Research Article Lie-Algebraic Approach for Pricing Zero-Coupon Bonds in C. F. Lo

advertisement
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
Journal of Applied Mathematics
Volume 2013, Article ID 276238, 9 pages
http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2013/276238
Research Article
Lie-Algebraic Approach for Pricing Zero-Coupon Bonds in
Single-Factor Interest Rate Models
C. F. Lo
Institute of Theoretical Physics and Department of Physics, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Shatin, New Territories, Hong Kong
Correspondence should be addressed to C. F. Lo; cflo@phy.cuhk.edu.hk
Received 17 December 2012; Revised 9 April 2013; Accepted 11 April 2013
Academic Editor: Alvaro Valencia
Copyright © 2013 C. F. Lo. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which
permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
The Lie-algebraic approach has been applied to solve the bond pricing problem in single-factor interest rate models. Four of the
popular single-factor models, namely, the Vasicek model, Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model, double square-root model, and Ahn-Gao
model, are investigated. By exploiting the dynamical symmetry of their bond pricing equations, analytical closed-form pricing
formulae can be derived in a straightfoward manner. Time-varying model parameters could also be incorporated into the derivation
of the bond price formulae, and this has the added advantage of allowing yield curves to be fitted. Furthermore, the Lie-algebraic
approach can be easily extended to formulate new analytically tractable single-factor interest rate models.
1. Introduction
In this paper we apply the Lie-algebraic method to tackle the
bond pricing problem in single-factor interest rate models.
In particular, we investigate the bond pricing equation of the
form
𝐻 (𝑑) 𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
πœ•2
πœ•
1
πœ•π΅ (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
≡ { 𝜎(𝑑)2 π‘Ÿ] 2 + πœ‡ (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
− π‘Ÿ} 𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) =
,
2
πœ•π‘Ÿ
πœ•π‘Ÿ
πœ•π‘‘
(1)
where ] is a real parameter, πœ‡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) is a real function of both
spot interest rate π‘Ÿ and time-to-maturity 𝑑, 𝜎(𝑑) is the timevarying volatility, and 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) denotes the price of a zerocoupon bond of duration 𝑇 with a value of unity at maturity;
that is, 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 0) = 1. By exploiting the dynamical symmetry
π‘†π‘ˆ(1, 1) ⊕ β„Ž(1) of the bond pricing equation, we derive
analytically tractable single-factor interest rate models in a
unified manner and obtain their closed-form bond pricing
formulae. It is found that not only four of the popular singlefactor models, namely the Vasicek model [1], Cox-IngersollRoss model [2], double square-root model [3], and AhnGao model [4], can be derived in a straightforward manner,
but also new analytically tractable models can be formulated
systematically. Moreover, time-varying model parameters
can be incorporated into the derivation of the bond pricing
formulae without difficulty. This has the added advantage of
allowing yield curves to be fitted, and thus a “no-arbitrage”
yield curve model can be developed to match the current
market data.
The Lie-algebraic method was introduced by Lo and
Hui [5–7] to the field of finance for the pricing of financial
derivatives with time-dependent model parameters. This new
method is very simple and consists of two basic ingredients: (1) identifying the dynamical symmetries of the given
pricing partial differential equations and (2) applying the
Wei-Norman theorem [8] to solve the equations and obtain
analytical closed-form pricing formulae. For demonstration,
the Lie-algebraic approach has already been applied to price
European options for the constant elasticity of variance
processes and corporate discount bonds with default risk,
multiasset financial derivatives, and so forth. It should be
noted that the Lie-algebraic method is different from the
Lie group analysis which was introduced by Ibragimov and
his coauthors [9, 10] to tackle partial differential equations
occurring in financial problems. The Lie group analysis is a
mathematical theory developed by Sophus Lie and classifies
partial differential equations in terms of their symmetry
groups, thereby identifying the set of equations which could
2
Journal of Applied Mathematics
be integrated or reduced to low-order equations by group
theoretic algorithms. (Details of the Lie group analysis and
its application to partial differential equations can be found
in, for example, Hydon (2000) and Bluman et al. (2010)
[11, 12].) Further applications of the Lie group analysis
in mathematical finance were subsequently explored by a
number of papers, for example, Goard [13], Pooe et al. [14],
Goard et al. [15], Leach et al. [16], and Sinkala et al. [17]. A
recent review of the applications of the Lie theory to problems
in mathematical finance and economics can be found in [18].
where
π‘ˆ0 (𝑑) = exp {𝑐1 (𝑑) 𝐾+ } exp {𝑐2 (𝑑) 𝐾0 } exp {𝑐3 (𝑑) 𝐾− } ,
π‘ˆπΌ (𝑑) = exp {𝑔1 (𝑑) π‘Š1 } exp {𝑔2 (𝑑) π‘Š2 } exp {𝑔3 (𝑑) π‘Š3 } ,
𝑐1 (𝑑) = 0,
𝑑
𝑐2 (𝑑) = −2 ∫ πœ… (𝜏) π‘‘πœ,
0
𝑑
𝑐3 (𝑑) = ∫ 𝜎(𝜏)2 exp {𝑐2 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ,
0
2. Lie-Algebraic Approach
We consider a possible set of differential operators realizing
the Lie algebra π‘†π‘ˆ(1, 1) ⊕ β„Ž(1) [19]:
π‘Š1 = π‘Ÿπ›Ύ
𝐾− ≡
πœ•
− πœ†π‘Ÿπ›Ό ,
πœ•π‘Ÿ
π‘Š2 =
1 1−𝛾
π‘Ÿ ,
1−𝛾
1
𝑔1 (𝑑) = ∫ [πœ… (𝜏) πœƒ (𝜏) exp { 𝑐2 (𝜏)}
2
0
1
+𝑐3 (𝜏) exp {− 𝑐2 (𝜏)}] π‘‘πœ,
2
𝑑
1
𝑔2 (𝑑) = − ∫ exp {− 𝑐2 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ,
2
0
π‘Š3 = 1,
1 2 1 2𝛾 πœ•2
1
πœ•
+ ( π›Ύπ‘Ÿ2𝛾−1 − πœ†π‘Ÿπ›Ό+𝛾 )
π‘Š1 = π‘Ÿ
2
2
2 πœ•π‘Ÿ
2
πœ•π‘Ÿ
1
+ πœ†π‘Ÿπ›Ό (πœ†π‘Ÿπ›Ό − π›Όπ‘Ÿπ›Ύ−1 ) ,
2
𝐾0 ≡
(5)
𝑑
𝑑
1
1
𝑔3 (𝑑) = ∫ [ πœ… (𝜏) + 𝑔1 (𝜏) exp {− 𝑐2 (𝜏)}] π‘‘πœ.
2
0 2
As a result, the bond price 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) can be expressed as
1
1
πœ•
π‘Ÿ
(π‘Š1 π‘Š2 + π‘Š2 π‘Š1 ) =
4
2 (1 − 𝛾) πœ•π‘Ÿ
(2)
1
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) = exp { 𝑐2 (𝑑) + 𝑔3 (𝑑) + 𝑔2 (𝑑)
4
1
× [𝑔1 (𝑑) + 𝑐3 (𝑑) 𝑔2 (𝑑)]}
2
1
πœ†
+ −
π‘Ÿπ›Ό+1−𝛾 ,
4 2 (1 − 𝛾)
(6)
1
× exp {𝑔2 (𝑑) exp [ 𝑐2 (𝑑)] π‘Ÿ} .
2
1
1
𝐾+ ≡ π‘Š22 =
π‘Ÿ2(1−𝛾) ,
2
2
2(1 − 𝛾)
where 𝛼, 𝛾, and πœ† are real adjustable parameters (see
Appendix A). Then we try to look for appropriate linear
combinations of these operators, namely, 𝐻(𝑑) ≡ 𝐴 − (𝑑)𝐾− +
𝐴 0 (𝑑)𝐾0 + 𝐴 + (𝑑)𝐾+ + 𝐴 1 (𝑑)π‘Š1 + 𝐴 2 (𝑑)π‘Š2 + 𝐴 3 (𝑑)π‘Š3 , where
the coefficients are arbitrary scalar functions of 𝑑 only, to
produce the bond pricing equation given in (1). Here are some
illustrative examples.
(1) For 𝐴 − (𝑑) = 𝜎(𝑑)2 , 𝐴 0 (𝑑) = −4𝐴 3 (𝑑) = −2πœ…(𝑑),
𝐴 + (𝑑) = 0, 𝐴 1 (𝑑) = πœ…(𝑑)πœƒ(𝑑), 𝐴 2 (𝑑) = −1, 𝛾 = πœ† = 0, and 𝛼
being arbitrary, we recover the bond pricing equation of the
Vasicek model:
In the special case of constant model parameters, that is,
𝜎(𝑑) = 𝜎0 , πœ…(𝑑) = πœ…0 , and πœƒ(𝑑) = πœƒ0 , the 𝑐𝑖 (𝑑) and 𝑔𝑖 (𝑑) can
be analytically determined as
𝑐1 (𝑑) = 0,
𝑐2 (𝑑) = −2πœ…0 𝑑,
𝑐3 (𝑑) =
𝑔1 (𝑑) = (πœ…0 πœƒ0 −
+
πœ•2
πœ•
πœ•π΅ (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
1
− π‘Ÿ} 𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) =
.
{ 𝜎(𝑑)2 2 + πœ… (𝑑) [πœƒ (𝑑) − π‘Ÿ]
2
πœ•π‘Ÿ
πœ•π‘Ÿ
πœ•π‘‘
(3)
By applying the Wei-Norman theorem, we can derive the
bond price 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) as (see Appendix B)
𝜎02 1 − exp (−2πœ…0 𝑑)
},
{
2
πœ…0
𝜎02
1 − exp (−2πœ…0 𝑑)
){
}
2πœ…0
πœ…0
𝜎02 exp (πœ…0 𝑑) − 1
{
},
2πœ…0
πœ…0
𝑔2 (𝑑) = − {
𝑔3 (𝑑) =
(7)
exp (πœ…0 𝑑) − 1
},
πœ…0
𝜎2
𝜎2
1
πœ…0 𝑑 − (πœƒ0 − 02 ) 𝑑 + (πœƒ0 − 02 )
2
2πœ…0
2πœ…0
2
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) = π‘ˆ0 (𝑑) π‘ˆπΌ (𝑑) 𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 0) ,
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 0) = 1,
(4)
×{
𝜎2 exp (πœ…0 𝑑) − 1
exp (πœ…0 𝑑) − 1
}+ 0 {
},
πœ…0
4πœ…0
πœ…0
Journal of Applied Mathematics
3
and the bond price 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) is reduced to the well-known
closed-form expression [1]:
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) = exp {(πœƒ0 −
𝜎02
1
)[
2πœ…02
Accordingly, the bond price 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) is given by
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
− exp (−πœ…0 𝑑)
− 𝑑]
πœ…0
𝜎2 1 − exp (−πœ…0 𝑑)
]
− 0 [
4πœ…0
πœ…0
= exp {𝑔3 (𝑑) + 𝑔1 (𝑑) 𝑔2 (𝑑)
2
(8)
1
× exp {𝑔2 (𝑑) exp [ 𝑐2 (𝑑)] √2π‘Ÿ + 𝑐1 (𝑑) π‘Ÿ} .
2
1 − exp (−πœ…0 𝑑)
−[
− 𝑑] π‘Ÿ} .
πœ…0
Μƒ
(2) For 𝐴 − (𝑑) = 𝜎(𝑑)2 , 𝐴 0 (𝑑) = −4𝐴 3 (𝑑) = −2πœ†(𝑑),
𝐴 + (𝑑) = −1/2, 𝐴 1 (𝑑) = −πœ…(𝑑), 𝐴 2 (𝑑) = 0, 𝛾 = 1/2, πœ† = 0,
and 𝛼 being arbitrary, the bond pricing equation of the double
square-root model is reproduced:
πœ•2
1
1
Μƒ (𝑑) π‘Ÿ] πœ• − π‘Ÿ}
{ 𝜎(𝑑)2 π‘Ÿ 2 + [ 𝜎(𝑑)2 − πœ… (𝑑) √π‘Ÿ − 2πœ†
2
πœ•π‘Ÿ
4
πœ•π‘Ÿ
In the special case of constant model parameters, that is,
Μƒ
Μƒ , the 𝑐 (𝑑) and 𝑔 (𝑑) can
𝜎(𝑑) = 𝜎0 , πœ…(𝑑) = πœ…0 , and πœ†(𝑑)
= πœ†
0
𝑖
𝑖
be analytically determined as
=
Μƒ −𝛾
2𝛾
2πœ†
0
+ 2
,
𝜎02
𝜎0 [1 − 𝐢0 exp {𝛾𝑑}]
Μƒ 𝑑
𝑐2 (𝑑) = − 2πœ†
0
As in the Vasicek model, we apply the Wei-Norman theorem
to determine the bond price 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) as (see Appendix B)
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) = π‘ˆ0 (𝑑) π‘ˆπΌ (𝑑) 𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 0) ,
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 0) = 1,
(10)
+ 2 ln {
= 𝛾𝑑 + 2 ln {
𝑑𝑐1 (𝑑)
Μƒ (𝑑) 𝑐 (𝑑) + 1 𝜎(𝑑)2 𝑐 (𝑑)2 ,
= −1 − 2πœ†
1
1
𝑑𝑑
2
𝑔1 (𝑑) =
𝑐1 (0) = 0,
0
1 𝑑
𝑐3 (𝑑) = ∫ 𝜎(𝜏)2 exp {𝑐2 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ,
2 0
1 𝑑
1
∫ πœ… (𝜏) [𝑐1 (𝜏) 𝑐3 (𝜏) exp {− 𝑐2 (𝜏)}
√2 0
2
1
− exp { 𝑐2 (𝜏)}] π‘‘πœ,
2
1 𝑑
1
∫ πœ… (𝜏) 𝑐1 (𝜏) exp {− 𝑐2 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ,
√2 0
2
𝑔3 (𝑑)
𝑑
1
1Μƒ
1
πœ… (𝜏) 𝑐1 (𝜏) exp {− 𝑐2 (𝜏)} 𝑔1 (𝜏)] π‘‘πœ.
=∫ [ πœ†
(𝜏) +
√2
2
0 2
(11)
Μƒ
√2πœ…0 πœ†
0
𝛾2
−
𝑑
Μƒ (𝜏) + 𝜎(𝜏)2 𝑐 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ,
𝑐2 (𝑑) = ∫ {−2πœ†
1
2𝛾
Μƒ ) [1 − 𝐢 exp {𝛾𝑑}]
(𝛾 − 2πœ†
0
0
},
1
𝑐3 (𝑑) = − 𝜎02 𝑐1 (𝑑) ,
2
π‘ˆ0 (𝑑) = exp {𝑐1 (𝑑) 𝐾+ } exp {𝑐2 (𝑑) 𝐾0 } exp {𝑐3 (𝑑) 𝐾− } ,
π‘ˆπΌ (𝑑) = exp {𝑔1 (𝑑) π‘Š1 } exp {𝑔2 (𝑑) π‘Š2 } exp {𝑔3 (𝑑) π‘Š3 } ,
Μƒ ) 𝑑]
2𝛾 exp [(1/2) (𝛾 + 2πœ†
0
}
Μƒ ) (exp {𝛾𝑑} − 1) + 2𝛾
(𝛾 + 2πœ†
0
where
𝑔2 (𝑑) = −
2 (exp {𝛾𝑑} − 1)
Μƒ
(𝛾 + 2πœ† 0 ) (exp {𝛾𝑑} − 1) + 2𝛾
𝑐1 (𝑑) = −
(9)
πœ•π΅ (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
.
× π΅ (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) =
πœ•π‘‘
𝑔1 (𝑑) =
(12)
1
1
+ 𝑐3 (𝑑) 𝑔2 (𝑑)2 + 𝑐2 (𝑑)}
2
4
𝑔2 (𝑑) =
2
1
1
exp {− 𝛾𝑑} (1 − exp { 𝛾𝑑})
2
2
(13)
πœ…0
1
1
(exp { 𝛾𝑑} − exp {− 𝛾𝑑}) ,
√2𝛾
2
2
√2πœ…0
𝛾2
2
1
1
exp {− 𝛾𝑑} (1 − exp { 𝛾𝑑}) ,
2
2
Μƒ
πœ…02
πœ…02 πœ†
1Μƒ
0
−
)
𝑑
−
exp {−𝛾𝑑}
𝑔3 (𝑑) = ( πœ†
0
2
2
𝛾
𝛾4
4
1
× (1 − exp { 𝛾𝑑})
2
+
πœ…02
(exp {𝛾𝑑} − exp {−𝛾𝑑})
2𝛾3
Μƒ 2 + 2𝜎2 and 𝐢 = (2πœ†
Μƒ + 𝛾)/(2πœ†
Μƒ − 𝛾).
with 𝛾 = √4πœ†
0
0
0
0
0
Consequently, we are able to recover the well-known closedform expression of the bond price 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) [3]:
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) = Ψ (𝑑) exp {Ω (𝑑) π‘Ÿ + Γ (𝑑) √π‘Ÿ} ,
(14)
4
Journal of Applied Mathematics
where
where
𝑑
𝑐2 (𝑑) = ∫ 𝐴 0 (𝜏) π‘‘πœ,
1 − 𝐢0
Ψ (𝑑) = √
1 − 𝐢0 exp {𝛾𝑑}
0
𝑑
𝛼 + 𝛼4 exp {(1/2) 𝛾𝑑}
× exp (𝛼1 + 𝛼2 𝑑 + 3
),
1 − 𝐢0 exp {𝛾𝑑}
Μƒ −𝛾
2𝛾
2πœ†
,
Ω (𝑑) = 0 2 + 2
𝜎0
𝜎0 [1 − 𝐢0 exp {𝛾𝑑}]
Γ (𝑑) =
Μƒ + 𝛾) (1 − exp {(1/2) 𝛾𝑑})2
2πœ…0 (2πœ†
0
π›ΎπœŽ02 [1 − 𝐢0 exp {𝛾𝑑}]
𝑐3 (𝑑) = ∫ 𝜎(𝜏)2 exp {𝑐2 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ,
0
𝑑
𝑑
3
1
𝑔3 (𝑑) = ∫ [− 𝐴 0 (𝜏) + 𝑔1 (𝜏) exp {− 𝑐2 (𝜏)}] π‘‘πœ.
4
2
0
,
(4) For 𝐴 − (𝑑) = 𝜎(𝑑)2 , 𝐴 0 (𝑑) = −4𝐴 3 (𝑑)/3, 𝐴 + (𝑑) =
𝐴 2 (𝑑) = 0, 𝐴 1 (𝑑) = 1, 𝛾 = 2, and πœ† = 𝛼 = 1, we can derive the
bond pricing equation:
πœ…02
Μƒ + 𝛾) (2πœ†
Μƒ − 𝛾) ,
(4πœ†
0
0
𝛾3 𝜎02
𝛼2 =
Μƒ + 𝛾 πœ…2
2πœ†
0
− 02 ,
4
𝛾
4πœ…2
Μƒ 2 − 𝜎2 ) ,
𝛼3 = 3 02 (2πœ†
0
0
𝛾 𝜎0
𝛼4 = −
πœ•2
1
πœ•
1
− π‘Ÿ} 𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
{ 𝜎(𝑑)2 π‘Ÿ4 2 + [π‘Ÿ2 − 𝐴 0 (𝑑) π‘Ÿ]
2
πœ•π‘Ÿ
2
πœ•π‘Ÿ
πœ•π΅ (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
=
,
πœ•π‘‘
(16)
1
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) = 1 − 𝑔1 (𝑑) exp {− 𝑐2 (𝑑)} π‘Ÿ,
2
2
(3) For 𝐴 − (𝑑) = 𝜎(𝑑) , 𝐴 0 (𝑑) = −4𝐴 3 (𝑑)/3, 𝐴 + (𝑑) =
𝐴 1 (𝑑) = 0, 𝐴 2 (𝑑) = −1, 𝛾 = 0, and πœ† = 𝛼 = −1, a bond pricing
equation with a special time-dependent nonlinear drift term
can be obtained:
πœ•2
1
𝜎(𝑑)2 πœ•
1
]
− π‘Ÿ} 𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
{ 𝜎(𝑑)2 2 + [ 𝐴 0 (𝑑) π‘Ÿ +
2
πœ•π‘Ÿ
2
π‘Ÿ
πœ•π‘Ÿ
(20)
which has both the π‘Ÿ2 dependence of volatility and a timedependent nonlinear drift term. By performing the same
analysis as in the other three cases, the bond price 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) is
found to be given by (see Appendix B)
Μƒ
8πœ…02 πœ†
0
Μƒ + 𝛾) .
(2πœ†
0
𝛾3 𝜎02
πœ•π΅ (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
=
πœ•π‘‘
(19)
𝑑
1
𝑔2 (𝑑) = − ∫ exp {− 𝑐2 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ,
2
0
with
𝛼1 = −
1
𝑔1 (𝑑) = ∫ 𝑐3 (𝜏) exp {− 𝑐2 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ,
2
0
(15)
where
𝑑
𝑐2 (𝑑) = ∫ 𝐴 0 (𝜏) π‘‘πœ,
0
𝑑
1
𝑔1 (𝑑) = ∫ exp { 𝑐2 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ.
2
0
(17)
which can be straightforwardly solved as in the Vasicek
model. As a result, the bond price 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) can be expressed
as (see Appendix B)
3
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) = exp { 𝑐2 (𝑑) + 𝑔3 (𝑑) + 𝑔2 (𝑑)
4
1
× (𝑔1 (𝑑) + 𝑐3 (𝑑) 𝑔2 (𝑑))}
2
1
× exp {𝑔2 (𝑑) exp ( 𝑐2 (𝑑)) π‘Ÿ}
2
1
1
× {1 + [𝑔1 (𝑑) + 𝑐3 (𝑑) 𝑔2 (𝑑)] exp ( 𝑐2 (𝑑)) } ,
2
π‘Ÿ
(18)
(21)
(22)
Next we apply the same analysis to derive the CoxIngersoll-Ross model and Ahn-Gao model from an alternative set of differential operators realizing the subalgebra L of
the Lie algebra π‘†π‘ˆ(1, 1) ⊕ β„Ž(1):
πœ•2
πœ•
1
1
𝐾− = π‘Ÿ2𝛾 2 + ( 𝛾 − πœ†) π‘Ÿ2𝛾−1 + π›Όπ‘Ÿ2𝛾−2 ,
2 πœ•π‘Ÿ
2
πœ•π‘Ÿ
𝐾0 =
1
πœ• 1
πœ†
π‘Ÿ + −
,
2 (1 − 𝛾) πœ•π‘Ÿ 4 2 (1 − 𝛾)
𝐾+ =
1
2
2(1 − 𝛾)
(23)
π‘Ÿ2(1−𝛾) ,
π‘Š3 = 1,
where 𝛼, 𝛾, and πœ† are real adjustable parameters (see
Appendix A). The subalgebra L is actually the reductive Lie
algebra π‘ˆ(1, 1).
Journal of Applied Mathematics
5
(1) By choosing 𝛼 = 0, 𝛾 = 1/2, and πœ† = 1/4 − πœ…πœƒ/𝜎2 , the
bond pricing equation of the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model with
constant model parameters can be expressed in terms of the
differential operators realizing the subalgebra L as
2
πœ•
πœ•
πœ•π΅ (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
1
= { 𝜎2 π‘Ÿ 2 + πœ… (πœƒ − π‘Ÿ)
− π‘Ÿ} 𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
πœ•π‘‘
2
πœ•π‘Ÿ
πœ•π‘Ÿ
1
πœ…2 πœƒ
= {𝜎2 𝐾− − πœ…πΎ0 − 𝐾+ + 2 π‘Š3 } 𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) .
2
𝜎
πœ…πœƒ
[πœ…π‘‘ + 𝑐2 (𝑑)]} ,
𝜎2
where
𝑑𝑐1 (𝑑)
1
= − − πœ…π‘1 (𝑑) + 𝜎2 𝑐1 (𝑑)2 ,
𝑑𝑑
2
2
(24)
(31)
× exp {𝑐3 (𝑑) 𝐾− } 𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 0) ,
where 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 0) = 1 and
𝑑
(25)
𝑐2 (𝑑) = −𝜎2 ∫ π‘Ž (𝜏) π‘‘πœ,
0
2
(32)
𝑑
𝑐3 (𝑑) = 𝜎 ∫ exp {𝑐2 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ.
0
Without loss of generality, we suppose that 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 0)
π‘₯−(2π‘ž+1) 𝑉(π‘₯), where π‘₯ = 2/√π‘Ÿ,
∞
∞
0
0
𝑉 (π‘₯) = ∫ 𝑑]]𝐽𝑝 (π‘₯]) ∫ 𝑑𝑦𝑦𝐽𝑝 (𝑦]) 𝑉 (𝑦) ,
𝑐1 (0) = 0,
(26)
𝑑
𝑑
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) = exp {𝜎2 (π‘ž + 1) ∫ π‘Ž (𝜏) π‘‘πœ} exp {𝑐2 (𝑑) 𝐾0 }
0
(Strictly speaking, the model parameters πœ…, πœƒ, and 𝜎 could be
time-varying with the constraint that πœ…πœƒ/𝜎2 is independent of
time 𝑑.)
By the Wei-Norman theorem, the bond price 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) can
be easily determined as (see Appendix B)
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) = exp {2𝑐1 (𝑑) π‘Ÿ} exp {
where π‘Ž(𝑑) is a real function of 𝑑. Then applying the WeiNorman theorem allows us to represent the bond price 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
by (see Appendix B)
=
(33)
and 𝑝 = √(2π‘ž + 1)2 + 8/𝜎2 . It is not difficult to show that the
bond price 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) is given by
∞
𝑐2 (𝑑) = −πœ…π‘‘ + 𝜎 ∫ 𝑐1 (𝜏) π‘‘πœ.
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) = ∫ 𝑑π‘₯σΈ€  𝐺 (π‘₯, 𝑑; π‘₯σΈ€  , 0) 𝐡 (π‘ŸσΈ€  , 0) ,
0
The Riccati equation with constant coefficients in (26) can be
straightforwardly solved to yield
exp {𝛾𝑑} − 1
𝑐1 (𝑑) = −
(𝛾 + πœ…) (exp {𝛾𝑑} − 1) + 2𝛾
(27)
where π‘₯σΈ€  = 2/√π‘ŸσΈ€  and
π‘₯σΈ€ 
𝐺 (π‘₯, 𝑑; π‘₯ , 0) = π‘₯ [
]
π‘₯ exp {𝑐2 (𝑑) /2}
σΈ€ 
with 𝛾 = √πœ…2 + 2𝜎2 . Once the 𝑐1 (𝑑) has been found, we are
also able to obtain
2𝛾 exp {(1/2) (𝛾 + πœ…) 𝑑}
𝑐2 (𝑑) = −πœ…π‘‘ + 2 ln (
)
(28)
(𝛾 + πœ…) (exp {𝛾𝑑} − 1) + 2𝛾
via analytical integrations. Beyond question, our finding is in
agreement with the well-known closed-form result [2]:
2πœ…πœƒ/𝜎2
2𝛾 exp {(1/2) (𝛾 + πœ…) 𝑑}
)
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) = (
(𝛾 + πœ…) (exp {𝛾𝑑} − 1) + 2𝛾
2 (exp {𝛾𝑑} − 1) π‘Ÿ
× exp {−
}.
(𝛾 + πœ…) (exp {𝛾𝑑} − 1) + 2𝛾
(29)
(2) By setting 𝛼 = −1/𝜎2 , 𝛾 = 3/2, and πœ† = π‘ž + 3/4,
we can cast the bond pricing equation of the Ahn-Gao model,
which includes nonlinearity in the drift term and a realistic
π‘Ÿ3/2 dependence in the volatility (not only the nonlinear
drift term of the Ahn-Gao model is consistent with the
empirical findings of Aı̈t-Sahalia [20], but also the chosen π‘Ÿ3/2
dependence of volatility is the best fit power law for volatility
[21, 22]), in terms of the differential operators realizing the
subalgebra L into the form
πœ•2
πœ•π΅ (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
πœ•
1
= { 𝜎2 π‘Ÿ3 2 + 𝜎2 [π‘Ž (𝑑) π‘Ÿ − π‘žπ‘Ÿ2 ]
− π‘Ÿ} 𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
πœ•π‘‘
2
πœ•π‘Ÿ
πœ•π‘Ÿ
= {𝜎2 𝐾− − 𝜎2 π‘Ž (𝑑) 𝐾0 + 𝜎2 (π‘ž + 1) π‘Ž (𝑑) π‘Š3 } 𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) ,
(30)
(34)
0
σΈ€ 
∞
2π‘ž+1
× ∫ 𝑑]]𝐽𝑝 (π‘₯] exp {
0
× π½π‘ (π‘₯σΈ€  ]) exp {−
𝑐2 (𝑑)
})
2
(35)
𝑐3 (𝑑) 2
] }.
2
The function 𝐽𝑝 (πœ‰) is the Bessel function of the first kind of
order 𝑝. Here we have made use of the fact that π‘₯−(2π‘ž+1) 𝐽𝑝 (π‘₯])
is an eigenfunction of the operator 𝐾− with the eigenvalue
−]2 /2. The integral over ] can be analytically evaluated to give
[23]
π‘₯σΈ€ 2 + π‘₯2 exp {𝑐2 (𝑑)}
π‘₯σΈ€  π‘₯ exp {𝑐2 (𝑑) /2}
1
exp {−
} 𝐼𝑝 (
)
𝑐3 (𝑑)
2𝑐3 (𝑑)
𝑐3 (𝑑)
(36)
for 𝑝 > −1, π‘₯σΈ€  > 0, π‘₯ exp{𝑐2 (𝑑)/2} > 0, and | arg [𝑐2 (𝑑)/2]1/2 | <
πœ‹/4. The function 𝐼𝑝 (πœ‰) is the modified Bessel function of the
first kind of order 𝑝. As a result, 𝐺(π‘₯, 𝑑; π‘₯σΈ€  , 0) is found to be
given by
𝐺 (π‘₯, 𝑑; π‘₯σΈ€  , 0) =
π‘₯σΈ€ 
π‘₯σΈ€ 
( )
𝑐3 (𝑑) exp {(2π‘ž + 1) 𝑐2 (𝑑) /2} π‘₯
× πΌπ‘ (
π‘₯σΈ€  π‘₯ exp {𝑐2 (𝑑) /2}
)
𝑐3 (𝑑)
× exp {−
π‘₯σΈ€ 2 + π‘₯2 exp {𝑐2 (𝑑)}
}.
2𝑐3 (𝑑)
2π‘ž+1
(37)
6
Journal of Applied Mathematics
Since 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 0) = 1, we can readily derive the bond price 𝐡(π‘Ÿ, 𝑑)
as follows:
𝐡 (π‘Ÿ, 𝑑) =
π‘₯−(2π‘ž+1)
𝑐3 (𝑑) exp {(2π‘ž + 1) 𝑐2 (𝑑) /2}
× exp {−
∞
0
× πΌπ‘ (
=
[π‘Š1 , π‘Š2 ] = π‘Š3 ,
π‘Š1 = π‘Ÿπ›Ύ
(38)
Γ (𝑝 + 1 − πœ”)
2 exp {𝑐2 (𝑑)}
𝑀 (πœ”, 𝑝 + 1, −
)
𝑐3 (𝑑) π‘Ÿ
Γ (𝑝 + 1)
πœ”
×{
[π‘Š1 , π‘Š3 ] = [π‘Š2 , π‘Š3 ] = 0.
(A.1)
By direct substitution, a possible set of differential operators
realizing the Lie algebra can be identified as
π‘₯σΈ€ 2
}
2𝑐3 (𝑑)
π‘₯σΈ€  π‘₯ exp {𝑐2 (𝑑) /2}
)
𝑐3 (𝑑)
A. Generators of the Lie Algebra π‘†π‘ˆ(1, 1) ⊕ β„Ž(1)
and Its Subalgebras
The generators {π‘Š1 , π‘Š2 , π‘Š3 } of the Heisenberg-Weyl Lie
algebra β„Ž(1) obey the set of commutation relations [19]:
π‘₯2 exp {𝑐2 (𝑑)}
}
2𝑐3 (𝑑)
× ∫ 𝑑π‘₯σΈ€  π‘₯σΈ€ 2(π‘ž+1) exp {−
Appendices
2 exp {𝑐2 (𝑑)}
} ,
𝑐3 (𝑑) π‘Ÿ
π‘Š2 =
(A.2)
where 𝛼, 𝛾, and πœ† are real adjustable parameters. Then, in
terms of these generators one can construct the generators
{𝐾+ , 𝐾0 , 𝐾− } of the Lie algebra π‘†π‘ˆ(1, 1) as follows:
1
𝐾− ≡ π‘Š12
2
πœ•2
1
1
πœ•
= π‘Ÿ2𝛾 2 + ( π›Ύπ‘Ÿ2𝛾−1 − πœ†π‘Ÿπ›Ό+𝛾 )
2 πœ•π‘Ÿ
2
πœ•π‘Ÿ
1
+ πœ†π‘Ÿπ›Ό (πœ†π‘Ÿπ›Ό − π›Όπ‘Ÿπ›Ύ−1 ) ,
2
𝐾0 ≡
In this paper the Lie-algebraic method has been applied to
solve the bond pricing problem in single-factor interest rate
models. Four of the popular single-factor models, namely the
Vasicek model, Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model, double squareroot model, and Ahn-Gao model, are investigated, and
analytical closed-form pricing formulae are derived. Since
all the four bond pricing equations exhibit the dynamical
symmetry π‘†π‘ˆ(1, 1) ⊕ β„Ž(1) or its subgroup, their solutions
can be derived in a unified manner and have very similar
mathematical structures. This interesting feature helps shed
new light upon the systematic formulation of new analytically
tractable single-factor interest rate models, as demonstrated
in Section 2. Time-varying model parameters could also be
incorporated into the derivation of the bond price formulae
without difficulty. This has the added advantage of allowing
yield curves to be fitted, and thus a “no-arbitrage” yield
curve model can be developed to match the current market
data. Hence, we believe that the Lie-algebraic method will
provide an easy-to-use analytical tool for the bond pricing
problem. Furthermore, the Lie-algebraic approach can be
easily extended to the pricing of other standard European
interest rate derivatives for they differ from the zero-coupon
bonds in the final payoff conditions only [25].
1 1−𝛾
π‘Ÿ ,
1−𝛾
π‘Š3 = 1,
where πœ” = −(2π‘ž + 1 − 𝑝)/2, Γ(πœ‰) denotes the Gamma function
and 𝑀(πœ‰, πœ’, 𝜌) is the standard confluent hypergeometric
function [23, 24]. Furthermore, (38) will reproduce the wellknown closed-form result if the model parameter π‘Ž(𝑑) is
independent of time [4].
3. Conclusion
πœ•
− πœ†π‘Ÿπ›Ό ,
πœ•π‘Ÿ
1
(π‘Š1 π‘Š2 + π‘Š2 π‘Š1 )
4
=
(A.3)
1
πœ• 1
πœ†
π‘Ÿ + −
π‘Ÿπ›Ό+1−𝛾 ,
2 (1 − 𝛾) πœ•π‘Ÿ 4 2 (1 − 𝛾)
1
1
𝐾+ ≡ π‘Š22 =
π‘Ÿ2(1−𝛾)
2
2
2(1 − 𝛾)
which satisfy the set of commutation relations [19]:
[𝐾+ , 𝐾− ] = −2𝐾0 ,
[𝐾0 , 𝐾± ] = ±πΎ± .
(A.4)
These six generators {π‘Š1 , π‘Š2 , π‘Š3 , 𝐾+ , 𝐾0 , 𝐾− } in turn form
the Lie algebra π‘†π‘ˆ(1, 1) ⊕ β„Ž(1), which is defined by the
following set of commutation relations [19]:
[π‘Š1 , π‘Š2 ] = π‘Š3 ,
[π‘Š1 , π‘Š3 ] = [π‘Š2 , π‘Š3 ] = 0,
[𝐾+ , 𝐾− ] = −2𝐾0 ,
[π‘Š1 , 𝐾+ ] = π‘Š2 ,
1
[π‘Š2 , 𝐾0 ] = − π‘Š2 ,
2
[𝐾0 , 𝐾± ] = ±πΎ± ,
1
[π‘Š1 , 𝐾0 ] = π‘Š1 ,
2
[π‘Š2 , 𝐾− ] = −π‘Š1 ,
[π‘Š1 , 𝐾− ] = [π‘Š2 , 𝐾+ ] = [π‘Š3 , 𝐾0 ] = [π‘Š3 , 𝐾± ] = 0.
(A.5)
Journal of Applied Mathematics
7
In addition to the subalgebras π‘†π‘ˆ(1, 1) and β„Ž(1), we may also
form another subalgebra L in terms of the four generators
{π‘Š3 , 𝐾+ , 𝐾0 , 𝐾− } satisfying the commutation relations:
[𝐾+ , 𝐾− ] = −2𝐾0 ,
[𝐾0 , 𝐾± ] = ±πΎ± ,
[π‘Š3 , 𝐾0 ] = [π‘Š3 , 𝐾± ] = 0.
(A.6)
The subalgebra L is actually the reductive Lie algebra π‘ˆ(1, 1).
Moreover, it is not difficult to show that an alternative
realization of the set of generators of the Lie algebra L is given
by
πœ•2
πœ•
1
1
𝐾− = π‘Ÿ2𝛾 2 + ( 𝛾 − πœ†) π‘Ÿ2𝛾−1 + π›Όπ‘Ÿ2𝛾−2 ,
2 πœ•π‘Ÿ
2
πœ•π‘Ÿ
1
πœ• 1
πœ†
𝐾0 =
π‘Ÿ + −
,
2 (1 − 𝛾) πœ•π‘Ÿ 4 2 (1 − 𝛾)
𝐾+ =
1
2
2(1 − 𝛾)
(A.7)
π‘Ÿ2(1−𝛾) ,
π‘Š3 = 1,
where 𝛼, 𝛾, and πœ† are real adjustable parameters.
πœ•π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑)
= 𝐻𝑆 (𝑑) π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑) ,
πœ•πœ
(B.5)
πœ•π‘ˆπ‘… (𝑑)
= {π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑)−1 𝐻𝑅 (𝑑) π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑)} π‘ˆπ‘… (𝑑) .
πœ•π‘‘
(B.6)
Since 𝑅 is an ideal in 𝐿, we can easily see that π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑)−1
𝐻𝑅 (𝑑)π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑) is in 𝑅. The fact that 𝑅 is solvable makes it easy
to find π‘ˆπ‘… (𝑑) once π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑) has been found. More details can be
found in [8].
For illustration, we apply the Wei-Norman theorem to the
following cases.
B.1. Heisenberg-Weyl Lie Algebra β„Ž(1). The Heisenberg-Weyl
Lie algebra β„Ž(1) is defined by the set of commutation relations
[17]:
B. Wei-Norman Theorem
Consider the linear operator differential equation of the first
order
π‘‘π‘ˆ (𝑑)
= 𝐻 (𝑑) π‘ˆ (𝑑) ,
𝑑𝑑
to a set of coupled nonlinear differential equations of scalar
functions in (B.4).
Moreover, according to Levi’s Theorem, “If 𝐿 is a finitedimensional Lie algebra with radical 𝑅 which is the maximal
solvable ideal of the Lie algebra, then there exists a semisimple
subalgebra 𝑆 of 𝐿 such that 𝐿 is the semidirect sum 𝐿 = 𝑆 ⊕ 𝑅,”
in the equation π‘‘π‘ˆ(𝑑)/𝑑𝑑 = 𝐻(𝑑)π‘ˆ(𝑑), where 𝐻(𝑑) generates
𝐿, the decomposition 𝐿 = 𝑆⊕𝑅 gives rise to the corresponding
decomposition 𝐻(𝑑) = 𝐻𝑆 (𝑑) + 𝐻𝑅 (𝑑), where 𝐻𝑆 (𝑑) ∈ 𝑆 and
𝐻𝑅 (𝑑) ∈ 𝑅. Then it is easy to verify that π‘ˆ(𝑑) = π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑)π‘ˆπ‘… (𝑑)
where π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑) and π‘ˆπ‘… (𝑑) satisfy
π‘ˆ (0) = 1,
(B.1)
where 𝐻 and π‘ˆ are both time-dependent linear operators in a
Banach space or a finite-dimensional space. According to the
Wei-Norman theorem [8], if the operator 𝐻 can be expressed
as
𝑁
𝐻 (𝑑) = ∑ π‘Žπ‘› (𝑑) 𝐿 𝑛 ,
(B.2)
[π‘Š1 , π‘Š2 ] = π‘Š3 ,
[π‘Š1 , π‘Š3 ] = [π‘Š2 , π‘Š3 ] = 0,
of its generators {π‘Š1 , π‘Š2 , π‘Š3 }. Given that
𝐻 (𝑑) = π‘Ž1 (𝑑) π‘Š1 + π‘Ž2 (𝑑) π‘Š2 + π‘Ž3 (𝑑) π‘Š3 ,
π‘ˆ (𝑑) = exp {𝑔1 (𝑑) π‘Š1 } exp {𝑔2 (𝑑) π‘Š2 } exp {𝑔3 (𝑑) π‘Š3 } ,
(B.9)
where the time-dependent functions 𝑔𝑛 ’s satisfy a set of three
coupled nonlinear differential equations:
𝑑𝑔1 (𝑑)
= π‘Ž1 (𝑑) ,
𝑑𝑑
where π‘Žπ‘› ’s are scalar functions of time and 𝐿 𝑛 are the
generators of an 𝑁-dimensional solvable Lie algebra or a real
split 3-dimensional simple Lie algebra, then the operator π‘ˆ
can assume the following form:
π‘ˆ (𝑑) = ∏ exp {𝑔𝑛 (𝑑) 𝐿 𝑛 } .
(B.3)
𝑛=1
Here the 𝑔𝑛 ’s are time-dependent scalar functions to be
determined. To find the 𝑔𝑛 ’s, we simply substitute (B.2) and
(B.3) into (B.1) and compare the two sides term by term to
obtain a set of coupled nonlinear differential equations
𝑁
𝑑𝑔𝑛 (𝑑)
= ∑ πœ‚π‘›π‘š π‘Žπ‘š (𝑑) ,
𝑑𝑑
π‘š=1
𝑔𝑛 (0) = 0,
𝑑𝑔2 (𝑑)
= π‘Ž2 (𝑑) ,
𝑑𝑑
where πœ‚π‘›π‘š are nonlinear functions of 𝑔𝑛 ’s. Thus, we have
transformed the linear operator differential equation in (B.1)
(B.10)
𝑑𝑔 (𝑑)
𝑑𝑔3 (𝑑)
+ 𝑔1 (𝑑) 2
= π‘Ž3 (𝑑) .
𝑑𝑑
𝑑𝑑
It is obvious that the set of differential equations can be easily
solved by quadrature:
𝑑
𝑔1 (𝑑) = ∫ π‘‘πœπ‘Ž1 (𝜏) ,
0
𝑑
𝑔2 (𝑑) = ∫ π‘‘πœπ‘Ž2 (𝜏) ,
(B.4)
(B.8)
the Wei-Norman theorem states that π‘ˆ(𝑑) can be expressed as
𝑛=1
𝑁
(B.7)
0
𝑑
𝑔3 (𝑑) = ∫ π‘‘πœ [π‘Ž3 (𝜏) − π‘Ž2 (𝜏) 𝑔1 (𝜏)] .
0
As a result, the operator π‘ˆ(𝑑) is thus determined.
(B.11)
8
Journal of Applied Mathematics
B.2. π‘†π‘ˆ(1, 1) Lie Algebra. We consider the evolution equation
of the operator π‘ˆ(𝑑):
π‘‘π‘ˆ (𝑑)
= {π‘Ž1 (𝑑) 𝐾+ + π‘Ž2 (𝑑) 𝐾0 + π‘Ž3 (𝑑) 𝐾− } π‘ˆ (𝑑) ,
𝑑𝑑
where
𝑑𝑐1 (𝑑)
= π‘Ž1 (𝑑) + π‘Ž2 (𝑑) 𝑐1 (𝑑) + π‘Ž3 (𝑑) 𝑐1 (𝑑)2 ,
𝑑𝑑
𝑑
(B.12)
𝑐2 (𝑑) = ∫ {π‘Ž2 (𝜏) + 2π‘Ž3 (𝜏) 𝑐1 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ,
π‘ˆ (0) = 1,
0
𝑑
𝑐3 (𝑑) = ∫ π‘Ž3 (𝜏) exp {𝑐2 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ.
where the operators {𝐾+ , 𝐾0 , 𝐾− } form the π‘†π‘ˆ(1, 1) Lie
algebra defined by the commutation relations [19]:
[𝐾+ , 𝐾− ] = −2𝐾0 ,
[𝐾0 , 𝐾± ] = ±πΎ± .
(B.13)
According to the Wei-Norman theorem, the operator π‘ˆ(𝑑)
can be expressed in the product form
0
𝑐𝑖 (0) = 0,
(B.14)
where the time-dependent functions 𝑐𝑛 ’s satisfy a set of three
coupled nonlinear differential equations:
𝑑𝑐 (𝑑)
𝑑𝑐 (𝑑)
𝑑𝑐1 (𝑑)
− 𝑐1 (𝑑) 2
+ 𝑐1 (𝑑)2 exp {−𝑐2 (𝑑)} 3
= π‘Ž1 (𝑑) ,
𝑑𝑑
𝑑𝑑
𝑑𝑑
𝑑𝑐 (𝑑)
𝑑𝑐2 (𝑑)
− 2𝑐1 (𝑑) exp {−𝑐2 (𝑑)} 3
= π‘Ž2 (𝑑) ,
𝑑𝑑
𝑑𝑑
𝐻𝐼 (𝑑) = π‘Ž1 (𝑑) π‘Š1 + π‘Ž2 (𝑑) π‘Š2 + π‘Ž3 (𝑑) π‘Š3 ,
where
1
π‘Ž1 (𝑑) = 𝑏1 (𝑑) exp { 𝑐2 (𝑑)} − [𝑏1 (𝑑) 𝑐1 (𝑑) + 𝑏2 (𝑑)]
2
1
× π‘3 (𝑑) exp {− 𝑐2 (𝑑)} ,
2
(B.20)
1
π‘Ž2 (𝑑) = [𝑏1 (𝑑) 𝑐1 (𝑑) + 𝑏2 (𝑑)] exp {− 𝑐2 (𝑑)} ,
2
π‘Ž3 (𝑑) = 𝑏3 (𝑑) .
(B.15)
After further simplification, these three differential equations
become
π‘ˆπ‘… (𝑑) = exp {𝑔1 (𝑑) π‘Š1 } exp {𝑔2 (𝑑) π‘Š2 } exp {𝑔3 (𝑑) π‘Š3 } ,
(B.21)
where
𝑑
𝑔1 (𝑑) = ∫ π‘‘πœπ‘Ž1 (𝜏) ,
𝑐1 (0) = 0,
0
𝑑
𝑔2 (𝑑) = ∫ π‘‘πœπ‘Ž2 (𝜏) ,
𝑑
𝑐2 (𝑑) = ∫ {π‘Ž2 (𝜏) + 2π‘Ž3 (𝜏) 𝑐1 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ,
0
0
(B.22)
𝑑
𝑔3 (𝑑) = ∫ π‘‘πœ [π‘Ž3 (𝜏) − π‘Ž2 (𝜏) 𝑔1 (𝜏)] .
𝑑
𝑐3 (𝑑) = ∫ π‘Ž3 (𝜏) exp {𝑐2 (𝜏)} π‘‘πœ.
0
(B.19)
Then, the operator π‘ˆπ‘… (𝑑) can be easily found to be given by
𝑑𝑐3 (𝑑)
= π‘Ž3 (𝑑) .
𝑑𝑑
𝑑𝑐1 (𝑑)
= π‘Ž1 (𝑑) + π‘Ž2 (𝑑) 𝑐1 (𝑑) + π‘Ž3 (𝑑) 𝑐1 (𝑑)2 ,
𝑑𝑑
(B.18)
Next, in order to determine π‘ˆπ‘… (𝑑), we need to evaluate
𝐻𝐼 (𝑑) ≡ π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑)−1 𝐻𝑅 (𝑑)π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑). Using the explicit form of the
operator π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑), we can apply the Baker-Hausdorff formula
[26] to derive the operator 𝐻𝐼 (𝑑):
π‘ˆ (𝑑) = exp {𝑐1 (𝑑) 𝐾+ } exp {𝑐2 (𝑑) 𝐾0 } exp {𝑐3 (𝑑) 𝐾− } ,
exp {−𝑐2 (𝑑)}
𝑐1 (0) = 0,
0
(B.16)
Hence, once the 𝑐1 (𝑑) is found by solving the Riccati equation,
the 𝑐2 (𝑑) and 𝑐3 (𝑑) can be readily determined by quadrature.
B.3. π‘†π‘ˆ(1, 1) ⊕ β„Ž(1) Lie Algebra. If 𝐻(𝑑) is a linear combination of the six generators {π‘Š1 , π‘Š2 , π‘Š3 , 𝐾+ , 𝐾0 , 𝐾− } of the Lie
algebra π‘†π‘ˆ(1, 1) ⊕ β„Ž(1), then, according to Levi’s theorem, we
may decompose the 𝐻(𝑑) into two parts 𝐻𝑆 (𝑑) = π‘Ž1 (𝑑)𝐾+ +
π‘Ž2 (𝑑)𝐾0 + π‘Ž3 (𝑑)𝐾− and 𝐻𝑅 (𝑑) = 𝑏1 (𝑑)π‘Š1 + 𝑏2 (𝑑)π‘Š2 + 𝑏3 (𝑑)π‘Š3 ,
and the operator π‘ˆ(𝑑) assumes the product form π‘ˆ(𝑑) =
π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑)π‘ˆπ‘… (𝑑) where π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑) and π‘ˆπ‘… (𝑑) satisfy (B.5) and (B.6),
respectively. It is obvious that the operator π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑) is given by
π‘ˆπ‘† (𝑑) = exp {𝑐1 (𝑑) 𝐾+ } exp {𝑐2 (𝑑) 𝐾0 } exp {𝑐3 (𝑑) 𝐾− } ,
(B.17)
References
[1] O. Vasicek, “An equilibrium characterization of the term structure,” Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 5, no. 2, pp. 177–188,
1977.
[2] J. C. Cox, J. E. Ingersoll,, and S. A. Ross, “An intertemporal
general equilibrium model of asset prices,” Econometrica, vol.
53, no. 2, pp. 363–384, 1985.
[3] F. A. Longstaff, “A nonlinear general equilibrium model of the
term structure of interest rates,” Journal of Financial Economics,
vol. 23, no. 2, pp. 195–224, 1989.
[4] D. H. Ahn and B. Gao, “A parametric nonlinear model of term
structure dynamics,” Review of Financial Studies, vol. 12, no. 4,
pp. 721–762, 1999.
[5] C. F. Lo and C. H. Hui, “Valuation of financial derivatives with
time-dependent parameters: lie-algebraic approach,” Quantitative Finance, vol. 1, no. 1, pp. 73–78, 2001.
Journal of Applied Mathematics
[6] C. F. Lo and C. H. Hui, “Pricing multi-asset financial derivatives with time-dependent parameters—lie algebraic approach,”
International Journal of Mathematics and Mathematical Sciences, vol. 32, no. 7, pp. 401–410, 2002.
[7] C. F. Lo and C. H. Hui, “Lie-algebraic approach for pricing moving barrier options with time-dependent parameters,” Journal
of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, vol. 323, no. 2, pp.
1455–1464, 2006.
[8] J. Wei and E. Norman, “Lie algebraic solution of linear differential equations,” Journal of Mathematical Physics, vol. 4, no. 4, pp.
575–581, 1963.
[9] N. H. Ibragimov and C. W. Soh, “Solution of the Cauchy
problem for the Black-Scholes equation using its symmetries,”
in Proceedings of the International Conference on Modern Group
Analysis, N. H. Ibragimov, K. R. Naqvi, and E. Straume, Eds.,
MARS, Nordfjordeid, Norway, 1997.
[10] R. K. Gazizov and N. H. Ibragimov, “Lie symmetry analysis of
differential equations in finance,” Nonlinear Dynamics, vol. 17,
no. 4, pp. 387–407, 1998.
[11] P. E. Hydon, Symmetry Methods for Differential Equations: A
Beginner’s Guide, Cambridge University, New York, NY, USA,
2000.
[12] G. W. Bluman, A. F. Cheviakov, and S. C. Anco, Applications of
Symmetry Methods to Partial Differential Equations, Springer,
New York, NY, USA, 2010.
[13] J. Goard, “New solutions to the bond-pricing equation via Lie’s
classical method,” Mathematical and Computer Modelling, vol.
32, no. 3-4, pp. 299–313, 2000.
[14] C. A. Pooe, F. M. Mahomed, and C. W. Soh, “Fundamental
solutions for zero-coupon bond pricing models,” Nonlinear
Dynamics, vol. 36, no. 1, pp. 69–76, 2004.
[15] J. Goard, P. Broadbridge, and G. Raina, “Tractable forms of the
bond pricing equation,” Mathematical and Computer Modelling,
vol. 40, no. 1-2, pp. 151–172, 2004.
[16] P. G. L. Leach, J. G. O’Hara, and W. Sinkala, “Symmetry-based
solution of a model for a combination of a risky investment
and a riskless investment,” Journal of Mathematical Analysis and
Applications, vol. 334, no. 1, pp. 368–381, 2007.
[17] W. Sinkala, P. G. L. Leach, and J. G. O’Hara, “Zero-coupon
bond prices in the Vasicek and CIR models: their computation
as group-invariant solutions,” Mathematical Methods in the
Applied Sciences, vol. 31, no. 6, pp. 665–678, 2008.
[18] I. Hernández, C. Mateos, J. NúnΜƒez, and Á. F. Tenorio, “Lie
theory: applications to problems in mathematical finance and
economics,” Applied Mathematics and Computation, vol. 208,
no. 2, pp. 446–452, 2009.
[19] A. Perelomov, Generalized Coherent States and Their Applications, Springer, New York, NY, USA, 1986.
[20] Y. Aı̈t-Sahalia, “Testing continuous-time models of the spot
interest rate,” Review of Financial Studies, vol. 9, no. 2, pp. 385–
426, 1996.
[21] K. C. Chan, G. A. Karolyi, F. Longstaff, and A. B. Sanders, “An
empirical comparison of alternative models of the short-term
interest rate,” Journal of Finance, vol. 47, pp. 1209–1227, 1992.
[22] J. Y. Campbell, A. W. Lo, and A. C. MacKinlay, The Econometrics
of Financial Markets, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, USA,
1996.
[23] I. S. Gradshteyn and I. M. Ryzhik, Table of Integrals, Series, and
Products, Academic Press, Boston, Mass, USA, 5th edition, 1994.
[24] N. N. Lebedev, Special Functions and Their Applications, Dover
Publications, New York, NY, USA, 1972.
9
[25] P. Wilmott, S. Howison, and J. Dewynne, The Mathematics
of Financial Derivatives: A Student Introduction, Cambridge
University, New York, NY, USA, 1989.
[26] W. H. Louisell, Quantum Statistical Properties of Radiation, John
Wiley & Sons, New York, NY, USA, 1990.
Advances in
Operations Research
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Volume 2014
Advances in
Decision Sciences
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Volume 2014
Mathematical Problems
in Engineering
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Volume 2014
Journal of
Algebra
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Probability and Statistics
Volume 2014
The Scientific
World Journal
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Volume 2014
International Journal of
Differential Equations
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Volume 2014
Volume 2014
Submit your manuscripts at
http://www.hindawi.com
International Journal of
Advances in
Combinatorics
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Mathematical Physics
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Volume 2014
Journal of
Complex Analysis
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Volume 2014
International
Journal of
Mathematics and
Mathematical
Sciences
Journal of
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Stochastic Analysis
Abstract and
Applied Analysis
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
International Journal of
Mathematics
Volume 2014
Volume 2014
Discrete Dynamics in
Nature and Society
Volume 2014
Volume 2014
Journal of
Journal of
Discrete Mathematics
Journal of
Volume 2014
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Applied Mathematics
Journal of
Function Spaces
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Volume 2014
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Volume 2014
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Volume 2014
Optimization
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Volume 2014
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com
Volume 2014
Download