MINING, OIL, AND INEQUALITY Graham A. Davis Division of Economics and Business Colorado School of Mines 1500 Illinois St. Golden, Colorado 80401 U.S.A. +1 303 273 3550 May 1, 2014 ABSTRACT It is commonly presumed that economies specializing in mining and oil supply have high income inequality. Policy prescriptions follow. I use five different data sets on income inequality, three of which are recent and have good coverage of mining and oil economies, to examine whether there is a structural relationship between mining and oil production and income inequality. Overall, I find no robust evidence pointing to persistently higher income inequality in mining and oil economies. JEL Classifications: O13, O15, Q32, Q33, Q38 Keywords: mining, oil, income inequality, resource curse, economic development. Statement on Conflict of Interest: I am currently a short-term consultant for the World Bank and provide expert consulting services to law firms representing international mining companies during disputes over land holdings. None of these parties were involved in funding this research, and nor were they involved in any other way. 1 INTRODUCTION Over the past four decades many economies have experienced an increase in income inequality. The study of the origins of increasing inequality often focuses on productive activity. Why, for example, are developing economies that have become heavily involved in mining and oil production particularly prone to high inequality? Is it because of their relatively closed trade policies, neglect of public education, or poor institutional quality, all of which have been shown to increase income inequality (Spilimbergo et al. 1999, De Gregorio and Lee 2002, Chong and Gradstein 2007)? Is it because the inequitable land holdings established during colonization have persisted to the present day via institutions set up to maintain the status quo (Engerman and Sokoloff 2002)? Or is it because these economies have a consistently high ethnic polarization that prevents income redistribution (Fum and Hodler 2010)? These are all interesting questions, but this paper seeks to answer none of them. Instead, it investigates the premise driving these questions, that economies heavily involved in mining and oil supply have high income inequality. I start here because this is an outcome, despite the certitude with which it has been presented, that has yet to be empirically demonstrated. There are arguably 40 to 50 economies in which mining or oil production is significant enough to affect their paths of development. This is a quarter of the world’s economies. Establishing whether or not there is high income inequality across this group is an important step in guiding modern development policy. As one NGO warns, mining is not “just another industry” (Power 2002, p. 6). I first review the case for high income inequality in mining and oil economies, and then synthesize the existing empirical studies. The main body of the paper examines income inequality in mining and oil economies using two new proxies for oil and mining intensiveness, the revenues from oil and mining production per unit GDP and the revenues per economically active population, and five data sources for income inequality: Gini Indexes compiled by Chen and Ravallion (2001), Fum and Hodler’s (2010) selection of Gini Indexes from the UNU-WIDER World Income Inequality Database (WIID), a Theil Index of wage inequality (Conceição and Galbraith 2000), an Estimated Household Inequality Index (EHII) that combines the Gini Index measurements by Deininger and Squire (1996) with wage inequality data (Galbraith and Kum 2005), and an estimated Gini series by Solt (2009) that applies a 2 missing-data algorithm to the WIID data set. The latter three data sets have unusually good coverage for mining and oil economies, yet have not been previously applied to the question at hand. IS HIGH INCOME INEQUALITY A REASONABLE PROPOSITION? High income inequality in mining and oil economies is taken as fact in academic writings (e.g., Engerman and Sokoloff 1997, 2002; Sokoloff and Engerman 2004, Karl 2004, Page 2006), the popular press (e.g., Stiglitz 2006, p. 137), publications by non-governmental organizations (e.g., Ross 2001, Power 2002, Society for International Development 2013, Slack 2009), and at multilateral development agencies (e.g., Nankani 1979, de Ferranti et al. 2004). Income inequality can be a sign of a well-functioning economy transitioning along its optimal growth path (Leamer et al. 1999). In this case, however, the income inequality is alleged to be the kind that slows long-run growth and leads in the short run to high poverty and civil unrest.1 The ultimate concern is that inequality causes mining and oil economies to be at a development disadvantage, a far cry from the “distinct advantages” once thought to be held by countries like Libya, Zambia, Chile, and Peru (Johnston and Kilby 1975). The main focus of current academic analysis is appropriate corrective policy.2 My review of this and related literature has found that the claims of high inequality are for the most part based on interpretive analyses or casual empiricism. The academic literature on mining, oil, and inequality is sparse and inconclusive. Yet the claims have had bite. In June of 2001 the World Bank, responding to civil society’s criticisms of its support for extractive industry and the inequality and poverty that follow, initiated both an internal and an external Extractive Industries Review (EIR). The mining industry itself established the Minerals, Mining, and Sustainable Development (MMSD) initiative in 2000 and subsequently formed and funded the International Council on Mining and Metals (ICMM), which has conducted a series of case studies to examine mining’s contribution to development.3 Both the Bank and academics have called for continued studies on the effects of mining and oil extraction on the poor (Weber-Fahr 2002, Karl 2007, Ross 2007). The claim of high inequality, even if anecdotal, is not provocative at first glance. There are three paths by which productive activity can affect income inequality.4 The first is through direct factor receipts from production. Production that is concentrated in a few hands, either due to economies of scale or 3 the geography of endowments, could lead to income inequality (Leamer et al. 1999). Because of the point-source nature of mine and oil deposits and the large amounts of equity required for entry into the market, one could indeed imagine rents being disproportionately distributed to private or public sector elites. The rents from mining and oil have been shown to increase per capita national incomes (Alexeev and Conrad 2009), but they could also increase the spread around that mean by expanding the right tail of the income distribution. At the same time concentrated production could strengthen institutions with the power to maintain or worsen these direct effects in the long run (Engerman and Sokoloff, 1997, 2002). Leamer et al. (1999) posit an endowment-related story that has inequality temporarily rising in mining and oil economies as their development proceeds, a type of Kuznets effect. In their model economies without nonrenewable resources or capital-intensive agriculture, on the other hand, would see a decline in income inequality over time. A second, more complete analysis recognizes that resource extraction creates complex factor movement and spending effects associated with a booming mineral sector. Goderis and Malone (2011) present a structural model of a resource-producing economy with learning by doing and these additional spending effects. They find that wage inequality can rise or fall during and subsequent to a resource price shock. The increase or decrease in inequality depends on the initial distribution of labor in the economy. They propose that wage inequality will fall in developing economies during a price boom because of increasing wage income of unskilled workers relative to skilled workers. Gylfason and Zoega (2003), on the other hand, build a model that predicts that discoveries of mining and oil endowments unequivocally raise income inequality during a boom, though with the possibility that taxes that protect the shrinking manufacturing sector can mitigate the impact by reducing the size of the discoveries and through this the increase in inequality.5 A third view recognizes the power of government, or institutions more broadly, to affect the distribution of income via rent-concentrating rent seeking or rent-disbursing taxation. Government often receives a large portion of mining and oil rent through direct equity participation or royalties and taxes. An additional effect on factor receipts is government spending on infrastructure financed by this taxation or by spending from accumulated Sovereign Wealth Funds.6 Using rents to reduce income inequality and build a social safety net was, for example, a common goal in the OPEC member countries (Amuzegar 1999, p. 8). Redistribution programs were also undertaken in some mining 4 economies, even at the expense of economic growth (Donaldson, 2008).7 There is also the countervailing thought that once governments avail themselves of mining and oil income they no longer need to tax citizens’ income or consumption (Bornhorst et al. 2009). Any progressive redistribution that was in place would dissipate. The effects of different redistribution policies are evident in the data; in an empirical investigation of income inequality in 44 countries, Latin American countries’ average Gini Index is 7 to 9 points higher than other countries in the sample after controlling for stage of development and mix of endowments (Leamer et al. 1999).8 Leamer et al. attribute these 7 to 9 points in part to differences in government policy across regions. The implication is that Latin America’s penchant for redistributive taxation is lower than in other regions. Adelman and Morris (1973), one of the first to find quantitative evidence linking nonrenewable resource abundance with high income inequality, note that resource-abundant countries with government programs aimed at health and education had significantly lower income inequality than those without such programs. In the end, once the indeterminate effects of mining and oil production on factor receipts are added to indeterminate effects of income redistribution that range from inequality-reducing social welfare programs to inequality-increasing rent-grabbing, there is no a priori reason to believe that income inequality in mining and oil economies will be unusually high. This makes claims that there is a structural link between resource extraction and income inequality all the more interesting, as they must reflect a story that data is revealing. THE EXTANT EMPIRICAL LITERATURE Thirteen peer-reviewed papers examine the relationship between natural resource wealth or production and income inequality. Only four of the papers have specifically tested whether mining and oil economies have unusually high levels of income inequality. I take some time here to review these 13 papers because I can find no existing synthesis and because I find that their record on mineral production and income inequality is far from clear. In the first of the four papers that specifically test the impact of mining and oil production on income inequality, Bourguignon and Morrisson (1990) find that the 10 mining and oil exporting countries in their sample of 35 small- and medium-sized developing economies had significantly higher income 5 inequality than the rest of the sample. Income inequality is measured by 1970 income shares of economically active individuals prior to redistribution, testing the pure factor receipts model of resources and inequality. Human capital accumulation was the only other significant determinant of income inequality, though its effect on the regression R2 is small compared with that of mining and oil exports. As an interesting side note, nine of the ten mining and oil economies in the sample had nationalized their resource industries by 1970, and yet the income inequality associated with resource production in that year persisted. Bourguignon and Morrison suggest that the inequality at that point was bequested from the time when the resources were discovered, which was under private ownership. This is a frightening proposition, as it means that any income inequality established during a resource boom may persist for decades after the boom has ended. A second paper that revises the raw data, increases the sample size from 35 to 38, and changes the empirical specification slightly finds that mining and oil exports are in fact not a statistically significant determinant of income inequality (Bourguignon and Morrisson 1998). The small sample size and sparse coverage of mining and oil economies in these two studies is typical.9 Leamer et al. (1999) use 1980 and 1990 Gini Index data from Deininger and Squire (1996) to measure inequality.10 They find that after conditioning for stage of development, tropical agriculture production creates income inequality while manufacturing production results in a more equitable income distribution. There is evidence that fertilizer, coal, natural gas, and metals production as a group promotes inequality, but that result is by no means definitive due to weak statistical significance. Surprisingly, oil production does not promote inequality. Since the Deininger and Squire (1996) Gini Index data includes pre-tax and post-tax income surveys as well as expenditure surveys (see Galbraith and Kum 2005, Table 2), Leamer et al. are likely picking up some post re-distribution effects rather than the pure factor receipt effects that they model. Their sample size is small, at less than 50 developed and developing countries. Easterly (2001) tests Engerman and Sokoloff’s proposition that tropical agricultural commodity exporters and oil and mining exporters have high income inequality. In a sample of 102 countries he finds the share of income accruing to the middle three income quintiles to be low in nonfuel commodity exporters compared with non-commodity exporters. Oil exporters have higher middle income shares than the nonfuel commodity exporters, but lower middle income shares than non6 commodity exporters. My reproduction of his analysis reveals that the sample includes only six oil producers (Algeria, Iran, Nigeria, Trinidad and Tobago, Turkmenistan, and Venezuela) and that many income share estimates are based on a single survey year over the 1960 to 1996 sample period.11 The next two papers regresses Gini Indexes on broad, aggregate measures of natural resource stocks. Gylfason and Zoega (2003) pool World Bank WDI Gini Indexes that again contain pre-tax and posttax observations of income inequality. They find that income inequality is positively correlated with natural resource wealth as share of total national wealth in 1994 for a sample of 75 countries, but that it is not correlated with natural resource wealth per capita. The resource wealth estimates come from the World Bank (1997).12 Gylfason and Zoega do not separately analyze the inequality associated with subsoil wealth, which is typically less than 30% of natural resource wealth (World Bank 1997).13 Fum and Hodler (2010) use WIID Gini Indexes and World Bank subsoil resource wealth estimates in an analysis of endowments and inequality. They specifically exclude Gini Indexes computed from pretax income surveys in order to measure inequality “after the political processes of rent seeking and redistribution.” They also exclude low-quality Gini estimates. In a cross-sectional analysis of income inequality for 75 developed and developing countries they find that having subsoil wealth (as averaged across the World Bank data for 1994 and 2000, in per capita terms) has decreased or increased income inequality, depending on the degree of ethnic polarization present in an economy. Subsoil wealth lowered inequality in economies with an ethnic polarization index of less than 0.70, and raised inequality otherwise. Fum and Hodler theorize that this is because of a penchant for equal sharing of the rents to support the poor in low ethnic polarization economies and a winner-take-all competition for rents in polarized economies. Of the 81 countries with ethnic polarization data and nonzero subsoil wealth, at the ethnic polarization cutoff of 0.70 there are 18 countries that will have experienced increasing income inequality as a result of their mineral endowments and 63 that will have experienced decreased income inequality.14 There is nothing notable about those 18 economies that have higher income inequality as a result of their mineral endowments – the grouping does not explain Latin America’s high income inequality, for example, since only 30% of the Latin American and Caribbean economies with subsoil wealth have ethnic polarization indexes greater than 0.70. That there can be both increased and decreased income inequality in mining and oil economies, depending on ethnic polarization, lends support to the idea that even if the pure endowment effect on the equality of factor 7 receipts is negative, as may be the case for coal, natural gas, and metals (Leamer et al. 1999), strategic redistribution efforts by the state can lead to positive net income outcomes. Fum and Hodler do not test whether subsoil wealth results on average in higher net income inequality, which is the claim that my paper is investigating. Using their data, regression 1 in Table 1 shows that more subsoil wealth on average lowers income inequality. This may be because of the inclusion of countries like Norway and Canada in the sample. Using Leamer et al.’s suggestion that less developed economies have structurally higher income inequality, regression 2 controls for stage of development using income per capita. It also controls for survey type, since income-based surveys have been shown to reveal higher inequality than expenditure-based surveys (Deininger and Squire 1996).15 Subsoil wealth now has no overall effect on income inequality. I do not control for additional factors that may influence inequality since the claims I refer to in the Introduction of the paper are made unconditionally.16 Controlling for level of development using income per capita may create a false development peer group for mining and oil economies, which have temporarily high GDP per capita due to their booming resource sector (Alexeev and Conrad 2009, Davis 2009). Regression 3 controls for stage of development using regional and economic dummies. Again, there is no indication that subsoil wealth increases income inequality on average. The adjusted R2 of the regression rises considerably once the regional dummies are added. This is not surprising since dramatic regional differences in income inequality have been noted elsewhere (Besley and Burgess 2003, Galbraith and Kum 2005). Regression 4 confirms that my control variates in regression 3 still produce Fum and Hodler’s finding that country-specific inequality outcomes depend on a proclivity for rent redistribution that varies with ethnic polarization.17 While the results in Table 1 may appear to definitively reject claims of overall higher income inequality in mining and oil economies, I do not put much faith in the World Bank subsoil wealth data used as the independent variable to detect oil and mining economies, even though its ubiquity in analyses of resource curse issues led me to take this short investigative detour. The World Bank data is not useful because of the limited number of minerals that it measures, its methodology for computing resource wealth, and the fact that resource wealth has no obvious relationship to mining and oil supply. 8 For example, Ireland is measured to have more subsoil wealth per capita than Peru or Zambia, two mining stalwarts. Canada’s economy is measured to have ten times the per capita subsoil wealth as Botswana, the most mining intensive country in the world. This downgrading of Botswana is because the World Bank measure does not include diamond production. Nor does the data include platinumgroup metal production, and so the subsoil wealth measure is likely to seriously underestimate South Africa’s and Russia’s endowments.18 Another three papers conduct a dynamic (changes in levels) analysis. Being interested in dynamics rather than levels, none of these studies measures whether the cumulative effects of booms and busts that resource economies experience over time yields a high ultimate level of income inequality, which is the question at hand. Davis (2009) examines changes in income inequality during 240 positive and negative growth episodes in 21 mining and oil economies and 67 non-mineral economies from 1956 to 1999. The mining and oil economies have slightly more frequent unambiguous reductions in income inequality than non-mineral economies and slightly less frequent unambiguous increases in income inequality.19 Goderis and Malone (2011) examine changes in Gini Indexes during a commodity price index boom.20 They find that wage inequality falls during an oil and gas price boom and via symmetry find the opposite in commodity price busts. 21 There is no response to an agricultural price boom. This does not test for the equilibrium level of wage inequality in mining and oil economies, only that the level will temporarily go down when prices rise and will temporarily go up when prices fall. The effect is very small, with a maximum decline of 0.37 Gini Index points for the most resource intensive country in the sample, Zambia, when faced with a two-sigma price shock.22 The effect measured by Goderis and Malone dissipates to zero after 20 years. Given that most current mining and oil economies came to their economic status as extractive economies as a result of sustained production booms that originated more than 20 years ago, the inference from Goderis and Malone’s results is that these economies should not have steady state wage inequality that is any different from non-mineral economies. In the last dynamics paper Davis and Vásquez Cordano (2013) conduct a random effects panel analysis of mining and oil booms in 57 developed and developing countries. They find no evidence that booms in mining and oil production worsen income inequality. The last four papers look specifically at local and regional effects of mining. Output booms at the Yanacocha gold mine in Peru increase incomes equally across the local population (Aragón and Rud 9 2013, fn 48), though Loayza at al. (2012) suggest that this is a best-case scenario due to international pressures for redistribution at that mine site. Loayza at al. find that mining in Peru as a whole has increased income inequality, as measured by the Gini Index, across and within districts proximate to mining activity, though the effect is very small; they measure a roughly 1 point increase in the Gini Index in mining districts compared with non-mining districts. Reeson et al. (2012) measure a 3 point Gini Index increase in the Statistical Local Areas within Australia where significant numbers of mining employees reside. Buccellato and Mickieviz (2009) use a panel estimation of within-region income inequality in Russia and find that oil and gas production per capita is associated with higher income inequality as measured by productions’ effect on quintile income shares and differences between low and high quintiles shares. They also find that oil and gas production contributes to between-region income inequality in Russia. In a recent summary of the literature on natural resources and growth, including the papers by Gylfason and Zoega (2003), Fum and Hodler (2010), and Goderis and Malone (2011), van der Ploeg (2011, p. 406) opines that “The best available empirical evidence suggests that countries with a large share of primary exports in GNP have bad growth records and high inequality, especially if quality of institutions, rule of law, and corruption are bad. This potential curse is particularly severe for pointsource resources such as diamonds and precious metals.” In my view the evidence in these and the other papers I have reviewed is mixed. Certainly nothing in particular can be said of inequality in economies that produce point-source resources like diamonds and precious metals because the data in the papers that examine inequality do not include diamonds or platinum-group metals. Moreover, the small sample size in these papers, with a bias away from the top mining and oil producers due to their listwise deletion, is likely to lead to unreliable results. The studies of regional effects in Peru, Australia, and Russia are more compelling since one may reasonably expect localized income inequality in and around producing districts. But this does not imply or confirm a general tendency towards income inequality at the national level or across all mining and oil producers. 10 A NEW LOOK AT THE DATA ON MINING, OIL, AND INCOME INEQUALITY To recap, the question is a simple one: is income inequality unconditionally higher than expected in countries identified as mining and oil intensive? Given the casual empiricism that pervades statements about income inequality and mineral wealth we are not looking for some hard-to-find residual effect in a comprehensive system of equations. We are looking for bald evidence that is obvious to all. In this light I initially simply divide developing economies into mining economies, oil economies, and nonmineral economies and then test for differences in mean income inequality across these groups. The groups are formed by measuring the revenues from mining and oil production circa 1990 at 1990 US dollar import prices and then ranking countries by revenues per economically active population or revenues per unit of 1990 GDP measured in current US dollars.23 Categorizing mining and oil intensity using GDP as the numeraire risks having the groupings influenced by the effect of oil and mining production on GDP. The resource curse, for example, may result in mining and oil economies having lower than normal levels of income. A categorization based on mining and oil revenues per GDP will then tend to include failing economies with low GDP and only moderate mineral revenues. It will likewise exclude successful mineral economies with high GDP. A better numeraire is population (Alexeev and Conrad 2009). I elect to use working-age population to avoid eliminating African countries from the oil and mining country groupings due to Africa’s burgeoning numbers of youth and resultant high population counts. Mining and oil production in 1990 is taken from the US Bureau of Mines Minerals Yearbooks. I consider production in 22 mined products, including coal, diamonds and platinum-group metals, and three petroleum products (oil, natural gas, and natural gas liquids).24 I assembled three different samples for my groupings of mining and oil economies: the top 15 mining economies and the top 20 oil economies worldwide; the top 20 mining economies and top 25 oil economies; and the top 25 mining economies and top 30 oil economies. The first sample includes only the most intensive mining and oil producers, while the last adds less intensive producers. After reviewing the countries included and excluded in each sample my preferred grouping is the most inclusive grouping, the top 25 mining economies and top 30 oil economies, as this ensures that Norway and Kazakhstan are included as oil producers, and that Russia and Zambia are included as mining producers. This also matches well what the IMF considers to be resource-intensive economies (Baunsgaard et al. 2012). The Appendix lists the country groupings for this sample and the income inequality coverage provided by each of the inequality data bases that I use in this paper. In the 11 analysis that follows I elect to separately analyze the mining and oil producers because the rents attributable to oil production are so much higher than the rents attributable to the same value of mining production and because the impacts of oil production on societies appears to be different from that of mining production (Ross 2004, Karl 2007, Petermann et al. 2007).25 This separation also prevents a non-effect from mining production clouding the effect from oil production where countries produce both products. In the next two sections I look for high pre-redistribution income inequality and post-redistribution income inequality in developing economies with extensive mining and oil production using a comparison of means. This is followed by a more traditional least-squares analysis. 1. Inequality Prior to Redistribution Effects The periodic nature of household income surveys combined with the unusually high volatility of the Gini Index values computed across sequential surveys has led researchers to look for other measures of income inequality. Conceição and Galbraith (2000) have constructed a “long and dense” time series Thiel Index of manufacturing wage inequality. Manufacturing includes the 26 two-digit ISIC classifications, which range from Agriculture and Hunting to Insurance. The data, available at the University of Texas Inequality Project (UTIP) web site, covers 154 countries over 4,030 observations from 1963 to 2008.26 Wage inequality is useful because it reflects the pure endowment effect on factor receipts prior to redistributive policies that vary by country. An added benefit to this data series is that it includes inequality data for all of the Middle East oil producers except for Saudi Arabia. Other measures of income inequality for these countries either do not exist or are of poor quality. Galbraith et al. (2000) suggest that this measure of inequality may behave differently from the more comprehensive income inequality that Gini Indexes are trying to measure, but that it has the advantage of coverage, consistency, and accuracy.27 Figure 1 presents a first look at differences in mean income inequality between 1963 to 2008 for developing mining economies, developing oil economies, and developing non-mineral economies using the per worker numeraire, along with inequality data for the 23 OECD economies. I separate out the OECD countries in an effort to control for stage of development. Wage inequality is measured by 12 the log of the Conceição and Galbraith Thiel Index of manufacturing wage inequality. A more negative number indicates less wage inequality. The two lines at the bottom of the chart show the total number of mining and oil economies for which wage inequality data exists in a given year. Given that I have identified a total of 25 mining and 30 oil economies in the sample, this gives an indication of the lack of data completeness that plagues research on resource wealth and income inequality, even when using this broad-based data set. Since the sample is not consistent across years, this wage inequality data should not be viewed as a time series. Rather, it is a series of separate year-by-year cross-country inequality comparisons. The data in Figure 1 show that the developing mining economies for which I have data on average have a tendency for lower wage inequality than non-mineral developing economies. This is contrary to the expectation in Leamer et al. (1999), who predict that wage inequality should be high in these economies during their mining boom. On the other hand, the oil economies for which I have data do have a tendency for higher wage inequality compared to non-mineral economies. A SatterthwaiteWelch two-tail t-test shows that the oil economies have a statistically higher average wage inequality than the non-mineral economies in three years, 1998, 2000, and 2001. A non-parametric Wilcoxon/Mann-Whitney test of medians confirms the results of the t-test. The fact that some years show a statistically significant difference while others do not is due to varying countries in the sample from year to year rather than changing conditions in these economies. The mean wage inequality in the mining economies is never statistically higher than in the non-mineral economies. The wage inequality in the OECD economies is lower than in all three of the developing economy groupings. Figure 2 repeats the exercise for mining and oil economies categorized by mining and oil revenue per unit GDP rather than per worker. This categorization has moved some low inequality mining economies with high GDPs from the mining group to the non-mineral group and replaced them with high inequality mining economies, the failed states that have low GDPs given their mineral output. The coverage of wage inequality data for the mining group, which now includes more failed states with no data, has dropped as a result. The inequality for those mining economies for which I have data has risen substantially, with income inequality now statistically higher than the non-mineral group for 1963, 1964, 1965, and 2003 using a Satterthwaite-Welch two-tail t-test. The oil grouping has 13 statistically higher wage inequality in 1997, 1999, and from 2003 to 2006. A Wilcoxon/Mann-Whitney test of medians confirms the t-tests in Figure 2 except for oil in 2003, 2004, and 2006. My conclusion from this data is that the direct (i.e., pre-redistribution) factor receipts from mining and oil production are in some samples more unequally distributed than in non-mineral economies. The evidence is not strong enough to support a claim that the higher inequality was a general tendency from 1963 through 2008. I also find that it matters whether one classifies an economy based on its mining and oil output per worker or per unit GDP. The latter, which has a bias towards including failed states in the mining and oil aggregate, shows stronger support for claims that the inherent nature of mining and oil production increases inequality in factor receipts, though again the evidence is not overwhelming. Overall, the preponderance of the evidence shows no persistent statistically different level of income unequality in mining and oil economies. 2. Inequality After Redistribution Effects As noted in the Introduction, governments in oil and mining economies, perhaps recognizing the inherent tendency for mining and oil production to worsen income inequality, may have attempted to use tax revenues from such production to improve the lot of the poor. There are arguments, on the other hand, that rent-seeking and a ruling elite have instead concentrated that wealth. The wage inequality data used in the previous section is unlikely to pick up these effects. It will also miss income inequality generated by unemployment or investment income. To examine a more comprehensive link between mining and oil production and income inequality I use an income-based Gini Index developed by Galbraith and Kum (2005). They generate a set of Estimated Household Inequality Indexes (EHII) that take advantage of the household pre-tax and post-tax income and expenditure surveys reported by Deininger and Squire (1996) but that also include the accuracy and consistency of the wage inequality data used in the previous section. The Index is the forecast from the regression I = α + βT + γ X + ε where I is the log of the Deininger and Squire (1996) Gini Index, T is log of the Thiel index of manufacturing pay inequality referred to in the previous section, and X is a vector of conditioning 14 variables including dummies for the various types of household surveys (e.g., income versus expenditure). I downloaded the estimated Gini Index data from the University of Texas Inequality Program web site.28 It contains 3,872 estimated Gini Index measurements over 149 countries from 1963 to 2008, only slightly lower than coverage of wage inequality used in the previous section. It again includes inequality data for all of the Middle Eastern oil producers save Saudi Arabia. Figures 3 and 4 repeat my analysis in the previous section using this measure of income inequality. Once again, when countries are grouped according to per capita mining and oil revenues the inequality in the oil economies is higher than the inequality in the non-mineral economies (Figure 3). The difference in means is statistically significant in seven of the samples using a t-test, though a Wilcoxon/Mann-Whitney test of medians confirms the t-tests only for 1964, 1965, and 2000. The income inequality in the mining economies is for the most part lower than the income inequality in the non-mineral economies, though the difference is not statistically significant for any year. The same analysis when done using GDP as the numeraire when measuring mining and oil intensity (Figure 4) reveals that the mining economies have a tendency towards higher than average income inequality. Once again it matters how one measures whether an economy is heavily engaged in mining and oil activity. Under this measure there are more samples for which both mining and oil economies have statistically higher income inequality than in the last section. A t-test shows higher mining economy inequality in 1963, 1964, 1965, and 2003, though the difference in inequality in 1963 and 1964 is not robust under a Wilcoxon/Mann-Whitney test of medians. There is higher inequality of oil economies in 1963, 1964, 1965, 1969, 1970, 1992, and from 1998-2006 based on a t-test, though a Wilcoxon/MannWhitney test of medians only finds higher income inequality in 1998, 2000, and 2002-2006. I have thus far measured mining and oil intensity two different ways and measured income inequality two different ways, resulting in 184 separate comparisons of mean income inequality between 1963 and 2008. Four results are evident. First, there is no indication that the average level of income inequality in oil or mining economies is always or even generally higher than in non-mineral economies. Second, normalizing mining and oil revenue by GDP creates a very different set of economies within the mining and oil groups than when normalizing by population (see the Appendix). Egypt, Nigeria, and Yemen, for example, are denominated as oil suppliers under the ‘oil per GDP’ measure, but not in the ‘oil per capita’ measure. Given that these countries’ income inequality is 15 unusually high, their inclusion in a data set that parses countries based on energy revenue per unit GDP strengthens the claim that energy economies are more unequal. If the analysis instead parses countries according to oil revenue per capita, these countries’ inclusion in the non-mineral grouping will strengthen the counterclaim that oil economies have unusually low income inequality. This is evident in my analysis: Figures 2 and 4 give very different impressions of inequality in mining and oil economies than Figures 1 and 3. I and others have argued that normalization by population avoids biasing the mining and oil groupings with a disproportionate number of failed economies, and so I put more faith in the analysis shown in Figures 1 and 3. Third, by comparing Figures 1 and 3 and 2 and 4, redistribution of factor incomes in mining and oil economies due to taxes or other programs has if anything increased the level of income inequality. Finally, the average level of income inequality in all three groups of developing economies – mining, oil, and non-mineral – is markedly higher than that of the OECD economies, though the gap is narrowing over time as inequality in the OECD rises (Galbraith and Kum 2005). 3. Mining and oil supply as continuous variables The analysis so far has compared simple averages across discrete country groupings. I now present linear regressions in the style of Fum and Hodler (2010) that make use of the continuous measure of mining and oil revenue that I have compiled. Four different measures of income inequality are used as the independent variable. I first use the post-redistribution WIID Gini Indexes compiled by Fum and Hodler (2010). The availability of this Gini Index data for the major mining and oil producers is shown in the Appendix. Note the limited data available for most of the oil producing nations. Table 2 repeats the analysis in regressions 3 and 4 in Table 1 but now using mining or oil revenue as the resource intensity variable instead of the stock of subsoil wealth as measured by the World Bank. There is no evidence that higher mining or oil revenue is associated with higher post-redistribution income inequality.29 Higher oil revenue per unit of GDP is actually associated with lower income inequality, with a two-standard-deviation change in log oil revenue resulting in a 4 point drop in the Gini Index.30 Surprisingly, ethnic polarization has no explanatory power in these regressions. If we are to believe that oil production inherently worsens income inequality, as hinted at in Figures 1 and 2, redistributive efforts within these economies have more than offset these nefarious effects of production. The lack of 16 significance of ethnic polarization indicates that such redistributive efforts are not dependent on ethnic homogeneity. In Table 3 I repeat the analysis using the EHII Gini Indexes from UTIP, as introduced in Figures 3 and 4 above. I average the Index for each country over a 1980-2008 sample period, a period that spans the year in which I measure mining and oil revenue.31 As I noted above, the advantage of this series is its availability for a large number of countries of interest to this paper (see the Appendix, which reports the mining and oil countries with at least one inequality data point in the 1980-2008 period). This inequality measure is internally adjusted for household survey type, so I no longer need the survey dummies. In Table 3 there is evidence that oil production is associated with increased income inequality, as was previously indicated in Figures 3 and 4 and which drew on the same data set. The impact of a two-standard-deviation increase in log oil revenue is 3 Gini Index points. There is no evidence of higher income inequality in mining economies. Solt (2009) produces a similar “estimated” Gini Index series based on WIID survey data. His series has about the same mining and oil country coverage as the EHII Gini but has the advantage of supplying both pre-tax and post-tax indices.32 Recomputing the four regressions in Table 3 using this data series, with the Gini indices for each country again averaged from 1980 to 2008, produces statistically insignificant coefficients on mining and oil revenue for both the pre-tax and post-tax Gini series (results not shown). The last measure of income inequality within countries is a Gini Index created by Chen and Ravallion (2001). Chen and Ravallion’s data was published on a now defunct World Bank web site http://www.worldbank.org/research/povmonitor/, and was updated from time to time.33 It is based on primary data from household surveys of income or expenditure in the poorer developing and transitional countries of the world.34 Besley and Burgess (2003) use it in their landmark study of regional income inequality. Over the years I monitored the site and collated the data. In the end, after cross-checking my data against Besley and Burgess’s compilation, there are 295 valid Gini Indexes over 85 countries from 1980 to 2002. These 85 countries represent about 89% of the population of the developing world. The richest country in the data set is Chile, at $3,864 per capita in 1993 PPP dollars. My inspection of the data does not find the type of questionable inequality volatility in countries from 17 year to year as found in the Deininger and Squire (1996) inequality data that preceded it (Galbraith and Kum 2005). To nevertheless smooth possible errors across surveys within each country I take Easterly’s (2007) suggestion and average the Gini Index values for each country, producing 85 data points. The availability of this Gini Index data for the mining and oil producers is shown in the Appendix. Dummies are again used for averages that include only income surveys, only expenditure surveys, or both. I now exclude the OECD dummy as none of the countries in the Chen and Ravallion data set are from the OECD. To continue to control for income and hence development differences across countries I replace the OECD control with controls for countries in East Asia and the Pacific, the Middle East and North Africa, and South Asia. These dummies reflect regional inequality relative to the base case of Eastern Europe and Central Asia, which have low income inequality. Table 4 produces the estimates using this data. Now mining production is associated with higher income inequality, while oil production is not. A two-standard-deviation increase in log mining output results in a 2 point increase in the Gini Index. Because of the small amount of ethnic polarization data for this 85 country sample I do not produce the regressions testing for the effect of ethnic polarization on inequality. CONCLUSIONS Measuring income inequality is fraught with difficulty, and I am keenly aware of the missing income inequality data for some of the mining and oil economies thought to be most problematic. Measuring whether or not an economy is mining or oil intensive is also problematic, the measure at a minimum being sensitive to the way one conditions for scale. I have sought to deal with these difficulties by including two measures of resource production and multiple measures of income inequality. I can find no robust evidence pointing to the higher income inequality in mining and oil economies that much of the interpretive literature alludes to; whether or not mining and oil production is associated with higher or lower income inequality depends on the way that mining and oil production is defined, the way inequality is measured, and, no doubt, the country sample available for each pair of measures. At best, a two standard deviation increase in log oil revenue creates a 4 point Gini Index decrease (mining production was never found to decrease income inequality). At worst, a two standard deviation increase in log mining or oil revenue creates a 2 to 3 point Gini Index increase. 18 My descriptive study of the data is by no means complex or exhaustive. It may well be that reverse causality or omitted variables are masking a strong relationship between mining, oil, and inequality. It may be that inequality is found only in diamond producers, or in countries with dictators. Or it may be that redistributive, educational, and institutional policies have already corrected what would otherwise be high inequality. Until those nuances are uncovered, the absence of any obvious statistical regularity suggests that caution be exercised when alleging a deterministic relationship between mining or oil production and economy-wide income inequality. It also raises immediate questions as to the need for broad-based policies that further reduce inequality at the national level. The more prudent approach may well be targeted programs aimed at reducing the inequality that has been convincingly measured at the regional level. 19 Appendix: Mining and Oil Cohorts and their Gini Index Coverage Measure of Production Intensity: Mining and Oil Revenue per Unit GDP Top 30 Oil Top 25 Mining Economies FH EHII S CR Economies FH EHII Albania Albania Botswana Algeria Central African Republic Angola Chile Azerbaijan China Bahrain Gabon Brunei Guinea Congo Guyana Ecuador Jordan Egypt Gabon Kazakhstan Liberia Indonesia Macedonia Iran Iraq# Mauritania Mongolia Kazakhstan Namibia Kuwait New Caledonia Libya Papua New Guinea Malaysia Poland Nigeria Sierra Leone Norway* South Africa Oman Suriname Qatar Togo Russian Federation Ukraine Saudi Arabia Syria Zaire Trinidad and Tobago Zambia Turkmenistan United Arab Emirates Uzbekistan Venezuela Yemen Totals 11 17 23 15 Totals 6 24 S CR 22 13 # *OECD member as of 1990. Iraq is included in this grouping even though there is no GDP data for this country. FH = Fum and Hodler Gini Index, EHII = Galbraith and Kum estimated Deininger and Squire Gini Index, S = Solt estimated WIID Gini Index, CR = Chen and Ravallion Gini Index. 20 Measure of Production Intensity: Mining and Oil Revenue per Economically Active Population Top 30 Oil Top 25 Mining Economies FH EHII S CR Economies FH EHII S Australia* Algeria Bosnia And Herzegovina Angola Botswana Australia* Bulgaria Azerbaijan Canada* Bahrain Chile Brunei Czechoslovakia/Czech Rep. Canada* Gabon Congo Greece* Ecuador Gabon Jamaica Jordan Iran Iraq Kazakhstan Macedonia Kazakhstan Mauritania Kuwait Mongolia Libya Namibia Malaysia New Caledonia Mexico Papua New Guinea Netherlands* Poland Norway* Russian Federation Oman South Africa Qatar Suriname Russian Federation Ukraine Saudi Arabia Syria United States* Trinidad and Tobago Zambia Turkmenistan United Kingdom* United Arab Emirates United States* Venezuela Totals 13 21 24 15 Totals 9 25 CR 22 9 *OECD member as of 1990. FH = Fum and Hodler Gini Index, EHII = Galbraith and Kum estimated Deininger and Squire Gini Index, S = Solt estimated WIID Gini Index, CR = Chen and Ravallion Gini Index. 21 REFERENCES Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A., 2012, Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty. New York: Crown Business. Adelman, Irma, and Morris, Cynthia Taft, 1973, Economic Growth and Social Equity in Developing Countries. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Alexeev, Michael, and Conrad, Robert, 2009, The elusive curse of oil, Review of Economics and Statistics 91.3, 586-598. Amuzegar, Jahangir, 1999, Managing the Oil Wealth: OPEC’s Windfalls and Pitfalls. London: I. B. Tauris. Aragón, Fernando M., and Rud, Juan Pablo, 2013, Natural resources and local communities: evidence from a Peruvian gold mine, American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 5.2, 1-25. Askari, Hossein, Nowshirvani, V., and Jaber, M., 1997, Economic Development in the Countries of the GCC: The Curse and Blessing of Oil. London: JAI Press. Atkinson, Anthony B., and Brandolini, Andrea, 2001, Promise and pitfalls in the use of “secondary” data-sets: income inequality in OECD countries as a case study, Journal of Economic Literature 39, 771-799. Baunsgaard, Thomas, Villafuerte, Mauricio, Poplawski-Ribeiro, Marcos, and Richmond, Christine, 2012, Fiscal Frameworks for Resource Rich Developing Economics, IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/12/04, May 16. Besley, Timothy, and Burgess, Robin, 2003, Halving global poverty, Journal of Economic Perspectives 17.3, 3-22. Bornhorst, F., Gupta, S., and Thornton, J. (2009). Natural resource endowments and the domestic revenue effort, European Journal of Political Economy 25, 439-446. Bourguignon, F., and Morrisson, C., 1990, Income distribution, development and foreign trade: a cross-sectional analysis, European Economic Review 34, 1113-1132. Bourguignon, F., and Morrisson, C., 1998, Inequality and development: the role of dualism, Journal of Development Economics 57, 233-257. 22 Buccellato, T., and Mickieviz, T., 2009, Oil and gas: a blessing for the few. Hydrocarbons and inequality within regions in Russia, Europe-Asia Studies 61, 248-264. Burgess, Robin, and Stern, Nicholas, 1993, Taxation and development, Journal of Economic Literature 31.2, 762-830. Carmignani, Fabrizio, 2013, Development outcomes, resource abundance, and the transmission through inequality, Resource and Energy Economics 35, 412-428. Chen, Shaohua, and Ravallion, Martin, 2001, How did the world’s poorest fare in the 1990s?, Review of Income and Wealth 47.3, 283-300. Chong, A., and Gradstein, M., 2007, Inequality and institutions, Review of Economics and Statistics 89, 454-465. Conceição, Pedro, and Galbraith, James K., 2000, Constructing long and dense time series of inequality using the Theil statistic, Eastern Economic Journal 26.1, 61-74. David, P., and Wright, G., 1997, Increasing returns and the genesis of American resource abundance, Industrial and Corporate Change 6, 203-245. Davis, Graham A., 2009. Extractive economies, growth and the poor, in Mining, Society, and a Sustainable World, Richards, Jeremy P., ed. Berlin: Springer-Verlag, pp. 37-60. Davis, Graham A., and Vásquez Cordano, Arturo L., 2013, The fate of the poor in growing mineral and energy economies, Resources Policy 38, 138-151. De Ferranti, David, Perry, Guillermo E., Ferreira, Francisco H. G., and Walton, Michael (2004), Inequality in Latin America: Breaking with History? World Bank, Washington, DC. De Gregorio, J., and Lee, J. W., 2002, Education and income inequality: new evidence from crosscountry data, Review of Income and Wealth 48, 395-416. Deaton, Angus, 2003, Measuring Poverty in a Growing World (or Measuring Growth in a Poor World), National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 9822, July. Deininger, Klaus, and Squire, Lyn, 1996, A new data set measuring income inequality, World Bank Economic Review 10.3, 656-591. 23 Donaldson, John A., 2008, Growth is good for whom, when, how? Economic growth and poverty reduction in exceptional cases, World Development 36.11, 2127-2143. Easterly, William, 2001, The middle class consensus and economic development, Journal of Economic Growth 6, 317-335. Easterly, William, 2007, Inequality does cause underdevelopment: insights from a new instrument, Journal of Development Economics 84, 755-776. Engel, Eduardo M. R. A., Galetovic, Alexander, and Raddatz, Claudio E., 1999, Taxes and income distribution in Chile: some unpleasant redistributive arithmetic, Journal of Development Economics 59, 155-192. Engerman, Stanley L., and Sokoloff, Kenneth L., 1997, Factor endowments, institutions, and different paths of growth among new world economics, in How Latin America Fell Behind, Haber, Stephen, ed. Stanford: Stanford University Press, pp. 260-304. Engerman, Stanley L., and Sokoloff, Kenneth L., 2002, Factor endowments, inequality, and different paths of development among new world economies, Economia Fall, 41-109. Fum, Ruikang Marcus, and Hodler, Roland, 2010, Natural resources and income inequality: the role of ethnic divisions, Economics Letters 107, 360-363. Galbraith, James K., and Kum, Hyunsub, 2005, Estimating the inequality of household incomes: a statistical approach to the creation of a dense and consistent global data set, Review of Income and Wealth 51.1, 115-143. Galbraith, James K., Conceição, Pedro, and Kum, Hyunsub, 2000, Inequality and growth reconsidered once again: some new evidence from old data, University of Texas Inequality Project Working Paper No. 17. Gallup, John Luke, 2012, Is there a Kuznets curve? Working paper, Portland State University. Gelb, Alan, 1985, Are Oil Windfalls a Blessing or a Curse? Policy Exercises with an Indonesia-like Model, Discussion Paper, Washington, DC: Development Research Department, Economics and Research Staff, the World Bank. Gelb, Alan, and Associates, 1988, Oil Windfalls: Blessing or Curse? New York: Oxford University Press. 24 Goderis, Benedikt, and Malone, Samuel W., 2011, Natural resource booms and inequality: theory and evidence, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113.2, 388-417. Gylfason, Thorvaldur, and Zoega, Gylfi, 2003, Inequality and economic growth: do natural resource matter?, in Inequality and Growth, Eicher, Theo S., and Turnovsky, Stephen J., eds. Cambridge: MIT Press, pp. 255-292. Gylfason, Thorvaldur and Zoega, Gylfi, 2006, Natural resources and economic growth: the role of investment," World Economy 29.8, 1091-1115. Humphreys, Macartan, Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Stiglitz, Joseph E., eds., 2007, Escaping the Resource Curse. New York: Columbia University Press Johnston, Bruce F., and Kilby, Peter, 1975, Agriculture and Structural Transformation. New York, Oxford University Press. Karl, Terry Lynn, 2004. Oil-led development: Social, political, and economic consequences, in Encyclopedia of Energy, Vol. 4, Cleveland, Cutler J., editor-in-chief. Philadelphia: Elsevier, pp. 661672. Karl, Terry Lynn, 2007. Ensuring fairness: the case for a transparent fiscal social contract, in Escaping the Resource Curse, Macartan, Humphreys, Sachs, Jeffrey D, and Stiglitz, Joseph E., eds. New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 256–285. Leamer, Edward E., Maul, Hugo, Rodriquez, Sergio, and Schott, Peter K., 1999. Does natural resource abundance increase Latin American income inequality?” Journal of Development Economics 59, 3-42. Loayza, Norman, Mier y Teran, Alfredo, and Rigolini, Jamele, 2012, Poverty, Inequality, and the Local Natural Resource Curse, unpublished manuscript. Nankani, Gobind, 1979, Development problems of mineral exporting countries, World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 354. Page, John, 2006, Strategies for pro-poor growth: pro-poor, pro-growth, or both?, Journal of African Economies 15.4, 510-542. Petermann, Andrea, Guzman, Juan, and Tilton, John, 2007, Mining and corruption, Resources Policy 32.3, 91-103. 25 Power, Thomas Michael, 2002, Digging to Development: A Historical Look at Mining and Development. Boston: Oxfam America. Reeson, A. F., Measham T. G., and Hosking, K., 2012, Mining activity, income inequality and gender in Australia, Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 56.2, 302-313. Richards, Jeremy P., ed., 2009, Mining, Society, and a Sustainable World. Berlin: Springer-Verlag Ross, Michael, 2001, Extractive Sectors and the Poor. Boston: Oxfam America. Ross, Michael, 2004, What do we know about natural resources and civil war?, Journal of Peace Research 41.3, 337-356. Ross, Michael, 2007, How mineral-rich states can reduce inequality, in Escaping the Resource Curse, Humphreys, Macartan, Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Stiglitz, Joseph E., eds. New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 238-255. Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Warner, Andrew M., 1997, Natural Resources Abundance and Economic Growth, Working Paper, November, Harvard University. Segal, Paul, 2011, Resource rents, redistribution, and halving global poverty: the resource dividend, World Development 39.2, 475-489. Slack, Keith, 2009, The role of mining in the economies of the developing countries: time for a new approach, in Mining, Society, and a Sustainable World, Richards, Jeremy P., ed. Berlin: SpringerVerlag, pp. 75-90. Society for International Development, 2013. The State of East Africa 2013. Nairobi. Sokoloff, Kenneth L., and Engerman, Stanley L., 2000, Institutions, factor endowments, and paths of development in the new world, Journal of Economic Perspectives 14.2, 217-232. Solt, Frederick, 2009, Standardizing the World Income Inequality Database, Social Science Quarterly 90.2, 231-242. Spilimbergo, A., Londono, J. L., and Szekely, M., 1999, Income distribution, factor endowments, and trade openness, Journal of Development Economics 59, 77-101. Spolaore, Enrico, and Wacziarg, Romain, 2013, How deep are the roots of economic development?, Journal of Economic Literature 51.2, 325-369. 26 Stiglitz, Joseph E., 2006, Making Globalization Work. New York: W. W. Norton and Co. Stijns, Jean-Philippe C., 2005, Natural resource abundance and economic growth revisited, Resources Policy 30, 107-130. van der Ploeg, Frederick, 2011, Natural resources: curse or blessing?, Journal of Economic Literature 49.2, 366-420. van der Ploeg, Frederick, and Steven Poelhekke, 2010, The pungent smell of “red herrings”: subsoil assets, rents, volatility, and the resource curse, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 60: 44-55. Weber-Fahr, Monika, 2002. Treasure or Trouble? Mining in Developing Countries. International Finance Corporation: Washington, DC. Available at http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTOGMC/Resources/treasureortrouble.pdf World Bank, 1997, Expanding the Measure of Wealth: Indicators of Environmentally Sustainable Development. Washington DC. 27 Table 1: World Bank subsoil wealth estimates and income inequality C Log subsoil wealth Log GDP per capita Income-based survey Expenditure-based survey Sub-Saharan Africa Latin America and Caribbean OECD Ethnic polarization Ethnic polarization x log subsoil wealth Dependent variable: Average Fum and Hodler WIID Gini Index, 1990 - 2004 (3) (4) (1) (2) 46.32*** 67.36*** 34.05*** 38.59*** (3.89) (10.28) (3.14) (3.99) -0.86** 0.17 0.20 -1.08** (0.35) (0.38) (0.33) (0.51) -4.35*** (1.30) 8.30** 5.56** 5.42** (3.24) (2.14) (2.11) 3.55 2.99 2.15 (3.49) (1.96) (2.04) 11.27*** 8.99*** (2.78) (2.55) 10.59*** 8.80*** (2.55) (2.50) -9.79*** -8.62*** (2.67) (2.88) -4.29 (4.57) 1.89** (0.81) Adjusted R2 0.05 0.26 0.59 0.63 Observations 78 78 78 75 Notes: Data from Fum and Hodler (2010). Income dummy = 1 if all Gini surveys for a country are income based or if surveys are a combination of income and expenditure. Expenditure dummy = 1 if all surveys for a country are expenditure based or a combination of income and expenditure. Significance at 1% ***, 5% ** and 10% *. Robust standard errors in parentheses. 28 Table 2: Income inequality as measured by Fum and Hodler C Log mining revenue/worker Log oil revenue/worker Log mining revenue/GDP Log oil revenue/GDP Income-based survey Expenditure-based survey Sub-Saharan Africa Latin America and Caribbean OECD Ethnic polarization Ethnic polarization x log mining revenue/cap Ethnic polarization x log oil revenue/cap Ethnic polarization x log mining revenue/GDP Ethnic polarization x log oil revenue/GDP Dependent variable: Average Fum and Hodler Gini Index, 1990 – 2004 (3) (4) (1) (2) 37.14*** 38.33*** 38.97*** 38.37*** (2.78) (3.40) (2.30) (2.64) 0.78 -0.05 (0.44) (0.84) -0.43 -0.51 (0.29) (0.62) 7.06 -15.41 (7.11) (51.26) -17.02*** -29.26 (6.20) (21.99) 3.15 3.80 2.97 3.67 (2.81) (2.40) (2.59) (2.40) -0.21 -1.11 -0.34 -1.95 (1.87) (1.94) (1.71) (1.96) 10.40*** 9.19*** 10.03*** 9.21*** (2.29) (2.29) (2.28) (2.46) 10.59*** 9.00*** 10.84*** 8.97*** (3.01) (2.67) (2.77) (2.58) -11.22*** -11.45*** -11.19*** -12.81*** (3.17) (2.87) (3.41) (3.16) 1.69 4.83 (4.51) (3.67) 0.74 (1.30) 0.23 (1.05) 25.63 (78.33) 14.91 (32.69) Adjusted R2 0.62 0.63 0.60 0.63 Observations 78 75 78 75 Notes: Income dummy = 1 if all surveys for a country are income based or if surveys are a combination of income and expenditure. Expenditure dummy = 1 if all surveys for a country are expenditure based or a combination of income and expenditure. Significance at 1% ***, 5% ** and 10% *. Robust standard errors in parentheses. 29 Table 3: Income inequality as measured by Galbraith and Kum C Log mining revenue/worker Log oil revenue/worker (1) 41.96*** (1.03) -0.09 (0.18) 0.43*** (0.15) Log mining revenue/GDP Log oil revenue/GDP Sub-Saharan Africa Latin America and Caribbean OECD 5.72*** (1.13) 3.11*** (1.12) -7.55*** (1.04) Ethnic polarization Ethnic polarization x log mining revenue/cap Ethnic polarization x log oil revenue/cap Ethnic polarization x log mining revenue/GDP Ethnic polarization x log oil revenue/GDP Dependent variable: Average EHII Gini Index, 1980 – 2008 (3) (4) (2) 40.08*** 41.67*** 41.64*** (1.93) (0.98) (1.54) 0.26 (0.63) 0.45 (0.38) 3.14 -9.28 (2.67) (26.10) 15.51*** 12.16 (4.38) (11.29) 4.81*** 5.31*** 3.99*** (1.18) (1.17) (1.28) 2.51** 3.49*** 2.07* (1.03) (1.16) (1.10) -7.93*** -6.33*** -7.38*** (1.25) (1.14) (1.26) 4.72 3.74* (3.24) (2.06) -0.16 (1.00) -0.34 (0.66) 17.18 (40.03) -6.73 (18.04) Adjusted R2 0.41 0.55 0.45 0.55 Observations 141 113 135 110 Notes: Significance at 1% ***, 5% ** and 10% *. Robust standard errors in parentheses. 30 Table 4: Income inequality as measured by Chen and Ravallion C Log mining revenue/worker Log oil revenue/worker Log mining revenue/GDP Log oil revenue/GDP Income-based surveys Expenditure-based surveys Sub-Saharan Africa Latin America and Caribbean East Asia and the Pacific Middle East and North Africa Southern Asia Dependent variable: Average Chen and Ravallion Gini Index, 1980 – 2002 (2) (1) 26.07*** 27.47*** (2.80) (2.80) 0.80* (0.44) -0.33 (0.36) 12.16*** (4.30) -3.89 (6.17) 2.87 2.90 (2.34) (2.32) 1.72 2.35 (2.29) (1.93) 16.55*** 15.76*** (2.97) (2.75) 20.08*** 19.95*** (1.95) (1.87) 9.25*** 8.44*** (2.75) (2.82) 7.67*** 7.61*** (2.68) (2.73) 1.68 3.16 (2.36) (2.02) Adjusted R2 0.56 0.55 Observations 85 84 Notes: Income dummy = 1 if all surveys for a country are income based or if surveys are a combination of income and expenditure. Expenditure dummy = 1 if all surveys for a country are expenditure based or a combination of income and expenditure. Significance at 1% ***, 5% ** and 10% *. Robust standard errors in parentheses. 31 Mining Oil OECD Mining Count Oil Count Ln (Thiel) 1963 1965 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Non Mineral -1.0000 70 -2.0000 60 50 -3.0000 40 -4.0000 30 -5.0000 -6.0000 10 -7.0000 0 Count 20 Figure 1: Average manufacturing wage inequality, mining economies, oil economies, non-mineral economies, and OECD Economies, 1963-2008. Mining and oil economies are identified based on mining and oil revenue per worker. Statistically significant differences in means at the 5% level between the oil group or mining group and the non-mineral group are shown by square data markers. 32 Mining Oil OECD Mining Count Oil Count Ln (Thiel) 1963 1965 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Non Mineral -1.00 70 -2.00 60 50 -3.00 40 -4.00 30 -5.00 -6.00 10 -7.00 0 Count 20 Figure 2: Average manufacturing wage inequality, non-OECD mining economies, oil economies, and non-mineral economies, and OECD Economies, 1963-2008. Mining and oil economies are identified based on revenue per unit GDP. Statistically significant differences in means at the 5% level between the oil group or mining group and the non-mineral group are shown by square data markers. 33 Oil OECD Oil Count Mining Count 55.00 70 50.00 60 45.00 50 40.00 40 35.00 30 30.00 20 25.00 10 20.00 0 Count Mining 1963 1965 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 EHII Gini Non Mineral Figure 3: Average EHII Gini Index, non-OECD mining economies, non-OECD oil economies, nonOECD non-mineral economies, and OECD Economies, 1963-2008. Mining and oil economies are identified based on revenue per worker. Statistically significant differences in means at the 5% level between the oil group or mining group and the non-mineral group are shown by square data markers. 34 Oil OECD Oil Count Mining Count 55.00 70 50.00 60 45.00 50 40.00 40 35.00 30 30.00 20 25.00 10 20.00 0 Count Mining 1963 1965 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 EHII Gini Non Mineral Figure 4: Average estimated Gini Index, non-OECD mining economies, non-OECD oil economies, non-OECD non-mineral economies, and OECD Economies, 1963-2008. Mining and oil economies are identified based on revenue per unit GDP. Statistically significant differences in means at the 5% level between the oil group or mining group and the non-mineral group are shown by square data markers. 35 Endnotes 1 This is probably a good place to raise the inevitable concern about the endogeneity of mining and oil resources and production. Given that resources are distributed randomly and unequally around the world and that income inequality cannot influence this geological lottery, resources and production can only be endogenous to the extent that income inequality somehow affects the exploration for resources and their conversion into proven reserves and production. I have yet to see a compelling model in this regard, David and Wright’s (1997) examination of America’s rise to resource abundance notwithstanding. The broadest geological measure of physical stocks of resources and the flows of minerals from those stock are almost perfectly correlated (Stijns 2005), providing a strong indication that it is geology, and not institutions, that causes production. 2 Aside from the usual remedies of redistributive taxation, education reform, and the development of institutions that contain inequality, there is also special emphasis on corruption, fiscal transparency, state and community capacity building, and development of agriculture and rural non-resource sectors (Davis and Vásquez Cordano 2013). Curiously, policy prescriptions for mining economies are generally proposed in separate texts from those for oil economies (e.g., Humphreys et al. 2007, Richards 2009). 3 In full disclosure, I have received research funding from the ICMM in the past and am currently a short-term consultant for the World Bank. Neither institution is associated in any way with this research paper. 4 If resource production weakens institutions, income inequality may worsen for reasons independent of the direct impacts of mining and oil production (Gylfason and Zoega 2006). Consistent with the new empirical work showing the “deep roots” of economic development (Spolaore and Wacziarg 2013), Alexeev and Conrad (2009) find no evidence that mining and oil wealth reduces institutional quality, and so effects via this channel are unlikely. In this same vein, Acemoglu and Robinson (2012) do not implicate mining or oil extraction in their sweeping review of the political economy of failed states. Economic volatility associated with mining and oil production has also been suggested to especially harm the poor and increase income inequality. This proposal has not found support in the data (Goderis and Malone 2011). 5 That the inequality-inducing rents emanate at the time of the resource discovery in this model, rather than at the time of production, is an important distinction when it comes to testing these theories empirically. The former requires measurement of the value of reserves and resources discovered in a given year, while the latter involves measurement of the annual rents from production, as often proxied by revenues. 6 Government spending on infrastructure is a major component of Gelb’s (1985) modeling of the effects of an oil windfall on economic growth and welfare. 7 Even so, radical changes to mining and oil economy tax structures may well do little to change de facto income inequality (Burgess and Stern 1993, Engel et al. 1999, Segal 2011). Moreover, mining rents are much lower than oil rents. Given this, it would be surprising if the impact of any redistributional government programs is statistically identifiable in mining economies. 8 In a similar analysis Gylfason and Zoega (2003) find a 10 point increase for Latin America. 9 This lack of data has been noted by Gelb and Associates (1988), Askari et al. (1997), and Ross (2007). 10 It is well known that an increasing Gini Index can provide an ambiguous measure of the change in income inequality. Davis and Vásquez Cordano (2013) provide an illustrative example. Measuring income inequality is in general far from exact (Deaton 2003). 11 I am unable to exactly replicate the analysis due to lack of original data. My replication recovers the data from the listed sources, but by inspection it is not identical to the data Easterly used in his original analysis (2001, Table 1). 12 From footnote 5 above, their model actually requires measurement of the additions to resource wealth in a given year, not the total resource stock in a given year. 13 Natural resource wealth includes pastureland, cropland, timber resources, nontimber forest resources, protected areas, and subsoil assets. In a related paper, Carmignani (2013) tests for income inequality in resource-rich economies conditional on institutional quality and ethnic fractionalization. In a sample of 80 developing countries that mainly exclude the extensive oil producers he finds a statistically weak but positive residual correlation between both resource stocks and flows and income inequality. The conditionality of the test makes this paper less useful given the posed research question. 14 I thank Roland Hodler for sharing his data and code with us. While I can replicate their results, I note that my WDI downloads for GDP per capita in 1990, population in 1990 and trade as a percent of GDP are not the same as those in their data set. I use their values here. 15 Fum and Hodler (2010) find the average difference between post-tax income and expenditure surveys from WIID to be 7.0. 16 Results finding unconditional inequality would motivate a search for the channels by which the inequality manifests. But we must put the horse before the cart. 36 17 Fum and Hodler additionally control for Kuznets effects on income inequality via a squared income term. For a trenchant critique of the very idea of Kuznets effects see Gallup (2012). As I noted above, Leamer et al. (1999) argue that the development path of mining and oil economies is likely to be subject to a Kuznets effect while non-mineral economies will see continuously declining income inequality as they develop. Since one does not want to control for the very effect one is testing for, I omit the squared income term. Fum and Hodler also control for population. There is no a priori reason to believe that population count would affect income inequality. Yet population is strongly significant in all of Fum and Hodler’s regressions. My analysis of their regressions shows that population is proxying regional differences in inequality. 18 Segal (2011), who uses the World Bank data in a study of hypothetical resource rent distribution, complains about its derivation and describes it as “indicative rather than authoritative” (p. 478). van der Ploeg and Poelhekke (2010) provide a comprehensive criticism of the methodology by which the Bank computes subsoil wealth. The World Bank sample is also highly skewed towards the richer economies of the world. 19 An unambiguous change in income inequality is defined as a shift in the entire Lorenz curve. 20 The index does not include precious metals or diamonds. 21 They use a Gini Index produced by Galbraith and Kum (2005), which is deterministically normalized to household pretax income to make time series inequality measures comparable. The deterministic normalization means that index will still contain effects of the idiosyncratic redistribution policies of each economy, and so is an imprecise measure of wage inequality. Goderis and Malone weight each price shock by the commodity export share in GDP in each country so that resource exporting countries are more impacted by the price shock. Their Table 2 lists the commodity export shares that they use for weights. Kuwait is shown to have a 0.0 commodity export share, making it more resource poor than Italy. Singapore and Iceland are measured to be resource rich because of their gasoline (Singapore) and aluminum (Iceland) exports. That manufactures like gasoline and aluminum are included in the same index as natural endowments like oil and copper when identifying countries with “an exogenous gift of resource income” (p. 390), combined with the erroneous weighting for Kuwait, leads me to treat their empirical results with caution. 22 This small impact is consistent with the analysis by Loayza et al. (2012) of regional inequality increases in and around mining districts in Peru. 23 The revenue per GDP measure is similar to the series SNR that Sachs and Warner (1997) use as a measure of mining and oil intensity, though they create the variable for 1971 and aggregate mining and oil products. 24 It would be more desirable to describe mining and oil intensity via cumulated revenues from, say, 1970 to 1990 so as to reflect the full impact of rent accumulation over time. There are two impediments to producing such a series. First, the US Bureau of Mines data is spotty, and many countries would have to be dropped for lack of data in certain years. Second, there is a lack of consistency in reporting production across periods (e.g., some years report total production of ores and concentrates, and other years report metal in concentrate). I have been able to determine that in each country the per worker revenues from these 25 mining and oil products in 1971 are highly correlated with the 1990 values: the Spearman Rank correlation across 147 countries is 0.84 and the logged values have a correlation of 0.85. In that sense, my 1990 figure for each country is likely a good proxy for the intensity of rents over a number of decades. 25 Botswana, arguably the wealthiest mining economy in the world, with mining revenues per capita equivalent to the oil revenues per capita of the Middle Eastern countries, has managed nothing more than graduation from least developed country status, in 1994. Saudi Arabia, on the other hand, had so much value-added from their production that they enjoyed PPP income per capita levels that were twice those of the United Kingdom in the early 1980s (Davis 2009). 26 UTIP-UNIDO updated 2013b.xls. 27 The Thiel Index measures wage inequality across UNIDO industrial classification codes (e.g., average wages in extracting petroleum and natural gas), not within groups (differences in wages within petroleum and natural gas). Because it is missing the within group inequality it is a lower bound on wage inequality. 28 EHII-UPDATED-10-30-2013 using 2004 DATA.xlsx 29 Galbraith and Kum (2005) find that income-expenditure differences in survey estimates are highly correlated with regional differences in survey types, and so it is not unusual for the coefficients on survey type to be insignificant in these and the remaining regressions. 30 In assessing the impact of revenues on Gini Indexes in this and the following tables, the sample standard deviation on log mining revenues per capita and log oil revenues per capita is between 2.5 and 3, while the sample standard deviation on log mining revenue per unit GDP and log oil revenue per unit GDP is about 0.1. 31 The results are similar when using a 1990 – 2008 average, though the sample size decreases. 32 Frederick Solt, 2013, "The Standardized World Income Inequality Database", http://hdl.handle.net/1902.1/11992 Frederick Solt [Distributor] V4 [September]. 37 33 Selected data was also made available at http://wwwwds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/IW3P/IB/2000/05/25/000094946_00050605490166/Rendered/PD F/multi0page.pdf. 34 They note that all other compilations of distributional data use secondary survey data. Compilations from secondary data have been criticized by Atkinson and Brandolini (2001) as potentially misleading. 38