Three Essays on Development Economics in China by Nancy Qian B.A., University of Texas at Austin (2000) M.A. Massachusetts Institute of Technology (2002) Submitted to the Department of Economics in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy at the MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF June 2005 © Nancy Qian 2005 The author hereby grants to Massachusetts Institute of Technologypermission to reproduce and to distribute copies of this thesis document in whole or in part. Signature of Author.. .... . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ..... . Department of Economics /f\ May 2005 c,I Certifiedby............ .. ......................................... Esther Duflo Professor of Economics Thesis Supervisor Certifiedby............ . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .. .. ... . . Abhijit Banerjee Ford International Professor of Economics Thesis Supervisor Certifiedby.... . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . I . . . . . . . . . Joshua Angrist Professor of Economics Thesis Supervisor Accepted by....... .... ....................... ................................... Peter Temin Chairperson, Department Committee on Graduate Students AHOCIiiv =,; Three Essays on Development Economics in China by Nancy Qian Submitted to the Department of Economics on May 2005, in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Abstract This dissertation is a collection of three independent essays in empirical development economics using data from China. In the first two chapters, I examine the determinants of choices within the household. In the first chapter, I estimate the causal effects of total income, relative female and relative male income on sex imbalance. The second chapter studies the effects of relaxations in the One Child Policy on sex ratios and family size and then exploits the exogenous variation in family size caused by the relaxations to estimate the causal effect of family size on school enrollment. The third chapter is a descriptive study of income inequality for top income earners in China during 1986-2002 and the potential redistributive effectiveness of progressive income taxation. Thesis Supervisor: Esther Duflo Title: Professor of Economics Thesis Supervisor: Abhijit Banerjee Title: Ford International Professor of Economics Thesis Supervisor: Joshua Angrist Title: Professor of Economics 2 Three Essays on Development Economics in China by Nancy Qian Submitted to the Department of Economics on May 2005, in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Abstract This dissertation is a collection of three independent essays in empirical development economics using data from China. In the first two chapters, I examine the determinants of choices within the household. In the first chapter, I estimate the causal effects of total income, relative female and relative male income on sex imbalance. The second chapter studies the effects of relaxations in the One Child Policy on sex ratios and family size and then exploits the exogenous variation in family size caused by the relaxations to estimate the causal effect of family size on school enrollment. The third chapter is a descriptive study of income inequality for top income earners in China during 1986-2002 and the potential redistributive effectiveness of progressive income taxation. 3 Acknowledgements I thank my thesis advisors Esther Duflo, Abhijit Banerjee and Joshua Angrist for much more than words can express. I thank Daron Acemoglu, David Autor, Dick Eckaus, Sendhil Mullainathan and Thomas Piketty for sharing their numerous insights with me. I also thank my fellow students Karna Basu, Matilde Bombardini, Thomas Chaney, Shawn Cole, Antara I)utta, Rema Hanna, Geraint Jones, Bill Kerr, Jin Li, Byron Lutz, Daniel Paravisini, Ver6nica Rappaport, Tali Regev, Ruben Segura-Cayuela, Henry Tang, Petia Topalova and Ding Wu for making learning fun; and especially Ivan FernandezVal for being the ideal office-mate in every respect. I thank Alfred Norman, Daniel Slesnick, Jacklin Chou and Kenneth Fortson for encouraging me to attend graduate school in economics. I acknowledge financial support from the National Science Foundation Graduate Research Fellowship, the Social Science Research Council Fellowship for Development and Risk and the MIT George P. Schultz Fund. I am particularly grateful to Ashley Lester for his intellectual input, continuing support and endless patience. I dedicate this thesis to my family who have enriched my life, but especially my parents, Shie Qian and Jun Lou. 5 I Contents 1 Missing Women and the Price of Tea in China: The Effect of Relative Female Income on Sex Imbalance 13 1.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ............ . . . . . . . . . . ................... 13 1.2 1.3 Background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ............ . . . . . . . . . . .................. 17 1.2.1 Previc )usWorks ................................ .......... 1.2.2 Agriciultural Reforms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18 1.2.3 Tea aind Orchard Conceptual Production . 17 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 F'ramework .................................. . 24 1.3.1 Decisi on Rule .................................. 24 1.3.2 House!hold Utility ................................ 25 ....................................... 28 1.4 The Data 1.5 Empirical Sti rategy................................... 30 1.5.1 Identi fication .................................. 30 1.5.2 Basic Results .................................. 32 1.5.3 Differ, ences-in-Differences 1.5.4 Robus 1.5.5 Two Stage Least Squares ...................................... stness .................................. . ......... ...................................... 1.6 Results on E,ducation Attainment ...................................... 1.7 Conclusion 1.8 Appendix- . 34 . 36 . 37 ....................................... robustness of Linear Specification .................... 2 Quantity-Quality: The Positive Effect of Family Size on School Enrollment 7 34 40 47 in China 49 2.1 Introduction ....................... ... 49 2.2 Background ........................ ... 53 2.2.1 ... 53 2.2.2 Rural Education ................ ... 54 2.2.3 ... 55 2.3 Data ............................ ... 56 2.4 Empirical Framework ................. ... 57 2.4.1 Identification ................... ... 57 2.4.2 The Effect of the 1-Son-2-ChildRelaxation . . ... 59 2.4.3 ... 63 ... 66 2.5 Family Planning Policies ............. Conceptual Framework ............ The Effect of Family Size on School Enrollment Conclusion ........................ 3 Income Inequality and Progressive Income Taxation in China and India, 1986-2010 3.1 Introduction ............ 73 ............ .. . . . . .. . . . 73 ... .. . . . 76 ... . . . . .. . . . 77 ... 3.2 Data and Methodology .................. . . . . .. 3.3 Top Income Shares in China and India, 1986-2001 . . . .. 3.4 Progressive Income Taxation in China and India, 1986-2010 .... 8 . . . 79 . This dissertation is a collection of three independent essays in empirical development economics using data from China. In the first two chapters, I examine the determinants of choices within the household. In the first chapter, I estimate the effects of total income, relative female and relative male income on sex imbalance. The second chapter studies the effects of relaxations in the One Child Policy on sex ratios and family size and exploits the exogenous variation in family size to estimate the effect of family size on school enrollment. The third chapter is a descriptive study of income inequality for top income earners in during 1986-2002 and the potential redistributive effectivenessof progressive income taxation. The first chapter is entitled "Missing Women and the Price of Tea in China: The Effect of Relative Female Income on Sex Imbalance". This essay evaluates the effects of an increase in relative adult female income, and increase in relative male income and an increase in overall income on sex imbalance for cohorts born during 1962-1990 in rural China. For these cohorts, the fraction of males in the surviving population increased from 50% to 54%. The first question this study answers is whether economics factor into parents' desire for girls relative to boys. It also addresses a long standing debate between economists who claim that richer households demand relatively more girls than boys and evolutionary biologists who hypothesize the opposite, that boys are luxury goods relative to boys. Furthermore, the study addresses the questions of whether it is necessary to increase female income as well (or instead) of increasing overall household earnings and whether this is due to the correlation between productivity increases for mothers and daughters or to an increase in the woman's bargaining power within the household. The main difficulty in empirically estimating the observed association between sex ratios and economic conditions cannot be interpreted as causal since it reflects omitted variables such as sex preference. This paper exploits regional variation in sex-specific labor input across crops and exogenous increases in agricultural income and relative female and male income caused by post-Mao reforms in China which increased the value of planting cash crops relative to staple crops. In particular, it uses the increase in relative value of tea and the fact that women tea is picked by women to estimate the effect of an increase in relative female income on sex ratios; and the increase in relative value of orchards and the fact that men have an advantage in producing orchards to estimate the effect of an increase in relative male income on sex ratios. I am also 9 able to estimate the effect of an increase in total household income without changing the relative shares of male and female income by estimating the effect of planting sex-neutral cash crops on sex ratios. The results show that increasing income alone has no effect on sex ratios whereas increasing relative female income increases survival rates for girls and increasing relative male income decreases survival rates for girls. Moreover, the findings show that increasing mothers' incomes increase education attainment for all children while increasing fathers' incomes decrease education attainment for girls and have no effect on boys' education attainment. The results can be best explained by a model of the household where mothers value education more than fathers and an increase in relative female income increases the weight of the mother's preferences within the household, and thereby increase female survival rates and education spending on both children. The policy implications are clear. Making households richer will not alleviate sex imbalance. Policy makers should target women either through subsidies or by increasing their employment opportunities. My calculations show that a 20% increase in rural household income that went entirely to the adult females of the household would have balanced China's sex ratios. The second chapter is entitled "Quantity-Quality: The Positive Effect of Family Size on School Enrollment". This essay studies the effect of having an additional sibling on the school enrollment of the first born child. Policy makers in many developing countries view restricting population growth as a helpful measure in increasing average human capital. Their belief is consistent with the observed negative correlation between quantity and quality of children across countries and across households within countries. However, because parents simultaneously choose the quantity and quality of their children, the observed correlation between family size and child outcomes cannot be interpreted as causal. This study uses the exogenous increase in family size caused by a relaxation in the One Child Policy to estimate the effect of family size on school enrollment. Specifically, it uses the relaxation which allows a rural household to have a second child if the first is a girl. This relaxation began in 1982 and enforcement varied across regions. I use this time and regional variation to first show that the "l-son-2-child" rule increased family size for first born girls. And contrary to previous findings, the results show that this exogenous increase in family size to find that an additional sibling increased school enrollment of the first child by 10-20%. Furthermore, I am able to use the relaxation 10 to examine the causal impact of the One Child Policy on sex ratios, which until now has not been carefully studied. I show that the One Child Policy decreased the fraction of girls in the surviving population by up to 10 percentage-points in some regions and the relaxation was only partially successful in mitigating the problem. Although more research is needed to understand the effect of quantity-quality outside of the one child context, these findings cast doubt on the hypothesis that quality is monotonically decreasing with quantity and the idea that restrictive family planning policies will necessarily help to achieve higher average human capital investment for developing countries. The third chapter is entitled "IncomeInequality and Progressive Income Taxation in China and India, 1986-2010". It is coauthored with Thomas Piketty. This paper evaluates the prospects for income tax reform in China during the coming decade (with a comparison to India), and argues that such reforms should rank high on the policy agenda in these two countries. Due to high average income growth and sharply rising top income shares during the 1990s, progressive income taxation is about to raise non-trivial tax revenues in China and India and to become an important political object. According to our projections, the income tax should raise at least 3% of Chinese GDP in 2010 (versus less than 1% in 2000 and 0.1% in 1990), in spite of the 20% nominal rise in the exemption threshold that took effect in 2004. The fact that progressive income taxation is becoming an important policy tool has important consequences for China's ability to finance social spendings and to keep under control the rise in income inequality associated to globalization and growth. Due to faster income growth and to a higher fraction of wage earners in the labor force, the prospects for income tax development look better in China than in India. This potential is however limited by the fact that Chinese top wage-earners are currently severely under-taxed relatively to top non-wage income earners. 11 I Chapter 1 Missing Women and the Price of Tea in China: The Effect of Relative Female Income on Sex Imbalance 1.1 Introduction Mlany Asian populations are characterized by highly imbalanced sex ratios. For example, only 48.4% of the populations of India and China are female in comparison with 50.1% in western Europe. Amartya Sen (1990, 1992) coined the expression "missing women" to refer to the observed female "deficit" in comparing sex ratios of developing countries with sex ratios of rich countries. An estimated 30-70 million women are "missing" from India and China alone. This phenomenon is almost certainly due to behavioral factors that reflect a preference for male children (selective abortion, infanticide and/or neglect).1 In the long run, male-biased sex 'There are two recent studies arguing that sex imbalance is caused by biological factors unrelated to economic conditions. Norberg (2004) finds that parents living with a spouse or opposite-sex partner were 14% more likely to have a male child in the U.S. However, since there is no evidence of increased cohabitation during this period in China and divorce rates were rising, her findings would suggest that the observed sex imbalance under-reports sex selection. In a recent study of the impact of hepatitis B on sex ratios, Oster (2004) argues that 75-85% of the observed sex imbalance in China is explained by the effect of hepatitis infection of pregnant mothers on miscarriage of female fetuses. However, Figure 1 shows that sex imbalance increases for cohorts born 1976 and after. (By comparing sex ratios by age from the 1982 Population Census with the 1990 Population Census, Figure 1 shows that in 1990, there are more males for every age under 14. In other words, the increasing sex imbalance observed 13 ratios can benefit women by increasing their price in the marriage market (Angrist, 2002). A more immediate concern, however, is that to select the sex of the child, parents without access to pre-natal gender revealing technologies must resort to infanticide or other forms of neglect which ultimately lead to the death of a child. Economists, beginning with Becker (1981) and Rosenzweig and Schultz (1982), have long argued that sex imbalance responds to economic conditions. The negative cross-country correlation between income and sex imbalance corroborates this argument. However, the sex imbalance within China is increasing, not decreasing, despite rapid economic growth. Figure 1 plots sex ratios by age from the 1982 and 1990 China Population Censuses and the 1990 U.S. Population Census. It shows that in 1982, sex ratios by age in China were very similar to that of the U.S. But in 1990, there are more males for every age under 14. In other words, sex ratios increased for cohorts born 1976 and after, which coincides with the beginning of post-Mao market reforms that led to an increase in GDP per capita and an increase in the gender wage gap. 2 This is consistent with the alternative explanation most recently posited by Foster and Rosenzweig (2001) which argues that sex ratios respond to sex-specific economic conditions. For example, parents may wish to avoid having female children when marriage requires a large dowry. Or, the demand for girls relative to boys may increase when female productivity increases. The main empirical challenge in establishing the link between sex ratios and economic conditions (including sex-specific economic conditions) is that both sex ratios and economic variables reflect omitted variables such as sex preference. The principal contribution of this paper is to develop and implement a strategy that captures the causal effect of economic conditions on sex ratios in China using exogenous variation in regional incomes over time. In particular, I exploit the variation in intensity of adult female and male labor input across crops and the exogenous variation in agricultural income caused by in the 1990 census data is a cohort effect rather than an age effect).Since there is no evidence of an increase in hepatitis B infection rates during this period (if anything, infection rates should have decreased due to the introduction of a vaccine), and because infection rates are likely to be correlated with socioeconomic variables which may affect sex imbalance directly,.it is likely that her results overestimate the true effect of hepatitis B. 2Accurate estimates of rural incomes during the early reform period are prevented by both the lack of data and the fact that rural workers did not receive wages. However, there is a general consensus between conventional wisdom and studies done using retrospective data that the gender wage gap began increasing with the onset of market reforms. This is consistent with the fact that before the reform, compensation for workers were set according to education, experience and skill. There was no differentiation, at least officially, between sexes (Cai et. al., 2004, Rozelle et. al. 2002). 14 two post-Mao reforms (1978-1980). The identification strategy of using exogenous price changes in sex-specific agricultural products to identify effects of changes in female-to-male wage ratio is similar to Schultz's (1985) study on Swedish fertility rates in the late 19th century. He used changing world grain prices to instrument for changes in the female-to-male wage ratio. In China, women are more productive in picking tea and men are more productive in orchard production. ence, an increase in the relative value of tea increases the total income and the relative female income in tea producing households while an increase in relative value of orchards increases the total income and the relative adult male income in orchard producing households. This study uses a differences-in-differences framework to compare sex ratios for cohorts born before and after the reforms, between counties that plant and counties that do not plant sex-specific crops that experienced a value increase due to the reform. First, I estimate the effect of an increase in adult female income holding adult male income constant on sex ratios by estimating the effect of an increase in relative tea value on sex ratios. Second, I estimate the effect of an increase in adult male income while holding adult female income constant on sex ratios by estimating the effect of an increase in relative value of orchards on sex ratios. Third, I investigate the effect of an increase in total household income without changing the proportion of female and male incomes by estimating the effect of an increase in the relative value of sex-neutral cash crops on sex ratios. Finally, by repeating the experiments above for education attainment, I am able to estimate the effects of increasing total and relative incomes on education investment for boys and girls. Setting the study in China during the period of 1962-1990has the advantages that migration was strictly controlled and little technological change occurred in tea or general agricultural production and sex-revealing technologies were unavailable to China's rural population for most cohorts in the study (Diao et. al., 2000; Zeng, 1993). The implementation of the One Child Policy largely controls for family size. To ensure that the results are not confounded by family size controls, I repeat the study on a sample containing only ethnic minorities (non-Han) who have never been subjected to family planning policies. The results between the non-Han sample and the whole sample are very similar. 3 An additional benefit of this study is that by measuring 3 Rural areas in China received relaxations to the One Child Policy beginning in 1982. Using relaxation data 15 the effect of sex-specific wages on sex imbalance and education investment, it study can speak to concerns regarding the impact of China's increasing gender wage gap. The results show that an increase in relative adult female income has an immediate and positive effect on the survival rate of girls. In the early 1980s, in rural China, increasing adult female income by US$7.70 (10% of average rural household income) while holding adult male income constant increased the fraction of surviving girls by 1 percentage-point. 4 Conversely, increasing adult male income while holding adult female income constant decreased survival rates for girls. Increasing total household income without changing the relative incomes of men and women had no effect on survival rates. I also find that increasing adult female income while holding adult male income constant increased education investment for both boys and girls, whereas increasing adult male income while holding adult female income constant decreased education investment in girls and had no effect for boys. Increasing total household income without changing the relative shares of male and female income had no effect of education attainment for anyone. The results imply that the post-reform increase in gender wage can partly explain the increase in sex imbalance and the decrease in rural education enrollment during the 1980s.5 Furthermore, they shed light on the mechanisms underlying the empirical results. While the effects on survival can be explained by either a model of the household with intra-household bargaining or by a unitary model of the household where parents view children as a form of investment, the results on education are not consistent with a model where children are viewed as pure investment goods and where households are unitary unless the returns to education for girls are negatively correlated with male income and the returns to education for both boys and girls are positively correlated with female income. Therefore, the results for survival and education investment together suggest that at least part of the effect is due to changes in the bargaining power of the woman in the household. In addition to being of general scientific interest, the results point to the possibility of nonfrom the China Health and Nutrional Survey, I find that tea counties and non-tea counties are equally likely to receive the relaxation. The sample with policy enforcement data amongst provinces which plant tea is not large enough to be used in statistical analysis. 4 This estimate is calculated using the empirical results of this study, data on crop composition from the 1997 Agricultural Census and net income data reported by Etherington and Forster (1992). The estimate assumes that the elasticity of demand for girls relative to boys with respect to relative female income is constant. 5 Both male and female school enrollment decreased in China during the early reform period (Hannum and Park, Mimeo). 16 coercive policies that can affect sex ratios. In particular, the results presented here suggest that factors that increase the economic value of women will also increase the probability that female infants are carried to term and female children live to adulthood. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the literature and policy background. Section 3 presents the conceptual framework. Section 4 describes the data. Section 5 discusses the empirical strategy and results for sex ratios. Section 6 discusses the results for education. Section 7 offers conclusions. 1.2 1.2.1 Background Previous Works Since Becker (1981) first argued that sex preference reflects underlying economic conditions, many studies have shown that sex ratios are often correlated with household income. However, the nature of this relationship is anything but settled. Becker (1981) theorizes that increased income leads to an increase in the relative demand of girls. This is consistent with Burgess and Zhuang's (2001) study using micro-level data from two provinces in China which shows that boy-preference occurs more in poor households. On the other hand, the Trivers-Willard (1973) hypothesis claims that higher status individuals have more male children (1973). In support of the latter view.,Edlund (1999) shows that in India, poor states have more girls and rich states have more boys. To add further controversy, Gu and Roy (1995) show that for China, the poorest and richest regions have the least sex imbalance. And Li (2002) found no correlation between sex ratios and factors such as household income, parents' education and the amount of monetary fine associated with the One Child Policy for children born during 1982-1987. Beginning with Ben Porath's studies of female labor supply (1967, 1973, 1975), studies have also shown that relative female income and/or education matters. For India, Rosenzweig and Schultz (1982) showed that female children receive a larger share of household resources relative to male children in communities where women's expected labor market employment is relatively high. Studies by Clark (2000) and Das Gupta (1987) in India; and Thomas et. al. (1991) in Brazil show that increased wages and/or education for adult women are positively correlated with health and education outcomes for girls. For China, Burgess and Zhuang (2001) show that 17 boy-preference is stronger in areas with fewer non-farm employment opportunities. If men are more valuable for farm labor, their results suggest that boy-preference is positively correlated with the value of adult male labor. In order to estimate the causal effect of sex-specific economic incentives on survival rates, Foster and Rosenzweig (2001) exploit sex-specific, regional and time variation in returns to human capital caused by the practice of patrilocal exogamy and productivity increases during the Green Revolution in India. 6 The empirical findings outlined above can all be explained by the unitary model of the household in which households maximize one utility function (e.g. parents have identical preferences or one member of the household dictates his preferences). Because parents maximize the potential earnings of their children in the unitary framework, increased adult female outcomes will increase relative investment in girls if the former reflects an increase in the relative returns to having (investing in) a girl. However, another reason why female income may differentially affect girls and boys is that household decisions are made as a result of a bargaining process in which the income of each family member can affect their bargaining power. For Ghana, Thomas (1994) shows that allocation of resources for girls relative to boys is strongly correlated to the education status of mothers relative to fathers. Duflo (2002) directly tests the unitary hypothesis by comparing the effect of pension payments to grandmothers to the effect of payments to grandfathers on health outcomes for girls in South Africa. She shows that contrary to unitary model predictions, pension payments to grandmothers, which cannot be interpreted as an increase in female productivity, benefit girls while payments to grandfathers do not. For China, Park and Rukumnuaykit (2004) find that household composition has differential effects on fathers' and mothers' nutrient consumption. They argue that this is inconsistent with the unitary model. 1.2.2 Agricultural Reforms Pre-1978 Chinese agriculture was characterized by an intense focus on grain production, allocative inefficiency, lack of incentives for farmers and low rural incomes (Sicular, 1988a; Lin, 1988). Agricultural policies aimed at subsidizing urban industrial populations with cheap food centered around production planning. 6 After agriculture was unified in 1953 (tong gou tong Patrilocal exogamy is the practice for married couples to reside with families of husbands. 18 xzao), planning included mandatory targets for crop cultivation, areas sown, levels of input applications and planting techniques by crop. Amongst these targets, sown area was the most important, in part, because it was easier to enforce (Sicular, 1988a). Central planning divided crops into three categories. Category 1 included crops necessary for national welfare: grains, all oil crops and cotton. Procurement prices for grain during this period were generally 20%-30% lower than market prices (Perkins, 1966) and market trade of these products was strictly prohibited (Sicluar, 1988a). Category 2 included up to 39 products, including: livestock, eggs, fish, hemp, silkworm cocoons, sugar crops, medicinal herbs and tea (Sicular, 1988b).7 Category 3 included all other agricultural items (mostly minor local items); these were not under quota or procurement price regulation. Under the unified system, the central government set procurement quotas for crops of categories 1 and 2 that filtered down to the farm or collective levels. Quota production was purchased by the state at very low prices. These quotas were set so that farmers were supposed to retain enough food to meet their own needs. But in reality, farmers were left with little remaining surplus (Perkins, 1966). Non-grain producers produced grain and staples for their own consumption and sold all cash crop output to the state at suppressed prices. Farmers had very little incentive to produce more than their quota. After the Great Famine (1959-1961), the government re-emphasized grain production by increasing procurement prices for grain relative to other crops. The state resorted to commercial and production planning to carry out the objectives of grain production (yi liang wei gang) and self-sufficiency (zi i geng sheng). The government increased production by enforcing mandatory sown area targets for crops and promoted self-sufficiency by purchasing but not selling grain and oils in rural areas. Mandatory sown area targets often required cultivation on land unsuitable for grain. Grain production grew at substantial cost of other production. Production declined for crops which competed with grain for land. Living standards declined significantly in areas suitable for commercial crops (Lardy, 1983). Post-Mao era reforms focused on increasing rural income, increasing deliveries of farm products to the state, and diversifying the composition of agricultural production by adjusting rel7 The number of crops in each category changed over time. And the number of crops reported in for each category for a given year may vary across sources. 19 ative prices and profitability. Two sets of policies addressed this aims. The first set of policies gradually reduced planning targets and reverted to earlier policies of using procurement price as an instrument for controlling production (Sicular, 1988a). In 1978 and 1979, quota and above quota prices were increased by approximately 20%-30% for grain and certain cash crops. By 1980, prices had increased for all crops. Although category 1 crops benefited from the price increases, emphasis was placed on cash crops from category 2. The second set of policies, named the Household Production Responsibility System (HPRS), devolved responsibility from the collective, work brigade, or work team to households (Johnson, 1996; Lin, 1988). The HPRS was first enacted in 1980 and spread through rural China during the early 1980s, devolving all production decisions and quota responsibilities to individual households. The HPRS allowed households to take full advantage of the increase in procurement prices by partially shifting production away from grain to cash crops when profitable. Together, the two reforms contributed to diversification of agricultural production, greater regional specialization, and less extensive grain cultivation (Sicluar, 1988a). There was an immediate and significant increase in the output of cash crops (Johnson, 1996; Sicular 1988a). However, although the value of all crops increased, continued emphasis on rural-urban subsidization of grain and other category 1 products caused the relative value of category 1 products to decrease. 8 I will compute the income from each crop directly in the next section, but the increase in the relative value of category 2 crops is also reflected in the disproportionate growth in output of category 2 crops in comparison with category 1 crops. Figures 2A and 2B show that although output for category crops increased, there is no change in the rate of increase. Figures 2C and 2D show that the rate of increase for suburban vegetables and orchard fruits, both category 2 crops, accelerated after the reform. Similar increases can be observed for tea, another category 2 crop, in Figure 3. In a second round of reforms designed to reduce the fiscal burden of grain subsidies, the state increased urban grain retail prices and stopped guarantees of unlimited procurement of category 1 products at favorable prices. On average, contract procurement prices for grain were 35% lower than market prices (Sicular, 1988a). This change, combined with the de-regulation 8The central government complained that staple crop targets were under-fulfilled while production of economic crops greatly exceed plans (Sicular, 1988a). 20 of other crops, further decreased the relative-profitability of category 1 products. Complete substitution away from producing grains was prevented by the state's continued enforcement of household level grain production quotas and its suppression of intra-rural grain trade. As late as 1997, virtually every agricultural household planted staple crops (Eckaus, 1999). Using the 1997 Agricultural Census, Diao et. al. (2000) show that on average, 80% of sown area is devoted to grain and that self-sufficiency in grain was still an important part of Chinese agriculture. One possible cause of the magnitude and speed of the response of the Chinese agricultural sector is the low labor productivity in the agricultural sector resulting from migration and other labor controls. Calculations for the marginal productivity of labor in Chinese agricultural production vary greatly. However, most studies agree that the high population-to-land ratio and labor market and migration controls result in low marginal productivity in rural areas during this period. Households living in areas with the appropriate natural conditions can then easily expand into cash crop production in response of new economic opportunities. This is consistent with the fact that agricultural households very rarely hired labor from outside the family. In 1997, 1 per 10000 rural households hired a worker from outside of the immediate family (Diao e. al., 2000). Since migration and labor market controls were more strict in the 1980s, it is most likely that the households studied in this paper hired even fewer non-family members. Plentiful cheap adult labor would also reduce demand for child labor. 1.2.3 Tea and Orchard Production This section discusses male and female labor intensities in tea and orchard production and how the production of each reacted to post-Mao reforms. I will also directly estimate the income from each crop and show that: the reforms increased income from category 2 cash crops (including tea and orchards) relative to income from category 1 staple crops; and income from tea did not exceed income from other category 2 cash crops. The latter fact addresses the possibility that the effect of income on sex ratio is not linear. An increase in income from tea (orchards) translates into an increase in total household income as well as an increase in relative female (male) income. On the other hand, sex neutral cash crops only affect total household income. To discern whether sex ratios are responding total income or relative female (male) income, I 21 estimate the effect of sex-neutral cash crops on sex ratios. However, if the income effect on sex ratio is non-linear such that there exists some threshold income which must be met before income will affect sex ratio, this strategy will only work if income from tea does not exceed income from sex neutral cash crops. Across Asia, tea is mainly picked by women. Labor input data by sex and crop is not available to examine sex specialization directly; however, in a study of South Indian tea plantations, Luke and Munshi (2004) show that 95% of workers are female. The most commonly cited reasons for why adult women have an absolute advantage in picking tea over adult men and children is that tea picking favors small and agile fingers. In general, the value of the tea leaves increase with the tenderness (youth) of the leaf. Adult women have a particular advantage over children, who are considered more careless, in picking green tea leaves, which is worthless if broken. 9 In addition, tea bushes are on average 2.5 feet (0.76 meters) tall, which disadvantages taller adult males. For China, the specialization caused by women's physical advantage might have been increased by strictly enforced household grain quotas that forced every household to plant grain. In households that wished to produce tea after the reform, men continued to produce grain while women switched to tea production. It follows that for tea planting households, an increase in tea value increased both the total household income and the relative value of adult female labor. Moreover, monitoring of tea picking is made difficult by the fact that tea picking is a very delicate task and that the quality and value of tea leaves vary greatly with the tenderness of the leaf. This resulted in almost no hired labor. Hence, the relative value of female labor increased in households that could produce tea despite the availability of cheap outside labor. In contrast, height and strength yields a comparative advantage for men in orchard producing areas. 10 For orchard producing households, an increase in the value of orchard fruits increased both total household income and the relative value of adult male labor. 9 Breakage causes tea leaves to oxidize and blacken. l°Adult men have a comparative advantage in orchard production during both sowing and picking periods. Sowing orchard trees is strength intensive as it requires digging holes approximately 3 feet (0.91 meters) deep. The strength requirement is re-enforced by the fact that Chinese soil is composed of 85% rock. The height of apple trees and orange trees range between 16-40 feet (4.9-12.2 meters) and 20-30 feet (6.1-9.1 meters). The height of the trees mean that adult males have advantages both in pruning and picking over adult females and children. Orchard trees that are most commonly observed in orchards today are either genetically modified (stunted) to be short or kept short by constant pruning. 22 The presence of child labor cannot be ruled out in any agricultural production. However, adult labor surplus resulting from land shortages and labor market controls leaves little demand for child labor. In section 4 of this paper, I will establish that the identification strategy is robust to the possibility that children and adult males (females) contribute to tea (orchard) production. The main effect of post-Mao reforms for tea production was to increase picking. Considered a priority crop, tea production was collectivized in the 1950s. Procurement and retail were completely nationalized by 1958. During the Cultural Revolution, the government pursued an aggressive expansion of tea fields. However, since farmers had little incentive to produce and tea picking is more difficult to enforce than sowing, most of the sown fields were left wild and untended until the post-Mao era, when the HPRS disaggregated 500 state tea farms into over 90,000 household level tea production units. Tea bushes were restored by extensive tending and pruning (Forster and Etherington, 1992). The procurement price for tea, which was largely unchanged between 1958-1978, doubled between 1979 and 1984. Figure 3A shows the increase in procurement; price and yield for tea. Since there was no change in sown area during this period, the yield increase reflects an increase in picking, which, in turn, reflects an increase in the value of female labor. Data for agricultural income by crop is not available during this period. Crop composition for the average household in tea planting counties from the 1997 Agricultural Census and data on net income by crop from tea planting households in 1982 (Etherington and Forster, 1992) suggest that in tea producing counties, tea comprises of 1-4% of total household net income. To examine the change in value of crops over time, I calculate the approximate gross income by crop using data on output per standard labor day by year by crop and procurement price by year by crop. 11 Figure 4A shows the national annual gross income from category 1 crops and tea. After 1979, income from tea increased at a faster rate than income from grains. I will exploit this increase to estimate the effect of an increase in relative adult female income on sex ratios. Figure 4B shows that the calculated income from orchard production increased at a faster rate than income from category 1 crops. I will exploit this increase to estimate the effect of an increase in relative male income on sex ratios. 1 Data on output per standard labor day by year by crop is reported by the National Bureau of Statistics of China. To the best of my knowledge, labor supply does not vary across years. 23 Amongst category 2 crops, the government maintained more control on tea than other crops. Tea was viewed as a political symbol by the central government from the early 1950s. In 1984, tea was one of the nine crops to remain under designated procurement price. The central government continued to maintain a retail monopoly on tea up to the early 1990s. Until the late 1980s, China exported tea at subsidized prices. Part of the subsidy was achieved by suppressingprocurement prices of tea (Etherington and Forster, 1992). Consequently, although price for tea grew significantly after 1979, tea was not as profitable as many other cash crops. Figure 4C shows that the gross income from tea experienced similar increases to other category 2 cash crops immediately after the reform. By 1983, the rate of increase was less than income from other category 2 crops although the income from tea continued to increase. 1.3 Conceptual Framework This section presents a simple model of sex imbalance. I use this framework to show that adult income affects the desirability of daughters relative to sons through two mechanisms: first by changing the consumption value of having a girl relative to having a boy; and second by changing the investment value of having a girl relative to having a boy. Moreover, it shows that if households are not unitary (e.g. parents do not have identical preferences), a change in adult income can also affect the relative desirability of girls by changing the bargaining power of each parent within the household. The model generates empirically testable predictions for the unitary case. 1.3.1 Decision Rule For most cohorts in this study, family size was constrained by China's family planning policies. Thus, I make the simplifying assumption that all households have exactly one child. The only decision which faces parents is the sex of their child. Because parents do not have access to prenatal sex revealing technology, parents select the sex of their child by deciding to keep or kill a child once she is born. Conditional on having a girl, parents for each household i compare the maximum utility that they can derive from a girl and the maximum utility they can derive from a boy, and will choose to keep a girl if VH-VH 24 > ci, where V" is the household's indirect utility in the state of the world where it has a child of sex s, s E {g, b}, and ei is the cost of sex selection for household i. The probability of having a girl can be written as: Pr(S =g) = Pr (e < V - b ) = F(V H -Vb) (1.1) An increase in the probability of keeping a girl will be reflected in the population as an increase in the fraction of girls. Let yp, p if (vf-) ayp {m, f} denote parents' (mother's and father's) incomes. Given that F'(.) > 0, > 0, then the probability of keeping a girl is increasing in parental income. Henceforth, denote ryp- 1.3.2 a - V. Household Utility The utility of parent p is uP(c), where p E {m, f} and s, s {g, b}, indicates the state of the world (sex of the child). c is each parent's consumption bundle. I normalize the price of consumption to equal 1. In each state s, parents pool their income and maximize the weighted sum of the mother's and father's utilities, usm(c), usf(c),subject to a household budget constraint comprised of the incomes of the father, mother and a child of sex s, y, Ym and Ys Credit markets are assumed to be perfect such that parents can borrow against the child's adult income. For convenience, I represent parents' consumption and investment decisions in a one period model. The indirect utility function in state s, Vs(y), is the maximand of the following household utility function. VH = mxu'(c) + (1-y)uf(c) C s.t. c = Yf +Ya +Ys The investment value of a child is characterized by the inclusion of his/her income in the budget constraint. mrnother'sand fther's The weight, z, which characterizes bargaining power, is a function of the income ratio. Hence, the mother's bargaining power is increasing in her income and decreasing in the father's income. Note that the unitary model is simply the special case of the bargaining model where parents have identical utility functions, u 25 = uf Assume that the productivity of a child is positively correlated with the productivity of parents such that a child's income is a function of his/her parents' incomes, Ys Ys(Yf, Ym). Furthermore, assume that the correlation is stronger between a child and a parent of the same sex such that Oyg > y and Yb 0 Ym a&yf Yf > 0 Yb aYm When parents decide whether they wish to keep or kill a girl, they solve for the maximum utilities they can achieve in the two states of the world where they have a girl or a boy. For each state s of the world, s E {g, b}, parents solve the Lagrangian for household utility maximization Ls = maxuu (c) + (1 - ) uf(c) - As [c- (yf + yi + ys)] The effect of a parent's income on the probability of having a girl is ryp - a/ OP- [( UM M b - / U Uf' u-ub)I F Y Ybl + A ayp -Ab- y- + 9 - Ab (1.2) It follows from the first order conditions that A is the bargaining weighted sum of the mother's and father's marginal utilities from income in the state of the world where the household has a child of sex s A9 - Ab is the relative "pure income effect" of having a girl as opposed to having a boy. Holding other variables constant, the effect of a parent's income on the probability of having a girl is increasing in the relative pure income effect. This means that if a daughter complements income more than a son, Ag > Ab, an increase in income will increase the desirability of daughters relative to the desirability of sons. In other words, an increase in parents' income will increase the probability of having a girl if girls are luxury goods relative to boys. Henceforth, I call this the relative "consumption value" from having girls. The terms in the second brackets characterize the relative "investment value" from having a daughter. Holding other variables constant, the relative desirability of a girl will increase if a girl's income increases more with the parent's income than a boy's income, 9 > Dyp 0 yb Yp' The terms um - um and u f - uf are the mother's and father's utilities from having a girl relative to having a boy. As long as parents do not have the same relative "sex preferences", Ug - b Uf f -9 f ,and bargaining power depends on income, - 4 0, an increase in parental b OYP 26 income will also affect the probability of having a girl by affecting the bargaining power of each parent. Otherwise, equation (1.2) reduces to the unitary case. In the general case, if parents view children as only a form of consumption, children's income will not be included in the budget constraint and the terms, Yg, aYp yb will drop out Dyp of equation (1.2). Similarly, if parents view children as only a form of consumption in the unitary case, equation (1.2) reduces to Ag- Ab, the pure income effect. Since the pure income effect is identical across all sources of income, the effects of mothers' and fathers' income on the relative desirability is also identical in this case, ryf. ym = Therefore, the joint hypotheses that households are unitary and parents view children as only a form of consumption can, in principle, be tested by comparing the effect of an increase in adult female income and the effect of an increase in adult male income on population sex ratios. The difference between the effects of the mother's income and the father's income for the general case can be written as Y- Yf y +A ( [u &g _/ > 0, since ay. > b - )- Ab (yb '9 Yg > Dyf' &pym 0 yf b (1.3) _ Yb &'Jf <a Yb Dym &yf Equation (1.3) shows that changes in the mother's income and the father's income will have different effects on the probability of having a girl because they affect each parent's bargaining power differently and because the correlation between each parent's income and a child's income is different for boys and girls. If households are unitary and parents view children as a form of investment, equation (1.3) reduces to the bracketed terms. The difference in mothers' and fathers' income effect on the relative desirability of girls is the difference in the correlation of the mother's and father's incomes with the relative investment value of a daughter. It follows that mothers' and fathers' incomes will only have different effects on investments in education or other factors that affect child productivity if they have different effects on the returns to education (or other factors). Therefore, if returns to education can be controlled for, the joint hypotheses that households 27 are unitary and parents view children as a form of investment can be rejected if the effect of increasing relative adult female income on education attainment differ from the effect of increasing relative adult male income. 1.4 The Data The analysis of sex ratios uses the 1% sample of the 1997 Chinese Agricultural Census, the 1% sample of the 1990 China Population Census and GIS geography data from the Michigan China Data Center matched at the county level.1 2 The sample includes 1,621 counties in China's 15 southern provinces, south of the Yellow River (Huang He) where any tea is planted. 13 Map 1 show that these counties are dispersed throughout southern China. The 1990 census data contain 52 variables, amongst which are data on sex, year of birth, education attainment, sector and type of occupation, and relationship to the head of household. Because of the different family planning policies and market reforms experienced by urban areas and rural areas, I limit the analysis to rural households. The individual and household level data are aggregated to the county level to match the agricultural census data. The number of individuals in each county-birth year cell is retained so that the regression analysis are all population weighted. Reliable data for procurement prices and output are not available for this period at the county level. For the sake of scope, accuracy and consistency between areas, this study uses county level agricultural data on the sown area from the 1% sample of the 1997 China Agricultural Census. Agricultural land is allocated by the village to farmers based on the number of members per household and quality of land. Land is usually allocated for 15 year terms (Burgess, 2004). There is no market for buying or selling land. Using 1997 agricultural data to proxy for agricultural conditions in the early 1980s introduces measurement error. It is also possible that the counties that which tea in 1997 are the counties which had stronger girl preference prior to the reform. In this case, comparing sex ratios in tea counties that plant tea in 1997 to tea counties that do not plant tea in 1997 12 This section describes the 0.1% sample of the 1990 Population Census. The analysis of education uses data from the 0.1% sample of the 2000 Chinese Population Census, which is described in Appendix Table A3. The organization of the two censuses are similar. l 3 Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Anhui, Fujian, Jiangxi, Shandong, Henan, Hunan, Hubei, Guandong, Guangxi, Sichuan, Guizhou and Shanxi. 28 will confound the effect of planting tea with the effect of underlying girl-preferences. However, as discussed earlier, the government emphasis on tea planting during the Cultural Revolution meant that the main determinant of whether a region had tea fields was geographic suitability rather than sex preferences preferences. Specifically, tea grows best on warm and humid hill- tops. The population density of the Chinese countryside and even distribution of hills through out southern China means counties that plant some tea should not be very different from their neighboring counties that plant no tea (in other respects). To assess whether counties that do not plant tea are good control groups for counties that plant tea, I loo)k for systematic differences between the treatment and control groups. While I will exploit differences over time in both types of counties, any differential evolution is more likely to be due to the relative income effect if the counties are otherwise similar. The average demographic characteristics and education attainment shown in Table 1 Panel A are very similar between counties that plant some tea and counties that plant no tea. The difference in ethnic composition will be controlled for in the regression analysis. The descriptive statistics for sector of employment in Panel B show that in both types of counties, 94% of the population is involved in agriculture. Panel C shows that households in tea counties farm less total land on average, devote more land to rice, garden production and less land to orchards. On average, agricultural households have very little farmable land, 4.06-4.85 mu (0.20-0.32 hectares) per household. Households in counties that plant tea have only 0.15 mu (0.02 hectares) of land for tea. For a visual representation of the similarity in agricultural production between tea producing counties and non-tea producing counties, refer the Maps B-lE, which show agricultural density and production by crop. The black colored counties are counties which produce some tea. The gray shaded counties are counties which produce some garden vegetables (Map 2A), orchard fruits (Map 2) and fish (Map 2C). Map 2D shows counties which produce some tea and counties where the average farmable land per household exceeds the median of 4 mu (0.27 hectares). These maps show that tea producing counties are not geographically distant from counties that produce other cash crops. 29 1.5 1.5.1 Empirical Strategy Identification The main problem in identifying the effect of increased relative female-to-male earnings on child outcomes is that both may be in part related to omitted household and community characteristics. For example, in communities with no male-bias, adult women will earn more and parents will view female and male children as equally desirable. In communities with strong male-bias, where adult women earn less and parents strongly prefer boys over girls, we will find a positive correlation between adult female income and girl survival rates. However, since female earnings and girls' survival rates are jointly determined by sex preference, the correlation would not reflect the effect of female income from the effect of sex preference on girls' survival rates. This problem is addressed by exploiting the increase in relative value of tea caused by post-Mao policies during 1978-1980. The exogenous variation in relative adult female earnings allows me to estimate the causal effect of an increase in relative adult female earnings on relative survival rates of girls. First, I estimate the effect of the agricultural reforms on girl survival rates in tea planting regions. The identification strategy uses the fact that the rise in adult female income varied across region and time of birth. Substantial variation in amount of tea sown existed across regions. Therefore, the number of surviving female children should have increased in tea planting regions for cohorts born close to and/or after the reform, and the increase should have been larger for regions that planted more tea. 1 4 I use a differences-in-differences estimator to control for systematic differences both across regions and across cohorts. Only the combination of these two variations is treated as exogenous. In other words, I compare relative survival rates between counties which plant tea and counties which do not plant tea, for cohorts born before and after the reform. Comparing sex ratios within counties for cohorts born before and after the reform differencesout time-invariant community characteristics. Comparing tea planting communities to non-tea planting communities differencesout changes that are not due to planting tea. Thus, 14 The exact timing of the response in sex ratios to the reform depends on the nature of sex selection. If sex selection is conducted by infanticide, the reform should only affect sex ratios of cohorts who were born after the reform. However, if sex selection is conducted by neglecting young girls, the reform can also affect sex ratios of children who were born a few years before the reform. 30 the causal effect of planting tea can be identified as long as tea planting areas did not experience changes which were systematically different from non-tea planting areas. Figure 5A plots the fraction of males of each birth year cohort for tea planting counties and counties which do not plant tea. It shows that prior to the reform, tea counties had higher fractions of males and after the reform, tea counties had lower fractions of males. The fact that the change in relative sex ratios between tea and non-tea counties occurred for cohorts born immediately after the reform suggests lends credibility to the identification strategy. The date of birth and whether an individual is born in a tea planting region jointly determine whether he/she was exposed to the relative adult female income shock. In other words, tea is a proxy for female earnings. The validity of the identification strategy does not rely on the assumption that only women pick tea. If men or children picked tea, the proxy for relative female income will exceed actual relative female income. Hence, the strategy will underestimate the true effect of relative female income on sex ratio. If there are any unobserved time-invariant cultural reasons that both cause women to pick tea and affect the relative desirability of female children, the effect will be differenced out by comparing cohorts born before and after the reform. The identification strategy is only in question if there is some time varying difference which coincides with the reform. For example, if the attitudes which drive sex preference changes in tea planting counties at the time of the reform, the estimate of the effect of planting tea ,will capture both the relative female income effect and the effect of the attitude change. Or, if the reason for women to pick tea was changed by the HPRS, the pre-reform cohort will be an inadequate control group. While I can not resolve the former problem, the latter concern is addressed by instrumenting for tea planting with time invariant geographic data. Second, I use the increase in value of orchard fruits relative to other crops to investigate the effect of an increase in relative male income on sex ratios. Third, I investigate whether the increase in tea value affects relative survival rates because of the increase in relative female income rather than an increase in total household income. I estimate the effect of the reform on girls' survival in regions that plant any cash crops (including tea and orchards) that experienced equal or more value increase than tea. The identification strategy is based on the increase in the value of category 2 crops relative to category 1 crops, for which prices continued to be suppressed, and category 3 crops, which 31 were never regulated. Therefore, the effect of category 1 and category 3 crops on sex ratios should not change after the reform. I estimate the effect of category 1 and category 3 crops on sex ratios. Figure 5B shows that indeed the effect of category 1 and 3 crops were identical before and after the reform. 1.5.2 Basic Results To see that the effect of tea and orchards on sex ratios is due to the post-Mao agricultural reforms and not due to other changes in these regions, I check that the effect of tea and orchard on sex ratios increased in magnitude at the time of the reform. The unrestricted effect of tea planted for each birth cohort can be written as 1990 sexic-= a + E (teaix dl)/l + yi+ Oc+ tic (1.4) 1=1963 The fraction of males in county i, cohort c is a function of: the interaction term between teal, the amount of tea planted for each county i, and dl, a variable which indicates if a cohort is born in year ; %, county fixed effects; and Oc, cohort fixed effects. The dummy variable for the 1962 cohort and all of its interactions are dropped. fi is the effect of planting tea on the fraction of males for cohort 1. If the effect of tea on sex ratios was due to the reform, fi should be zero until approximately the time of the reform, after which, it should become negative. The estimates for the coefficients in vector p1, reported in Table 2 column (1), are statistically significant for cohorts born after 1979. Figure 6A, the plot of the estimates of l, clearly shows the link between the increase in tea value and the decrease in the fraction of males. The estimates oscillate around 0 until 1979, after which, they steadily decrease. To test the joint significance of the effect of planting tea for cohorts born before the reform and for cohorts born after the reform, I estimate the F-statistic for each cohort. They are 3.59 and 2.05, both statistically different from 0. In a similar regression, I estimate the effect of orchard planted in each county i on the fraction of males in county i, cohort c. 1990 sexic= o + E (orchardix dl)61+ ?i + Oc+ ic 1=1963 32 (1.5) The coefficients in vector 5l are plotted in Figure 6B. The plot shows that the effect of planting orchards on the fraction of males becomes positive after 1979. The estimates, reported in Table 2 column (2), are statistically insignificant. However, the F-statistics for the interactions for the pre-reform cohort and the post reform cohort are 0.82 and 1.75. This means that while being born in an orchard planting county before the reform has no effect on sex ratios, the effect of being born in an orchard planting county after the reform is jointly significantly different from 0. Figure 6C plots the coefficients from a similar regression estimating the effect of all category 2 cash crops on fraction of males. The plot shows that the effect of cash crops on sex ratio experienced no change after the reform. Table 2 column (3) presents the estimates. The F- statistics for the pre-reform cohort and the post reform cohort are 1.32 and 1.37. Neither are statistically different from 0. Because the relatively few counties produce tea or orchards while all counties produce grains, the reference group in equations (1.4) and (1.5) are counties that produce grains. Consequently, controlling for the amount of orchards planted should not affect the unrestricted estimates of the effect of tea from equation (1.4). To check that the unrestricted estimates are unchanged by including controls for orchards and cash crops, I estimate the following equation. 1990 1990 1=1963 1990 1=1963 sexic =-- E (teai x dl)/1 + E (orchardix dl)31 + (1.6) (cashcropx dl)pl+ Hanice+ + i + ?c+ Sic 1=1963 Teai is a continuous variable for the amount of tea planted in each county i. The dummy variable indicating that a cohort is born in 1962 and all its interactions are dropped. The estimated coefficients for the vectors /1, 61 and Pi are reported in Table 3. The similarity between these estimates and the unrestricted estimates from equation (1.4) and (1.5) can be seen in Figure ID, which plots the coefficients for tea and orchards. The figure shows clearly that before the reform, sex ratios were very similar between tea and orchard regions, whereas after the reform, planting orchards increased the fraction of males while planting tea decreased the fraction of males. However, the estimates for tea are no longer statistically significant. 33 1.5.3 Differences-in-Differences To summarize the effect on sex ratios, I estimate the following equation where the fraction of males in county i birth cohort c is a function of the interaction term of a dummy variable for whether a county plants tea and a dummy variable for whether a cohort is born after the reform, controlling for the amount of orchards and all category 2 cash crops planted, fraction of Han, county fixed effects, and a dummy variable for being born after the reform. sexi = a~+ (tea x post)l + (orchardi x postc) 2 (1.7) +(cashcropi x postc)3 3 + Hanjic + /i + postc2y+ sic The differences-in-differences estimator, 1, is the difference in the fraction of males between cohorts born before and after-reforms between tea planting counties and counties which do not plant tea. orchardi and cashcropi are continuous variables for the amount of orchards planted in county i. All standard errors are clustered at the county level. The estimates in Table 4 columns (3) and (4) show that planting tea decreased the fraction of males by 0.7 percentage points, whereas planting orchards increased the fraction of males by 0.9 percentage points. Both estimates are statistically significant at the 1% levels. However the estimate for the effect of all cash crops, 3, is not significantly different from zero. Because the absolute increase in income from tea does not exceed that of other cash crops (Figure 4C), I conclude that increase total household income has no effect on sex ratios. 1.5.4 Robustness Migration If migration patterns differed significantlybetween tea and non-tea areas, and between orchard and non-orchard areas, the OLS estimates could be capturing the effects of migration rather than of income changes. Cohorts born after the reform are 11 years of age or younger in the 1990 Census. Hence, migration would bias the estimates if households with boys are more likely to migrate out of tea areas and households with girls are more likely to migrate out of orchard areas. Migration controls, however, made migration of entire households impossible. Another possible cause for bias is if amongst pre-reform cohorts, females were more likely to migrate out 34 of tea areas and males were more likely to migrate out of orchard areas. However, because strict migration controls suppressed long term migration from rural areas throughout the period of the study, migration is unlikely to be a serious issue. To address this problem, I estimate the upper and lower bounds of the absolute value of the effect of planting tea and orchards on sex ratios by estimating equation (1.7) in a sample where migrants are assumed to be women in tea counties and men in orchard counties. To construct the inferred populations, the fraction of urban residents in each province that report they are not born in that city and the population of the province are used to calculate the maximum possible number of rural-urban migrants per province. The population of each county is then used to calculate the fraction of provincial population in each county. I then add the multiple of this fraction and the maximum number of migrants for that province back into each county. Since the post reform cohort is less than 10 years of age and migration of children is not likely, I assume that the new additions are all born prior to the reform. To estimate the lower bound of the effect of tea, the new additions to the pre-reform cohorts in tea counties are assumed to be female. To estimate the upper bound of the effect of tea, the new additions are assumed to be male. Similarly, for the lower bound of the effect of orchard, all the added inferred migrants in orchard counties are assumed to be male. To estimate the upper bound, all the inferred migrants are assumed to be female. The estimated bounds are very similar to the OLS estimates on the reported population, ruling out the possibility that the results are driven by migration. Cohort Trends Cohort fixed effects control for variation across cohorts that do not also vary across counties. They cannot control for county-varying cohort trends which may have occurred over the 29 years of this study. I address this issue by including linear cohort trends at the county level. In order to make the estimates comparable to the 2SLS estimates in the next section, I restrict the sample to only counties for which there is geography data and estimate the same specification as the second stage of the 2SLS. This specification does not explicitly control for orchards because planting orchards can be endogenous for the same reasons as those discussed in the next section 35 for tea. I estimate sexic = a + (teai x postc)l + (cashcropi x postc)/32 (1.8) +Hanic( + ,i x trendc,+ 4 i + postc? + sic Teal is a dummy variable indicating whether a county plants any tea. h x trendc is the interaction between county specific fixed effects with a linear time trend. Columns (1) and (2) of Table 5 shows estimates without and with the the county-level cohort trend. The point estimates are similar and both statistically significant at the 5% level. Thus, the OLS estimates are robust to changes across counties over cohorts. 1.5.5 Two Stage Least Squares Two problems motivate the use of instrumental variables. First, using 1997 agricultural data to proxy for agricultural conditions in previous years will introduce measurement error which may bias the estimate downwards. Second, the OLS estimate will suffer from omitted variable bias if families which prefer girls relative to boys switched to planting tea after the reform. In this case, the OLS estimate will overestimate the true effect of an increase in the value female labor because it will confound the aforementioned effect with the sex-preferences of households which switched to planting tea after the reform. I address both problems by instrumenting for the tea planting with the average slope of each county. Tea grows in very particular conditions: on warm and semi-humid hilltops, shielded from wind and heavy rain. Hilliness is a valid instrument for tea planting if it does not have any direct effects on differential investment decisions and is also not correlated with any other covariates in equation (1.10). Map 2 shows the slope variation in China, where darker areas are steeper. Map 3 overlays the map of counties which plant tea onto the slope map. The predictive power of slope for tea planting can be seen by comparing the tea planting counties with the steep regions in Map 2. I use the GIS data pictured in Map 2 to calculate the average slope for each county and estimate the following first stage equation, where both the amount of tea planted and slope is time-invariant. Note that since orchards is also an endogenous regressor, the 2SLS 36 specification does not separately control it. The first stage equation is teal x post = (slopei x post,)A + (cashcrop x post,)p (1.9) +Hanic( + a + 4i + postc7+ eic The predicted residuals are used to estimate the following second stage regression. sexi = (teai x postc)i3+ (cashcrop x postc) (1.10) +Hanic~+ a + bi + postjY + Eic Column (3) of Table 5 shows the first stage estimate from equation (1.9). The estimate for the correlation between hilliness and planting tea, A, is statistically significant at the 5% level. Column (4) shows the two stage least square estimate from equation (1.10). The estimate is larger than the OLS estimate and statistically significant. Column (5) shows the two stage least squares estimate controlling for county-level cohort trends. The estimate is similar in magnitude to the OLS estimate but no longer statistically significant. It is important to note that the estimates with and without trends are not statistically different from each other. The estimate without trends is larger in magnitude but also less precisely estimated. The 2SLS estimate in column (5) shows that conditional on county-level cohort time trends, the OLS estimate is not biased. Furthermore the OLS and 2SLS estimates in columns (2) and (5) are almost numerically identical to the initial OLS estimate in column (1). These results give confidence to the robustness of the initial OLS estimates of the effect of tea and orchards. 1.6 Results on Education Attainment The main results of the effect of relative adult earnings on sex ratios rejected the hypothesis that households are unitary and parents view children only as a form consumption. However, since increasing adult agricultural earnings also increase the earnings potential of children, these results do not distinguish the hypothesis that households are unitary and increasing mothers income increases the survival rates of girls by increasing the relative investment value of girls from the alternative hypothesis that increasing female income may increase the survival rates of girls 37 through increasing female bargaining power. To gain further insight in the household decision making process, I investigate the effect of adult income changes on education attainment. Recall that in the unitary model where parents view children as a form of investment, the decision to invest in a child's education depends solely on the returns to education. Hence, increasing mother's income and increasing father's income will only have different effects on education investment for children if they have different effects on returns to education. Similarly, increasing mother's income and increasing father's income will only have different effects on the relative education investment for girls if they have different effects on the relative returns to education for girls. Because there is no income data from this period, I cannot explicitly control for returns to education. However, returns to education are presumably low for manual agricultural labor. Under the assumption that returns to education are the same for planting tea and for planting orchards, I can test the hypothesis that households are unitary and parents view children as a form of investment by estimating the effect of relative female income and relative male income on education attainment. This analysis uses county-birth-cohort level data from a 0.05% sample of the 2000 Population Census. 15 In order to isolate the sample to children who had completed their education, I restrict the sample to cohorts born between 1962 and 1982. Individuals in the sample should not be affected by the Cultural Revolution since disruptions to schools were generally isolated to urban areas. 16 I use cohorts which had not yet reached public preschool age at the beginning of the reforms (born before 1976) as the pre-reform control. 17 The empirical strategy is the same as before. I estimate the following equation to examine the effect of planting tea, orchards and all category 2 cash crops on education attainment for the all individuals. I then repeat the estimation for the sample of girls, the sample of boys and the difference in education between boys and girls. eduyrsic = (tea * postc)/l + (orchardi* postc)/3 2 + (1.11) (cashcrop * postc)/ 3 + Hanic( + at+ i + postc"y+ Sic 15 Descriptive statistics are in Appendix Table A3. 16I repeat the experiment on the sample of cohorts born after 1967, who did not begin primary school until after 1974, when schools were re-opened. The results are similar and statistically significant. 17Children enter public preschools at age 4 or 5 in China. Public nursery schools, targeted at children age 1-4, are not available to most rural populations. 38 eduyrsic is the average years of education attainment for individuals born in county i, birth year c. The estimates in column (1) of Table 6 show that planting tea increased overall, female and male education attainment by 0.2, 0.25 and 0.15 years. On the other hand, planting orchards decreased female education attainment by 0.23 years and has no effect on male educa- tion attainment. These estimates are statistically significant at the 1% level. Planting orchards had no effect on male education attainment. The estimates in Column (4) show that planting tea decreased the male-female difference in education attainment whereas planting orchards increased the difference. The latter is statistically significant at the 1% level. The estimates for all category 2 cash crops are close to zero and statistically insignificant. I re-estimate equation (1.11) with continuous variables for the amount of tea and orchards planted in each county i. Columns (5)-(8) of Table 6 show that the estimates have the same signs as the estimates with the dummy variables in columns (1)-(4). The estimates show that one additional mu of tea planted increases female education attainment by 0.38 years and male education attainment by 0.5 years, whereas one additional mu of orchards decreases female education attainment by 0.12 years and has no effect on male education attainment. Note that the effect of income from tea increases male education attainment more than for female education attainment and that cash crops in general have no effect on female education attainment but decreases male education attainment. To observe the timing of the effect of tea on education attainment, I estimate the effect of planting tea by birth year. 1982 eduyrsic -- 1982 (tea x dl)l + E (orchardi x dl)Jl + 1=1963 1982 (1.12) 1=1963 (cashcrop x dl)pl + (Hanic + ce+ 'i + +£ic 1=1963 The dummy for the 1962 cohort and all its interactions are dropped. The estimated coefficients for each cohort 1 in vectors /1, Jz and P are shown in Appendix Table A4. I plot the three year moving averages of the estimates for female education attainment in Figure 7. It shows that female education attainment was similar between tea and orchard areas until 1976, after which it increased in the former and decreased in the latter. By showing that the income effect for education is not equal across different sources of 39 income, the results for education, like the main results for sex ratios, reject the hypothesis that households are unitary and parents view children as only a form of consumption. Moreover, if returns to education are not affected by the reform, these results cannot be explained in the context of a unitary model where children are a form of investment. The findings that an increase in adult female income increases education attainment for all children while an increase in adult male income decreases girls' education attainment and has no affect on boys can only be explained by the unitary model (where parents view children as a form of investment) if an increase in tea value increases returns to education of both boys and girls while an increase in orchard value decreases returns to education of girls and does not affect that of boys. The lack of income data prevents a direct analysis of the returns to education. However, there are reasons to think that the returns to education are not differentially affected by the reforms. First, evidence from India shows that returns to education for tea workers is close to zero (Luke and Munshi, 2004). Second, there was no technological change in tea or orchard production that would have changed the relative productivity of girls (Foster and Rosenzweig, 2001). Overall, the unitary model where parents view children purely as a form of investment can only explain these results in the context of unlikely scenarios, the results can be easily explained with a model where mothers value education more than fathers and increasing the mother's income will increase the investment in education for all children because it increases her bargaining power within the household. 1.7 Conclusion This paper addresses the long standing question of whether economic conditions factor into parents' demand for girls relative to boys. Methodologically, it resolves the problem of joint determination in estimating the effect of changes in adult income on survival rate of girls by exploiting changes in total household income and sex-specific incomes caused by post-Mao reforms in rural China during the early 1980s. I find that increasing total household income without changing the relative incomes of men and women had no effect on survival rates of girls or education attainment. Increasing female income while holding male income constant had a large and immediate positive effect on the survival rates of girls and increased education 40 for all children. Conversely, increasing male income while holding female income constant immediately decreased survival rates and education attainment of girls. The results reject the joint hypothesis that households are unitary and parents view children as only a form of consumption. Furthermore, the unitary hypothesis where parents view children as a form of investment can be rejected unless implausible assumptions are made about returns to education. The empirical findings give a clear and affirmative answer to the question of whether sex imbalance responds to economic incentives in the short run. In addition, increasing total household income without changing the relative shares of female and male income will have no effect on survival rates. In association with the increased gender wage gap, these results can help explain the increased sex imbalance and the observed decrease in rural education enrollment in post-reform China. Policy makers who aim to decrease excess female mortality or to increase education investment should create policies that increase proportional adult earnings of women. For example, an effective method of immediately decreasing excess female mortality is to increase the relative income of adult women. The results indicate that for rural China in the early 1980s, increasing female wages by US$15 (20% of household income) without changing male wages would have balanced sex ratios. 41 Bibliography [1] Angrist, Joshua and Krueger, Alan "Empirical strategies." The Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. III, Chapter 23, North Holland, 1999. [2] Banister, J. China's Changing Population, Stanford, California: Stanford University Press, 1987. [3] Becker, Gary A Treatise on the Family, Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1981. [4] Ben-Porath, Yoram "The Production of Human Capital and the Life Cycle of Earnings." The Journal of Political Economy, 75(4) Part 1, 1967, pp. 352-365. [5] Ben-Porath, Yoram "Economic Analysis of Fertility in Israel: Point and Counterpoint." The Journal of Political Economy, 81(2) Part 2, 1973, pp. S202-S233. [6] Ben-Porath, Yoram and Welch, Finis "Do sex preferences really matter?" The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90(2), 1976, pp. 285-307. [7] Bourguignon, Francois, Martin Browning, Pierre-Andre Chiappori and Valerie Lechene "Incomes and Outcomes: A Structural Model of Intra-household Allocation." Journal of Political Economy, 1993. [8] Browning, M. and Chiappori, P. A. "Efficient intra-household allocations: A general characterization and empirical tests." Econometrica, 66(6), 1998, pp. 1231-1278. [9] Burgess, Robin "Mao's legacy: Access to land and hunger in modern China." London School of Economics Working Paper, 2004. 42 [:L0]Burgess, Robin and Zhuang, Juzhong "Modernisation and son preference." London School of Economics Working Paper, 2001. [11] Cai, Fang, Albert Park and Yaohui Zhao "The Chinese Labor Market." University of Michigan Working Paper, 2004. [12] Clark, S. Son preference and sex composition of children: Evidence from India." Demography, 31(1), 2000, pp. 21-32. [13] Coale, A. J. and Banister, J. "Five decades of missing females in China." Demography, 31(3), 1994, pp. 459-79. [14] Croll E., I). Davin, et. al. China's One Child Family Policy, London: Macmillan, 1985. [15] Das Gupta, Monica "Selective discrimination against female children in rural Punjab, India." Population and Development Review, 13(1), 1987, pp. 77-100. [1.6]Diao, Xinshen, Yi Zhang and Agapi Somwaru "Farmland holdings, crop planting structure and input usage: An analysis of China's agricultural census." Trade and Macroeconomics Discussion Paper, No. 62, 2000. [17] Duflo, Esther "Grandmothers and granddaughters: Old age pension and intra-household allocation in South Africa." World Bank Economic Review, 17 (1),2003, pp. 1-25. [18] Eckaus, Richard "Report #50: A study of the effects of natural fertility, weather and productive inputs in Chinese agriculture." MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change, 1999. [19] Edlund, L. "Son preference, sex ratios and marriage patters." Journal of Political Economy, 107(6), 1999, pp. 1275-1304. [20] Foster, Andrew D. and Rosenzweig, Mark R. "Missing women, the marriage market, and economic growth." Brown University Working Paper, 2001. [21] Foster, Andrew D. and Rosenzweig, Mark R. "Technical change and human capital returns and investmnent: Evidence from the Green Revolution." American Economic Review, 86(4), 1996, pp. 931-953. 43 [22] Garg, Ashish and Morduch, J. "Sibling rivalry and the gender gap: Evidence from child health outcomes in Ghana." Journal of Population Economics, 11(4), 1998, pp. 471-493. [23] Gu, B. and Roy, K. "Sex ratios at birth in China with reference to other areas in East Asia: What we know." Asia-pacific Population Journal, 10(3), pp. 17-42. [24] Hannum, Emily and Park, Albert "Educating china's rural children in the 21st Century." Mimeo. [25] Jensen, Robert "Fertility preferences and female disadvantage in the developing world: Equal treatment, unequal outcomes?" Harvard Kennedy School Working Paper, mimeo. [26] Johnson, Gale "China's rural and agricultural reforms: successes and failures." Chinese Economics Research Centre at the University of Adelaide, 96(12), 1996. [27] Lardy, Nicholas R. Agriculture in China's Modern Economic Development. New York, New York: Cambridge University Press, 1983. [28] Li, Guanghui "Effects of the One-Child policy on the Number and Sex Composition of Children in China," Mimeo, 2002. [29] Lin, Justin (1988) "The household responsibility system in China's agricultural reform: A theoretical and empirical study." Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 36, pp. s199-s224. [30] Luke, Nancy and Munshi, Kaivan "Women as agents of change: Female incomes and household decisions in South India." BREAD Working Paper, 2004. [31] Oster, Emily "Hepatitis B and the case of the Missing Women." Harvard Working Paper, 2004. [32] Park, Albert and Rukumnuaykit, Pungpond "Eat drink man woman: Testing for gender bias in China using individual nutrient intake data." University of Michigan Working Paper, 2004. [33] Perkins, Dwight H. Market Control and Planning in Communist China. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1966. 44 [34] Rosenzweig, Mark R. and Schultz, T. P. "Child mortality and fertility in Colombia: Individual and community effects." Health Policy and Education, Vol. 2, pp. 305-348. [35] Rosenzweig, Mark. R. and Schultz, T. P. "Market opportunities, genetic endowments, and intrafamily resource distribution: Child survival in rural India." The American Economic Review, 72(4), 1982, pp. 803-815. [361 Rozelle, Scott et. al. "Gender Wage Gaps in Post-Reform Rural China." World Bank Working Paper, 2002. [37] Schultz, T. P. "Demand for children in low income countries." Handbook of Population and Family Economics, New York: Elsevier Science, 1997, pp. 349-430. [38] Schultz, T. P. "An economic model of family planning and fertility." The Journal of Political Economy, 77(2), 1969, pp. 163-180. [39] Schultz, T.P. "Changing World Prices, Women's Wages, and the Fertility Transition: Sweden, 1860-1910." The Journal of Political Economy, 93(6), 1985, pp. 1126-1154. [40] Schultz, T. P. and Zeng, Yi "Fertility of rural China: Effects of local family planning and health programs." Journal of Population Economics, 8(4), 1995, pp. 329-350. [41] Sen, Amartya "More than 100 million women are missing." New York Review of Books, 1990. [42] Sen, Amartya "Missing women." British Medical Journal, 304, 1992, pp. 587-588. [43] Sicular, Terry "Plan and market in China's agricultural commerce." The Journal of Political Economy, 96(2), 1988a, pp. 283-307. [44] Sicular, Terry "Agricultural planning and pricing in the post-Mao period." The China Quarterly, No. 116, 1988b, pp. 671-705. [45] Strauss, John and Thomas, Duncan "Health, nutrition and economicdevelopment." Journal of Economic Literature, 36(2), 1998, pp. 766-817. [46] Thomas, Duncan "Like father, like son; like mother, like daughter: Parental resources and child height." Journal of Human Resources, 29(4), 1994, pp. 950-988. 45 [47] Thomas, D., Strauss, T. and M. Henriques "How does mother's education affect child height?" The Journal of Human Resources, 26(2), 1991, pp. 183-211. [48] Trivers, R. L. and Willard, D. E. "Natural selection of parental ability to vary the sex ratio of offspring." Science, 1973, pp. 179, 190-192. [49] White, T. "Birth planning between plan and market: The impact of reform on China's One-ChildPolicy." China's Economic Dilemmas in the 1990's: ... Studies in Contemporary China, London: Sharpe, 1992, pp. 252-269. [50] Zeng, Y., Tu, P. et. al. "Causes and implications of the recent increase in the reported sex ratio at birth in China." Population and Development Review, 19(2), 1993, pp. 283-302. 46 1.8 Appendix - Robustness of Linear Specification The empirical analysis of sex imbalance uses the fraction of males in the existing population as the dependent variable. To check the robustness of the additivity implied by the linear specification, I repeat the experiment using the log of male-to-female ratios as the dependent variable. Using log odds restricts the sample to county-birth year cells where there are both males and females. I estimate equations (1.4), (1.5) and (1.6) using the new dependent variable. The estimates are shown in Table A1 and plotted in Figures (A)-(A4). The effects of tea, orchards and category 2 cash crops are statistically significant and very similar to the linear estimates. I estimate the differences-in-differences effect using equation (1.7) with the new dependent variable. The estimates are shown in Table (A2). They are statistically significant at the 5% level. The estimates in column (2) show that planting tea decreases the relative proportion of boys by 2.9% and planting orchards increase the relative proportion of boys by 2.7%7.This translates to a 0.6 percentage-point decrease in the fraction of boys from planting tea and a 0.5 percentage-point increase in the fraction of boys from planting orchards. These estimates are very similar to the linear specification estimates reported in Table 3. 47 Chapter 2 Quantity-Quality: The Positive Effect of Family Size on School Enrollment in China 2.1 Introduction The trade-off between quantity and quality of children has been a question of long standing interest in labor economics. Understanding this tradeoff is especially relevant to developing countries today as policy makers in these countries attempt to curb population growth as a way of increasing average human capital investment. Both China and India, the world's two most populous countries, have experimented with different family planning policies to limit family size. Examining the trade-off between quantity and quality of children is of first-order importance for evaluating the effects of past policies as well as for constructing effective future ones. Empirical findings on the quantity-quality trade-off are conflicted. On one hand, the effect of family size on education has been found to be negative by Rosenzweig and Wolpin (1980) in India; by Goux and Maurin (2004) in France; by Conley (2004), Berhman et. al. (1989) and Stafford (1987) in the U.S. On the other hand, studies by Lee (2003) in Korea, Kessler (1991) and Guo and VanWey (1991) in the U.S. have found that family size has no effect on education 49 while Gomes (1984) found that family size was positively correlated with education attainment for first born children in Kenya. Adding to the controversy, in studies using data from Norway and'the U.K., Black et. al. (2004) and Iacavou (2004) use dummy variables for family size instead of the traditional continuous variable and found that while family size and education outcomes are negatively correlated for children from households with two or more children, children from one-child families perform worse than children from two-child and three-child families. Black et. al. (2004) estimates that only-children, on average, attain 0.21 years less of schooling than other children. The main empirical challenge in estimating the effect of family size on child outcomes is caused by two sources of endogeneity. The first source arises from parental heterogeneity. For example, if parents who value education more also prefer to have fewer children, the correlation between quantity and quality will be driven by parental preferences rather than by family size. To address this problem of joint determination, past studies have exploited the exogenous variation in family size caused by multiple births or the sex composition of the first two children (Rosenzweig and Wolpin, 1980; Conley, 2004; Lee, 2003). However, both instruments fail the exclusion restriction since they affect child outcomes other than family size. In a study of Indonesia, Duflo (1998) found that twin births of younger siblings were correlated with higher mortality rates of the first born child. She argued that short birth spacing may be a channel through which an increased number of children lower their average quality; the strain on resources is especially problematic if the household is credit constrained. The sibling-sex instrument is equally problematic: Dahl and Moretti (2004) and Ananat and Michaels (2004) find that sibling sex composition directly affect divorce rates. Using sibling sex composition has the additional limitation that it requires the sex of children to be randomly assigned, and consequently, it cannot be used in a country with sex-selection such as China (Qian, 2004).1 The second source of endogeneity arises from heterogeneity in the quality of the first child. For example, if parents are more likely to have a second child when the first child is of high quality, the OLS estimate of the family size effect will be biased upwards. Instead of looking for exogenous variation in family size, Guo and VanWey (1991) and Black et. al. (2004) attempt to control for the unobserved differences across households by controlling for household fixed effects in panel data. However, fixed effects estimates are biased if unobserved household-level heterogeneity are time varying. 50 This principal contribution of this paper is to address the two sources of endogeneity by exploiting regional and time variation in relaxations of China's One Child Policy. Specifically, it uses the relaxation that allows families to have a second child if the first child is a girl to instrument for the family size of first born children born before the relaxation was announced. Three facts are exploited: first, an individual is only affected by the relaxation if she is born in a relaxed area; second, amongst first born children born in relaxed areas, only girls are affected; and third, amongst first born girls born in relaxed areas, the relaxation only affected girls whose family size were constrained by the initial One Child Policy (born in 1976 or after). 2 The instrument for family size is the triple interaction term of an individual's sex, date of birth and region of birth. The interaction between whether a girl was born in a relaxed area and whether she was born in 1976 or after estimates the effect of the relaxation of family size. The additional comparison with boys controls for region specific changes in school provision that affected boys and girls similarly. There are two main benefits in setting this study in China. First, family planning policies provide a unique source of exogenous variation in family size. Second, this study can evaluate the effects of the One Child Policy, one of the most restrictive and large scale family planning policies ever undertaken. While demographers and sociologists have conducted descriptive studies of the policy's impact on fertility, the lack of local enforcement data has prevented an examination of the causal effect of the One Child Policy on child outcomes. The empirical findings show that the One Child Policy decreased the fraction of girls amongst first born children in the surviving population by up to 10 percentage-points in certain regions. This increase in sex imbalance mostly reflects an increase in excess female mortality since prenatal sex revealing technologies which enable selective abortion were not introduced to the population in this study until the end of this period (Zeng et. al., 1993). The results show that consistent with official reports, the 1-Son-2-Child relaxation was implemented in communities that experienced larger increases in boy-biased sex selection after the One Child Policy. The relaxation immediately decreased the level of sex selection although sex ratios did not return to their initial pre-One Child Policy levels. The difference in levels of sex selection between relaxed 2 The One Child Policy began in 1978-1980. However, prior to that were policies which encouraged birth spacing of at least four years between children. I show that the One Child Policy was actually binding for the family size of cohorts born in 1976 and after. 51 and un-relaxed regions suggests that parents who kept girls in relaxed regions are on average different from parents who kept girls in un-relaxed regions. Comparisons between these two types of regions will therefore suffer from selection bias. In particular, if parents of girls born in regions with the relaxation value education for girls more than parents of girls born in other regions, the two stage least squares estimate using the triple interaction term to instrument for family size will confound the family size effect with parental preferences and be biased upwards. To address this, I will estimate a lower-bound of the absolute value of the effect of family size on school enrollment. The first stage results show that the relaxation increased family size for first born girls and had no effect on the family size of first born boys. The two stage least squares estimates show that an additional sibling increases school enrollment of the first born child by 18-20% on average. This finding can be explained by a model where there are fixed costs in education or a model where other children are complements in each child's production function. The plausibility of the latter hypothesis is strengthened by the finding that the family size effect varies by the age gap between the two children. Although more research is needed to understand the effect of quantity on quality outside the one-child context, the empirical findings of this paper suggest that there is a strong only-child disadvantage and consequently reject the hypothesis that quality is monotonically decreasing with quantity. The results cast doubt on the idea that restricting family size will necessar- ily help to increase average human capital investment in developing countries. Policy makers should weigh the benefits of implementing restrictive family planning policies against the substantial "costs" related to sex selection and the long run consequences of the resulting sex imbalance. In addition, policy makers who wish to restrict family size to one child should consider implementing programs which increase interaction between children. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses family planning policies, education in rural China and the conceptual framework. Section 3 describes the data. Section 4 presents the empirical results. Section 5 offers interpretation of the results and concluding remarks. 52 2.2 2.2.1 Background Family Planning Policies In the 1970s, after two decades of explicitly encouraging population growth, policy makers in China enacted a series of measures to curb population growth. The policies applied to individuals of HElanethnicity, who comprise 92% of China's population. Beginning around 1972, the policy "Later [age], longer [the spacing of births], fewer [number of children]" gave economic incentives to parents to space the birth of their children at least four years apart. The One Child Policy was formally announced in 1979. Actual implementation began in certain regions as early as 1978 and enforcement hardened across the country until the policy was firmly in place in 1980 (Croll et. al., 1985; Banister, 1987). Past studies generally consider the One Child Policy to have only affected the family size of cohorts born after 1978-1980. However, this paper will show that because of the previous four year birth spacing rule, the One Child Policy affected cohorts born in 1976 and after. Policy tightened gradually and second births became forbidden except under extenuating circumstances. Local cadres were given economic incentives to suppress fertility rates. In the early 1980s, parts of the country were swept by campaigns of forced abortion and sterilization and reports of female infanticide became widespread (Greenlaugh, 1986; Banister, 1987). Local governments began issuing permits for a second child as early as 1982. However, permits for a second child were not made widespread until the Central Party Committee issued "Document 7" on April 13, 1984. The two main purposes of the document were to: 1) curb female infanticide, forced abortion and forced sterilization; and 2) devolve responsibility from the central government to the local and provincial government so that local conditions can be better addressed. It asked cadres to deal with each case individually and move away from inflexible, uniform enforcement. The document allowed for second births for rural couples with "practical" difficulties, and strictly prohibited coercive methods (Greenlaugh, 1986). The main relaxation following Document 7 is called the "-son-2-child" rule. It allows rural couples to have a second child if the first child was a girl (Greenlaugh, 1986).3 The explicit purpose of 3 Practical difficulties included households where a parent or first born child was handicapped, was engaged in a dangerous industry (e.g. mining). 53 or if a parent this relaxation was to decrease female infanticide of the first born child. White (1992) found that 5% of rural households were allotted second child permits in 1982. These permits were generally granted to regions with extremely high levels of infanticide. After Document 7, the permits expanded to 10% of the rural population in 1984, 20% in 1985 and 50% by 1986. Document 7 made provincial governments responsible for both maintaining low fertility rates and decreasing infanticide. While the exact process of granting permits is unclear, I use county level data on family planning policy to show in the next section that the probability for a county to obtain the 1-son-2-child relaxation is positively correlated with the rate of prerelaxation sex selection, and both are positively correlated with distance from the provincial capital. These facts most likely reflect that in order to maintain low aggregate fertility rates and decrease female infanticide, provincial governments granted relaxations to regions that were distant to the administrative capital, and where female infanticide was more prevalent. The higher prevalence of sex selection in rural areas can be due to both more boy-preference in distant rural areas and the fact that geographic distance increases the provincial government's difficulty of preventing infanticide. 4 Issues of identification that arise from the correlation of obtaining a relaxation and sex selection will be addressed explicitly in section 4. 2.2.2 Rural Education Inequality in education provision greatly increased during the 1980s both across provinces and across counties within a province. Inequality between school finance increased as changes in the fiscal system reduced subsidies from rich regions to poor regions. The system of "eating from separate pots" (fen zou chi fang) devolved expenditure responsibilities from the central and provincial governments onto local governments in order to give the latter stronger incentives to generate revenue. The ratio of the per capita schooling expenditure in the highest spending province to the lowest spending province doubled in one decade. Many rural schools were closed; rural enrollment rates dropped dramatically and did not recover until the mid to late 1990s (Hannum and Park, mimeo). Using spending data from 4 Levels of income between counties with some relaxation and counties with no relaxation are comparable in the CHNS data. This is consistent with the findings of Qian's (2004) study of rural China, where she finds that sex selection was driven by the female-to-male income ratio and not by total household income. 54 Gansu, Hannurn and Park (mimeo) found that per capita school expenditure was positively correlated with income and significant variation in school quality existed across counties. They found little variation within counties, suggesting that studies examining education outcomes should focus on variation at the county level. Hannumrn(1992) show that difference in school provision between rich and poor areas are much greater for middle school and high school than primary school. This is consistent with the CHNS data used in this study, where primary school enrollment remained stable while middle school and high school dropout rates increased for poor areas (Hannum and Park, mimeo). The CHNS data show that counties with some relaxation and counties with no relaxation have similar geographic access to schooling in 1989. However, the data does not reveal quality of schooling or the changes in school availability during the early 1980s. Because relaxed areas tend to be more rural, it is likely that the quality of schools declined in relaxed areas during the same time that the 1-son-2-child relaxation took effect. To control for this, I will compare outcomes for girls to boys within counties. The strategy is robust as long as the changes in school quality and the economic conditions that determine school quality in relaxed areas have the same impact on boys and girls. 2.2.3 Conceptual Famework There are two models in the economics and sociology literature that predict an interaction between the quantity and quality of children. The quantity-quality model, known in sociology as the "resource dilution" model, dates backs to Becker (1960), Becker and Lewis (1973) and Becker and Tomes (1979). They theorized that when income increases, parents who prefer that children within a household have equal quality will want to increase the average quality of their children. Their model predicts that quality monotonically decreases with quantity. An alternative model is the "confluence model", which to date, has not been explored in the economics literature. Psychologists Zajonc and Gregory (1985) argue that children benefit from interacting with adults and teaching younger children. The quantity and quality of children are inversely related because increasing the number of children decreases the adult-to-children ratio within a household. At the same time, children from one-child families and the youngest child from a multi-child family are worse off because they cannot take advantage of the learning 55 which comes from teaching younger children. This model, therefore, predicts an inverse "U" shape for the relationship between quantity and quality of children. This is consistent with findings from Iacavou's (2004) study of children in the U.K. She finds that although general family size is negatively correlated with measures of school performance, first born children from one-child families perform worse than first born children from two-child families. Moreover, the only-child effect decreases for children who interact more with other children outside of school. 2.3 Data This paper matches data from the 0.1% 1990 Population Census with data from the 1989 China Health and Nutritional Survey (CHNS) at the county level. The 1990 Population Census contains 52 variables including birth year, region of residence, whether an individual currently lives in his/her region of birth, sex and relationship to the head of the household. The data allows children to be linked to parents. Thus, family size and birth order of children within a household can be calculated. Because the identification is partially derived from the region of birth, the sample is restricted to individuals who reported living in their birth place in 1990. The CHNS uses a random cluster process to draw a sample of approximately 3,800 households with a total of 16,000 individuals in eight provinces that vary substantially in geography, economic development, public resources, and health indicators. Most importantly, the survey provides detailed village and township level information on family policy enforcement. Since ethnic minorities were exempt from all family planning policies, I restrict the analysis to four provinces which are mostly composed of individuals of Han ethnicity. The matched dataset contains 21 counties in four provinces. 5 These provinces exclude rich coastal provinces or poor interior provinces. For the analysis of family size and education, the sample is restricted to first born children in cohorts born during 1972-1981. This has two main advantages. First, all children in the sample have access to public schooling in 1990. Second, including children born after the relaxation may induce bias in the 2SLS estimate. After the relaxation, parents who prefer larger families may choose to keep girls. This means that the 2SLS estimate will show that girls with larger 5 Liaoning, Jiangsu, Shandong and Henan. 56 family size are better off. But the estimate will be partially driven by parental preferences. Exclusion of first born children born after 1981 removes this possibility. The descriptive statistics in Table 1 Panel A show that counties with no relaxation are very similar along demographic characteristics to counties with some relaxation. Each has 52% boys on average and is mainly composed of ethnic Hans. Children in relaxed counties have on average one more sibling than children from counties without the relaxation. Approximately 65% of children are enrolled in school. The data shows that counties with some relaxation are almost four times as far from the provincial capital as counties with no relaxation. Distance to school is similar between the two types of counties. Panel B of Table 1 describes the data for first born children from one-child families and from families with two or more children. 47% of children in multi-child families are boys while 60% of one-child families are boys. Children without siblings are on average enrolled in school 12% more than children with at least one sibling. 2.4 Empirical Framework 2.4.1 Identification Sex, date and region of birth jointly determine an individual's exposure to the 1-Son-2-Child relaxation. The relaxation allowed parents to have a second child only if the first born child was a girl. Therefore, family size should be positively correlated with being a girl. The One Child Policy, introduced around 1980, followed family planning polices which encouraged birth spacing of at least four years. Consequently, the relaxation should only affect girls born 1976 or after. The interaction between whether a girl was born in a relaxed area and whether she was born 1976 or after estimates the effect of the relaxation on family size. The additional comparison with boys controls for education provision changes that affected both boys and girls similarly. The instrument for family size is the triple interaction of an individual's sex, date and region of birth. Only the combination of the three is exogenous. The exclusion restriction for the instrument is that it must be correlated with family size and have no direct effect on school 57 enrollment or other right hand side variables. Like simple differences-in-differences estimators, cohort-invariant differences across regions are differenced out by the comparison across cohorts. Changes across cohorts which affect different regions similarly are differenced out by the comparison across regions. The triple difference adds the advantage that cohort varying differences that affect boys and girls similarly across regions are also differenced out by the comparison between girls and boys within each cohort and region. The exclusion restriction is only violated if a change with differential impacts on relaxed and un-relaxed regions and on boys and girls occurs at the same time the relaxation took effect. In other words, the 2SLS estimate will be biased only if there is a sex-specific, region-specific change for the treated cohort. I find in the next section that consistent with official reports, the extent of the relaxation is strongly correlated with the extent of sex selection for One Child Policy cohorts (1976-1982). The determinants of sex-selection may also affect education investment differentially for boys and girls. For example, Qian (2004) shows that increasing male-to-female earnings increase boy-biased sex-selection. She also shows that increasing male-to-female earnings has no effect on education investment for boys but decreases education investment for girls. This means that sex-selection is correlated with lower education investment for girls relative to boys. This will not bias the estimates as long as the correlation is time invariant, in which case it will be differenced out by the before and after comparison. 6 A potential source of bias introduced by the One Child Policy is the selection of parents who choose to keep girls. Parents who choose to keep girls born during 1976-1982 in relaxed counties may have different preferences from parents who keep girls in counties without the relaxation. For example, if parents who decide to keep girls in relaxed counties also value education more than parents who keep girls in non-relaxed counties, the 2SLS estimate will overestimate the true effect of family size on school enrollment. To address the problem of sample selection, I construct an alternative sample where the "extra" boys from relaxed counties in the actual sample are taken out and replaced with girls so that for each cohort, the sex ratio is equivalent between counties with some relaxation and 6 The CHNS does not have accurate data on individual income within the household since much of rural production is conducted at the household level and income cannot be accurately assigned to individual members. Consequently, I cannot directly examine the role of relative earnings in this study. 58 counties without any relaxation. In order to estimate the lower bound of the absolute value of the effect of family size on school enrollment, I remove only boys who are not enrolled in school and add girls who are not in enrolled in school. This increases the average enrollment rate for boys born 1976-1982 in counties with the relaxation, and decreases average enrollment rate for girls in counties with the relaxation. 2SLS using this "stacked" sample will underestimate the true effect of family size on school enrollment. Thus, using the actual sample and the constructed sample, I will be able to estimate the upper and lower bounds of the absolute value of the family size effect. 2.4.2 The Effect of the 1-Son-2-Child Relaxation Effect on Family Size One benefit of this policy experiment is that it is possible to check whether the policy was enforced correctly by estimating the effect of the policy on family size for boys and girls separately. If the policy was correctly enforced, it should increase the number of siblings for girls born 1976 and after and have no effect on boys. The following equation separately estimates the effect of the relaxation on family size for boys and girls born during 1962-1981. 1981 sibsitc= E (relax x dil)/l + yt + a + &c+ Vitc (2.1) 1=1973 The number of siblings for individual i, born in county c, birth year t, is a function of: the interaction term of relaxc, the extent of relaxation in county c and d, whether the individual was born in year ; a dummy indicating t, birth year fixed effects and c, county fixed effects. The reference group is comprised of individuals born during 1962-1972. It and all of its interaction terms are dropped. For all regressions, standard errors are clustered at the county level. /3j is the effect of being born in a relaxed county on family size for an individual born in year I. The estimates for girls and boys are shown in Table 2, columns (1) and (2). The estimates for girls are statistically significant at the 1% level for the affected cohorts (born 1976-1981). The estimates for boys are statistically insignificant. The coefficients are plotted in Figure 2A. It shows that family size for boys and girls were similar for cohorts born 1973-1976, after which 59 the family size for girls increased and the family size for boys remained the same. This difference in the effect of the relaxation on family size between boys and girls can be written as the interaction between sex, date of birth and region of birth. 1981 1981 (relaxc x girlitc x dil)Bi + sibsitc = E (relax x dil)Sl (2.2) 1=1973 1=1973 1981 + E3 (girlit x dil)(j + (relax, x girlit,)A+ girlitI 1=1973 + C + 7t + / + it The number of siblings for individual i, born in county c, birth year t, is a function of: the triple interaction term of relaxc, the extent of relaxation in county c, girlitc, a variable indicating whether a child is a girl and di, a dummy indicating whether the individual was born in year ; the interaction term of relaxc and dil; the interaction term between girlitc, and di; the interaction term between relaxc and girlitc; girlitc; -t, birth year fixed effects; and %bc,county fixed effects. As before, the reference group of cohorts born 1962-1972 and all its interactions are dropped. l is the difference in the effect of being born in a relaxed areas on family size between girls and boys. The estimates should be zero for cohorts who were not affected by the One Child Policy and relaxation (1973-1976) and positive for affected cohorts (1976-1981). The coefficients are shown in Table 2, column (5). They are statistically significant at the 5% level for the effected cohorts. Figure 2A plots the coefficients. It shows that the difference in the effect of being born in a relaxed area on family size is zero for unaffected cohorts and positive for the affected cohorts. The relaxation increased family size of first born girls by approximately 0.25 children on average. Effect on Sex Ratios by Birth Parity This section evaluates the effect of the relaxation on sex ratios by birth parity. To observe the effect of the relaxation on sex ratios, the sample must be expanded to include cohorts born after the relaxation. Past studies comparing hospital birth records and population census data, or by comparing sex ratios for the same cohort at different ages have found that sex 60 selection mostly occurs at very young ages, which is consistent with the lack of prenatal gender revealing technology and tough government enforcement against infanticide (Qian, 2004; Zeng et. al., 1993). Hence, any sex selection caused by the One-Child Policy should be observed for cohorts born very close to 1980. I estimate the following equation using a sample of cohorts born between 1962 and 1989 by birth order. Because of widespread under reporting of children under one year of age, I exclude the 1990 cohort (Zeng, 1992). The reference cohort is composed of individuals born during 1962-1968. 1989 maleitc= a (relaxc x dil)3l -+-t + a + -, + Vitc (2.3) 1=1969 This equation is similar to (2.1). The dependent variable indicates whether an individual is male. Table 3 column (1) shows the estimates of l for first born children. They are statistically significant. Column (2) shows that the estimates are robust to the addition of a control for whether individuals are ethnically Han. Columns (3) and (4) show the estimates for second born children. Columns (5) and (6) show the estimates for children of higher birth parity. The coefficients for first, second and later born children from columns (1), (3) and (5) are plotted in figures 2A, 2B and 2C with their 95% confidence intervals. The solid vertical line in the figures indicates the beginning of the [initial] One Child Policy in 1978. The dashed line indicates the beginning of the relaxation in 1982. Figure 2A shows that in areas that received the relaxation, the fraction of males increased after the One Child Policy relative to other areas. It also shows that the relaxation decreased the fraction of males. Figures 2B and 2C show that the One Child Policy and subsequent relaxations did not affect sex ratios of higher order births in relaxed counties differently from counties without relaxations. The relaxation did not change the sex composition of siblings for first born children born between 1972 and 1982. This is important because the exclusion restriction for using the triple difference as an instrument for family size requires that the instrument does not affect any right hand side variable other than family size. Dahl and Moretti (2004) and Ananat and Michaels (2004) show that the sex composition of children has a direct affect on the divorce rates of parents. Hence, if the relaxation also changed the sex composition of children in families of the affected cohort, the 2SLS estimate will be biased. 61 To estimate the effect of the relaxation on sex ratios, I estimate the following equation using the sample of first born children. The children are divided into three groups according to birth cohort. The reference group is comprised of individuals not affected by the One Child policy and the relaxation (born before 1978). The second group comprises of children born after the One Child Policy but before the relaxation (1978-1981). The third group comprises of children born after the relaxation (1982-1989). 3 maleitc = Z(relaxc X postil)jl + a + at + ~ + &itc (2.4) 1=2 The probability of being male for individual i, born in county c, birth year t is a function of: the interaction term between relaxc, and postil, a variable indicating the individual's cohort group; ,', county fixed effects and yt, cohort group fixed effects. The estimate for 61 is shown in column of Table 3. It shows that first born children born in relaxed regions after the initial One Child Policy are 8% more likely to be male than children born in un-relaxed regions. After the relaxation, first born children born in relaxed areas are only 4% more likely to be male than children born in areas without the relaxation. Both estimates are statistically significant at the 1% level. It is interesting to note that although the One Child Policy constrained the family size of individuals born as early as 1976, sex selection from the One Child Policy appears only in cohorts born after 1978. This is consistent with past findings that sex selection in China mostly occurs for very young children. In other words, once the policy is announced in 1978-1980, parents were unwilling (or unable) to kill girls that were more than 1 or 2 years of age in order to have a boy. These results suggest that parents in counties which received relaxations reacted differently to family planning policies than parents in counties without relaxations. These differing re- actions may reflect different preferences towards investment in children that is time, sex and region specific, which will confound the two stage least squares estimate for the effect of family size.. Excluding cohorts born after the relaxation (1982-1990) partially addresses this problem. It has the additional advantage of excluding households which kept girls in order to have a second child. The sample selection issue from the [initial] One Child Policy (1978-1981) will 62 be addressed by estimating the absolute value of the lower bound effect of family size with the alternative sample. Effect on Female Labor Supply If the relaxation caused parents to have a second child and mothers to stay home to take care of the child, the 2SLS estimate will confound female labor supply effects with family size effects. To address this, I estimate the effect of the relaxation on mother's work status controlling for mother's age. The results are not reported in this paper. They show that mothers of affected girls were less likely to stay at home. 2.4.3 The Effect of Family Size on School Enrollment OLS The correlation between school enrollment and family size can be obtained by estimating the following equation for the sample of first born children. 1981 enrollitc = sibsitcb + Xct + E (urbanc x dil)6l + a + At + ,c + Eitc 1=1973 School enrollment for individual i, born in county c, birth year t, is a function of: sibsitc, the number siblings he or she has; Xit, individual characteristics; the interaction term between urban, distance to urban area, and dl, a variable indicating whether an individual was born in year ; yt, birth year fixed effects; and V,, county fixed effects. The estimate in Table 5 column (1) shows that on average, one additional sibling is correlated with 1.7 percentage point less of enrollment. The estimate is statistically significant at the 1 level. Columns (2)-(5) show that the OLS estimate is robust to controls for the full set of double interaction terms from equation (2.2), a variable indicating whether an individual is ethnically Han, distance to urban area and mother's education. 7 Panel B shows the OLS estimates using the constructed sample. The point estimates are similar to those of the original sample and statistically significant. 7 The double interactions include the interaction term of relaxc and dij; the interaction term between girlitc and di,;the interaction term between relaxc and girli; and girlitc. The reference group is comprised of cohorts born during 1962.-1972.The dummy variable for the reference cohort and all its interactions are dropped. 63 Reduced Form Estimates To illustrate the identification strategy, I will first estimate the effect of the relaxation on enrollment separately for boys and girls. This can be characterized by the following equation. 1981 enrollitc = a (relaxc x dil)/3l+ ca+ t + ?c + Vitc (2.5) 1=1973 The reference group is comprised of individuals born during 1962-1972. The dummy variable for the reference group and all its interactions are dropped. The coefficients for girls and boys are shown in Table 2, columns (3) and (4). The estimates are statistically significant for girls. Figure 3A plots the estimates for boys and girls. Cohort to the right of the solid line are those affected by the relaxation. The plot of the reduced form shows that for the affected cohort, girls have higher education enrollment than boys, whereas for the unaffected cohort, girls had lower school enrollment rates than boys. The estimates in Figure 3A show that relative to areas without the relaxation, enrollment for both boys and girls decreases after primary school. This is consistent with the hypothesis that school provision and quality in relaxed regions relative to regions without the relaxation declined during this period. I control for this by comparing the effect of the relaxation on enrollment for boys with the effect of the relaxation on enrollment for girls, which can be characterized by an equation similar to equation (2.2) with school enrollment as the dependent variable. 1981 1981 enrollitc = E (relax x girlitc x dil) l + 1=1973 1981 + E E (relaxc x dil)3l (2.6) 1=1973 (girlitc x dil)(lj+ (relax x girlitc)A + girliteK 1=1973 + a + t- + 4c + Vitc The reference group is comprised of individuals born during 1962-1972. The dummy variable for the reference group and all its interaction terms are dropped. The coefficients are shown in Table 2, column (6). The estimates show that for older cohorts not affected by the relaxation, individuals born in relaxed areas have on average 1% to 17% less school enrollment than areas 64 without the relaxation. However, for cohorts affected by the relaxation, individuals born in relaxed areas are on average enrolled in school 5% more than individuals born in areas without the relaxation. The estimates are statistically significant at the 1% level. Figure 3B plots the triple difference reduced form estimates. It shows that school enrollment in relaxed areas is higher for girls of the affected cohort than for boys. Two Stage Least Squares Using the predicted residuals from the first-stage equation (2.2), I estimate the following second stage: 1981 enrollitc = sibsitcb + E (relaxc x girl x dil)/3 1=1973 1981 1981 + E (relaxc x dil)6l + E 1=1973 1981 + E (girli x dil)( 1=1973 (urbanc x dil)S1 + (relaxc x girli)A /=1973 +X.tr + 9 + o+ ±ft V + Vitc X:ct is a vector of individual controls (e.g. mother's education, ethnicity). urbani is the average distance to the nearest urban area. Column (7) in Panel A of Table 5 shows that contrary to the negative OLS estimate, an additional sibling increases school enrollment by 20.5% in the actual sample. The estimate is statistically significant at the 5% level. I repeat the estimation for the alternative constructed sample to estimate the lower bound effect of family size on school enrollment. The result is shown in Panel B of column (7). It shows that one additional sibling increases school enrollment of the first born child by 18.4%. The estimate is statistically significant at the 1% level. Columns (8)-(10) show that the 2SLS estimates of both the actual sample and the constructed sample are robust to individual and county level controls. 65 2.5 Conclusion This paper has two purposes. It evaluates the effects of the One Child Policy and the subsequent 1-son-2-child relaxation. Then, it uses exogenous variation in family size caused by this relaxation to evaluate the causal effect of family size on school enrollment. The One Child Policy is one of the most internationally controversial policies undertaken by the post-Mao Chinese government. It reportedly increased female infanticide and led to a generation of "spoiled children". However, the common misunderstanding that the One Child Policy is uniformly enforced across China and the lack of local enforcement data has, until recently, prevented researchers from measuring the causal effects of China's family planning policies. The lack of transparency in the policy enforcement decision process added to the difficulty of such studies. This paper uses local enforcement data of the 1-son-2-child relaxation to evaluate the effects of the relaxation and the One Child Policy on sex ratio and family size. It shows that although the One Child Policy was enacted in 1978-1980, previous family planning laws which encouraged birth spacing meant that the former was actually binding for cohorts born as early as 1976. The results show that the 1-son-2-child relaxation was indeed implemented in regions where sex selection was more severe after the initial One Child Policy. The relaxation decreased sex selection from the levels immediately following the implementation of the One Child Policy, but sex ratios in these regions did not return to their initial pre-One Child Policy levels. I use the exogenous increase in family size of girls born in relaxed regions to evaluate the causal effect of family size on school enrollment. The advantage of this method is that it addresses the endogenous relationships between family size and parental preferences over education and between family size and the quality of the first child. The results show that school enrollment for girls from one-child households increased by 18-20% when parents had an additional child. The findings reject models which predict that quality is monotonically decreasing in quantity. However, the results are consistent with evidence from previous studies which show that although family size is negatively correlated with education outcomes for children from households of two or more children, only-children are disadvantaged compared to children from two or three child families. Further research is needed to examine the family size effect beyond the two-child context. 66 There are several hypotheses that can explain the only child disadvantage. In a simple framework where parents and children have the same preferences (or where parents internalize child preferences), family size can increase school enrollment if children complement each other in their respective production functions. Iacavou's (2004) finding that the only child disadvantage decreases as the child interacts more with children outside of school suggests that there are comrplementarities in learning or development for children. In this study, I find that the family size effect varies according to the age gap of the two children. Similarly, psychologists Zajonc and Gregory (1982) hypothesized that children benefited from teaching younger children. This hypothesis predicts that the younger child will be worst off relative to the older child. Exploration of this hypothesis is prevented by the fact that the second child in this study is 6 years of age or younger. There may also be economies of scale in schooling costs and learning (or other psychological responses). In the context of a developing country, text books and clothes can be considered as fixed costs for sending children to school. Then having a second child will lower the average and marginal cost of school attendance for the first child as long as the secondary market for these goods functions such that transferring the goods to children from other families is more costly than transferring them to children within the household. 8 In summary, this paper presents strong empirical evidence that only-children are worst off compared to children from two or three child families. More research is needed to understand the 8 f parents and children have different preferences, the results can also be explained by child behavioral responses in regard to the decrease in her share of tangible and intangible resources within the household. While there has been many studies about parents' decisions to reallocate resources in response to the decrease in average resources, the effect of the first born child's behavioral response and parental response to child behavior has been left unexplored. The results of this paper, however, suggest that this is worthwhile considering for there are several ways that child behavior can cause parents to increase the first child's school attendance. For example, if the first child dislikes sharing tangible goods and parental attention with the younger sibling, she may behave badly and therefore increase her parents' desire to send her to school, away from the sibling during the day. Simultaneously, being at school may have an added attraction relative to being at home for the first child as a place where her position is not affected by the birth of the latter. In addition, the first child may be more motivated to attend school because she feels that academic distinction will increase her stature in the household relative to the younger child. It is important to note that in China, there is no schooling beyond high school in rural areas. Universities are highly concentrated in the largest cities. In fact, rural students with academic potential generally leave their homes during high school, or even middle school to attend better quality schools in urban areas. The lack of economic opportunities in rural areas means that such children do not return home after graduating from college. Therefore, if parents desire to keep at least one child near them, they are more likely to encourage the child to pursue higher education if they have a second child to keep near them. This will translate into lower drop out rates for the first child. Like the hypothesis proposed by Zajonc and Gregory (1982), this explanation implies that family size effects may be different for the children of different birth order. 67 family size effect beyond the one-child context and to understand the mechanisms underlying this effect. In the mean time, the results show that the relation ship between quantity and quality is not monotonically decreasing and a richer theoretic model is needed to understand the effect of family size on child quality. Policy makers should note that "one" is not the optimal number of children per household and consider administering aggressive family planning policies in conjunction with programs that increase interaction between children outside of school. 68 Bibliography [1] Ananat, Elizabeth O. and Michaels, Guy "The effect of marital breakup on the income and poverty of children." MIT Working Paper, 2004. [2] Angrist, Joshua D. and Evans, Williams N. "Children and their parents' labor supply: Evidence from exogenous variation in family size." The American Economic Review, 88(3), Jun. 1998, pp. 450-477. [311Banister, J. China's changingpopulation. Stanford, California., Stanford University Press, 1987. [4] Becker, Gary S. and Lewis, H. Gregg "On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children." The Journal of Political Economy, 81(2) Part 2, Mar.-Apr. 1973, pp. S279-S288. [5] Becker, Gary S. and Tomes, Nigel "Child endowments and the quantity and quality of children." Te Journal of Political Economy, 84(4) Part 2, Aug. 1976, pp. S143-S162. [6] Berhman, Jeremy; Pollak, Robert A. and Paul Taubman "Family resources, family size and access to financing for education." The Journal of Political Economy, 97(2), Apr. 1989, pp. 389-419. [7] Behrman, Jeremy and Taubman, Paul "Birth Order, schooling, and earnings." Journal of Labor Economics, 4(3) Part 2, Jul. 1986, pp. S121-S145. 18]Black, Sandra E.; Devereux, Paul J. and Kjell G. Salvanes "The more the merrier? The effect of family composition on children's education." NBER, Working Paper 10720. [9] Blake, Judith "Family size and the quality of children." Demography, 18, pp. 421-442. 69 [10] Brown, Phil and Park, Albert "Education and poverty in rural China." The Economics of Education Review, Forthcoming. [11] Conley, Dalton "What is the 'true' effect of sibship size and birth order on education? Instrumental variable estimates from exogenous variation in fertility." New York University, Working Paper. [12] Croll, E., D. Davin, et. al., Eds. China's One Child Family Policy. London, Macmillan, 1985. [13] Dahl, Gordon and Moretti, Enrico "The demand for sons: evidence from divorce, fertility, and shotgun marriage." NBER, Working Paper 10281, 2004. [14] Duflo, Esther "Evaluating the effect of birth-spacing on child mortality." MIT, Mimeo. [15] Gomes, Melba "Family size and education attainment in China." Population and Development Review, 10(4), pp. 647-660. [16] Goux, Dominique, and Maurin, Eric "The effects of overcrowded housing on children's performance at school." CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3818. [17] Greenlaugh, S. "Shifts in China's population policy, 1984-1986: Views from the central, provincial, and local Levels." Population and Development Review, 12(3), 1986, pp. 493-515. [18] Guo, Guang and VanWey, Leah K. "Sibship size and intellectual development: Is the relationship causal?" American Sociological Review, 64(2), Apr. 1999, pp. 169-187. [19] Hannum, Emily "Education stratification by ethnicity in China: Enrollment and attainment in the early reform years." Demography, 39(1), 2002, pp. 95-117. [20] Hannum, Emily and Park, Albert "Educating china's rural children in the 21st Century." Mimeo. [21] Hanushek, Eric "The tradeoff between child quantity and quality." The Journal of Political Economy, 100(1), Feb. 1992, pp. 84-117. [22] Iacavou, Maria "Family composition and children's educational outcomes." Institute for Social and Economic Research, Working Paper, 2001. 70 [23] Kaufman, J., Z. Shang, et. al. "Family planning policy and practice in China: A Study of four rural counties." Population and Development Review. 15(4), 1989, pp. 707-729. [24] Kessler, Daniel "Birth order, family size and achievement: Family structure and wage determination." Journal of Labor Economics, 9(4), Oct. 1991, pp. 413-426. [25] Lee, Jungmrin "Sibling size and investment in children's education: An Asian instrument." University of Arkansas at Fayetteville, Working Paper, 2004. [26] Qian, Nancy "Missing women and the price of tea in China: The effect of income on sex imbalance." MIT, Working Paper, 2004. [27] Rosenzweig, Mark R. and Wolpin, Kenneth I. "Testing the quantity-quality fertility model: The use of twins as a natural experiment." Econometrica, January 1980, 8(1), pp.227-240. [28] Rosenzweig, Mark R. and Schultz, T. Paul "Fertility and investments in human capital: Estimates of the consequence of imperfect fertility control in Malaysia." Journal of Econometrics, 1987, 36, pp. 163-184. [29] Stafford, Frank P. "Women's work, sibling competition and children's school performance." The American Economic Review, 77(5), Dec. 1987, pp. 972-980. [30] White, T. "Birth planning between plan and market: The impact of reform on China's One- Child Policy", China's Economic Dilemmas in the 1990's: The Problems of Reforms, Modernization, and Interdependence. Studies in Contemporary China. Armonk, N.Y.U.S.C.J.E. Committee and London, Sharpe, 1992, pp. 252-69. [31] Zajonc, Robert B. and Markus, Gregory B. "Birth order and intellectual development." Psychological Review, 1982, pp. 74-43. [32] Zeng, Yi. "Is the Chinese family planning program 'tightening up?' Population and Development Review, 15(2), 1989, pp. 333-37. [33] Zeng, Y., Tu, P. et. al. "Causes and implications of the recent increase in the reported sex ratio at birth in China." Population and Development Review, 19(2), 1993, pp. 283-302. 71 I Chapter 3 Income Inequality and Progressive Income Taxation in China and India, 1986-2010 (Joint with Thomas Piketty, EHESS Paris-Jourdan) 3.1 Introduction Current debates about policy reform in LDCs generally focus on improving the delivery of social services, the design of market-friendly economic institutions, the effectiveness of poverty reduction programmes, or the role of trade and market liberalization, and very rarely deal explicitly with t ax reform and the need to develop modern income tax systems in those countries. This is unfortunate for at least three reasons. First, poor countries tend to rely excessively on highly distortionary tax instruments such as taxes on trade or indirect taxes on specific consumption goods. The gradual shift towards modern and transparent income and payroll tax systems is generally regarded as an important, efficiency-enhancing aspect of the modernization process. Next, many LDCs need to raise more tax revenues in order to properly finance education and health investment, and income taxation can be part of the solution, especially in an international context characterized by sharp downward pressures on tariffs and various indirect taxes. 73 In countries like China and India, in spite of very rapid growth, tax revenues are currently stagnating around 10%-15% of GDP, which is probably far too little. There is no example of a country in the West that has been able to develop a proper education and health system with total tax revenues around 10-15% of GDP. Improving the efficiency of social services is probably a good idea, but might well be illusory in case those services are not properly funded. Finally, many LDCs have witnessed a sharp rise in income inequality during the recent period. Progressive taxation is probably one of the least distortionary policy tools available to keep the rise in inequality under control and to redistribute a bit more equally the gains from growth (it is less distortionary than more radical policy tools such as nationalization, minimum wages or autarky). In India, the fact that many people did not benefit from the 5%-6% annual growth rates advertised by the government and felt left out of "shining India" probably played an important role in the recent electoral defeat of the BJP. In this paper, we choose to focus on the case of progressive income taxation in China. Although a progressive individual income tax system has been in place in China since 1980, it has received very little attention so far, probably because the fraction of the population with income above the exemption threshold was negligible until the 1990s (less than 1%). Using annual, 1986-2001 tabulations from urban household income surveys collected by China's State Statistical Bureau (SSB), we compute series on levels and shares of top incomes in China over this period, as well as series on theoretical numbers of taxpayers and total income tax receipts (based on actual tax law). We also make projections about the evolution of the number of taxpayers and total receipts over the 2002-2010, assuming that constant income trends and income tax schedules. One additional motivation for computing theoretical numbers of taxpayers and tax receipts is the fact that there is widespread presumption that official Chinese income tax law is not being applied very rigorously by tax authorities. In particular, many observers seem to believe that tax authorities make deals with large firms and autonomous regions or cities whereby the latter offer a lump-sum payment to tax authorities and their employees and residents are not subject to the official income tax schedule. Although at this stage there does not seem to exist detailed tabulations of income tax returns by income brackets or tax liability in China (such tabulations exist in most countries with an income tax system), we were able to use aggregate 74 1996-2001 incomrnetax receipts series (broken down by wage income, business income and capital income for 2000-2001) and compare them with our theoretical series. It turns out that although there is some evidence that the law is not fully applied, actual receipts and theoretical receipts are reasonably close. We were also able to compare our Chinese findings with similar series for India. Contrarily to its Chinese counterpart, the Indian tax administration has been compilingdetailed tabulations of income tax returns every year since the creation of a progressive income tax in India (1922). Indian tax returns tabulations were recently exploited by Banerjee and Piketty (2003) to study the long run evolution of top income shares in India, and we use their results for the 1986-2001 sub-period as a comparison point for our Chinese series. Our main conclusions are the following. First, our general conclusion is that progressive income taxation is about to become an important economic and political object in China and India, and that income tax reform should rank high on the policy agenda in these two countries. Due to high average income growth and sharply rising top income shares during the 1990s, progressive income taxation is starting to hit non-negligible fraction of the population in both countries (as more and more workers pass the exemption threshold, following what happened in Western countries half-a-century ago) and to raise non-trivial tax revenues. According to our projections, the income tax should raise at least 3% of Chinese GDP in 2010 (versus less than 1% in 2000 and 0,1% in 1990), in spite of the 20% nominal rise in the exemption threshold that took effect in 2004. The fact that progressive income taxation is becoming an important policy tool has important consequences for China's ability to finance social spendings and to keep under control the rise in income inequality associated to globalization and growth. Due to faster income growth, to lower bracket indexation and to a higher fraction of wage earners in the labor force, the prospects for income tax development look better in China than in India. This potential is however limited by the fact that Chinese top wage-earners are currently severely under-taxed relatively to top non-wage income earners. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly describes the SSB data used in this paper. In Section 3, we present our findings for the evolution of top income shares in China, and compare them to the Indian series of Banerjee and Piketty (2003). The results of our income tax simulations are presented and analyzed in section 4. 75 3.2 Data and Methodology The Chinese data used in this paper comes from the urban household income surveys collected by China's State Statistical Bureau (SSB). These surveys are designed so as to representative of urban China. Between 13 000 and 17 000 households are being surveyed each year (see appendix Table A1). The micro-files for these surveys are unfortunately not available for all years, and we asked SSB to provide us with annual, 1986-2001 tabulations based on the micro-files. We asked for two series of tabulations: household tabulations and individual tabulations. Household tabulations report for a large number of income brackets (and in particular a large number of top income brackets) the number of households whose total household income falls into that bracket, their average total income and household size, as well as their average income broken down by income sources (wage income, business income, capital income and transfer income). Individual tabulations report for a large number of income brackets (and in particular a large number of top income brackets) the number of individuals whose individual income falls into that bracket, their average income and household size, as well as their average income broken down by income sources. In practice, some forms of income cannot be properly attributed to a specific individual within the household (this is particularly true for transfer income and capital income), so that the total income aggregates reported in household tabulations are larger than in individual tabulations, and various adjustments are necessary when one uses the latter (see appendix Tables A1 and A2). However the important advantage of individual tabulations is that China's income tax applies to individual income (rather than household income). We used standard Pareto interpolation techniques to approximate the form of the Chinese household and individual distribution of income, and we then used these structural parameters to compute top fractile incomesand to make income tax simulations. The Chinesedata appears to be very well approximated by a Pareto distribution (for any given year, Pareto coefficients are extremely stable within the top decile), although there is some presumption that top incomes are severely underestimated in the survey data (more on this below). We did not attempt to use similar tabulations from rural household surveys, but given that our focus is on top incomes and progressive income taxation this should not be too much of a problem: average rural income was in 2001 more than 3 times smaller than average urban income, so that there are probably very few rural households and individuals in the national 76 top decile, and even less so within the top incomes subject to progressive income taxation (agricultural income is exempt from the income tax and is being taxed separately). We did not use any new Indian data in this research. All our series regarding India are borrowed from Barnerjee and Piketty (2003), who used Indian income tax returns tabulations published in "All-India Income Tax Statistics" brochures (annually available since 1922) to estimate top income levels and national accounts to compute the average income denominator. Top income shares estimates based upon income tax returns are likely to be higher than estimates based on survey data (as the latter generally underestimates top incomes), but there is no obvious reason why the trends should not be comparable. Note also that the standard household surveys used by economists working on India (NSS surveys) can hardly be used to compute top income shares, as these are mostly expenditure surveys: except for particular years, and contrarily to SSB surveys, NSS surveys contain no systematic information on incomes. 3.3 Top Income Shares in China and India, 1986-2001 Did income inequality in China increase as much as in India during the 1990s? Before we look at our top income shares series, it is useful to recall one important difference between Chinese and Indian incomes during the past 15 to 20 years. While real GDP per capita increased by almost 160% in China between 1986 and 2001 (6,4% per year), it increased by slightly more than 60% in India (3,4% per year) (see Figure 1). According to the best available PPP conversion factors, real per capita GDP was virtually identical in China and India in 1986 (less than 20% larger in China), and it is almost twice as large in China as in India by 2001. Note that the growth gap is even larger if we look at survey data rather than national accounts. While total 1986-2001 income growth is virtually the same in Chinese national accounts and household surveys, there exists a well-known "growth paradox" in Indian statistics: real GDP per capita (as measured by Indian national accounts) has increased by 64% between 1986 and 2001 (3,4% per year), but real consumption per capita (as measured by NSS surveys) has increased by only 24% (1,4% per year). According to official Chinese statistics, there exists no such growth paradox in China: real GDP per capita (as measured by Chinese national accounts) has increased by 154% between 1986-2001 (6,4% per year), and real per capita income (as measured by SSB surveys) 77 has increased by 140% (6,0% per year). If we now look at the evolution of the top decile income shares in China over the same period,,we find that income inequality has increased at a very high rate during the 1986-2001 period. According to our urban survey estimates, the top decile income share rose from about 17% in 1986 to almost 26% in 2001, i.e. by more than 50% (see Figure 2). The levels are probably underestimated (they are even lower than in the most egalitarian developed countries, e.g. Scandinavia), but the trend seems large and robust. As we move up the income hierarchy, the trend gets even bigger. For instance, the top 1% income share has almost doubled between 1986 and 2001, from slightly more than 2,5% in 1986 to over 5% in 2001 (see Figure 3). If we compare these results with those obtained for India, we find that the levels are much lower in China than in India (the Chinese 2001 top 1% share is lower than the Indian 1986 top 1% share), which again suggests that survey-based measures underestimate top incomes, but that the trend is substantially larger in China. The top 1% income share has increased by more than 90% in China between 1986 and 2001, and by less than 50% in India (see Figure 4). These results can be used not only to evaluate the prospects for progressive income taxation in China and India (see Section 4 below), but also to shed some new light on the on-going debate about globalization and the rise in inequality. Although our data does not allow us to identify precisely the causal channels at work, and in particular to isolate the impact of globalization, we note that the fact that the rise in income inequality was so much concentrated within top incomes in both countries seems more consistent with a theory based on rents and market frictions (see e.g. Banerjee and Newman (2003)) than with a theory based solely on skills and technological complementarity (i.e. inequality rises in the South because low-skill southern workers are too low-skill to benefit from globalization; see e.g. Kremer and Maskin (2003)), which would seem to imply more gradual shifts in the distribution. To the extent that the skill distribution is more unequal in India than in China (e.g. literacy rates are substantially higher in China), the skill-based theory would also seem to imply that income inequality should have risen more rapidly in India than in China, whereas we find the opposite (as far as the top 1% income share is concerned). 78 3.4 Progressive Income Taxation in China and India, 1986-2010 VWenow come to the issue of progressive income taxation. Table 1 describes the evolution of Chinese income tax schedules during the 1980-2004 period. The striking fact is that China's income tax law has remained basically unchanged since its creation in 1980. The only major change is that the nominal exemption threshold for wage earners has been raised from 9600 yuans per year in fiscal years 1980-1998 to 12000 yuans in 1999-2003 and 14400 yuans since 2004. Also note that the Chinese income tax systems treats wage income in a much more favorable manner than business income and capital income: while wage-earners are subject to the income tax only if their annual wage is high enough, all business and capital income is subject to the tax. In contrast to the Chinese income tax, the Indian income tax (which is much older, since it was created in 1922) has always treated all income sources equally: the progressive tax schedules apply to total individual income, irrespective of where the income comes from. Another important difference is that the tax schedule has been changed almost constantly in India during the 1986-2004 period, resulting into a general decline in tax rates and a continuous increase in the exemption threshold (see Table 2). From our perspective, the first important implication of these differing evolutions is that the exemption threshold (for wage earners) has increased less than inflation (and much less than nominal incomes) in China since 1986, while it increased approximately at the same rate as inflation in India, resulting into a massive increase in the proportion of the population subject to the income tax in China and a more modest increase in India (see Figures 5, 6 and 7). In China, the exemption threshold in 1986 (9600 yuans) was about 7 times larger than average individual urban income (1394 yuans), so that less than 0,1% of all wage earners were subject to the income tax. By 2001, the exemption threshold (12000 yuans) was less than 15% larger than average individual urban income (10787 yuans), so that 32,2% of all wage earners were subject to tax according to our estimates. In India, the exemption threshold has always been set around 2-3 times average income during the 1986-2001 period, and it is only because of the rise in top income shares that the proportion of the population subject to the income tax has increased somewhat during this period (from 0,7% in 1986 to 3,8% in 2001). This is an important rise from an historical perspective (the proportion of the population subject to the 79 Indian income tax had been relatively stable around 0,5%-1% between the 1920s and the early 1990s), but this is clearly much less than in China: due to lower bracket indexation and higher real income growth, the Chinese income tax has become a mass tax during the 1990s, while it remains an elite tax in India. Assuming that China's 2004 income tax law applies until 2010 (i.e. there is no further rise in the exemption threshold after 2004) and the income trends (both in average income and top income shares) continue after 2001 at the same rate as during the 1996-2001 period, our projections indicate that almost two thirds of Chinese urban wage earners (over 200 millions individuals) will be subject to the income tax by 2010 (see Figure 8). One important question, however, is whether the Chinese income tax law is really being applied in practice. I.e. do all individuals who are supposed to be subject to the income tax according to the law really pay the income tax? Many observers in and outside China seem to believe that tax authorities make deals with large firms and autonomous regions or cities whereby the latter offer a lump-sum payment to tax authorities and their employees and residents are not subject to the official income tax schedule. Unfortunately, there does not seem to exist any reliable statistics on the number of income tax taxpayers in China (let alone tabulations of taxpayers by income brackets, similar to what is being published in India and other countries), so we cannot compare our theoretical numbers of taxpayers with the actual numbers. However we can use data on aggregate income tax revenues and compare it to theoretical tax revenues in order to evaluate how strictly the law is being applied. We compiled from China Tax Yearbooks aggregate income tax revenues series for 1996-2001, broken down by income source (wage income, business income, capital income and other income) for 2000-2001. This very useful decomposition of tax revenues does not seem to be available prior to 2000. The comparison between actual tax revenues and theoretical tax revenues is given on Table 3. The first conclusion emerging from Table 3 is that actual income tax revenues are reasonably in line with theoretical tax revenues (as a first-order approximation), thereby suggesting that income tax collection in China is somewhat less chaotic and arbitrary than what many observers tend to assume. In 1996, actual income tax receipts made 0,28% of GDP, and theoretical receipts 0,33% of GDP; in 2001, actual income tax receipts made 1,02% of GDP, and theoretical receipts 0,66% of GDP (Table 3). If we look separately at receipts by income source for 2001, we find theoretical receipts on capital income were equal to 40% of actual receipts (this reflects the 80 fact capital income in under-reported in surveys), and that the corresponding figure was 64% for business income (business income is also under-reported in surveys, but less severely than capital income) and 96% for wage income. The latter figure could be interpreted as saying that wage income is fully reported in surveys, and that tax law if fully applied (all wage earners who are supposed to pay the income tax do pay it). Such an interpretation might well be misleading, however. There are good reasons to believe that top wages are under-reported in SSB household surveys, in which case the fact that theoretical receipts (based upon under-reported top wages) and actual receipts coincide merely reflects the fact that collection rate is less than 100%. If we adjust top survey wages so as to obtain reasonable Pareto coefficients for the distribution, we find that theoretical receipts for wage income are equal to 216% of actual income, i.e. the tax collection rate for wage income is less than 50%. Although the problem is probably less severe than what many observers tend to assume, these illustrative (and highly uncertain) computations suggest that there does exist a tax collection problem in China. It is also interesting to note that actual receipts have increased at a significantly higher rate than theoretical receipts during the 1996-2001period. One interpretation could be that tax collection has improved. Another interpretation is that household surveys underestimate not only the levels of top incomes, but also the upward trend in top income shares. In order to get a sense of the likely magnitude of this effect, we computed by how much the upward trend in top income shares needs to be scaled up in order to ensure that the trend theoretical receipts does match the trend in actual receipts. We find that the 2001 top 1% share should be scaled up by about 35% relatively to the top 1% share in 1996, which is substantial (see Figure 9). Although there is some uncertainty about the quality of tax collection and survey data, actual and theoretical tax receipts both show that income tax receipts (as a fraction of GDP) have increased substantially during the 1990s. The contrast with India is particularly striking: while Indian income tax revenues have stagnated around 0,5%-0,6% of GDP during the 1990s, Chinese income tax revenues have been multiplied by more than 10, from less than 0,1% of GDP in the early 1990s to over 1% of GDP in 2001 (see Figure 10). The stagnation of Indian tax revenues reflects the fact that tax rates have been continuously reduced (see Table 2) and that the proportion of individuals subject to tax has increased only modestly (see Figure 7). The 81 substantial rise in Chinese tax revenues reflects the facts that tax rates have remained the same (see Table 1) and that the proportion of individuals subject to tax has increased enormously (see Figure 7). Note that Chinese tax revenues would be substantially larger in the absence of a preferential tax treatment given to top wage earners over top business and capital income earners. We computed that if the business income tax schedule was applied to wage income as well, then Chinese income tax revenues in 2001 would be more than 3% of GDP (instead of 1%). Although this preferential tax treatment of wage income might raise serious political problems in the medium run (as independent workers feel more and more disadvantaged as compared to top wage earners in large firms), as it did in other countries where similar preferential tax treatment was applied (such as France), removing this legal provision is however unnecessary to ensure the growth of Chinese income tax revenues. Because of the phenomenal growth in average incomes (and even more so of top incomes), income tax revenues should make much more than 1% of GDP in 2010. According to our projections, which are based on the assumption that tax law will not be changed after 2004 and that income trends will remain the same as in the 1996-2001 period, income tax revenues in China should make about 4,3% in GDP by 2010 (see Figure 11). The assumption that the exemption threshold will not be raised after 2004 does not seem unreasonable, given that the 2004 increase in the exemption threshold was fairly high (from 12000 to 14400 yuans, i.e. 20%) and that inflation is currently very close to 0%. Moreover our projected tax revenues estimates should be viewed as a lower bound, first because we assumed that the survey-based trends and levels in top shares were not under-estimated (in particular we did not make the adjustment reported on Figure 9), and next because we assumed that there would be no improvement in tax collection (1996-2001 show that there has been some improvement in tax collection and/or an under-estimated rise in survey-based top income shares). In other words, there are good reasons to believe that the income tax will raise at least 4% of GDP in China by 2010. If this happens, then China will have gone through its fiscal revolution. As Table 4 illustrates, moving from an elite income tax raising less than 1% of GDP to a mass income tax raising around 4-5% of GDP is exactly the kind of process through which Western countries during the 1914-1950 period (when their income levels were similar to current Chinese levels). Although 82 Indian income tax revenues will probably increase during the coming years, the prospects for India look less good, both because of lower income growth and higher bracket indexation. One reason why India faces more difficulties than China in making its income tax a mass tax might also be that the proportion of formal wage earners in the labor force is ridiculously low in India. 83 Bibliography [1] A. Banerjee and A. Newman (2003), "Inequality, Growth and Trade Policy", mimeo, 2003 [2] A. Banerjee and T. Piketty, "Top Indian Incomes, 1922-2000", mimeo, MIT and EHESS (Paris-Jourdan), 2003 [3] S. Chen and Y. Wang, "China's Growth and Poverty Reduction: Recent Trends between 1990 and 1999", mimeo, World Bank, 2001 [4] A. Deaton, "Adjusted Indian Poverty Estimates for 1999-2000", Economic and Political Weekly, January 25, 2003 [5] R. Eckaus, A. Lester and N. Qian, "Income Inequality in a Transitional Economy: China as a Case Study", mimeo, MIT, 2003 [6] M. Kremer and E. Maskin, "Globalization and Inequality", mimeo, Harvard, 2003 [7] Piketty, Thomas (2003), "Income Inequality in France, 1901-1998", Journal of Political Economy 111, 1004-1042 [8] Piketty, Thomas and Emmanuel Saez (2003), "Income Inequality in the United States, 1913-1998", Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 1-39 [9] M. Ravallion and S. Chen, "When Economic Reform is Faster than Statistical Reform: Measuring and Explaining Income Inequality in Rural China", mimeo, World Bank, 2003 [10] S. Tendulkar, "Organized Labour Market in IndiaSchool of Economics, 2003 84 Pre and Post Reform", mimeo, Delhi [11] S.J. Wei and Y. Wu, "Globalization and Inequality: Evidence from Within China", NBER Working Paper 8611 (2001) 85 o00 -o -C a1) U) 0 CS a Ca) ')c . - a)- a 3 a) 0m E C-l -0 0 ma r t 0 -c U) a) I 'r I . I r 4 (B I iC f 1 I 00 o00 S n .0 -co C a) Co U) o o = n -d ._ ,CL 0 C- 0'' ,L 0 ~ , oa) C) o = 0 Icu>5 D E o CL C) .- ':.- Cu Wa) 0aVa) LC)= W0 c mC *C',1 L N I rs 0n 0 c C. m. co m -n CD -C U) ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~M.^ .: w C 0 0, 0 Um C .5 .,c *0o0 C- Y O i 0)V u 0.L2 0 _0.0 10 (co0 (0 C CCU) L) Cu6 C O a5 T 20U 0 CuCu 1 ) I- -, u, <I- m 0. 0.Q Cu Sr c h gC QL c n 00 cO * .s ;: . " , : U) 0 m 1) U))0 Qa, Ii 0- 1 of'if. 0 .D I J! C: 0 0 . U) =C m0 _0 C') a, -c c c tD 00 C 0) 0) - C) $ Cu C3u 0 ii ' N f= 0 o 0 - OC4 co CO 0m 0 0 i m m Q) E ox 00 a) D s00o a 0 00 - o - >C)< CD U) o0I Cu bC- Ct.) x U) (- CO U. a) -o - I- a) 02) EL 00 -r U) 'C U- ) C') C' U U 0 20 o20 20 20 20 6o 20 6 2 6 20 selel~l o uoloeJ_- 6 0 6 20 a) 6 z0 ·- a) O D a).o (.)- a, -; . 0 o 0 K 0 c a0 0 c - m co -2 o a) occi U) .0) ) - cw 80 0 c- , c o C " c Cu I N I, -C = cc c0)c ' - 2 a) L clc .2) 2 a ) O- a) D CD N - ~!a) - .?U1 C N a)D Oa) rD - a) a2 ) cn E)i a) 0 , ur ) 0) c cc~~~ So ~ c cO ot.D o o cN o0 o 00 o co occ 0-a- 0c-i 0 cc 0)~~~ o cc o cc 0o0 .i 0 0 C' _ c) o0 Icn ~~~c OO - Zo c 0 0 U) .-c o r- 0) -c u) 0 0W_0 -- o. a,) Lo o F co I-0 o c~ 0 .. =C Co o O0 0 0) o Cu 1- - 0 a: -; am- =o tn~'4 "00'a) r- o) 0) cc ~~~~i7 ~A> <Da) en N) a) L ~~~~~D O >o~ U-. I ) CR .to_ 0) . ow 0) ~Cu Ov a) cc cc tg 0O 00 0 c 0 O L, 0 0 cc 0 cc 0n' 0 'i 0 c-i 0 0 0 0 CD 0 'I 0 c-I 0 t ou C"' 0 0 - oo Em 00. 00,0 0O C aC O 3Cl .-o' a) u ) C) 0 O 'o O sa mid ia- C3C 0 cc a.) 0 Co 0) C =)d 0o ~ z ( 2o , 0,) E 0CIO O scm - 00- C r.0) C) .o ira. *- ooE Nz o 0c Lo 'a.O* z oo o Co o 0 Z 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 o o 0 o o 0 o - N 0 -o Li *-Q oE°o |OmCl o -- a) ( o48 co CCo EC E Co o o Co v O 0 0 T 0 cm 0 I N 0 O0 0 0 N 0 o 0 0 0 Co 0 6> 000ooo'o01. /8Ai' 0) o - (0 T o M N - 0 - C C -c Co 2O tL -~'o a) aa _' o 0) a ' 0 Co C O0D o O o. U) ~.- 0) a) r- *0 m Lm Co 0 OD - 0 CD C ~0Q <im._ 0O aI0 (L V --O i ')r-CYC- LO ,U) · 0) °a Co ci) -5 I- a)CD C C0v ) -0 . "- Co C , 6 CO elH/ H 000L N - 0 75 ) U0C o ~o o o z C o oo . cO0)~l CE C~l ,-,~~~~~~~u) >- -- -) gV C E U)(V~~~~U a) CO C)( 'E co ._. CD co D (U) ~~ 0) . 0 cn · ~ b E',, .C o 8 'a r_ Ca) ci C 0o (Lo 0 0 0 00 Co 0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~1)0 V 0 Cli LO N N C - o 0 -z L( 0 Figure 5A- Fraction of Males in Counties which Plant Some Tea and Counties which Plant No Tea 0.54 0.53 0.52 0.51 0.5 0.49 1962 1966 1970 1974 1978 Birth Year -No 1982 1986 1990 Tea -Tea Figure 5B - The Effect of Category 1 and 3 Crops on Sex Ratios Coefficients of the Interactions Birth Year * Amount of Category 1 Crops Planted and Birth Year * Amount of Category 2 Crops Planted in Unrestricted Sex Ratios Equation 0.03 0.02 0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.03 -0.03 I 1964 I I 1968 I I , 1972 , i I 1976 r 1980 i Il I 1984 I I I 1988 Year -- Cat 1 .- Cat 3 93 Cu c 0= 0 0 0 Cu o0. 0 m =0 a) E .2 .C S° O Cuc l\s / 0IC a) _U O 3CW 0a) 0~m am ca ,_ cn Cd)0 Cn C 0 W 4a)X -oC C6 \ N U =00-0 .52c C.) . _ 00 ~ o-x .) I a) EL0a) o O co a) I o N - o 0) .- Ecn C.) co 0) m e 0 Ci 0 6 6 O C) C'J 0 O 0 O -O N Cm 0 0 0 o_ 2 m CU) C i 7C-- 0 r C.- xO 0) XOo U) < Z, c-w oo CO a)6 C0 CD 0: 0 E C- U 0)n *) 03) fC- a) I...= o Cu a) oO . C- 0- 01 m 0.O - a) Io; *5. Cu U a) ;z a) = .,- ,- Ca0 T = Cu a) CO CO 0 c o a) C.) CO Cu 0; 6 0 0 o 6 o~~~~~~~~ 0 6~ o0 C 90 0- 90 U) 0O 90 t3 ao) o Uw ._L a 4) .I-r cm x 0o o aO < 0 r CS co O .2n O W 4 >- co i ,a) C'. n D U), 0) , 0 C 0 C - I (2= C2) U. 0 co Ca) - C)w 0L _0. CD o ~._W Cl SO / ~Cu _) . i t) I-r 0 U) ,- t t a) a) .- ;a) .. 0V m C. 6 0o 6 0 0 6 c, 0 0 Figure 7 - The Effect of Planting Tea and Orchards on Girls' Education Attainment Coefficients of the Interactions Birth Year * Amount of Tea Planted and Birth Year * Amount of Orchards Planted in Pooled Education Equation 0.15 -0.1 0.1 -0.3 0.05 -0.5 0 U, ° -0.05 -0.7 O -0.15 -0.9 -0.2 -1.1 ..0 -0.1 (U !-- -0.25 -1.3 -0.3 -0. 35 -1.5 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 Birth Year - Orchards - Tea 95 C -1 ~ oo CO O ON 0 C0 0 0 ON N- C CD0O 0 Co 0 0 0 oo 0 00 00_ 00 00 ON00 Ci) N -D N 0 CD Co 0 CO Co 0 ) 666666 0 N) · N CO 0 OO r0 o;o oo 000o 0O0 0 o'00 C) 0 0 0 CD C .t CO LO ~''It o ~d N Co 0 0 0C U 0 N C) CD 0 -D C mCD ) * o N 00 O) c o N C N 0C o o N o ooCoCC 'O 6666 N CD O CD 'r- 0 c. O ~: tO 0 0) o) 0 !O!! °°°Olrl CO Duo O stt m FD FC o- tDC 0 C0 q) 0') 0 o 0 0 0 00 o0) 009 O9 0. o o 0 0 0 o 0 0 0 0 000 o o o66 0) 000 oOo0 ) E 6~ E) O; ; O0 o U) C 00 Co 0 C00 0 C) ~r~' 0 0 0 N Co 66ooo o Oa a a 0 U) u) 0 in0 . q 0 0 COC LO 0 N 0 0 0 o CD ) 0 0 N CD 0 0 oq 6 O o O) o~ q sa.ss.as. N N N 0 0 0 o '- N CD CD~ 0 0 0 NCD 0 0 q0 C N- o q . o <0 0 0 ~ O - gg ._'r ._ N- C 0 0 0 Qo ~-o O CO 0 CO > CO CO D 0 SR (D CD NOCO O- I CO CO CO ur uR COUR CD CD CD CD CD -t It -It w 'I) t CD uC1-CD rCD N- N Co C - CD CD CD CD C 0 0 0 0 CN , 0C C N NO CD N- C O U- 'C) co:) cl CDt CD CD CD N co (D CD CD N O0 O0t O O, 0 0 0 0 I- C U) 0 Co CD co D 0o CN N 't ~~36 o E Rlo C 0*0I0 D 0)Cu ~ CD CD CD CO C 0: Co COCo CO cN N "t N 6 X )- o N > 0 - .U) V 'U =g_ c) -ZX :51 co D C CD .x II ~iLC 0 U) 0) a) s F- 3U) 00 - 0 CU U) 0. 0 > 0 CU co N CD 0 E · U) 0 O o 0 o g= '=EU _C- w L) VS ) .c,°o s _~a) C CV.8--- I_ U) Cu 0 Eoo- * o) -~ 0o C)0 gU) o C C UIO 0 0. U) o- a 4Li Co . U) 00O OL*, o .- 0._= m a) 4- 0 _) _ e uEEs° C 0 0X /) U <c- -3 . Cu U) c 6 C) >~ N 2 'sO .0 CD C ii 0 cn 3 0n c CUC C: Cf) C- c C: 0 0 § Cu CDi- 0 0 C/) Ca) W Cu a) C0 a) .) E in= Cu 0 U) wOO0 Table 2 - The Effects of Tea, Orchards and Cash Crops on Fraction of Males (Unrestricted): Coefficients of the Interactions between Dummies Indicating Birth Year and the Amount of Tea, Orchards or Category 2 Cash Crops Planted in the County of Birth Dependent Variable: Fraction of Males Tea Orchards (1) Cat 2 Cash Crops (2) (3) Birth Year Coeff. Std. Error Coeff. Std. Error Coeff. Std. Error 1963 -0.005 (0.013) 0.001 (0.005) 0.000 (0.002) 1964 0.005 (0.023) 0.003 (0.006) -0.001 (0.002) 1965 -0.026 (0.013) 0.000 (0.005) -0.003 (0.002) 1966 -0.009 (0.014) 0.003 (0.005) -0.001 (0.002) 1967 -0.014 (0.015) 0.003 (0.005) 0.000 (0.002) 1968 -0.021 (0.014) -0.003 (0.005) -0.003 (0.002) 1969 0.001 (0.015) 0.000 (0.005) -0.001 (0.002) 1970 -0.022 (0.016) -0.007 (0.007) -0.004 (0.002) 1971 -0.008 (0.011) 0.002 (0.006) -0.002 (0.002) 1972 -0.012 (0.010) -0.006 (0.005) -0.003 (0.002) 1973 -0.022 (0.011) -0.007 (0.006) -0.004 (0.002) 1974 -0.019 (0.014) 0.000 (0.005) -0.003 (0.002) 1975 -0.014 (0.012) -0.008 (0.007) -0.002 (0.002) 1976 -0.002 (0.019) -0.005 (0.006) -0.002 (0.002) 1977 -0.010 (0.018) -0.003 (0.005) -0.002 (0.002) 1978 -0.023 (0.014) -0.005 (0.006) -0.004 (0.002) 1979 -0.006 (0.011) 0.003 (0.006) -0.002 (0.002) 1980 -0.031 (0.015) 0.000 (0.005) -0.004 (0.002) 1981 -0.021 (0.015) 0.001 (0.006) -0.004 (0.002) 1982 -0.024 (0.011) 0.010 (0.005) 0.000 (0.002) 1983 -0.029 (0.015) 0.003 (0.005) -0.002 (0.002) 1984 -0.035 (0.018) -0.003 (0.005) -0.005 (0.002) 1985 -0.026 (0.016) 0.002 (0.005) -0.003 (0.002) 1986 -0.028 (0.014) -0.003 (0.005) -0.004 (0.002) 1987 -0.016 (0.016) 0.003 (0.005) -0.001 (0.002) 1988 -0.042 (0.012) -0.006 (0.006) -0.006 (0.002) 1989 -0.037 (0.019) 0.000 (0.005) -0.005 (0.002) 1990 -0.037 (0.018) 0.010 (0.006) -0.003 (0.002) Observations R-Squared 49082 49082 49082 0.14 0.14 0.14 All regressions include county and birth year fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at county level. 97 Table 3 - The Effects of Tea, Orchards and Cash Crops on Fraction of Males (Pooled): Coefficients of the Interactions Between Dummies Indicating Birth Year and the Amount of Tea, Orchards and Category 2 Cash Crops Planted in the County of Birth Dependent Variable: Fraction of Males Orchards Tea (1) Cat 2 Cash Crops (2) (3) Coeff. Std. Error (0.009) 0.000 (0.002) (0.010) -0.001 (0.002) 0.012 (0.009) -0.003 (0.002) 0.011 (0.009) -0.001 (0.002) (0.018) 0.002 (0.009) 0.000 (0.002) -0.014 (0.017) 0.003 (0.009) -0.003 (0.002) 1969 0.013 (0.018) 0.011 (0.009) -0.001 (0.002) 1970 -0.013 (0.019) 0.001 (0.010) -0.004 (0.002) 1971 0.008 (0.014) 0.016 (0.011) -0.002 (0.002) 1972 -0.003 (0.014) 0.002 (0.010) -0.003 (0.002) 1973 -0.001 (0.013) 0.003 (0.010) -0.004 (0.002) 1974 -0.003 (0.017) 0.014 (0.010) -0.003 (0.002) 1975 -0.021 (0.016) -0.012 (0.011) -0.002 (0.002) 1976 0.003 (0.023) -0.002 (0.012) -0.002 (0.002) 1977 0.001 (0.021) 0.006 (0.009) -0.002 (0.002) 1978 -0.008 (0.016) 0.008 (0.009) -0.004 (0.002) 1979 0.009 (0.014) 0.015 (0.010) -0.001 (0.002) 1980 -0.014 (0.017) 0.014 (0.009) -0.004 (0.002) -0.004 (0.002) Birth Year Coeff. Std. Error Coeff. Std. Error 1963 -0.005 (0.016) 0.001 1964 0.019 (0.026) 0.015 1965 -0.013 (0.016) 1966 0.000 (0.016) 1967 -0.015 1968 1981 0.003 (0.018) 0.022 (0.010) 1982 -0.014 (0.014) 0.017 (0.010) 0.000 (0.002) 1983 -0.021 (0.018) 0.009 (0.008) -0.002 (0.002) 1984 -0.016 (0.021) 0.012 (0.009) -0.005 (0.002) 1985 -0.006 (0.019) 0.017 (0.009) -0.003 (0.002) 1986 -0.016 (0.017) 0.006 (0.009) -0.004 (0.002) (0.002) 1987 -0.005 (0.018) 0.014 (0.009) -0.001 1988 -0.025 (0.015) 0.008 (0.009) -0.005 (0.002) 1989 -0.015 (0.022) 0.019 (0.009) -0.005 (0.002) 1990 -0.013 (0.023) 0.029 (0.011) -0.002 (0.002) Observations 49082 R-Squared 0.14 All regressions include county and birth year fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at county level. 98 t Ea - 0o o oo 0000 0 0 co - (D °,o ° 0l> 00 C o a) a) o E 0 o c C) m-_ cuz 0) CUa0 c 030 4) 0 0) a) X E U) o,~*oo CU C o ) 8 o~* CD cD tC0 *:O o 2 v w U) C 0 0 0 -. U) C-3 C 0 0 sc in 0u .2 c 4) O- .C 0 0 c I a) C o (DRno 0) ot EF l 0u CD CO 0es)0q qC) 066 C) 0 00 O0 000)6C 2 °) co q0 qC) 0W ) Z0 O CU U) . 03 E 0 06 4 E) V CUO su 0 C V o a) -- a 0 4- C E 0 .E 0 0 OCUE C: 0 ' cE _ 0 CU a) 2 CU 8 X° a) U 00 O4 0Q.C @ - a) 0 0 <:OCU C-, 0) V 0 CU 0 0) > (n 0) 0; 9o 0 rI' -, U) 96 LO (D >- ... .). 0 a 0 -o ._o O- o: 9 0 o, o SI 'O CQ I- C) 0~~ Z LO LO oC z CDz, ~E 00 -= 0 0 -C JL u0 0 .c 0CeD U) =0o m C0D' U) 0o >- -O , o O UsC\J co c~~~~~~~~~c~ (O0 == C m ci 2 Cu 0 U) .0 CU *aO )°E) 0c ~0 0I~.Co > ~ ~o I" C o C RI Cu Cu U) 0 a) 0 CL) O 0 C j3c o 0) U) - Cu . U)- 0) 0 sa 0 U- js CD eo ~~~~~(0 C-. LO CDO n -Cl) Cu 0 0 cn-J 9906 'z -o0 0 0 cL ) Cs oO U) o~ .x, 0 a C U)0 C iLa) 0- -i C U)~~~~~~~~~~~~~l I-''D 0C U)u 0 _C ~0 0 o -D a) 0 o C C 0. C .C _ 0 0 n.?J 0o a) co 0 0 0 0 cu C 0 0 ( -o <r1 C s 1~ O cn a)M E E- a Ct 0) q Z 0:) co CD No4O C' CO ) OD o co V O9' ci C-' >C p 0 cu cu 0 'a a) c It) C - a; CO) oo _- 'a o o oo otU) C o 0) 0 66~ C.) CO C) 0n 0 R t 0~ca) I0a) ES~ -C .cU )c=o(/3 E .u' Ca) < 0, CD E 0, ILL co CO oo: u: C)~ O) , o,' oC 0 0. 0 00 It)c It O ". 5ooO9 - co ~o C~C C C. Cu 1u 0 C a o,_ OD- C 0 ooL 15 - (O o,' C CO CO) Ci C) N4 f LO C Cu o a) 0 I C 13.C c - -~ = o-0 u n 0 q-0~ 0 ,-- c'(9 C 0 C CD o 'o i0 oC) <tC .0 MI X ECOO CD 0, z5 0( c CD 0 - (0 (D V2 6 o o 0 u3 to x0O V B'O XC a) CD ~O co O O 9o c)a) C:' O 0 06 Io ,t COX C 3 9o 069C c : 0). 'tC co c 0?. Cu CD O0 0 I: 0. (0 c3 o cn 0 , a) 0 E :E N E 0, IL I'- LO C 6 C) C .oo (N0 L C ,.t CN N o. oN) ,6 c0 L) O 0 .I 0,~ xO X (9 m iR . O3 CDO CC CD · t j. oN 6o CI d C1i C) 96c a o0 .0 (9 0, 0, C C C 00, C 0 2 co c; ( CO -C (3Ea) o 0)0 0 *O.y C V Q-C a) 'Q 0_ a) I- 0) 0 0o a) 0 cC 0 0 Cu (N °Zot -0 V'a) ) 2 Onm 0, Cu 0,Q a) .0 .S Cu1V)U C1 c0 O - t C (NI U, o.- o 0 l----..-..--.----....... ........----....... I t a oL C-, C o I f O- 111 c X o .c0d V o <. N I I .72 co a) O) ) aw cm0 t4. ui . :2 I44) -x 0)o fa 0 S CU oC muC: , I0 c -0) - m 0 a) t C VD a) w C i CD 0) c. C: a) - ° 0 6 o s r U) .' V ' 0 6 C) 6 Cm N 0 6 0 Z0 0 0O 6 r | CN 0 M 4 0 0) r - Cl- C CII _,0, QW - w CL 0> 66 6 ci 6 6 . 6cm. C, CD c 0 U- x xL.X C') 0 0 99 a) X Dc C CnO )C1 O) 0 s 0O C- m -j n (D C- / 02~~~ aL OCU-- (n c 0, C C0s o) . 0 (U C,)O3 0 0) 3 ( m (U >-C O03 0)4 °:E O : -0 c3 UWUXi o0 c- CD o- 0 CD I)i. -- co (4) co a) .- <CU U) q 0 0 U)U) o C\ 0 C Lo 'I o c" o o o o o o oo N o C o o V: U) 0~ oC) U) 0 oS C) C) U aD 0 O R ooo6o 6 6 oo o666 6 oo C) o C) F3 C) ) ) C) C) C) O C) O co C)D 6 E) 6 ZC) C 6 C) C) C) Ca o x- o ~o 66 o v C N U)C Oq N, a) o 0 U- D i - O C)~ C C i U) 0 -I v O ON ~ ON Nq N 0 C C C C) D 0 N:- NZ- ; - i - LO - (C 0 - q Nq N, - - - C ) N 0 0 N - - 'It U)- M- 6 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 O9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 q Nq- D CO U) C C) U1) -C -5 -o2 0 Q ., 0n ( i 0 C N O) O O CO C) O) a a) a O OOO6 O O6O C ) C) C) 0 0 C C -* 0 0 - ' o C) C) C N- - O0 C C ) O0 N-- 0 0 C) F );;C co 0C) c50C) c 6)C) C)c ) O 0 C) C) C C o0 0 C C -:1- N-,: 0 0 0 0 0 C ) 0 j- C 6 6)o G) CN IC)2 -6 C 0 N CD C) t 0 0 - 0 0 0 CD CD ci) ra co c; c c a0 - a N 0 C0 C c c ;o 9 w M0 ON i . CO C) 0 0 N C0 ;c o o oo N 0 CD LO 0 )C N 0 U) "t ) 0 N0- o o o o o o o 0 ~- CA) C 0N 0 0 C) C) C) 06 - N C) C) C) a C 0 C C C v- U' CO m~ w- N-z N:0 m C C) C C C c)c 0 C) 0 0 C) aCa a a) Nq C 0 N Oa a a C) C C C) C C C oc)666 , 0) R C ) C) - 0 C 0 C 6 6 a C) 0 C 0 C R N v- C C 0 ~' a aC a) 0ci C0ooU w LONtm 't U)C(D LO 0N m t C) o m U~0C m ' (D NC) 0o 0 m 0 0tm N N 0 C) 9~~~ o od o 00 o o- 0Do00 o U)C o -- C) ) o- C) N d C0 9 C) C 9 C C C) C) C) C) c) C) c) C) c) C) C C C 9 9 C 9 9 C) oU)t N 0 (I, ) C) 9 C CD 00 -j0 'O o ci U0 w~ En V6 0 ~uC1 IE2 0 0) 0 C) 0 C) C) C) C) C C C) C) C) C) 0 0 N- N- C) c3 C) o C) :. oc3 C) C) C) C) C) C) oa C) 0n C) C) N::- N- N-, N-: C) C) C) 0 0 0 0 C) NC: C C NZ- N- 0a C C C C) R- o) c3)o ,) ~;N C) ) C CD tt) 0 9~ c) 0 9 o a 0 C) U) N- CD 0 C) C C) C) C) C) 9 C) 6 9) 9 99 C)0 .C)C C) 9 0 qC)q 0 CD CD N-_ NC C) C) C) ~ C) C) C) 0 C) o C) 9- co Io w-CDo0C,C) N) 0 C) C) C) C) v6C)N C CC) C) C) C) 2a) 666 0) 00o CD 0D D C) -D -C c 0 O O o N C C) C) 0 C6666a~ CD U) N 0 0 0) 0 N- U) CD C) C) a a aO a Cco 6 a a a 0o a0a6 C) C) C C o- ot C) C C) 0 - r-0 C C) - a3 .11. C) C) C) 0 LO C) 6666o C) 0U N N-- CC) Cq C) C)C)C)6O6 Q -C CD a) 0ai) - C) !PCD N tt, 0 C0 N U C C ooooM 0 N C M t C N N N- C N C ) C 9 C 9 C 9 C) C) C 9 9 9 - w'- C Oq v ~ 9 C) C) N N- 9 C) 9 - U C) C) C 9 C) C) 'o .C cC:_ co, 03 CoU;: U) U) 00 -j ) U C C C 6 6 66 NU) C) CD (O U) CD O CD (O C) C C C C) C) a C) ~' N C C) 'It CO ~0 666 C C) C U) No 0N 0- 0O co C CD CO ' C) C C a C ) C C o a C)oC C C 6 66 N U) CD - CD U) C C) C) C 6 CD LO I- C ) C C) 0 00 00 LU a)-- '- =; 0c .-C~ tCU iE 3 0 M N- "I c Di to U) LC 0C N- LO U) U) U) ~0 CD N- - D N C N U) N 0 N N 0 U)0 909U) 9N- N C) 90) 9N 0 0) 9 C 9 9 9 t 6 6 C ) 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6606 9 96 90 06 C C C C C 0 C i U) i CD CD Di NC i 0 c Di 0 CD i C)O~ N- NDi i O N N.Di 0 Ni t NDi U) Ni CD NDi NNi 0 NDi 0 C Nl- 0 i Di 0 i N 0 Di 0 0 i .0 Di U) 0 i CO 0 Di N0 Di 0 0 D Di 0 Di C 6 g ci -C= CU -c .0 0 CU) 0 C- C) Di Di A o Table A2 - Differences-in-Differences Estimates of the Effect of Planting Tea and Orchards on Sex Ratios: Coefficients of the Interactions between Dummies Indicating Whether a Cohort was Born Post Reform and Dummies Indicating Whether Any Tea was Planted in the County of Birth Dependent Variable: Log Sex Ratio Tea * Post (1) (2) -0.039 -0.029 (0.010) (0.011) Orchards * post 0.027 (0.013) Observations R-Square 30355 30355 0.13 0.13 All regressions includes controls for category 2 cash crop*post, post and county fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at county level. 104 Table A3 - Descriptive Statistics of 0.1% Sample of the 2000 Population Census Counties that Plant no Tea Counties that Some Tea Obs Mean Std. Err. Obs Mean Std. Err. Fraction of Male 81774 53.31% 0.0017 25290 53.56% 0.0031 Fraction of Han 81774 93.47% 0.0008 25290 86.05% 0.0019 Years of Education 81774 7.14 0.0110 25290 6.89 0.0198 Male-Female Education 58590 0.55 0.0071 18034 0.55 0.0141 Fraction with Tap Water 81441 31.39% 0.0012 25182 37.60% 0.0021 Cohorts born 1962-1986 Birth Year x County Cells 105 U) R _ N O 2. m0 (D O 0 C N C C O~ OIOD- C O C O - O - O O ~" ; 2 ~' C N"~ 0 O O O 6O O O O 0 O O O O O O O_ O_~ O 0O _) v ON ) ,)N DU)0 O dO)O) U) N C 0O 0C OO O0 OC) N 0 t O D C (D C) 1) NMNN NNN - NN-)MNMN C -t - D t t 0 O CD O tO O N O O O Ct O OD C) O O) O O O0OD O) N O CD O O) L) O O U) O N CDNCoD C) 0D 'a) 0 05 66 C D-W)0ON O O O Cl) N O U 0 O C 0 OO (D - N U) I O d v) C)6 N ) C N d N 0 C ) N CC' N Nt CD )DM 0oot000 UtD )t6o6o666 u ur ) M rC CD :C 00t U) 0 Cl 000 00 ovu) OC '-E0o .'m . C OC== 'U) o -i oo c < O O:o 0 Cu Z a) c 0 Cu I '2 M CD Cl)O CD N1 Cl) C) Cl Cl) a) ~ ~ C w() N C N- N C)) " C) - N ~ ~ ~ ~ ' -Cl 't ' C) N C)N ~ C O -'-C) U) d~ ~ ~ ~ ~ C ) O O O N CD Cl U) C) Cl) CD ~ t- - 1 ~ ~ ~ O 0 CO C) C') t- D t CCD U) 00 U) U C) ~ ~ ~ O ~ ~ U' U) cu U) 0CNl )NCDN NNNC(DCsd--CDtF N O 0N l) N O O O 0 O U m) IOdOODC CD O Cl) NO 0O)CD m CD N N O 0UDN CO N 0O O O O OO OO OO vO t o _0 a) 0 U) .T m~ 0U)C 0o U) OD d 0 N c CD N U) t s N N a u) U-) CD C)! O ov 6666666666O F N -C CD C) C-- N U) :- 0 C') LO)N 0) LO O O O O ..... o. .o7 OS O aoao _ ON _6_6 CuQ) a) s-C C a0 a a 0 x 696o t o oM t m o (o oooo6O6ooo9o9O6 w oD 0 rccm Oru LU) Cu> 0m) CS r- C) Cu 0-ocn O a) o m m o 666666666666666666 N ~U) 0 C- a N CD0OO0 -00 ~ v cn =Z aO n (O CD C N 0) - 0 U) N N N N N N N .) N N C) 0 C N N N Cl) U) L CD U)0 C) U N- 0' N C OOOOO°°°°°°°°°°°°°°_ n C N N N N 0 ) C) N mc)N N N 0 CDCl) 0N - r N U N ,) ) o D CD U) 0 CD N O 9969699969699969999 ~0 a) rC nC-f 0 (n C-) .0 C cua)e0- 0 O, U -D U) 00 CD a) 0 0 N OU - CD C-) N 0 0 D U 00 - Cl N'- C t° CO Oo D 00 00, C) U) CDN m 0 C0 o6 U) C 0 N'- Ut C C t D U) N U) 0 U CD CD CD N U)c CD-C) N ,0 U) _ 0) Cm ND C DU) N CD IN U) CD CD CD N- 0I CD U) N U) Cl CD0 U^)~ cq Cl) (D U) C CD) 0 CD '0w C'O cDt t0D N oo d U 0) N 0 (O ~ Ci° O) 0NsNe 0 (O ~ N(D 0d0 0~ 00 ) 0 tUO o 'o I U) D C C) C) CD CD C CD N C) C) C) C) N CJ) C) C) N N N N N C) C) C) C) C) N N CD CD CD C) C) C) C) 0 * CY -0)I - In 0 ( 0 N 02 ) ) m - - .- w m t O - - 0 -o 0 O 0 0 0 N N N N 0m) 0 CO N uO 0 o - 0 a) a 0 r (U 0 o(Da) C> 0 N . ONO mOCOO O- C O O cC O 0O NO ) .-O O CDO O- 0) O O '') U) 0) C 0) N ND OO o OD-O O U) C) NO CO N- C)X N C- N N N N N C) CD O) CiC) - N N N N C ) O 0 ) C) C, 0 I.. a0cn a) In a) E2 0 0m) C) C C-2 ) u) NO t ) N C'- N N 0 1 O) C) U) N O CMO 1) t) (0 N CO U) C d O NU) C) .LO) oo666666666666666666 0 C') 0) UJ C0) N C') N C) N N- C 00) a0) C) N D N N CO N C) CO U&) C) NC N- CD N- N N ) c o LOCD -1 00C6 - 0O CD a U 0 ' T .) Ut) CO . O .4 L CO U) C,) 0 ~ 'C ._ a)0 1- I_--- cm mog C 6666 0 0 0 0 0 O N -O) D 0 L O O CO O N CO U) ~ N 0) CO )U) 0 ) ) O O O 0 ~ .4 U O 0It N N 00 * U ) CO 0 N C) 0) 0) 0) O 0) M CO .- 0) 0 .4 N C)0 w - ~ O ~ O C) U) .m N to 00 ) N CdO t 0t 0 ) Of O M C) - cO L 0 CO 0) u) 0) Ct 0 CO NN U) 0) N 0 0 O ~ NC CO C ) U C N 0 s0 O 00 ~ ~ ~ N- U') N U 0 .4 0 ~ ~ t Uc) - .4 ) N D ) Cl) 'O m -c m In 0o a) a U) 00 0 a (U W, 00 0 0 O 0 Nl 0 co 0) O O O CO C N ) NO t0 0 O) N ) 0) CO 0) Nc N 0).N N o I) . t 0 co C NO a) L Ca 0 '- a, o_r *X 0 'O 0 o= °a0< rn a, C 0 (U C) 0 t N . ) 20 0) U) 0 4 .- 0) N- 0) 0) m U) N.) C) N () N cO CO(0(0 . C N 0) 0 CO - 0 0 0 C') CO C') 0 LO ) CD C C 0 CD CO 0) CO 0 .- N- .4 C' 0 C') .4 CO ) .4 NO co :3a) *0>CD a,t a') O N N- O C' 00 wi .C 0 0 in 0 N- U) C' O CO N CO 00 C' 0 N.4 o .4 N CO LI) c 0) -C 'O X C') co) 0 CO U) C') C ) 666666 Oo Ooooo6666ooo oo (U ua 0 CO C') U) Ue Vu LU L cO NCO . a, ¢ - a) F- N N.4 N a) ,N U)CO 0N N-U) N 0 N N (0 0 CO 0) "' 0 CO) CO) CO) C' 0 0 0 0 . c N CO~ ) ') Id' N CO) C 6 0 N NN u I' 6s )° - C' ) N N 0 0XCa Ca . 0 'a) .t N 1 t - - (0 0) I: U CO N - - N '-N 0 :._ -D U) C') o I4- C') C" 0 0 00a U)0- En oc2 oC'CO N N Co 0) 96690006666006066066 C~ . > s) )C o. o o o C: N~ "; -c (D CO , *t a) -2a) En a) c U) C U) I- a). c') C) S - UI) CO CO0 ) (0 CO C ( 0) (00) CO 0) 0) 0) C0 N0) -1 S tC' U) 0 N- C m ) 0 c N -0) -0 -0) 0)- 0)N- NN- NN- O CO 0) 0) 0) 0) 0) 0) 0) o U) 0 c a: - <C) Ca Figure 1A: The Effect of Relaxation on Family Size Coefficients of the Interactions between Born in a Relaxed Area * Birth Regions 0.5 0.45 0.4 0.35 0.3 - Girls -- Boys 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 Birth Year Figure 1 B: The Effect of Relaxation on Family Size Coefficients of the Interactions between Dummy for Girl * Born in a Relaxed Region * Birth Year 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 -0.05 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 Birth Year 1979 1980 1981 108 Figure 2A: The Effect of Relaxation on Sex Ratios of First Born Children and 95% Confidence Intervals Coefficients of the Interactions between Born in Relaxed Region * Birth Year 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 -0.()5 -0.1 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 Birth Year Figure 2B: The Effect of Relaxation on Sex Ratios of Second Born Children and 95% Confidence Intervals Coefficients of the Interactions between Bomrn in Relaxed Region * Birth Year 0.2 0.1 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 -0. 5 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 Birth Year 109 Figure 2C: The Effect of Relaxation on Sex Ratios of Later Born Children and 95% Confidence Intervals Coefficients of the Interactions between Born in Relaxed Region * Birth Year t A U., 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 Birth Year 110 Figure 3A: The Effect of Relaxation on School Enrollment Coefficients of Interactions between Born in Relaxed Region * Birth Year A n .,.,J 0-0.05 -*-Girls -0.1 - -Boys -0.15 -0.2 -0.25 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 Birth Year Figure 3B: The Effect of Relaxation on School Enrollment Coefficients of Interactions between Dummy for Girl * Born in Relaxed Region * Birth Year 0.1 0.05 0 -0.05 -0.1 -0.15 -0.2 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 Birth Year 111 Table 1: Descriptive Statistics CHNS 1989 and 0.1% Sample of China Population Census Obs Mean Han 13271 Siblings Std.Err. Obs Mean 0.944 (0.002) 15500 0.949 (0.002) 13271 1.153 (0.009) 15500 0.922 (0.008) Sisters 13271 0.504 (0.006) 15500 0.511 (0.006) Brothers 13271 0.649 (0.006) 15500 0.411 (0.005) Enrollment 13271 0.473 (0.004) 15500 0.456 (0.004) Mother's Education 12862 6.063 (0.037) 14890 5.668 (0.035) Father's Education 12134 8.058 (0.034) 14239 7.628 (0.033) Mother is Housewife 13271 0.119 (0.003) 15500 0.139 (0.003) Relaxed Area 13271 0.254 (0.003) 15500 0.242 (0.003) A. By Sex Female B. By Family Size Std. Err. Male Siblings Only Child Sex 19038 0.502 (0.004) 9733 0.611 (0.005) Han 19038 0.941 (0.002) 9733 0.958 (0.002) Enrollment 19038 0.399 (0.004) 9733 0.591 (0.005) Mother's Education 18488 5.300 (0.029) 9264 6.952 (0.048) Father's Education 17623 7.476 (0.027) 8750 8.530 (0.044) Mother is Housewife 19038 0.134 (0.002) 9733 0.121 (0.003) Relaxed Area 19038 0.279 (0.003) 9733 0.186 (0.003) No Relaxation C. By Relaxation Some Relaxation Sex 10828 0.544 (0.005) 17943 0.535 (0.004) Han 10828 0.968 (0.002) 17943 0.934 (0.002) Siblings 10828 1.048 ((0.010) 17943 1.016 (0.007) Sisters 10828 0.512 ((0.007) 17943 0.505 (0.005) Brothers 10828 0.536 (0.007) 17943 0.511 (0.005) Enrollment 10828 0.437 (0.005) 17943 0.480 (0.004) Mother's Education 10454 5.034 (0.040) 17298 6.345 (0.033) Father's Education 9914 7.439 (0.036) 16459 8.058 (0.031) Mother is Housewife 10828 0.111 ((0.003) 17943 0.141 (0.003) Relaxed Area 10828 180.299 (1.256) 17943 147.335 (1.195) Distance to Urban 9460 2.041 (0.017) 17943 11.849 (0.087) Agriculture 10818 0.720 (0.004) 17903 0.569 (0.004) Distance to Primary School Distance to Middle School 10828 10827 0.230 1.008 (0.006) 1(0.009) 16672 16672 0.399 1.584 (0.004) (0.011) Distance to High School 10827 4.920 (0.084) 16672 4.506 (0.067) Sample of cohorts born 1962-1981 112 Co N C) 0) (D to u. =E EF COil ~~ 0)C ~~' Co ~~ c'.0 J O CD (D 0 In °, a O cN R It N O , O°' O R M 0) Nt O Oa z 0) N OO,OOO OCD w O -t e- (0 C 0 - It) -)o U) ao # 9 C. o ) o °9O6 C) o N CD. O1 O6666OO6OO6OO6O O o O o c'. oc C)j 6O - COc ) 0a) toz 0O r Cs 0DO 6O -0 C .= X ._ O:._= DC .0 C-O O = c- cu C ' ,a CD OX m 't 0) O LO 0) o) O o N~ 0) 0) 0) 0) o 0) OU) 0) 0) 1~~~~~~~ ~ x 0 .- CD a) U) o 0 N a) E> CU _0 a) ca -O U a) &~ t- U) a) .0 aU X a) *a) a C C a) o 0 a O a) ) aa) C a) a -o U) C No co :. O ° C)O C (D C OC co ° o O °aO o o cN a 96 O ° O o g E . - op 00 a 9696 9 9 9 69 6996 ° w U) - .0 Co CO C) oo C) CO v-~~~~~ O ~~ ~ (NJ ~~N N N aoC C) ) R~ It) It 0) (N o o N- Coo,oCoo C) oc Co) o Co)oCo o o co (NJ Lo) - m~ () m~ m~ a) C) LO C C) LCO a) CO C) W U) X a) c _ o o-0NOOo CO cN 't. O,OO o0IO O O O O O O~ (O O, O 1O O ~ O O CO LO m~ It) CX C Cu 0 (NJ U) U) 0)0 C, U) r it C .5 0ca) _ CC O '-O ~-O - --- O ~-O ,N --~- O, NC) C C 666666-6666O L a a C aO- CD O ,r LO O ' C: 0 0~1 ,r CO v~- LO ~~- LO O CO~' 'O, ~- CO ~ O ~- LO O v- T° EE -s-s C) C) ._C Cu.n C .2C--- ~CO : C C i 0i U) U) oo~ 0 a) a) a) t) a , 02 0cn C-) o, a) CD U -5 CO 0) LO ) -- 0) -- 0) CO 0) - - - 0)~ O 0) 0) 0) 0) 0) - - - U) 0) - 0 a) -C a) It U) 02 o0 0 7Cu3 _C: C/) ) *0 '- wo t C2 OO U) W)C) a1) 0 0 10 C/, m Nm 6a 66 o O C C) _ 6 O C) C) a _0 N- C) C) C) o o o o cN * co o sao _4 st '4 C N U) C o N;- _ CO q C) ( q CD C) C) O 0 N Cy) 'T C o C O °, °,) S ) 0 ° N( C c Cq O '4 a7 ) °, O N (0 _ a0 tC) C) I C C) N C) ' U) m C q - 0 CD C o oN O ° O r_ I_ U) N C) t C) It w C ) 6 6 C 6 U) '0t NCD U) U) C NU) C) 6 6 6 6 a)~ CD 0 (0 CC) O ~C LO O) U)' C)i U) 00 LO >- Ot ` O U) C C) 6 C6 66 o ) C CO q C) 0 ( C) aa a a a C 66_ C) 66660n C)C (0 00 CO SS q ) C) C) N C) NC) U) O °° - 't ) ) ) ) P P ) O O O O O ° , C) U) N0 °U) a t ) (0) NO (0 ' . w °N t NP P CO O O °, O O O ° O O O O N w (~0 '4. N- C) (0 N w I''4 0 0 N (D 0 0 0 C) C) 6 . - C I. . I 6 0 O~ O~ ; U C c0 C) a - (0 0 (D 0 U) ( C) q q a a LO (O (O U) ) C (0 C 0 C) U C) N N- '4 U) (0 U) C) '4. (O C) C) C)C O) O - C) C) U) U) (0 N- (0 '4 (0 C) (0 U) C (0 '4 ) (0 C) C Z CO (D U) (0 C) 0 0 O) C) ,-C) '4 C C) C) a a q_ q 6 6 6 6 a 0. 0I 0. t CO C) U) q C) 0. 0. 60 U) N (0 C) ) O C) . CO CD 60 N ' 4 C) U) ' t '- 't 0. 0. 0 C (0 'T C (0 (0) C) 60 60 0I . toi 666 ~6a q_ O_ _t _ CD C) c C) z 0 . N R 0 '4 ( - N C N U) ( N 6 0 cO . . . a ( C 0 't C) (0 0D (0 C C (0 C) CN U) C) 0. (0 60 60 . .~~~~~ 0 0. (0 0 C cn _ C I0 'C a 0 0 O (I, 0= CD co n oo_ C Cu 0 oo ~0 E E 0 o4 o) o)_CC_C) Nr (D U) U CD N N N 'tU) (D ) C) N N C N N 6 N '- N a ao (s ,It U) (0 (0 (O C) C) C) (0 N-~:~'- - X CU3 U)o Cu U) U) LO ) 6 6 CO C C) N- ( C) C) C) C) 66666666O C U) C ' C)a6a666 U) (00 00 N-0 C) C) C) C ( C) C) ) NC NNC) >- N rlP '4. a) EFE a1) 0 .a) C 4t ( (0 0 (D (D (0 ) OC) )C)O C)C)66 (D C) o N ) CO Is q_ ac. Q) 0 U) N L) C) (0D 'O - O- N- N0 CO CM Cq C) 0 O a) N ( (N03 0 U-) oCC) o C o6 6 6 6 a6 o6 6 C C)C) - 0: 0 0) U) N(0 (0 C )c N (0 C) C 66O 'T (0 )C) N NIw C) C) CC) m em ( 0 U) C (0 w C '4 t '- U) 6 C)6 0C66)C N- U ) N 't oC)i-C)C C) U) C) ( (0 (0 C) a)' a _ a '4 ILOU) C) C) U) 66O ( (O ( t C) (0 N- ( It . C) C) C N ' CC C)C)C)) - 't ) C) (0 (0 U (0 00 0(0 C) C) x -0 LE C) C) cu CD a) C) z ( ( (0 C C)C) 'I I4t N(0 :) ,I. N- C C X la0 0 C) N- _0 C a) .C C) C -8 = a) o a) a) in 0 0 In C 0 Cu a) 'C (0 N C) ~~~~~~~~~~~I '4 U) (D N- (0 ) C C) C) C) c) C) C) O C) (0 C) N (0 C ( (0 C) t (0 C) U) (D (0 oo(0 C) C) N(0 c) ( (0 C) D C) C c a) ) N CD ) C) C5) C C 2 a) .0 0 a, C . U)._n o 0 In a) 0 a) Cu C a) m - Q1) Table 4: The Effect of Relaxation on Sex Ratios for First Borns The Effect of Relaxation on Sex Ratios for First Borns Dependent Variable: Dummy for Male _. (1) Born in relaxed region * Born 1976-1981 Born in relaxed region * Born 1982-1989 0.106 0.098 (0.024) (0.025) 0.037 0.035 (0.021) (0.021) N Y 44234 44234 0.00 0.00 Han, Han * Birth Cohort Observations R-squared (2) Regressions include county and birth cohort fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the county level. 115 c o 0) 0) 0) o0 F(D C i q C)o O 04 o I.co oo LO COF C0 0 LO fl 014 oc-o Co -J Co) m w-- C 00 . No C- c o C:) Ea (-4 (i c o 0o 0 W 0 - _ 66 Ci c) U) 0 U) a) Un a) u) CD in 0 U) o 0C) in c- O 0 a a c o 6o ~o d o i in U) E O o U) in 0 CO I-LO 04 z z z 0 i a w La N0 0 0 co iO in 0E oo 0 U) iDn O o LO oD c co o 0l(c c 0 0 0 1I- C) a) 9~o 0 oo tC Co -i C -- 96 0006 _ ) CO C U) z U) c.' CD U) s 0 0 U)Z ) U) in 0 0 z0 z0 zz 00 0 on in o 6R O > n -C C C.- U') .- ts 0N .a D ._) cn a) t- r (-4 CU U) o ~C o in60. C) 9 C I- 0 > CD 0 N 0 z z U)o U) oRo C'z0) Co C- CU zzz 0 0 9 -j 0 CO 04 °: t-- ( R r- 0 0 (q C) 0 a w co o a a) E CO N U) U) LO Iin~ oo 00C) 0 vl; c)0 C-- i c . .a w >a) w-0 0 N ',_ ~o 00 c N co > > 0 0 00 z z 0 U? t- E ._ 0 U r a o 0' T) U) V o© C x cn CU c _2 C) - x <~ io C n i o) CD m U) p ._ U) 0 -_ a) E U) w .m sn U) C) tn a)n u m U0 ~~~.o , 0=mw D U) C U) zo 7 Un C) .0 ., w tn >s 00 a) - m un ._ o2 .0- C 00 c 0C U1) C a) C DI= ..._ C: C I C.i0 ' a) cn C .0 F -0 0 ,C) U;) _< C : v Figure2: Thetop 10%incomesharein China,1986-2001 27% 25% 23% 21% 19% 17% 15% 13% CD W e0 CO c> D 0) ~ 01 0) w c ~ x o o~ Source:Authors'computations using urbanhouseholdsurveys tabulations(TableA5, col. (1),ind.income) Figure 1: Real per capita GDPin Chinaand India, 1986-2001 (1986= 100) 260 250240- 230 220 - 4-China --- India -- 210 200 - 190 180 170 160 -_ 150 140 -130 L--________. 120 - __ __ 110-_ - _ 100 - 90- -- _-N Source:Authors'computationsusing nationalaccounts(see TableAO,col. (5) and(16)) 117 Figure3: Thetop 1%incomesharein Chinaand India,1986-2001 10% 9% 8% 7% OZ 6% -|-- Top 1% share(China) 5% -- Top %share (India) 4% 3% 2% 1% distribution); (TableAS,ccl. (4),md. householdsurveystabulations computationsusing urban authoss China: Source: 0% O N o - > of O 8 O 0 O N 'lN~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~8 Source:China:authoss'computations usingurbanhouseholdsurveystabulations(TableAS,col.(4),ind.distribution); India: auhors'computationsusing ncometax returnsdata(seeBanerjeeandPlketty(2003,TableA3.col.(1))) Figure 4: The top 1% income share in China and India, 1986-2001 (1986 = 100) 200 190 180 170 160 +Top -4- 1% share (China) -- D-Top 1% share (India) 150 140 J /M- 130 / ' / 120 110 100 90 Source:China:authors'computationsusingurbanhouseholdsurveystabulations(Table AS,col. (4),ind. distribution); India: authors'computationsusing ncometax returnsdata(seeBanerjeeand Piketty(2003,TableA3,col.(1))) 118 Figure5: Incometax exemptionthreshold,averageincomeand P99thresholdin China,1986-2001 (currentyuans) 40,000 36,000 32,000 28,000 24,000 20,000 16,000 12,000 8,0001 4,0001 0 - I I I> Ix Ix o ) o In) Ix o Source:Exemptionthreshold:Chinesetax law (seeTable1); averageincomeand P99threshold:authors'computationsusing urbanhouseholdsurveystabulations (TableA1, col.(10),andTableA4,col. (15)) Figure 6: Incometax exemptionthreshold,averageincomeand P99thresholdin India, 1986-2001 (current Rs) 100,000 90,000 80,000 70,000 60,000 50,000 40,000 30,000 20,000 10,000 0 Source: Exemptionthreshold: Indiantax law (see Table2); averageincomeand P99threshold: authors'computations using nationalaccountsandincometax returns data (see Banerjeeand Piketty(2003,TableAO,col. (7),andTableA, col. (9)) 119 Figure7: Thefractionof individualssubjectto the incometax in ChinaandIndia,1986-2001 36% 34% 32% 30% 28% 26% 24% 22% 20% 18% 16% 14% 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% ~ ~~ ~ ~ ~ ~~~~~ X~ eo 0. 0. 1X1 0. 0. 0 I 0 0 0 Source: China: authors' computations using urban household surveys tabulations (Table A6, col. (1)); India: authors' computations using tax returns data (see Banerjee and Piketty (2003, Table A, col.(4))) Figure8: Projectedfractionof individualssubjectto the incometax in China,1986-2010 (assumptions: tax lawunchangedafter2004;post-2001incometrendssimilarto 1996-2001) 70% 65% 60% 55% 50% 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% Source: China: authors' computations using urban household surveys tabulations (Table A6, col. (1)); India: authors' computations using tax returns data (see Banerjee and Piketty (2003, Table A0, cl.(4))) 120 Figure 9: Using 1996-2001 Tax Receiptsto Re-Evaluatethe Riseof Top IncomeSharesin China --- r z/u 260 250 240 230 220 210 200 190 180 170 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 Source:Authors' computationsusing urbanhousehold surveystabulationsand actualincometax receipts Figure 10: Incometax revenuesas a fraction of GDPin China and India, 1986-2001 4 '02 1. /0 _. 1.1% 1.0% 0.9% 0.8% 0.7% 0.6% 0.5% 0.4% 0.3% 0.2% 0.1% 0.0% CD. Source: China: 1996-2001: 1- °o actual tax receipts 0 0 0 from China Tax Yearbook 0 (see Table 3); 1986-1995: adjusted 0 simulated tax receipts 0 - N (see Table A6, col.(15)); India: actual tax receipts fromAll-India IncomeTax Statistics (see Banerjeeand Piketty(2003)) 121 Figure11:Projectedincometax revenues(asa fractionof GDP)in China,1986-2010 (assumptions:tax lawunchangedafter2004;post-2001incometrendssimilarto 1996-2001) A{An!A 4.0% 3.6% 3.2% 2.8% 2.4% 2.0% 1.6% 1.2% 0.8% 0.4% 0.0% -. I -2 9 . 9. . t, o. . NA 9 . . Or rD . . s,. oM9 s2°; 2° . ° . ° . °I.. I . I gI o N Source: 1996-2001: actual tax receipts from China Tax Yearbook (see Tab 3); 1986-1995 and 2002-2010: adjusted simulteded tax receipts (see Table AS, col(15)) 122 E'~ 0 x C, 0 I CU O 0X) ECD) -) '- C 0..C y- O >, a) E -2 0 .C 00 0 0^ U) 0 0 0 00!0C a) C Un a) C0 .CD 0) C C 00~ O O ~_0 . EZ o ,C a En ) r)C 0V O0 .) C le CCU Cu:3 7 N 0-Z C co 0) 0 0 0) C 000O 0O O *_X CuC m C° "O 0 N C= 00) dD C) OC CO 0) 0 (00a 0 aC CF) N 0)0) -' a)X D -0CC- 0 Ea)0 * c aCu . -1 -0 0 CU 00 Cu_ o 0 0 0 0 C 00 00 o CC cu:3 0D00 CO 0 OO C O N N C N N- N C)O N CN 00D ) CD 0 0 o00 0 0N 0CO0(0 N N 00C1 0 CN NO CO O 0) O CD gq N N8 'a) 00 0 -CuE 0) aCu 0 en 0f c CC ° 0LO U'- U-- Cu0) 0 >< C4 C a>D no ->0e C. .0) V ca C Cu Co M3 :3 Un a) 15 E .~C 0 0 0.) TC:C co 0))0 (0 (0 0 ( 00C O 00) 00 ) (0 O 0 N 0 (0 0 D OL CO O5 C) C) co CO( C> ( 0)O (O0 (D COO ND (D (0) CD - 0 cm40 a) Cu 0.3 CC.-Dc~CD 0)a)C (0 2 0 0 0 E 0C 'CuC5)V Zi UC0 aE L CO O) 0-0T O N UO0C 0o U) C) ( N 0) ) :~- B< X a Cu0) -C_ L. 0 -a V C CO 0') 0 C C ) 00 CuC cO C) 0) 0a) co* CM) CD CD w0'U)0)) .0a) (U C.) ) C) EL 0) XC c- _ z EX V5 ,C C F .C o0- 0. x ,cs n 4-In a)) > a) E ct 0 0 c, 0 c) ~0 U) Ca ) CDc 0C O C V WE E 0 I% n a) X C) CCa Cu 0) CO N mu I- U) E! I' cC 0) 'c 0. .Zo M0E o 0 CD t C0 ) t U a) 0, 0) 0 O0)O 0OO 0OO -C ° C) Yco 0) U xU, 0 U) N U) Q C UC 0om E U)0C 0 C.) c~ c:n Eo 04E -E-E0 oc en ~. U0)0 0 CC En~ a) C L 00 a .' (! 0 0 O )L 1 0O cn a)0)0 a) O C)C -2 CD 0) Cu QO = U) 0) oo U) -E C D CO9 X0-f -C a .0 C) C C o0 (CaC CN o Q0 N CD 0 (0 0) u UC 02c) E .a U) C0) CD C C, EtC6 Vu 0 C Table2: Progressive IncomeTaxSchedules in India,1986-2004 1986-1988 1989-1990 1991 1992-1993 Brackets of annual Marginaltax Bracketsof annual Marginaltax Brackets of annual Marginaltax Brackets of annual Marginaltax income(Rs) rate income(Rs) rate income(Rs) rate income(Rs) rate 0-15000 0% 0-18000 0% 0-22000 0% 18000-25000 25% 18000-25000 20% 22000-30000 20% 25% 25000-50000 30% 25000-50000 30% 30000-60000 30% 30% 50000-100000 40% 50000-100000 40% 60000-100000 40% 30000-40000 35% over100000 50% over100000 50% over 100000 50% 40000-50000 40% 50000-70000 45% 70000-100000 50% 0% 15000-20000 20% 20000-25000 25000-30000 over100000 0-18000 55% 1994 1996-1997 1995 1998 Brackets of annual Marginaltax Bracketsof annual Marginaltax Brackets of annual Marginaltax Brackets of annual Marginal tax income(Rs) rate income(Rs) rate income(Rs) rate income(Rs) rate 0-28000 0% 0-30000 0% 0-40000 0% 0-40000 0% 50000-100000 20% 50000-100000 20% 40000-60000 20% 40000-60000 15% 50000-100000 30% 50000-100000 30% 60000-120000 30% 60000-120000 30% over100000 40% over100000 40% over120000 40% over 120000 40% 2000- 1999 Brackets of annual Marginaltax Bracketsof annual Marginaltax rate income(Rs) rate income(Rs) 0-40000 0% 0-50000 0% 40000-60000 10% 50000-60000 10% 60000-150000 20% 60000-150000 20% over150000 30% over 150000 30% Note: India'sincometax appliesto individualincome,not to householdincome(exceptfor HinduUndividedFamilies).The general principleis that all incomesourcesare subjectto the sametax rates(theprogressive tax scheduleappliesto the sumof all individual incomes,whateverthe source).Thereare howeverspecialexemptions for particularformsof interestincome,transferincome,etc.The tax schedulesreportedonthis tabledo notindude"temporary" tax surcharges (forinstance,a 10%tax surcharge hasbeenappliedto all incomesabove60000Rssince2000,sothat theeffectivetoprateis 33%ratherthan30%). 124 Table 3: Simulated vs Actual Income Tax Revenues in China, 1996-2001 Actual Income Tax Revenues Total Receipts Wage income Receipts Busines income receipts Capital income receipts Other receipts (billions current yuans) Total Receipts (% GDP) 1996 19.3 0.28% 1997 26.0 0.35% 1998 33.9 0.43% 1999 41.4 2000 66.0 28.3 13.3 19.0 5.5 0.74% 2001 99.6 41.1 16.0 34.8 7.7 1.02% Other receipts Total Receipts 0.51% Simulated Income Tax Revenues Total Receipts Wage income Receipts Busines income receipts Capital income receipts (billions current yuans) (% GDP) 1996 22.2 12.0 2.2 8.0 0.33% 1997 32.0 18.6 3.3 10.0 0.43% 1998 37.6 22.1 4.0 11.4 0.48% 1999 36.5 19.7 4.9 11.9 0.45% 2000 48.5 28.0 8.3 12.2 0.54% 2001 63.7 39.6 10.3 13.8 0.66% 2001b '147.3 88.8 16.0 34.8 7.7 1.52% Ratio Simulated/Actual Income Tax Revenues Total Receipts 1996 115% 1997 123% 1998 '111% Wage income Receipts Busines income receipts Capital income receipts 1999 88% 2000 73% 99% 63% 64% 2001 64% 96% 64% 40% 2001b 148% 216% 100% 100% 100% Source: Actual receipts: China Tax Yearbook, various issues (1997-2002); Simulated receipts: authors' computations using urban household surveys tabulations (see Table A6) Note: Simulated receipts for 1996-2001 have been computed by applying the relevant tax schedule to the individual distribution of wage income, business income and capital income estimated from urban household survey tabulations and reported on Tables A2 and A3. The 2001b estimates have been computed by inflating business, capital and other income so as to matach actual tax receipts, and by inflating survey-based top decile wages by 50%, so as to obtain a realistic Pareto coefficient for the wage distribution. 125 Cl \'q - EL (f001- C) >) O L - 00) L C) 0) 6 "I N CO 0) N O '"t (O -a, -. s d) ) Cr) c- Oc c xxi =3 COCa) cD ) Om CD 0a)() oa c , E CL C Co O -s Lo * C) oO C) >_ e- 0 . N U' C m 7 M 10 10 -o o -a) 0 0 U) O- C d) . (0.o '- U o w- 00 0 U) e =o xQ D - - 6i0 a..Cqa~( N: CN C0(N .L C (L)- n)- E 0 I (n o a) > .00m cE 0X E CLo c) (U) 0 c C CDo °0 E 0o u O: o N - U') C: 0 0 o0 .Q) Oo 0CCa) x) 2- > Ua) 0 0 -a N 0 .I_ 0 .0 (U I- (NL(( o( o= I-- cN t o ; 0 a DCL (va C0 b(0 C O a) a 0 0) (0 0 (N - (n a) 0 V a) D 0 LO C) - 00 0 ' 0 )0 0) 0C vO aD a) CDD (55- V '0 a - 0C~c a) Co>> a) O N- . XE 0a) vOO 00 LCO (N C L. L LL 0) 0) O O O O O O O O) O O OO) O 0 a)CNO o oCN . S . a) _0 01O 0O a) U nF 0 C co 0 0 a) oo o0 0 (0 o C) oq 0 LO - . S . S 0C 0O c C O) O - -) O C oq v'C~ aO (N Oq C (DCI . S C: C r a) g 00 0 cn 0- ' r-- A o 0 o N (0 (0 Lo a) Lo (0 Lo g o I (nC/ O 0 U 0 In U) > Ln o ( N t (0 CD 0 0) n N ) <(0 (0 (0 (D (0 CD C0 (0 C) rNN In 0 (0 c 0 t N co N 0 In C) w ni U) ) 0 O 0 0n (0 (D -t- Ni 0 ) N o-(0 I 0 (0 (0 (0 Int tD( U m m' N t 1- ) - a) c) (a 0 0) C N ~ a) N to U N- 0 ,I Lo C N In) t I¢ N 0 N N- (0 ' v N N 02 In In N (0 co N- IO (0 N U) 0 0 (0 N N a C - 0 a ..)04a) Q-. C ~ I L 0 (0 U)I Ci a) o -$ N0 0 NIn C) a) N T N 0 N 0 ( (0 D U) N N U) N C) (0 U) N- C) CS In (0 C) N- (0 0 0 N N N U) t In In In)U(0 (0 N- 0 t U) C) II --CD N (0 In) C) o o I- ,I - 0 In 0 N- 0 In In C) ts N o 0U' 0n tN a) . O U On N (0 0 (0 N U) U) 0 ) t C) IN N (0 0) N- ( N In (0 In ( N - 0 n 0 c 0N- (0 0 I '-E6 o0. X° j2. a)8 (N IN In (0 U Co ->CIR. _ N aD N N In FL 0 ,0 N-0 In C)O) O co6 £0 0 0 > - ID (0 C)j CD~ - o ao o, x 8 U) - 75 0 CL In) NN- N- 0 N N 0) In N C) 0n 0n 0n 0n 0 0 0 N co 0 ) In N- C) C) C) C) C) v ) a)>a) a 0 I CO o cE > a) o OEn -- N ao C £- S 2 00 N o N- 1-i - e °O ' -5 C i-I Ul r- 0 - 0U) - t t (0 I U) - C ( (0 o C) N U) 0 N N I ( N N M C N 0 I 0 a t - t 0 0 N- N .C, In ( U T 0…NM 0 D a) 0 a) ~0 0. - t(0 r- 0 0 N- 0 0 0 - N N n rNi C 0 N N N N …. .vN 0 zo 0 _ oo N (0 C) C) cn U) U) -D C U (0 IN - 0 (0 m0 In N O O N co (0 CO t O C) N 0) (0 U) N- U)D C )Un aw~~~~ C a0 C 0 0 0 N N N N NN (0 0- N C) (N txN 0 - 0OC o n N Co'), o n q>-o 0- U) (0 ° I .0 OS (0 u-)r N In o N) N 8 --B C 'ci 0. B ., CD -eg ft > E (0 N N 0 N NCO) > F C) U° (0 C) CD C) 0 C) U ( nN Nto s_ ssa) 1 c d C) nr N- U) ) …VIU0~ n(0(0V I In - , N -2 C 0. I F a) CD ) o o o o N N N N N N In (0 0 0n N- t m 0 0 U) In 0 N LO N U) U) U) o N o N o N o o N o I o m m a)C Coa) (0 0 .0 C In I0 ( In U) .n 0 C) U) (0 - . N N N N N n c~~~~~0 m a C)¢ N (0 0 N- 0 m ) (0 N U) U) U) t 0 N- N U) N ( C) m N0 U (0 0 t In In) In (0 I · >r .0 N U) 0 C N 4 N CC CC In t 0 0 N N ~0)In. Cq NN (0 UN (0 N N NC))nnN U N *0 E Co ,Ct C CL n 0 N C) U) IN 2 U (0 I( (0 (0 N- N- a))c I)a) a)0 a)U1 a x -(0 Ia)2 CD C) C) o§ a M 0) m ~- In 0OC) (0 N- 2 tD 0 - 0 ci_ (-) (0 N 0 U) N N O 0n N- 0n 0 U C. oa) CD Ca) >t . r- a) a) . X N C) tIn N n0 (U0 D1-- c 0 . a . -(0 BeE CC0L N IN10!P In (0 0O! 0 O 1D -C NC) , ~t n 0~0 co 0 C. U) *0 U °C In C …oNUU)UU0U a) C-^ C N 0}. CL _- 31 Io O 0 ~ O N 0 - (D I N t n tD (0 In -D C) C) C) In (0 (0 (0 N- t ) C) R-C) In 0 In ( 0 IC C ,rN N M It LO0 (D InU) N C) 0+ N- U 0 I - I N In C - I - I N (0 I U) st In It U0 N M 0a I- c c 0a) ,, Y 0 0 C) C) 0 C) 0 C) C) -N C) C) U) C) C) C) C) tI C) C) C) C) (D N 0 C) C)C C) C) C c ) 0 C) R) 0 g c N (II …~~~~~~N' N .. ) C) C 1 (a) mo cn0 0 N 0 0 0 C) C) a)- N. C (0 iV a > C (c (0 aCC ) 0CO N C - ~CDa ))) .g 00 C-,l *~~0 8 .E a, E .o 2 8I E;5 0 0 0 U)U)U~~~~U 0a C') CO H (n q' 0 0 N , CO 0…N~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~CIC4 1 -~~~c = ~~ ~~~ ... 6E 6 U C') Oo oo 0) _ C ..,-, CU U U - 61-444 64 2 0. CL 00 <0 CO CO CO ' ) 0) 0 0) 0 0 0) X0 )n ,C .C a, c7 N@ 2>E . C - CD a) 0) :5ux .1 C e a :Coo- 8.a~ 2 0>,C° C 8 E 0 O ° tC) Ua) O CO0 N ) H N 0 N o L-o"E C u.) .E ,o= -o', It C .0 Cu V V Co m .z.2 ,-o o U)8 E > c, ~D '2 E-> l: Z 8 Iq R 0) CO 0' < 5 0 CO CO N o ,c Ct 0) (C') N C ) D CO CO 0 N N~ :)NtO NlcCCO IL IR Cm 00 0l I)st O t CO 0 st CO H N0) N0) C 0 C') CO CO CO CO CO N Nx N N N CO Nt 0 H CO N N (R Cli N H0 N CO 0D CO N Cw0)- CO N CO tD CO tO H O0 N N CO CO C) 0)) N gC CD H N N N C O L) -a 8 0 o C, a, O 8 F" F-' 'I,:''~,~S a C E 0)C .20 C ~ l V O o - CL g cu _ CZCD0 · ) .C -CoU~E,C o r- E u_8 - °-- °' N 0 66 .: o -N - 0 O -)t ' o o NN O ,… - o o O 0)0 NN N wN a -o o aE 0, u a, 8 2 o oS o o -°o - a,~ a 0 ~a'n D C ~o oOa Cuu5 o- >) . ~CC.) 5.o ~ o -oc C0 -- 02a) .0 E CD. ,. CO OO a Cu _ .g C 0 a, 3 .0C 0 .0) a, 0 Z 0 ) -o , ,-) O- oc') oC') oS oCO oSo o~ ~ N C) ~ 0 0 0 C oN 0 0 )C- H ") 0 HD 0 H r-HH-O0 s0 0 sH sNO s sCO<)N s s F sN 1_~0 I' s2 I' N CO CO 4~:- > E08 m- 4 N N - 4 L L) N t CO H N 1: S c - CO N C'O -0N N v C' 0 -s CD C I -P O CDCCm a,2 _') aC.U)- N CO CO CO CO CO H ) ) c0 c0 - l' oM C 0 )o L- Z; CO 0) C a) o; ) 0 t a) t C ) c0) C' c) N N 0l) c) O o a) 0) N O 1- 0-D CO N c) o N c0) co - - c) 0 o o 0 _ .2CU E EO 0) N CO H O H H N co O N CO CO H N c D ) H H 0N - N oc)0 e .0-- U, ''U, -P p 0 )0 , a, .0 C0 CO C O 0 N o ) 0 0) (D O CO C0') C C) 0 CO0 O 0) 0 O 0 0 C 0 U, CCm C.)C.D N - C: R 0CD r Q5) -o ~ 0 I._ ==1 C CO 0D UM, a, O >E , a, 2 a0 CD co 0) H O O O 0) 0) 0) 0 0) o a) 0) 0) N a) 0 0) a) 0) It a) 0) u) a) 0) U E>'~ a CDCuO O 0) ) - N CO H -O 0) O a) a) a) 0) c 0) 0)~ o 0O 0) 0)cs zO - CuC .0CC2CO .0 Cl ci .. a- Q) a) c 0 a C U( N o F 51, CD 2_ (0N o N~ c(N eII N N 6d t cN n : s EE ) (-D CDo ( °R ° ) a) N 0) N(((( N r0. 0U C U) >. o a 3 a -2 'M 0 Co C0) ~_~~~ C) (N ~ CD C (0 ~ N- CC) ~ ~ C N a)o "O o0.C .,. 0) . U) C m- 0 .0 ~o O cn E C 0a) E) en (DL E 0 c~) 1 COIn6) 't 0 O02 OO cdO C) ) L) 0 ) CO N- N (N -t ) ( D (N ) 0 oC=(D 0 N N- o c) O 't (0 m ) N m< L) t ) m I t r- c) I- o o r co m) o c a) CD o O D NNl- Fr. CD E ;R,coa)E 0_ C V I- CDC ca.0 E. 0 0O 0 0 E o N R _~z. E 0eD cn .' -, CD mO a) CD ) N(N t - cO N N O O m CD CO N o) C N-C (D (N N N 0 c c - oo° N O - O Co N C (N L UC) )L (U C ° CD- --: E.~r0 ~.o ou E u ao ( C O )- cJa.L) On L N- 0) N > CO D ~ O ) CD Cu C) y ) C1 C N- 00 CDI CD , a - o ,, U, , (0 6&6O COC) oDiu °t C) C U) a a(N C -0 (0 - N- (c t ) N- C) (N ) 'I : C ) s (0 N- 0) 0 ( N N N j Cl .~=u' OCCU) O -)) 8 a) nS _) - = .0 Ia) Cu0ns C >a0 D u a).c ) SCo) a) = II' 0E E CY °, ~, a'E co 0 C. CL L) uEO ) .a V o Oo 0 o o ' . >, U) tO C) co ) U0 a8,, 8 (N In.CD D CD .0 C W C)coD ) ~~ U) = CC) m- 0 na' C> ro ~ s ~ z(N t. c) I) (N )O C)). (NoNCNNo CC _ o Cu C -, .Q a, ID CD 0 E I-- . U) a 0 NCO C (N (N 0 C) 0) c C) N O CC) Lm . 0 N (N 0 0) L5) NC D 0 ) O 0 (N CO O C) N0 It)O v) -~aco...a) a) 0 a)c. CuD0 2. CU a, .o Cu co Cuu> 0co . a, )_ 0 -a .. n -a Coc 0) CD 0 a) ou, .)E > '- E E Ecn' C) NN C Ir E a) In )0N) m o oo CO 0 N uI CN (3D cO Iq o 0 O.~ O. O D-Z 0- C.0 -- CZ a:I E - 0 F C ~~ u(DcO) tIt = C0N -. ~-(NCO'FJ-COCOCOC)C 0 0~~ 0. 0, C - 2 cn CIO >, (C ) 0 Nco C) 0 ) 0) 0) 0 0) ) 0) (N 0 0) >'.0 Cto cn m 0) 0) 0) 0) CO 0) 0) C) 0) 0) N-o 0) 0)o C) 0) 0) O ) 0) 0 0 0 0 N a, C. c Co Z 2 a~. ) Co … )C _ IliF a) a) 0 0 N "6 2! ) _ =D 0D 9!E. CO - n _ _ _i '! (O 0 _2 A - t N 0t U) 0 N " - -2 a) CD N- a) c.) a) V~ 0 I N 0N tNIliN 0 w Iw0 C' a) 0 UM N 0 a 0 (0 rD N 1~ U) a c m00 N _ .I O In m Ci l> lc 114 No t C') N Cn U n c N O Ir o 1 0 o I I Cn CC wg 0 0 N U) ) - I U U) Om c N M N N :' 1 O ur U) ) tN O U) 0 oW _ N0 0 N .) aT ol~ 0 0.; o 0) t i N U) N -1a) 03 O a)0 N N 0 _: N 2! 0 m) N1 C1 0C a) a. U) 03 N N '-C N I C) st NN- a) ) A I U) N U) N N tD tD a) N- In 0 tO _ N- U) m_0 uw m N . 0 N r O C¢ OL) 0 t _- A ) N1 a l tD Cm O- 'InD 0 uO a)~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~, I- 0 0 0) ( N a) 0 O a. _ N a) . Nr N tD 10 fl: N 0 0 U) - rU) U) - 0' U) Cn N a N a) st U) - N- 0_ta-)) N ID N N-) N 0 1t O - 0 U) nNN O N 0 a)O . -,; C N -. N atZ) N . IT_ I N (D0 0 N t w (D 0 I- a) oU (D a) O U) NO U) Na__) Q) - '! a) a) l Z; a) - a> ° N) 0 U- o i,, N N M N 0 a ) NU U)ULNtD a) S cli o a) a . U) N -00 U--U)03'NO03) _O CD N . (' a) N- ur s O6C N- - U) --- N - 0 N N C' ) U) a) On) CO O a N 0 a) - U U) url i N- cli O 0_C C' m N- C) e ! 0N CO _ o66 N C 0 ' U- IN- a U) -; Q- = 0 . PNN N NNCN 3! NN*N =X cq (V ( U N N ) C oN~ )C03)~ - N N D C)- 2 N 0I 0N--N0-0 CD a CD 0 N C 0 FZ di Ili U V aa - h- - rf L) a) C'4 lo 0 .0 Lo a). m ( "_ d O cl N: - Lo m0 , a o) U' - CU o o a 0 0m a O QN t At C' C00 - m 2 CC O~a) N0 -~) _ vt (CN . _N ) N Uq 0 - 'T 16 1 _; 0 . 0 .v . mo mm o0) ( )'oU - U1)oN-Noa 0 N t N, LO N N_0 )'_ C ) ~ N ll0S R >_m eV "t mV Na ) CC CC D - ~ ) a) 0 0 a) U o 0 '- )N-a)0N - a) N U) a) UN m) m )- m -, 4 Ld N-~ N 1) U- 0 N t N N o L a ': °- N' U- C' C' D & ')U) a a U- ° o I- 0 m) I- 'I,) 12 I- 0 N- N a) 0' 0' 0' 0 (3 _ O U) U) t o In a0>~~~ a) O0 C! tv 0 'Ioq T) _ I N "' 03 N9 U) a) C 03 0 C oU) o a) )U) CD U) 1-mt U U) 0 0 0 _ N N N 0C0O0OCON a) E _ N a) vx Uv0 a 0 Q iz N U' N ')O(0 - U) 0 N It It U0 ' a) C 0 N 0 N 'ITN 0 N C 06 0C C0 0 tv U) 0 0 a) N I a)0 N-- 0a N C' -N-1 NN v N N No N ')')o N ,D - U) - dIN- c. N 6 6 Uz m U- 03 No a)D U) CD Nsta0) r. t CD 1U) c)N 0 U- U) 0 U) N U N- C N 0 0 S !u N 0 U- . -gh U.) C0 COS -m O)1rU--a). U) - C' a I I.-vs N N O " o N- N-U) ,:v: CO?!~ °6 06 a) S cC _ !C ,N- V _ CI ('C O lo) a) 0N ) a) I_ N N (D 0t N m N ") N _' N U) 0 O.N o UM St ' a) N ('C tD . N NaU) 0 a) a, N N CN0 _ 0 0 a) N N- - N N a U) N C U) a) _ It - )o('3'0 a) 0 I 0 U) 0 0 U ) 0 N- 0 a 03 NN IQ vO o^ dT ) o iu) U- N- N 0 0 I C') IDC a) 03 ) N a) N a ; 'I CO a) U) Oat a N w a 1. a) N a0 C) N U) D t a) oUZ 0_a) a) XNN a) a) ED N a) N- C! C 0 t N N CU) 0na) C a) (C ,~ o c3i U0 U I' (' U U) a) s 0 _ _N -C os _ a) U) N CO 1- 0 CO g 0 0t 0 I -N 100 - )v00 U)U0 N -tt 0 N -tr 1 - O L M ) N N O. ci9 , _ NOt UNi -1Oi O N o)6C N * C'6a ---N -UU~ a) In ) ) ~2 vi N C; , N-., M .- O 1N- . - 3 N u) O NU) C U 0a) C'N CM )(3U Nt …NN N_- ° N -C'C C')0 U)C U )0 ,,m 0l "IlO U)o >N - N- lN- t U-t 0 0 30l l l tv 03o 0 Na )- c N ' i -6 66- i U) u N i a) 0 - 0 N-w a) I)C° C o N0 N 3a) O O O- a a) 0 0 0 Lo ('C W 0 ciU- - ') N N-~ a)- 0 0 U) a) U- N - N. ) t~t N Ott tt U- 0 U) 0 C0) U- a) a) a) 0 a) No 0 C' oU) ItU- m ID.) o0, ID D w N U- rD N CD N (0 a) 0 U) N Cd 0' 0 CC L(' 9! ,L 9! g_ o CL N- _ C a) N- L^ a) N0 LN N l_ Ev s^CS 'nN N- C O ') N CO C IQU^ l) C) 6 um g N 0 UoU) cct . N N- CC C' CO N 1s - nN-0 . - C^ N- Cu^ N O N L^) U) 0v 0 _ a a U) N- U) _ CD qN I lo O- 0d N 0 0 0 wDs 0 0 C'I t ~~~ ~. , N O Cv^.' ) O V: C'!) IQ L6s 6 I v: a) 0 0 N _ n "-1- O ON 0)N NC 'C _-_-N N 0 m c9 . U) M - a) a C -n N N M M 0 CO Cv W) C(v " 0 'T - M 't Cv L^ a U lc^ A ', C) 1 L^ tv I c') ao t -t LU N C C. N) CO N N t0 N CO o a) C I 1_ 0 . iU - U ) N - N . C C N ~m~~~~~~m~ ~ ~~ c c i c6 'L R 'L L) O CN ') N N CO l0 _ - N 0 O O t t ' N UC' N CvM g Lo N' L, O : o o N O :I - 0. N U C N N C') 0 CN N U- N- N- 0 a) a) 0 0 N ( 0 a U CD C-) N.) U- )t' CO 0 a N N- 0 N O "C N1) t N C') tO) - N N !! 6 N '- t^l N N N. L N CO a) u ;iu~ C') C _' C') L^' N O C 0 nNU- 03 LU) N Ut t vN Lo U- L^. L^. C^ Ihi . . C ^ - t^ 03 (, a t tv - - C 2E 00o cl Cv~L N -° 0 UNCO R-O tv N CJ N- - N - - - N C') a) C I LU) CO N a ) CC CC 0) a C a) a) C 0 CC a ) O0 CC0 C 0 to IFc> ) ) a) CC a) 0 C C CO0 0 tO000000 In a ) !~ C c C - ) _, 0C a 0C a _~ 0 a _, _) _ o 0 c0 C_ C.^ co N CO NC3 a ) CC CC a) a) a a a) 0) 0 a) C _ N a) a 0C a) 0 P r-. C') - L a) 3 8 o0 o 0 ! Cv a(.N N N - InU LCC LU C :i L a) IN - NC I'l m tN s C) N a) v cO v N 1-N ^ c') o L^ CO C') UT U-1 U-t L^ U) N-U -N . 0,U C C - -r- L, wb a) U) 0 N N i 0N _ C- ' C' - 'a (' C' U- . N 0) a 0 aU- a) N- U)C' t )03UO vb (v OvT~1 N- 0 O) C ^0 0 03 a) U- C) NU') N O - L U L L^ N U) U- N N Lo _ (D 0D U- 0) a) w N - N- N-I'I^ a) - ;:~, No a) N N O14 Ol: ON c') 0 0 N CO L t N tO N N Ut 0 CN U- a)O N N ( NC a) ) N CO CC C3 O N O, N, .6 F7 a_ L. m:, N 4 a, - - '! I^ A 0 N- M 0 - A CD 7 M N N N C I_ 0 N D _ U1 N0t . . t C° _ D C 0 I^ N C CDN- M C - C ,-,~~2 CD 0 C 0 Mi M-, si ON0CDOC 0 CD 0 CD0 N -' 0 n t CD O IQ Iq - N- n EL . 0 i a U) It 0 ) CD CD CD w 0 C N st * N N _ O 0 OR N "t DC - d, N Cli - a ci.-Z m N -^, N N CDN CDC 0 ID D _ _ --- CD t, ID NN- CD C t_ DC CD - m o w ) m C N N N )a,:t °mU: 0 0 ~o"I o !O o 0C tC 0 0i ~o ' ~ V CD' t° to N CD _D - 0 CD 0 C CD -DC t- - F t 0_ Dt^C 0t '0 N - C N0 N C0 0 q 0C O NC I N ( z2 N N 1oi CL - N CD O N N D t N O L 0 CD N0 CR ~i - LO N CD N CD mm v N 0 CD N t0 D Z O 0 N 00 N _ CD T C O C N D Cw CI s D _ 1- - aOs '"_,N v0CCD 't,t I~N N DDC 0 N R U),F R CD 0. 0OCDN C N 0 N C N C CD D Wm mm 0 0s L CD N CD 0 CD N N DC CD - _ N N 0 0 N N CD - M 0 N AO o_ N ~ N CD 0 N ', D. N _ NCD N 0 CD st t Z C 0 0 CD C CD C CD CD DC CD CD _ CD 1- m^ m N At 1PR0 N t'7 r Cy - N N CD N w - CN- 0 C C CD CD, CD 0. N CD DC - L C^ 'T ONC N- 't -: N ID NCD N DC 0r^ N CD DC 0 N Lo m t 0 -It I t' I-CD 0 CD CD 0 CD CD _ N t7 t t C Dc CD , , D 0 N 0 N CD D N N 0 DCN- N …NNCD 0 N t O - …- --C0 O0 0 !… 0 a, ; N CD NLN) 2 CD _ Lo N … -,N I NU - ~2M 0 C 0 N N Nl CD o CD o CD N CD D CD C DC FC U7 0' Cz 0 CD NCD N! t0 1- 0 0 0~ - ND N1- t NN I I'd N D N N- o 0 Ct^D CD 0 -t CD C CD 0 NCD, CD CD t0 "It r- t " t0: D 0 N! O CD ICD N 0 P< 0 CD DC N Id: 0 N-MCDUCDNt-D CD) CD 0 N C ! …N o 0 CD C t O t aC ~0 0C N N. t 2 CD ww. .2 N2 _ A ,:6 UT - T N0 _2 00 - 0 0 CD Cttw C D CD _ N CD U CD 4- 0 N-DCC D 0 0 CD C D ti j 0 cD' N CD t N CD ° S 1 0 0 a)N-D u)U D-CD 'C t m m N04 D N-C _ICD P Nc' I",0 U° o v o Ct N L6 a. -tO N' 10 . 4 C t CC co CD N- CD C DI'-c 0; -~ C) D - pO oa)o CD w C4 N C tco N ot N N- CDN t°s N--. ') NU 0° N4 N D CD N Fjoiq o (o(, d ~o CD O CDY C N co C ~ N CD ~----N 0lo CD r-L) 0v C, ~ ND 0N N' C f~o gt Ot0 CD OO N N Cl N- - CD ~ 1 D .; - - N t n D0 - 0 N CD N . N NNCD D tD N CD O NC : C LN r.t O O N tD O D 10 C D0~C C CD t o I D clN 0D ND C 0; o 0 tN D0 CD -CD^CD.^ ON N¢ 0 -j - 0DCCD , O t 'N N i tVj cLi CO0D N C N N- mDN - C CD N- DC 2~ N -DC CD t CD DC NCD t0 NN 1M CD q q~ R~ 0 ( 0 O CD t Ct U N I-t-I - N - CD N C D 0 DC DC DC DC DC - N C D- DC DC CD N DC DC C DC DC M 0r I I C~~~~NC1NC N oN N LoI' ^ N c 0 NCD0 N UD - 0 …N 0D -! W N - CD 6 -~ Dc -D DC CD . oCt N IQ t0D oN N 0tD O - -N N NO N- CD CD D ~ 0 0 Lo Uo tT <ti _ N N) tO -l toi DC 0 I o U' Lj _~~~~c - . D CDDCO O tO oi ^ q^ r0 0 w - - O t°N 0 CD CD D DC 0 CC L6 C C - C t>O0 D N N 04 tON C to 0 N0CD 00- 0 .Z Ca 0 oL CD - o C C CD 10 (D IU) Um m n N- N0 't s 0 ~Ko - D . CD CD N- C D 0z (et 4~~~~~ 4s 'd_ ) 0 0 CD tO C C O .2 2 ^ 0N NCD 0 n t D~C0sttD1' CD N CD CD CD CD Cl CD - t 0 U^ ) C CD N CD tO w ___N CD C OtO-O N:: Uii tOt^ Lo t I " ClN N 0 0 i r -tN 0 N N . CD ' 0 0 0 CD U oC CD DC 0 N O n -4 4- 0 C a DC N- C C C DC2 DC 0DC 0 C D D DC D DC N D DC C D C DC! DC CD CD D 0 DC DC N DC DC M 6S - CD cc t t … CD C 0N 0 CD N N a st - N 0 0 0 cN …NoN~C "i , - NC C D 0 D D DC2 DC 0 R0 DC ~( tD~cj °- CD 0 0c1 r 0 0 , Cj N0 N -C NNDOtCDO -1 0 t<) CD _ N_ ~o0 0 CD C oj CD N- N 00 NN _ N CD CD N CD DC CD N-t N- 0i O cC 2 Dco U t° tODCDDCCDN-DC C cniO DOCDCDDC OD0 Il0ND I NC0 6 El g VVV~CD ~~o~ ~ ~~~~~~~~~~~u ~ C4 , N~ N~ r IN 8_ N Lo a cDDCo 'IT - - C Ea - tO Nt 0 0C NtO N-. CD M CD -q T w No j 0 0 d :s qO 4CD 6a t - Ot N- iz tL N ctO- D~ 0 CD NO 0 1- tq R 51 a- a) N 0) a. -CD c6 -a ,:K (I c CD Ct CD .0- NDC CD tC N N co 1-r N t CD Ct CN … t a : I 0 NN P .0 CD CD CD CD - t0 CD CD m 0 t CD - - g I D - t I U N N D N- - _ CDC 0 NW CD N0 N N *M-- rC ~N-CDDCN-'tqt N- wN I C N ^ O N C I CD 0_0 t O (L N 0 -N-_-.DDNN Nv c mm t IT ^ts N- C - 't r. N CD--~ C C 0o - D U 0 N t)0 M DC 0) CM0D C CDD0 q N N m wD CDO0 N- N 0 0 DN0O CD - S0 0 If) N 0 V - - C) CD _1 CD NNl- D Q LCD 0- N -NNNN *N D( DCDC C N … 0 'P N- q ;,c"Ao0 , t^ 0£ CD N- '0t 0 C^ CD C L " NCD CD D CD D l N' CD Nl- "I CD 0a0 -N!coto ~CD MCD,1,tN M _NNC :-o ND D0 t CD ~ N- tU o:, 0 N _C 0 0t ,4 0 s ^ N _ M co< DCC C_ ^ -CDO00 CD DC N O w^ _ CD- C C 0 DCN NC N CD 0 0C -t_- tCD CD C CDi cD CD r: tO t_ N . !~0 CD: O 0, CD 0 N NCDInNDl N 0 tLF 0 DC CD N - CD C N ~ _ d CD DC NN~00NN--D o DC C ° 0 0 CD DC CDi 0 CD N--RCC0 CD _D CD 0 N N-~ 6 w CD CD -o - N - . i sg C ze A11 N - DC N- c N - N CD -CN " ° _ N N - N-4 DC - - - L g 0 M N 0 D N CDw N 0M C _ D C 10 CD 0 N NN O tL t N 0 CD D C 0C CD 0 CDD CDCDDCDCCDCD1 2 0 -- C M C° C t I N- N- - D Z-O CD) CD °^ _7 UD 0 CD t C r- A. 0 D0 N N 0 N t St IQ 0 - EL-= _li D 0 C - -,.-,o,, N r- IN I . C c 0 _D On - N CD TableA5: Topfractilesincomessharesin totalincomein urbanChina,1986-2001 household distribution P90-100 (1) P95-100 (2) 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 18.7% 18.5% 18.9% 19.7% 19.7% 19.8% 21.1% 22.6% 23.4% 23.0% 23.3% 23.8% 23.8% 24.2% 24.5% 24.9% 10.6% 10.5% 10.8% 11.6% 11.6% 11.7% 12.7% 13.7% 14.3% 14.0% 14.2% 14.5% 14.6% 14.9% 14.9% 15.3% individual distribution P90-100 (2) P95-100 (3) 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 17.4% 17.8% 19.2% 19.7% 19.3% 19.5% 20.6% 22.6% 23.6% 23.3% 24.0% 24.8% 24.7% 24.9% 25.5% 25.9% 9.8% 10.0% 11.1% 11.7% 11.4% 11.6% 12.5% 13.8% 14.4% 14.3% 14.8% 15.3% 15.2% 15.4% 15.8% 16.1% P99-100 P99,5-100 P99,9-100 (3) (4) (5) 2.8% 2.7% 3.0% 3.3% 3.3% 3.5% 4.0% 4.2% 4.4% 4.2% 4.3% 4.5% 4.6% 4.7% 4.6% 4.8% 1.6% 1.6% 1.7% 1.9% 1.9% 2.1% 2.4% 2.5% 2.5% 2.4% 2.5% 2.7% 2.8% 2.8% 2.7% 2.9% 0.5% 0.5% 0.4% 0.5% 0.5% 0.6% 0.7% 0.8% 0.7% 0.7% 0.7% 0.7% 0.8% 0.8% 0.8% 0.9% P99-100 P99,5-100 P99,9-100 (4) (5) (6) 2.6% 2.7% 3.3% 3.4% 3.3% 3.4% 4.0% 4.3% 4.4% 4.4% 4.7% 4.9% 4.8% 4.8% 5.0% 5.1% 1.5% 1.5% 2.0% 2.0% 1.9% 2.0% 2.4% 2.6% 2.6% 2.6% 2.8% 2.9% 2.9% 2.8% 3.1% 3.1% 0.5% 0.5% 0.6% 0.6% 0.6% 0.6% 0.8% 0.7% 0.8% 0.7% 0.9% 0.9% 0.9% 0.9% 1.0% 1.0% P90-95 (6) P95-99 (7) 8.1% 7.9% 8.1% 8.2% 8.2% 8.1% 8.3% 8.8% 9.1% 9.0% 9.1% 9.3% 9.2% 9.3% 9.5% 9.6% 7.8% 7.8% 7.9% 8.3% 8.2% 8.3% 8.8% 9.5% 9.9% 9.8% 9.9% 10.0% 10.0% 10.2% 10.3% 10.5% P90-95 (8) P95-99 (9) 7.6% 7.8% 8.1% 8.0% 8.0% 7.9% 8.1% 8.8% 9.2% 9.0% 9.2% 9.5% 9.5% 9.6% 9.7% 9.8% 7.2% 7.3% 7.7% 8.3% 8.0% 8.2% 8.6% 9.5% 10.0% 9.9% 10.1% 10.4% 10.4% 10.6% 10.8% 11.0% P99-99,5 P99,5-99,9 P99,9-100 (8) (9) (10) 1.2% 1.2% 1.3% 1.4% 1.4% 1.4% 1.6% 1.7% 1.8% 1.7% 1.8% 1.8% 1.8% 1.9% 1.9% 1.9% 1.1% 1.1% 1.2% 1.4% 1.4% 1.4% 1.6% 1.8% 1.8% 1.8% 1.8% 2.0% 2.0% 2.0% 1.9% 2.0% 0.5% 0.5% 0.4% 0.5% 0.5% 0.6% 0.7% 0.8% 0.7% 0.7% 0.7% 0.7% 0.8% 0.8% 0.8% 0.9% P99-99,5 P99,5-99,9 P99,9-100 (10) (11) (12) 1.1% 1.2% 1.3% 1.4% 1.4% 1.4% 1.6% 1.8% 1.8% 1.8% 1.9% 2.0% 2.0% 1.9% 2.0% 2.0% 1.0% 1.0% 1.4% 1.5% 1.4% 1.4% 1.6% 1.8% 1.8% 1.9% 2.0% 2.0% 2.0% 2.0% 2.1% 2.1% 0.5% 0.5% 0.6% 0.6% 0.6% 0.6% 0.8% 0.7% 0.8% 0.7% 0.9% 0.9% 0.9% 0.9% 1.0% 1.0% Source:Authors'computations basedontop fractilesincomeslevelsreportedon TablesA2 and A3 132 - Qm CD .-I 0 - 0006 666666666666 O . N N O O 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 - - 1- - U~0q (P N' N C (2 oE MD ,o .0 rD )- ( 0. :3- O d, lyCL N OC- O O N ODLo - -i 0) t N t - 0) N 1 ,ob O--N~ I - - C- -0 N1 1 O 0 O0 0 ) 0 ~ C o6 C w ( C C'O t C 0 r19 N ') !t ) t- (NCO "I' - 0 0~ 02 c-N 1 t N M CO N 0 N (0 0) 0 - 11 Ot t (- ( CD ( N" Q t N (0 ci) E 5 ) -E C)*0) 0 C ON wD rN -o W ._ ° E cN 0 0Co Cj o 0 N 6 OOC' a- (0 COC-N) (0(0(0(0( C-0) CO) J 0 C - -(§ 0 '~ -CN NC')C ) (0 C)CDC0(00) (CO0 ) 0)000 C C'° '-0). Co O 6a- c\ cq r,:o c~ c~ op~ ~o ) n000e Iz) In sJ eD h-I eD 0(000 sc s ~ ~ N N0 .0 U C 0 d, aw O ° 0 ° CL N N C ° O ° o ( 0 CO 0 N ~ci566O0NC r) W C' 000 0 0 Ui (0 N (0 04 CO (0 V Ol0N) t o L~ 22 °0 .) u R 6K C 0o 0q 0 oS 0cS 0o R CO (0 7 u? CO c° (0 (R (0 0GF 0 Otot CO (0 O1= (0oD (Pqo= 9= 01 Cu ° C ( 0= a' N C- ._ OCC) 0 E x o- X 0 O-O7 00000 C5 CL 0 O O O66666666 0O 0…O N No O O 0) (D N - NO O O O OO - 0C? N N 0 X O it (0 0 ?0 OO PC~ C LO to C -ui= CD <ccU) X oiJ -o E 0 A C 0O 01 C O O O O O O O N0 JC~(~( o O 6Q 6t O O C- O 00 0 C 6 O C N (0 CO N C cc -, 0) c. o ' C.0 cci o'O m ]N 0O 0o 0C- 0 N N C1 0) ( 0 , N 0 °N 0) N (0 N O - N ID ( 0, c0U)1D0. N 0 (0 (0 e .0' L) u> -5 8QCC ' c 0 0 O ° (0 0 (0 oooO6oc .oo _= ( 0 (C - I_ o C 6 ~ a) co o ( (m c.0.0. EjEE~ c D0N O 0 C) q 04 - )D OOl N (O N o o~o o c) 6 ~ - 0 0 C' 0 0) -E0 0l ) ci) )X oEQ .0 (0 u coi~. (0 N't w 0. 2. 0 ( 0(0 oocD I- 0 N ( 0 (0 q N'Itm- --- N O N 0 0 O CO ( - (0 - (0 0) C- 0 N 0 N (0 s (0 -- (0 N (O (0 N C (0 0.2 00 D e - C C ') __,. E - O q 6~~~N c (q ci ci g~~~~~" 7 a-R 2D m EuO 0 N (0 (0(0(00 C- (0 0) 0 ) 0) 0 N )0)) C t ( 0) 0) 0) 0 i c 2N N N N N (0 - ( 0) 0 0) 0) 0) oS cI c 6oSI- )00)00)0)0)0 ci oo 0) ci~ ci N 0 CO 00 ci N C N N " N - a O C t 0 N 0 00 q Lo t t ( C 00 N 0 N 0 r- I a o o -4 (0 (0 (0 - (0 0) C 0 0 N 0 C N (\ ( U 000 N ? - __C 00 D ccipo