) 00 a c) L. CM -n. o io r- O (D 6 !2 rC CZ -D -3 0O) _CZ _0 C U) CD co ,O (D o0 a) CCD0 ::3 C V. 4.. [L 0 C cn -Da D ,t o 0 - co doo - C) c0 - rr- 0 o o c6 0 C:0 .L 0cn E C. . . ) 0 ._C a a) en CD0 @ Im ¢3. L 0 00 Im .. .0 C 0 0 ns (D n (D 'O-_ a) o3 C) C 0) ~C 0 .) ) a.C O (D0 )C a) 'n -COU 0) 6. mQ o0) E _E ._ 0. a) Cu CD a) E : CD v Cu~~~ E 2) U 2) 0.. X 0 -E o o D 0) a na = > E > E > a < n = a (OaDOa L.. < n < o .2 II 11 > Cssuv ,6 o II a- C-) a n ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~(._ 00 0co X cDo 2) 6. 0.- W w 0 0 C =O 0 0) 0 E > > CZ O O ao- c 0 (0 'I- 00 0) .0 if co II 11 S- a) >- S- a) >. L- a >. O) CT Ocx ns a.- .~= 0 o o C: O O CZ U) (3 0 T_ cm O 00o 0 n~ o~~~~~oo o o oCo 9 ~o qn 0 C~ O~~9C;C 6 v 0 0 C; 0 c E 0 U) co 5 c °,' o -) &~ oC-C o c > U) s oo -OU) C) cm UCO a) 1 .'- LU. 0 C 0 000 '--0 0"Z U)2c cUC o ._ - I- 00 ~~Odod o-E Cia)C E E 0Cl 0W o ) 0 0 0. 0o 0 L. a 0 0 2 EE m c.o x 0 0 E o0nos ) E~E - U) 0 4 () C c ~ C c5 o L; U) .0 0 I._. U) - clc_ a)= 00 C) U '4- he- ) m -- -~ E 0. .0 'B LU < 04 oco ~.C 0 0e EE 0.4 C 0E o = > 4> o0U)0 ( ( 0C. 4 . 0. > Oc 0 -e0 D. a) 0 >0. OZUCZ Z 00 Table 5 Average risk of beneficiaries moving in response to a change in premium under different assumptions Rt %FFSt Part A demographic factor 0.9723 Part B demographic factor 0.9909 Risk score 0.9785 0.017 0.015 -0.005 $10 $10 $10 84.9% .Are..um ,&premium Number of people Percent drop in HMO market share 3% 4% switching sectors in percentage points (%Movers) 0.45% 0.60% 1.29 1.21 5% 0.76% 1.17 1.16 0.92 6% 7% 8% 9% 10% 0.91% 1.06% 1.21% 1.36% 1.51% 1.13 1.11 1.09 1.08 1.07 1.13 1.11 1.10 1.09 1.08 0.93 0.94 0.94 0.95 0.95 85 Risk level of movers 1.27 1.20 0.88 0.91 Table 6 Average risk of beneficiaries moving in response to dropping prescription drug benefits under different assumptions Part A Part B demographic factor demographic factor Risk score 0.9723 0.9909 0.9785 -1.422 -1.316 0.021 -1 -1 Rt %FFSt 84.9% fiRx ARx -1 Number of people Percent drop in switching sectors in HMO market share percentage points (%Movers) 8.0% 8.5% 9.0% 9.5% 10.0% 10.8% 11.0% 11.5% 12.0% 12.5% 13.0% 13.5% 14.0% 14.5% 15.0% 1.21% 1.28% 1.36% 1.43% 1.51% 1.63% 1.66% 1.74% 1.81% 1.89% 1.96% 2.04% 2.11% 2.19% 2.27% Risk level of movers 1.99 1.93 1.87 1.83 1.79 1.73 1.71 1.68 1.65 1.63 1.60 1.58 1.56 1.54 1.52 86 1.93 1.87 1.83 1.78 1.74 1.69 1.68 1.65 1.62 1.60 1.57 1.55 1.53 1.51 1.50 0.96 0.96 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 Table 7 Average risk of beneficiaries moving in response to lowering brand. name coverage under different assumptions Rt %FFSt Part A Part B demographic factor demographic factor Risk score 0.9723 0.9909 0.9785 -0.812 -0.883 -0.056 0.0002 -$70 84.9% [coverageamount Pcoverage amount squared 0.07 0.076 Acoverage amount -$70 -$70 Number of people switching Percent drop in HMO market share sectors in percentage points (%Movers) 12.0% 12.5% 13.0% 13.5% 14.0% 14.7% 15.0% 15.5% 16.0% 16.5% 17.0% 1.81% 1.89% 1.96% 2.04% 2.11% 2.22% 2.27% 2.34% 2.42% 2.49% 2.57% Risk level of movers 1.2607 1.2494 1.2390 1.2293 1.2204 1.2089 1.2042 1.1970 1.1901 1.1837 1.1777 87 1.3045 1.2922 1.2809 1.2704 1.2606 1.2481 1.2431 1.2352 1.2277 1.2208 1.2142 0.9973 0.9966 0.9959 0.9953 0.9947 0.9939 0.9936 0.9931 0.9927 0.9923 0.9919 Table 8 Average risk of beneficiaries moving in response to lowering monthly covered expenditure under different assumptions Part A Part B demographic factor demographic factor Risk score 0.9723 0.9909 0.9785 -0.031 -$27 -0.033 -0.003 -$27 -$27 Rt %FFSt 84.9% Pcoveredexpenditure Acovered expenditure Percent drop in Number of people switching sectors in percentage points HMO market share (%Movers) 15.0% 15.5% 16.0% 16.5% 17.0% 17.3% 18.0% 18.5% 19.0% 19.5% 20.0% 20.5% 2.27% 2.34% 2.42% 2.49% 2.57% 2.61% 2.72% 2.79% 2.87% 2.94% 3.02% 3.10% Risk level of movers 1.29 1.28 1.27 1.27 1.26 1.25 1.24 1.24 1.23 1.22 1.22 1.21 88 1.33 1.32 1.31 1.30 1.29 1.29 1.28 1.27 1.26 1.26 1.25 1.24 1.01 1.01 1.01 1.01 1.01 1.01 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Chapter 3: The Welfare Loss from Medicare+Choice I. Introduction The Balanced Budget Act of 1997 (BBA) made several changes to the Medicare fHMN4O program. It changed the formula for calculating the base reimbursement rate for the HMOs, increased the administrative requirements for plans participating in the program, and opened the program to other kinds of private health plans, including PPOs and private fee-for-service plans. The goal of these changes was to expand the role of private plans in the Medicare program and to provide more choice to Medicare beneficiaries. The act had the opposite effect, however. In the four years following the implementation of the act in 1999, the Medicare+Choice program (as the BBA renamed the Medicare HMO program) saw the number of HMOs in the program drop from 290 to 147, or by just under 50%. Many of the plans that remained in the program made changes that reduced their availability and desirability, such as reducing their service area, increasing their premiums and lowering their benefits. The average premium charged by Medicare HMOs rose from $12.68 to $37.62, nearly tripling, and the percent of plans offering brand-name prescription drug coverage dropped from 68% to 39% between 1999 and 2002. The effect of the withdrawals and reductions in service on availability and enrollment was large. The number of counties that had Medicare HMOs available dropped from 808 to 540 between 1999 and 2002, while total enrollment in the program, 89 which had been rising steadily throughout the 1990s, dropped from 6.1 million to 4.8 million. The withdrawals came as a surprise to legislators and policy analysts. Immediately after the act passed, before the withdrawals started, an analyst from the Congressional Budget Office reported that the CBO estimated that, as a result of the BBA, enrollment in Medicare HMOs in 2005 would be 15% higher than it would otherwise have been and would reach 34% of total Medicare enrollment (Christensen 1998). Instead, enrollment in the HMO program dropped from 17% of total Medicare enrollment in 1999 to 13% in 2002, and dropped to 11% by the end of 2004 (Kaiser Foundation 2004). Several studies have been done on the factors that contributed to the HMOs' decisions to withdraw or reduce their service area. A report by the General Accounting Office in 1999 found that HMOs were more likely to withdraw from a county if they had offered a plan in that county for a shorter time, had lower enrollment, faced larger competitors or had not established a provider network in the county (GAO 1999). Lake and Brown (2002) did a multivariate analysis of the first three years of withdrawals after the BBA and found plans were more likely to withdraw if they were national or for-profit plans, had lower enrollment, were in rural counties, had larger competition, or had been in the county longer, or the county had a lower overall Medicare HMO penetration rate. Ellis and Gurol (2002) do a more formal model of entry and exit in the commercial and Medicare HMO markets and find that HMOs are more likely to offer a Medicare plan in a county if the county has a larger Medicare population or already has a greater number of Medicare HMO plans. 90 There has been relatively little attempt at quantifying the effect of the losses on beneficiaries, however. Laschober et al. (1999) did a qualitative study of what happened to Medicare HMO beneficiaries who were involuntarily disenrolled from their HMO. They found that only two thirds of the beneficiaries enrolled in another Medicare HMO, either because they chose not to or were unable to because there were no other HMOs in their county. One third of involuntarily disenrolled beneficiaries had lower benefits, 39% had higher premiums and one in six lost prescription drug coverage as a result of the disenrollment. They found that the disabled, the oldest old, and the near poor were most adversely affected. In this paper, I take a more quantitative approach to understanding the effect of the withdrawals and service reductions on beneficiaries. Using the parameter estimates from the structural model of demand for HMOs and their prescription drug benefits presented in Hall (2005), I calculate the welfare losses associated with the withdrawals of the HMOs, their service area reductions, and the increases in premiums and reductions in benefits during the period 1999-2002. Hall (2005) estimated a utility function of Medicare HMOs and their prescription drug benefits for Medicare beneficiaries using a nested-logit model of demand, and found that raising premiums by $10 lowered HMO market share by 5-8% and doubling prescription drug benefits raised HMO market share by 17%. It also estimated the welfare effects of changing prescription drug benefits and found that raising annual brand-name coverage by $100 increased welfare by $25. As discussed below, estimating welfare using a logit or nested-logit model of demand is relatively straightforward. 91 I also calculate the change in costs resulting from the withdrawals. While the withdrawals decreased consumer welfare by removing choices, they also reduced spending on the Medicare program by the government. Spending would have been reduced by a lower enrollment in the Medicare HMO program because of the favorable selection Medicare HMOs experienced relative to traditional Medicare. Previous to the BBA, the base reimbursement rate for Medicare HMOs was 95% of the projected per capita spending by the traditional Medicare program in the county the HMO is servicing. Studies have shown, however, that HMO enrollees probably would cost somewhere between 80 and 90% of the reimbursement that is paid on their behalf, if they were enrolled in traditional Medicare. As a result, Medicare HMO beneficiaries usually cost less to treat in traditional Medicare than in an HMO, so the reduction in enrollment in the Medicare HMO program would have resulted in savings for the Medicare program as a whole. This cost savings can be calculated by multiplying the reduction in enrollment in each county by the county reimbursement rate. These estimates of welfare loss and cost saving will offer some evidence as to how great the damage caused by the plan withdrawals was. II. Background: The Medicare HMO Program and the Balanced Budget Act of 1997 While the Medicare managed care program has existed in one form or another since the beginning of Medicare in 1965, the risk-based program, where HMOs contract with Medicare for a flat reimbursement and bear all the risk themselves, did not start until 1982, with the passage of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act (TEFRA). The program grew during the 1980s to peak in enrollment in 1987 and then shrank between 92 1987 and 1991. After that, enrollment began climbing again as enrollment in managed care grew in the commercial sector. Between the end of 1994 and the end of 1998, enrollment in Medicare HMOs tripled from 2 million to 6 million and 74 percent of beneficiaries had access to at least one Medicare HMO by 1998 (Zarabozo 2000). Christensen (1998) discusses the motivation for reforming the Medicare HMO program and the parts of the BBA that relate to it. By 1997, the Medicare HMO program was widely viewed as needing reform for several reasons. First, researchers were calling attention to the favorable selection in HMOs and therefore to the question of whether HMOs were being paid more by the Medicare program than the TEFRA intended they should. While some favorable selection comes from healthy beneficiaries having a greater tolerance for managed care, the HMOs were also perceived as unfairly targeting healthy beneficiaries and excluding sicker beneficiaries through their marketing techniques (Neuman 1998). The reimbursement rates were also seen as having too much variation, both across counties and over time and the cross-sectional variation was blamed for the inequality in access to the program by beneficiaries. The change in the formula for the reimbursement rate was therefore designed to reduce this variation. As mentioned above, before the BBA passed, the base reimbursement rate was 95% of the projected per capita spending by the traditional Medicare program in the county. The BBA changed the formula so that the reimbursement was the largest of three numbers. The first was a fifty-fifty blend of the local and national per capita spending rate by traditional Medicare. The second was a minimum floor for the rate (set at $379.80 in 1999) and the third was a minimum 2% raise from the reimbursement rate for the county the year before. These changes raised the reimbursement rates for rural counties, 93 which had relatively low reimbursement and few HMOs before, and reduced the rates for urban counties, which were the counties that had the most HMOs offering plans. The BBA also required that the Center for Medicare and Medicaid Services begin risk-adjusting their payments to HMOs based on health status starting in 2000, to prevent HMOs from being paid more than the expected value of taking care of the beneficiary and also removed the government's payments for graduate medical education from the calculation of local fee-for-service spending. Both of these changes would have the effect of reducing the HMOs' revenue. The act made other changes to the program besides the formula for the reimbursement rate. It increased the administrative burden on the plans by requiring them to implement quality-improvement programs and to submit encounter data, so that the risk adjustment could be made. It also moved up the deadline for HMOs to submit contract proposals for the following calendar year from September to May, which the HMOs said was too early for them to predict costs and market conditions. As mentioned above, the act also expanded the type of plan allowed in the program to include PPOs and private fee-for-service plans and it also removed the requirement that plans in the program have no more than 50% of their enrollment from Medicare and Medicaid. As previously discussed, all these changes caused many HMOs to withdraw from the program, either entirely or partially. The withdrawals came in several waves over the next few years. The GAO report in 1999 found that 407,000 enrollees were involuntarily disenrolled from their Medicare HMO as a result of the withdrawals that year and, of these, 61,000 were unable to enroll in another HMO because there were no HMOs left in 94 their county. According to the GAO, the primary reasons for leaving cited by the plans were that the reimbursement rates did not keep up with medical inflation and that the administrative requirements were too burdensome. There were two legislative attempts during this period to encourage the HMOs to stay in the Medicare program. The BBA did not allow HMOs who had left a county to reenter it for five years; the Balanced Budget Refinement Act (BBRA) of 1999 lowered this to two years and added a new-entry bonus for underserved areas (Berenson 2001). The Benefits Improvement and Protection Act (BIPA) of 2000 raised the minimum floor rates, added a new, higher floor rate for urban counties and raised the minimum update rate for one year to 3%. Neither of these acts had any discernible effect on the exits of the HMOs from the program. Calculations from CMS's HMO enrollment data show that in 2000, 432,000 HMO enrollees (or 7% of the Medicare HMO population) were involuntarily disenrolled from their HMO. In 2001, 1.3 million enrollees (or 21%) were disenrolled and in 2002, 900,000 (or 17%) were. In 2000, 85,000 of the disenrolled beneficiaries had no other HMO in their county and in both 2001 and 2002, 100,000 enrollees had no other HMO available. Even larger numbers of enrollees were affected by premium increases and benefit reductions. In 2000, 2.4 million HMO enrollees had their premium rise and 2.6 million had their prescription drug benefits drop. In 2001, these numbers were 2.8 million and 1.9 million respectively and in 2002, 3.0 million and 1.2 million. The effects of the BBA on the Medicare HMO program were therefore felt widely and affected a large number of beneficiaries. 95 III. My approach to estimating welfare The challenge of estimating the welfare effect of the BBA is making assumptions about what would have happened in the Medicare HMO program if it had not passed. The Medicare HMO program was not in a steady state before 1997. While enrollment had been rising since the early 1990s, it would not necessarily have continued rising even if the act had not passed, since the managed care industry was in flux in the late 1990s. The report from the GAO on the Medicare HMO withdrawals (GAO 1999) notes that many HMOs were in financial trouble in 1999 and that there were several withdrawals from the federal employees benefits program at around the same time, so it is possible HMOs would have withdrawn from the program anyway. On the demand side, demand for Medicare HMOs would probably peak at some point and enrollment would level off but it is not clear when this would have happened without the BBA. We also do not know what would have happened to premiums and benefits without the BBA. Medicare HMO plans were rising in generosity up until the BBA (Gold et al. 2004). Again, however, their generosity would have probably leveled off at some point but we do not know when. The plans' generosity might have continued rising since their reimbursement was so closely tied to spending in the fee-for-service sector which would have continued rising, but, on the other hand, drug prices were also starting to rise faster during this period and this increase might have caused the plans to pull back on their generosity. Since it is so difficult to know what would have happened if the BBA had not passed, I will estimate welfare and costs under two different scenarios, one conservative 96 and one less so. Under the conservative scenario, I will merely calculate the welfare loss from the withdrawals each year. That is, for each year I will calculate the welfare gain if the plans that withdrew at the end of the previous year had stayed in just for that year. This approach probably underestimates the overall welfare loss since plans that stayed in the program for 1999 would probably have continued staying in for 2000 and after, but it minimizes the uncertainty in predicting counterfactual benefits, premiums and service areas. Under this scenario, plans that stayed in will have the same benefit and premiums that they offered in reality and plans that left will have benefits and premiums imputed to them. To understand the method by which they are imputed, it is necessary to know that the HMOs can offer multiple benefit packages within their service area. An HMO can offer a different benefit package in each county of its service area, the same benefit package in the whole service area, or group the counties into benefit packages. They can also offer more than one benefit package in a county but the enrollment data is only provided at a county level. As in Hall (2005), I assume all the enrollment is in the cheapest plan the HMO offers. This approach understates the welfare from the HMO program slightly. The imputation was done as follows. Plans that partially withdrew and only offered one benefit package will have the same benefits and premiums that were offered in the county that they stayed in, assigned to the county that they left. If the plan offered more than one benefit package, the county they left is grouped with the same counties that it was grouped with the previous year. If it is ambiguous which county it should be grouped with because the group it was in was split up into multiple packages, it is 97 grouped with a county it is geographically close to. If there is no county it is close to or there were no counties it was grouped with (because the plan withdrew all the other members of its group), it is assigned the average benefits and premiums of all the counties the plan stayed in. If a plan withdrew entirely, it is assigned the average benefits and premiums of the state it is in. An example of imputing when a plan partially withdraws is given by the HMO with contract number H 1406, which offered a Medicare HMO plan in the Chicago area in 2000 and 2001. Table 1 shows which benefit packages were offered in which counties by the plan and Figure shows a county-level map of the Chicago area. In 2000, the HMO offered three different benefit packages in eight counties: one package in Cook County, one in Kankakee County and one in the remaining six counties. In 2001, it also offered three different packages, but the grouping of the counties changed and it withdrew from three counties, including Kankakee County. Since Kankakee County was not grouped with any counties in 2000, the HMO's plan in this county is assigned the average premiums and benefits of the five counties it stayed in. Since Lake County, IL and Will County were grouped with Du Page, Kane and Kendall counties in 2000, they are assigned the same benefit package as the HMO's plan in those counties in 2001. Another example is given by the HMO with contract number H3251, which offered a Medicare HMO plan in New Mexico in 2000 and 2001. In 2000, the HMO offered one benefit package in nine counties. In 2001, the HMO withdrew from four counties, and split the other five counties into two benefit packages. Table 2 shows which counties were assigned which benefit packages and Figure 2 shows a county map of New Mexico. Since splitting the counties made it ambiguous which counties the counties with 98 imputed benefits should be grouped with, the counties were grouped geographically. Rio Arriba and Socorro counties were assigned benefit package #2, since they are closer to Sandoval and Valencia counties while San Miguel County was assigned benefit package #18 since it is closer to Santa Fe and Torrance counties. In the case of ties, MSA boundaries were used to break them; Los Alamos County was therefore assigned benefit package #18, since it is in the Santa Fe MSA. This method of imputing benefits and premiums is not perfect. HMOs' premium and benefit decisions are joint with their service area decisions, so, if they had stayed in the counties they withdrew from, they probably would have offered different premiums and benefits. In order to make the welfare estimate however, benefits and premiums had to be imputed to the counties that plans withdrew from, and this is a conservative method for doing so. In the more generous scenario, however, I will assume that all plans that withdrew stayed in until 2002 and that their benefits and premiums remained constant at their 1999 levels (or the level of their year of entrance, if they entered after 1999). This is not the most generous scenario that could be imagined; the most generous would probably involve enrollment rising and benefits becoming more generous over time but it is a minimally generous scenario. In both scenarios, I will assume that plans that entered in reality after 1999 still entered. While more plans exited than entered during the period 1999-2002, it is not the case that there was no entrance at all. I also calculate costs for both scenarios by multiplying the increased enrollment in each county by the reimbursement rate in that county. The reimbursement rates used are 99 the actual reimbursement rates set by the formula in the BBA. While it would be preferable to use the counterfactual reimbursement rates, they are not available. Since actual reimbursement rates are usually lower than the counterfactual reimbursement rates would have been in counties with HMOs, this approach will understate the increased costs that would have been incurred if the plans had not withdrawn. IV. Estimating welfare in nested-logit models Small and Rosen (1981) discuss estimating welfare in discrete-choice models. As they show, the change in the expenditure function from a quality change can be found by integrating over the share function with respect to the utility function. In logit and nestedlogit models, this integral has a closed-form expression. Share in the nested logit model are given by: exp(Uj /I -a) Z exp(Uk/- Iexp(Uk /- a)j[ kEGC g () - r) kE g Uj represents the mean utility, i.e., the portion of utility common across consumers (and omitting the individual error term). The integral of this share formula with respect to the utility function evaluates to: JsjdUj = In 0 exp( Uk) ~g ~kEg (2) 1 Logit and nested-logit models have the property that the matrix of the derivatives of the shares with respect to the utilities is symmetric. That is, si auj - sj for all aui plans i and j. This property is useful because it allows the welfare effect of several simultaneous 100 quality changes to be evaluated with this one integral. When there are multiple quality changes in multiple products, the difference in welfare can be measured by evaluating each utility function with and without all of the quality changes. Since the integral is in utils, to find the welfare effect in dollars, the integral is divided by the marginal utility of income. As mentioned above, Equation (2) gives the change in the expenditure function from a quality change, also known as the compensating variation. More specifically, it gives the compensating variation from a quality change for a representative person in the market. To find the total welfare change in a market, it must be multiplied by the number of consumers in the market. V. Applying welfare estimation to the Medicare HMO market For the purposes of calculating welfare, I will be using the same mean utility function for Medicare HMOs as in Hall (2005): Umt -tP m- XjmtJ jmt t (3) + where j represents the plan, m the county and t the year. pjmt is the plan premium, Xjmtis a vector of prescription drug benefit characteristics, and quality. (jmt represents unobserved plan is a year-specific effect, to account for the change in demand for Medicare HMO benefits over time. The utility parameter estimates were made in Hall (2005). I use the estimates from the IV nested log specification, with the prescription drug benefits measured as the amount of expenditure by an average prescription drug user that would be covered by the 101 plan. (Estimates using the actual features of the plan, such as the amount of brand-name drug coverage, were qualitatively similar.) To calculate the effect of the withdrawals, utilities were calculated for each plan using the parameter estimates from Hall 2005 and inputted into the integral in equation (2). For the endpoint without the withdrawals, the premiums and benefits given under the two counterfactual scenarios discussed above were used and for the endpoint with the withdrawals, the premiums and benefits that were offered in reality. In Hall (2005), was estimated with the residual from the demand regression. It therefore had to be imputed to observations (plan-county-year combinations) that were not in the sample. Since the demand regression included plan-county fixed effects, a plan had to be in the county for at least two years in order for the observations to be in the sample. If an observation was not in the sample because the plan was in the county for only one year, could be predicted easily using the actual share and plan characteristics. For all other observations, , was assumed to be zero, since, as the demand regression is estimated with a constant, that is its expected value. Since the mean utility of traditional Medicare was normalized to zero in Hall 2005, the endpoints each give the amount of welfare provided by the Medicare HMO program above the welfare from traditional Medicare. This amount is always positive since, in logit models, welfare is always increasing in the number of choices available. Since the welfare measures give the welfare added by the Medicare HMO program, in order to correctly compare the costs, the total costs must be adjusted to find the cost added by the Medicare HMOs to the costs incurred by traditional Medicare. It is difficult to know exactly which enrollees in traditional Medicare would have enrolled in 102 HMOs without the withdrawals so it is therefore difficult to estimate exactly the difference in costs. Estimates of the expected cost of HMO enrollees if they had enrolled in traditional Medicare in the literature range from 88% of their cost in the HMO program (Riley et al. 1996) to 100% (Rogers and Smith 1995, Dowd et al. 1996). The higher the cost of treating the enrollee in traditional Medicare, the more net welfare is added by the Medicare HMO program. I present results calculated under several different assumptions about the cost differential between traditional Medicare and the Medicare HMO program. The counterfactual enrollments were also calculated, to give an estimate of how many people were affected by the change. They were calculated using the share formula in equation () and the premiums and benefits from each counterfactual scenario, and then multiplying these predicted shares by the number of Medicare eligibles in each county. VI. Results of welfare and cost calculations The results of the welfare and cost calculations are reported in Tables 3 and 4. Table 3 reports the results for the first, more conservative scenario. As the middle column shows, the Medicare HMO program generates net positive welfare in all four years even with the most conservative assumption about how much HMO enrollees would have cost in the traditional Medicare program. Over the period 1999-2002, the Medicare HMO program generated gross welfare of $64.8 billion and incurred gross expenditure of $156.2 billion. If we assume that HMO enrollees' costs would have been 80% of the total expenditure of the HMO program if they had been enrolled in 103 traditional Medicare, then the HMO program only added $31.2 billion to overall Medicare expenditure and thus generated net welfare of $33.5 billion. If, as is more likely, their costs would have been 90% of the costs in the HMO program, the HMO program only added $15.6 billion to overall Medicare expenditure and thus generated net welfare of $49.1 billion. The first column of Table 3 shows how much welfare and expenditure the HMO program would generate under the conservative scenario, where plans are assumed to only stay in the program for one more year and did not have more generous benefits. Under this conservative assumption, it can be seen that the withdrawals caused a significant reduction in both enrollment and welfare from the Medicare HMO program. Total enrollment over the four years from 1999-2002 was 2.8 million less because of the plan withdrawals, equivalent to an 11.1% reduction in enrollment. For welfare, under the most conservative assumption that HMO enrollees would have cost 80% of what they cost in the HMO program if they had been enrolled in traditional Medicare, the withdrawals caused a $4.3 billion loss in welfare in the four years from 1999-2002, equivalent to lowering net welfare by 11.5%. Under the more plausible 90% assumption, the withdrawals caused a $6.2 billion loss in welfare, equivalent to lowering net welfare by 11.2%. The withdrawals also seemed to have lowered the HMO program's costeffectiveness slightly. The last four rows in each panel of Table 3 give the average cost of $1 of welfare in the program with and without the withdrawals and of the plans that withdrew. This number was calculated by simply dividing the estimated cost added by the HMO program by the gross welfare generated by the program. As they show, the 104 plans that withdrew in 1999, 2000, and 2001 were providing more welfare at a lower cost than the plans that remained, and the cost-effectiveness of the program was slightly lowered by the withdrawals. This result offers evidence against the hypothesis suggested by the GAO that HMOs were withdrawing in 1999 because some of them had over- entered and could not compete effectively, not because of the BBA. In 2002 however, the plans that withdrew were less cost-effective, suggesting that the kinds of plans who were leaving the program were changing over time. Table 4 reports the results for the less generous scenario. In this scenario, since I did not have detailed benefit data for 1998, I had to start the simulation at the 1999 levels of benefits and entry. In this respect, the scenario is less generous than the previous one, which assumed the plans that left in 1998 stayed in for one more year. The welfare without the withdrawals and the enrollment are still considerably larger, as the last panel with the totals shows. The withdrawals lowered enrollment by 5.3 million beneficiaries from 28.0 million, equivalent to a reduction of 19.0%. Total gross welfare without the withdrawals is estimated to be $81.4 million over the three years. Under the conservative assumption that HMO enrollees would have cost 80% as much in traditional Medicare, the HMO program added $37.2 billion to expenditure, implying a net welfare amount of $44.2 billion. Under the more plausible assumption that they would have cost 90%, the HMO program added only $18.6 billion to expenditure, generating a net welfare amount of $62.3 billion. Under the 80% assumption, the withdrawals caused a loss of $12.3 billion in welfare (or 27.8%) and under the 90% assumption, they caused a loss of $16.6 billion in welfare (or 23.0%). 105 Under the scenario presented in Table 4, the loss of cost-effectiveness was even greater than in Table 3. Under the 80% assumption, without the withdrawals, the average cost of $1 of welfare would be $0.46, while, with the withdrawals, it was $0.48. The plans that left had an implied cost of only $0.36 per $1 of welfare. Under the 90% assumption, the plans that left had an implied cost of $0.18, raising the cost of $1 of welfare from $0.23 to $0.24. In summary therefore, the estimates of the gross welfare loss from the plan withdrawals ranged from $8.1 billion to $16.6 billion and the gross expenditure decrease from $18.7 billion to $29.6 billion. The estimates of the net welfare loss range from $4.3 billion to $16.6 billion, depending on the scenario and what we assume about how much enrollees who would have enrolled in HMOs if the plans had not withdrawn, ended up costing in traditional Medicare. The implied percentage decrease in welfare from the withdrawals ranges from 11.5% in the first scenario to 21.5% in the second scenario, both under the 90% assumption. VII. Conclusion The intent of the TEFRA of 1982 in creating the risk-based Medicare HMO program was that the federal government would take advantage of the presumed greater efficiency of HMOs to create savings for the Medicare program. As many have noticed, and as this paper shows, the program has not really worked out that way since Medicare HMOs have increased overall spending by Medicare. The plan withdrawals in the Medicare+Choice program were highly publicized, affected many people, and made a deep impression on all parties concerned. As a result, in 2003, when the program was 106 renamed the Medicare Advantage program by the Medicare Modernization Act (MMA), the reimbursement rates were raised to 100% of the expected per capita cost of traditional Medicare in the county, to encourage plans to come back into the program. This change obviously resulted in an increase in expenditure for the program; the Medicare Payment Advisory Commission estimated that Medicare paid 7% more for HMO enrollees in 2004 than it would have if they had been in traditional Medicare. The welfare estimates presented here, however, show that the Medicare HMO program is not a waste since it does generate a positive return on spending, even under the most conservative assumptions. The estimates suggest that $1 spent on the Medicare HMO program brings just over $2 in welfare for beneficiaries in the form of lower cost-sharing and supplemental benefits. The welfare results also show that total net welfare from the program would have been higher by an amount that is estimated to be from $4.3 billion to $16.6 billion if plans had stayed in after the passage of the BBA in 1997. They also show that cost- effectiveness of the Medicare HMO program was slightly reduced by the withdrawals. This leads to an optimistic conclusion for the Medicare Advantage program: that, as plans reenter the program, cost-effectiveness will rise again. 107 References Berenson, R. A. (2001). "Medicare+Choice: Doubling Or Disappearing?" Health Affairs(Web Exclusive): W65-W82. Christensen, S. (1998). "Medicare+Choice Provisions in the Balanced Budget Act of 1997." Health Affairs 17(4): 224-231. Dowd, B., R. Feldman, et al. (1996). Competitive Pricing for Medicare. Washington, DC, AEI Press. Ellis, R. P. and I. Gurol (2002). Health Plan Entry and Exit in the Medicare Managed Care Market. Boston University: 28. General Accounting Office (1999). Medicare Managed Care Plans: Many Factors Contribute to Recent Withdrawals; Plan Interest Continues. Gold, M., L. Achman, et al. (2004). Monitoring Medicare+Choice: What Have We Learned? Finding and Operational Lessons for Medicare Advantage, Mathematica: 51. Hall, A. E. (2005). Estimating the Demand for Prescription Drug Benefits by Medicare Beneficiaries. Working paper, MIT. Kaiser Family Foundation (2004). Medicare Advantage: Fact Sheet. Menlo Park, CA. Lake, T. and R. Brown (2002). Medicare+Choice Withdrawals: Understanding Key Factors, The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation: 41. Laschober, M. A., P. Neuman, et al. (1999). "Medicare HMO Withdrawals: What Happens To Beneficiaries?" Health Affairs 18(6): 150-157. Neuman, P., E. Maibach, et al. (1998). "Marketing HMOs To Medicare Beneficiaries." Health Affairs 17(4): 132-139. Riley, G., C. Tudor, et al. (1996). "Health Status of Medicare Enrollees in HMOs and Fee-For-Service in 1994." Health Care Financing Review 17: 65-76. Rogers, J. and K. E. Smith (1995). Do Medicare HMOs Reduce Fee-for-Service Costs? Washington, DC, Price Waterhouse. Small, K. A. and H. S. Rosen (1981). "Applied Welfare Economics with Discrete Choice Models." Econometrica 49(1): 105-130. Zarabozo, C. (2000). "Milestones in Medicare Managed Care." Health Care Financing Review 22(1): 61-67. 108 Table 1: Benefit packages and service areas for contract number H1406 in 2000-2001 County Benefit package number in Benefit package number in Cook County, IL Du Page County, IL Kane County, IL 2000 8 6 6 2001 13 15 15 Kankakee County, IL 13 Withdrew Kendall County, IL Lake County, IL 6 6 15 Withdrew Will County, IL 6 Withdrew Lake County, IN 6 17 Table 2: Benefit packages and service areas for contract number H3251 in 2000-2001 County Benefit package number in Benefit package number in Bernalillo County 2000 2 2001 2 Los Alamos County Rio Arriba County 2 2 Withdrew Withdrew Sandoval County 2 2 San Miguel County 2 Withdrew Santa Fe County 2 18 Socorro County 2 Withdrew Torrance County Valencia County 2 2 18 2 109 Table 3 Welfare effect of plan withdrawals from the Medicare HMO program 1999-2002 Scenario : Plans stay in program for one year longer than in actuality In $ millions Without withdrawals With withdrawals (estimated) (actual) Difference 7,012,938 $20,536 $45,237 6,133,876 $17,781 $39,757 879,062 $2,755 $5,480 $9,047 $7,951 $1,096 $4,524 $3,976 $548 $2,262 $1,988 $274 1999 Total annual HMO enrollment Tot. ann. welfare from HMO program Tot. exp. on the HMO program Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee 100% of HMO enrollee costs 80% costs 90% costs 95% costs cost Net welfare gain (80%) Net welfare gain (90%) Net welfare gain (95%) Net welfare gain (100%) Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare (80%) (90%) (95%) (100%) $0 $0 $0 $11,489 $16,013 $18,275 $20,536 $0.441 $0.220 $0.110 $0.000 $9,830 $13,805 $15,793 $17,781 $0.447 $0.224 $0.112 $0.000 $1,659 $2,207 $2,481 $2,755 $0.398 $0.199 $0.099 $0.000 6,573,776 $19,118 $44,157 6,166,351 $17,957 $41,603 407,425 $1,161 $2,554 $8,831 $8,321 $511 $4,416 $4,160 $255 $2,208 $2,080 $128 2000 Total annual HMO enrollment Tot. ann. welfare from HMO program Tot. exp. on the HMO program Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs 80% of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by of HMO enrollee Costs added by of HMO enrollee Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs 90% cost HMO if FFS enrollee costs 95% cost HMO if FFS enrollee costs 100% of HMO enrollee cost Net welfare gain (80%) Net welfare gain (90%) Net welfare gain (95%) Net welfare gain (100%) Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare (80%) (90%) (95%) (100%) 110 $0 $0 $0 $10,286 $14,702 $16,910 $19,118 $0.462 $0.231 $0.115 $0.000 $9,637 $13,797 $15,877 $17,957 $0.463 $0.232 $0.116 $0.000 $650 $905 $1,033 $1,161 $0.440 $0.220 $0.110 $0.000 Table 3 (con.) Welfare effect of plan withdrawals from the Medicare HMO program 1999-2002 Scenario : Plans stay in program for one year longer than in actuality In $ millions 2001 Total annual HMO enrollment Tot. ann. welfare from HMO program Tot. exp. on the HMO program Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee 5,496,639 $15,683 $39,163 1,022,546 $2,828 $6,971 $9,227 $7,833 $1,394 $4,613 $3,916 $697 $2,307 $1,958 $349 costs 80% costs 90% costs 95% costs 100% of HMO enrollee cost Net welfare gain (80%) Net welfare gain (90%) Net welfare gain (95%) Net welfare gain (100%) Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare 6,519,185 $18,511 $46,134 (80%) (90%) (95%) (100%) $0 $0 $0 $9,284 $13,898 $16,204 $18,511 $0.498 $0.249 $0.125 $0.000 $7,851 $11,767 $13,725 $15,683 $0.499 $0.250 $0.125 $0.000 $1,434 $2,131 $2,479 $2,828 $0.493 $0.247 $0.123 $0.000 5,371,742 $14,673 $39,405 4,852,681 $13,337 $35,715 519,060 $1,336 $3,691 $7,881 $7,143 $738 $3,941 $3,571 $369 $1,970 $1,786 $185 2002 Total annual HMO enrollment Tot. ann. welfare from HMO program Tot. exp. on the HMO program Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs 80% costs 90% costs 95% costs 100% of HMO enrollee cost Net welfare gain (80%) Net welfare gain (90%) Net welfare gain (95%) Net welfare gain (100%) Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare (80%) (90%) (95%) (100%) 111 $0 $0 $0 $6,792 $10,733 $12,703 $14,673 $0.537 $0.269 $0.134 $0.000 $6,194 $9,766 $11,552 $13,337 $0.536 $0.268 $0.134 $0.000 $598 $967 $1,151 $1,336 $0.553 $0.276 $0.138 $0.000 Table 3 (con.) Welfare effect of plan withdrawals from the Medicare HMO program 1999-2002 Scenario : Plans stay in program for one year longer than in actuality In $ millions Total Total annual HMO enrollment Tot. ann. welfare from HMO program Tot. exp. on the HMO program Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs 80% of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs 90% of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs 95% of HMO enrollee cost 25,477,641 $72,838 $174,933 22,649,549 $64,759 $156,238 2,828,093 $8,079 $18,695 $34,987 $31,248 $3,739 $17,493 $15,624 $1,869 $8,747 $7,812 $935 Costs added by HMOif FFSenrollee costs 100% of HMO enrollee cost $0 $0 $0 Net welfare gain (80%) Net welfare gain (90%) Net welfare gain (95%) Net welfare gain (100%) Average cost of $1 of welfare (80%) Average cost of $1 of welfare (90%) Average cost of $1 of welfare (95%) $37,852 $55,345 $64,092 $72,838 $0.480 $0.240 $0.120 $33,511 $49,135 $56,947 $64,759 $0.483 $0.241 $0.121 $4,340 $6,210 $7,145 $8,079 $0.463 $0.231 $0.116 Average cost of $1 of welfare (100%) $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 112 Table 4 Welfare effect of plan withdrawals from the Medicare HMO program 1999-2002 Scenario I: Plans stay in program through 2002 In $ millions Without withdrawals With withdrawals (estimated) (actual) Difference 6,133,876 $17,781 $39,757 6,133,876 $17,781 $39,757 0 $0 $0 $7,951 $7,951 $0 $3,976 $3,976 $0 $1,988 $1,988 $0 1999 Total annual HMO enrollment Tot. ann. welfare from HMO program Tot. exp. on the HMO program Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs 80% of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by of HMO enrollee Costs added by of HMO enrollee Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs 90% cost HMO if FFS enrollee costs 95% cost HMO if FFS enrollee costs 100% of HMO enrollee cost $0 $0 $0 Net welfare gain (80%) Net welfare gain (90%) Net welfare gain (95%) $9,830 $13,805 $15,793 $9,830 $13,805 $15,793 $0 $0 $0 Net welfare gain (100%) $17,781 $17,781 $0 0.4472 0.2236 0.1118 0 0.4472 0.2236 0.1118 0 0 0 0 0 6,796,390 $20,062 $44,820 6,166,351 $17,957 $41,603 630,039 $2,105 $3,218 $8,964 $8,321 $644 $4,482 $4,160 $322 $2,241 $2,080 $161 Average Average Average Average cost cost cost cost of of of of $1 of $1 of $1 of $1 of welfare welfare welfare welfare (80%) (90%) (95%) (100%) 2000 Total annual HMO enrollment Tot. ann. welfare from HMO program Tot. exp. on the HMO program Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee costs 80% costs 90% costs 95% costs 100% cost Net welfare gain (80%) Net welfare gain (90%) Net welfare gain (95%) Net welfare gain (100%) Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare (80%) (90%) (95%) (100%) 113 $0 $0 $0 $11,098 $15,580 $17,821 $20,062 0.4468 0.2234 0.1117 0 $9,637 $13,797 $15,877 $17,957 0.4634 0.2317 0.1158 0 $1,461 $1,783 $1,944 $2,105 0.3058 0.1529 0.0764 0 Table 4 (con.) Welfare effect of plan withdrawals from the Medicare HMO program 1999-2002 Scenario I: Plans stay in program through 2002 In $ millions 2001 Total annual HMO enrollment Tot. ann. welfare from HMO program Tot. exp. on the HMO program Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs of HMO enrollee cost Net welfare gain (80%) Net welfare gain (90%) Net welfare gain (95%) Net welfare gain (100%) Average cost of $1 of welfare (80%) Average cost of $1 of welfare (90%) Average cost of $1 of welfare (95%) Average cost of $1 of welfare (100%) 7,454,451 $21,739 $50,352 5,496,639 $15,683 $39,163 1,957,811 $6,056 $11,189 $10,070 $8,321 $644 $5,035 $4,160 $322 $2,518 $2,080 $161 $0 $11,669 $16,704 $19,222 $21,739 0.4632 0.2316 0.1158 0 $0 $7,363 $11,523 $13,603 $15,683 0.5305 0.2653 0.1326 0 $0 $5,413 $5,734 $5,895 $6,056 0.1063 0.0531 0.0266 0 7,580,396 $21,774 $50,921 4,852,681 $13,337 $35,715 2,727,714 $8,437 $15,207 $10,184 $7,143 $3,041 $5,092 $3,571 $1,521 $2,546 $1,786 $760 $0 $11,590 $16,682 $19,228 $21,774 0.4677 0.2339 0.1169 0 $0 $6,194 $9,766 $11,552 $13,337 0.5356 0.2678 0.1339 0 $0 $5,396 $6,916 $7,677 $8,437 0.3605 0.1802 0.0901 0 80% 90% 95% 100% 2002 Total annual HMO enrollment Tot. ann. welfare from HMO program Tot. exp. on the HMO program Costs added by HMO if FFSenrollee costs 80% of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs 90% of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs 95% of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee costs 100% of HMO enrollee cost Net welfare gain (80%) Net welfare gain (90%) Net welfare gain (95%) Net welfare gain (100%) Average cost of $1 of welfare (80%) Average cost of $1 of welfare (90%) Average cost of $1 of welfare (95%) Average cost of $1 of welfare (100%) 114 Table 4 (con.) Welfare effect of plan withdrawals from the Medicare HMO program 1999-2002 Scenario I: Plans stay in program through 2002 In $ millions Total Total annual HMO enrollment Tot. ann. welfare from HMO program Tot. exp. on the HMO program Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee of HMO enrollee cost Costs added by HMO if FFS enrollee 22,649,549 $64,759 $156,238 5,315,564 $16,598 $29,613 $37,170 $31,248 $5,923 $18,585 $15,624 $2,961 $9,293 $7,812 $1,481 costs 80% costs 90% costs 95% costs 100% of HMO enrollee cost Net welfare gain (80%) Net welfare gain (90%) Net welfare gain (95%) Net welfare gain (100%) Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare Average cost of $1 of welfare 27,965,113 $81,357 $185,851 (80%) (90%) (95%) (100%) 115 $0 $0 $0 $44,186 $62,771 $72,064 $81,357 0.4569 0.2284 0.1142 0 $33,023 $48,891 $56,825 $64,759 0.4825 0.2413 0.1206 0 $12,269 $14,434 $15,516 $16,598 0.3568 0.1784 0.0892 0 116 Figure 1 Map of area around Chicago showing counties lmm --Rockford I · ~BOONE wINNEBAGo I . \ . McHENRY LAKE I hli'~ ,>. orth Chic cago . 7 I LAKE !- CHICAGO-. GARYKENOSHA (PART) Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Economics and Statistics Administration, Bureau of the Census 117 Figure 2 Map of northern New Mexico showing counties Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Economics and Statistics Administration, Bureau of the Census 118