UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION Market-Based Rates for Public Utilities Docket No. RM04-7-000 COMMENTS OF THE AMERICAN PUBLIC POWER ASSOCIATION AND THE TRANSMISSION ACCESS POLICY STUDY GROUP Pursuant to the Commission’ s February 11, 2005 “ Notice Inviting Comments,”the American Public Power Association (“ APPA” ) and the Transmission Access Policy Study Group (“ TAPS” ) submit these joint comments on the generation market power prong of the Commission’ s market-based rate (“ MBR” ) test. APPA and TAPS support the Commission’ s continued re-examination of its MBR program. APPA and TAPS members want –and the Commission’ s reliance upon market pricing under the Federal Power Act (“ FPA” ) requires –a wholesale market that offers meaningful choices among competing power suppliers. The Commission’ s MBR test must support with factual evidence, not market theory, the conclusion that sufficient supply choices exist to discipline MBR sales to just and reasonable levels, and that specific MBR sellers either lack or have mitigated their market power. To ensure that the MBR test meets these statutory requirements, APPA and TAPS submit these comments. The Interim Screens, Delivered Price Test (“ DPT” ), rebuttable presumptions, and default mitigation adopted last year in the MBR orders, AEP Power Marketing, Inc., 107 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,018 (2004) (“ MBR Order” ), order on rehearing, 108 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,026 (2004) (“ MBR Rehearing Order” ), are a significant improvement over prior Commission practice, because the Commission now examines a broader array of evidence bearing on the ability and incentive of a seller to exercise market power. APPA and TAPS strongly oppose efforts to weaken this -2regimen, for example, by adoption of the so-called “ Contestable Load Analysis”promoted by the Edison Electric Institute and a number of its members. While such proposals are premised on the claimed unfair result that a majority of vertically integrated, control-area operating public utilities failed the Interim Screens, particularly the Market Share Screen, the Commission should not shy away from the closer look it has undertaken in the ongoing Section 206 investigations. The investigated public utilities are dominant suppliers in their regions, and it is entirely appropriate that the Commission undertake a more thorough assessment of their market power potential. The Commission should also not be overly concerned about “ false positives.”Sellers who in fact do not possess market power will presumably be able to make the requisite showings in their Section 206 investigations to overcome any initial, false positive results. The far greater risk is the false negative –sellers with market power that nonetheless pass the Screens.1 Unless a separate complaint proceeding is initiated, customers will not have no vehicle in which to rectify a false negative result. As noted by Professor Darren Bush in his attached Affidavit,2 the Contestable Load Analysis will only significantly increase the risk of false negatives. Bush Aff. at ¶ 26. APPA and TAPS propose refinements to the interim MBR test intended to fill holes that could cause the Commission to overlook important evidence bearing on the seller’ s market power or that create analytical flaws. We also propose a Generation Market Power Test that APPA and TAPS believe is better suited to the dynamic nature of electricity markets and allows 1 Accord January 27, 2005 Technical Conference Transcript (Tr.) at 35 (Goulet) (“ We believe that an entity can pass the interim screens and yet still possess the potential to exert market power.” ). All transcript cites are to the January 27, 2005 technical conference in RM04-7-000, unless otherwise indicated. 2 Professor Bush as an assistant professor at the University of Houston Law Center where he teaches courses and writes on antitrust, regulated industries, and law and economics. He also holds a Ph.D. in economics. -3consideration of the specific and non-uniform impacts of retail rate regimes and long-term contracts on the ability and incentive of a seller to exercise market power. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY The Commission should replace its Interim Screens with APPA/TAPS’ s proposed Generation Market Power Test. Elements of the Generation Market Power Test include a Horizontal Market Power Screen, which utilizes pivotal supplier, concentration and supply curve metrics, and the examination of Effects Factors (sales and transactions, native load obligations, entry conditions, transmission control, demand elasticity and other regional or local factors). The Generation Market Power Test is detailed in the Appendix to these Comments. Assuming the Commission does not adopt the APPA/TAPS proposal, the Commission should refine, not weaken, the existing MBR test, by: o Conducting the Pivotal Supplier Screen on a monthly basis to account for the fact that suppliers can be pivotal at times other than the annual system peak. o Calculating Uncommitted Capacity under the Market Share Screen to include all capacity available to compete in wholesale markets at some point during the season by deducting an applicant’ s minimum load, not just minimum peak day load, from installed capacity. o Including a concentration metric, such as the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (“ HHI” ), in the Market Share Screen to measure collusion risks. o Rejecting the “ Contestable Load Analysis”and its variants, because the approach is fatally flawed, affords applicants excessive discretion, and is not necessary to overcome claimed defects of the Market Share Screen. o Encouraging analysis of historical data and other market-specific facts as a supplement to, not a substitute for, the Delivered Price Test (“ DPT” ). o Lowering the threshold for passing the HHI component of the DPT to 1800, because the current 2500 threshold is excessive and improperly transplanted from its origins. The Commission must take realistic account of transmission constraints, not merely give them lip service, when it defines relevant geographic markets and determines transmission import capability. o The Interim Screens’default geographic market definition –the applicant’ s home control area or, in the case of ISO/RTO markets, the ISO/RTO footprint –must be genuinely rebuttable. o Simultaneously Available Transmission Capability (“ ATC” ) should be used as the measure of transmission capacity when performing the MBR test. -4 Where an applicant is found to possess market power, remedies should be targeted to effectively eliminate the seller’ s ability and incentive to exercise market power. With its ample authority, the Commission should adopt remedial conditions to achieve structurally competitive markets, including: o Reducing the seller’ s dominant generation position by putting the ownership or control of generation capacity into the hands of competitors. o Providing customers embedded in a dominant MBR seller’ s own transmission system access to broader markets through transmission set-asides and clarification of network customer roll-over rights. o Increasing the ability of buyers and sellers to reach each other by promoting development of a robust transmission grid through targeted upgrades, inclusive transmission planning on a regional basis, and expanding ownership and participation in transmission to all load serving entities (IOUs, municipalities, and cooperatives). The Commission correctly requires cost-based rates and sales where a seller has not mitigated its market power. Where necessary to address market power, MBR authority should be denied even outside an applicant’ s control area, due to the discriminatory and market-distorting effects of the seller’ s failure to provide embedded customers access to the broader market. The Commission should not exempt from the MBR test sellers solely with post-1996 units, because market power risk can be posed by any seller, regardless of the age of its facilities. The Commission should not automatically accept ISO/RTO mitigation as adequate to mitigate an MBR seller’ s market power. Instead, there must be fact-based findings that the mitigation measures address the market power problems presented by the applicant. The Commission should organize MBR reviews on a regional basis to improve the availability and access to data needed for such reviews. However, such regional review does not mean pre-defining geographic markets as regional absent a proper, fact-based definition of the geographic market. The Commission should not extend the Interim Screens to ancillary services markets, because of the greater competitive concerns presented by such markets. The apparent over-designation of data as Critical Energy Infrastructure Information (“ CEII” ) and the inability of intervenors to conduct a DPT in 21 days greatly impairs meaningful participation. The Commission needs to remedy the great difficulty market participants have obtaining and using data necessary to assess an MBR filing by automatically extending the response time by up to 60 days where an intervenor seeks needed CEII or intends to submit a DPT. -5 The Commission should condition MBR sales to require regular reporting of the sales and transmission data it and market participants need to conduct the MBR test. COMMENTS I. THE COMMISSION SHOULD REFINE, NOT WEAKEN, THE EXISTING TEST A. The Commission Has a Legal Obligation to Examine the Market Power Risk Posed by MBR Applicants To find a market-based rate lawful, the Commission must find that a seller “ lacks market power (or has taken sufficient steps to mitigate market power), coupled with strict reporting requirements to ensure that the rate is ‘ just and reasonable’and that markets are not subject to manipulation.”Cal. ex rel. Lockyer v. FERC, 383 F.3d 1006, 1013 (9th Cir. 2004). Pursuant to its MBR policy, the “ Commission allows power sales at market-based rates if the seller and its affiliates do not have, or have adequately mitigated, market power in generation and transmission and cannot erect other barriers to entry. The Commission also considers whether there is evidence of affiliate abuse or reciprocal dealing.”See Alliant Energy Corp. Servs., Inc., 109 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,289, P 27 (2004).3 The Commission’ s determinations cannot be abstract or theoretical. Rather, there must be “ empirical proof”that “ existing competition would ensure that the actual price is just and reasonable.”Farmers Union Cent. Exch., Inc. v. FERC, 734 F.2d 1486, 1510 (D.C. Cir. 1984). The Commission’ s MBR test must satisfy its legal obligations. B. The Pivotal Supplier Screen Should Be Conducted For Monthly, Not Just Annual, Peaks The Pivotal Supplier Screen examines an extreme case –the peak month (MBR Order P 91) -- and ignores the fact that a supplier could be pivotal at other times. In the affidavit 3 Citing Progress Power Marketing, Inc., 76 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,155 at 61,921-22 (1996); Northwest Power Marketing Co., L.L.C., 75 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,281 at 61,899-900 (1996); accord Heartland Energy Services, Inc., et al., 68 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,223 at 62,062-63 (1994). -6accompanying APPA/TAPS’ s February 4, 2004 SMA Comments (hereafter “ Kirsch SMA Affidavit),4 economist Dr. Laurence Kirsch explained (at 8-9): Screens should recognize that the ability to exercise market power changes over time with changes in load levels, generation output, and the availability of generation and transmission facilities. At a minimum, screens should examine market power for the on-peak and off-peak periods of the different seasons and, as appropriate, for forthcoming years. The Commission Staff has previously proposed to conduct the pivotal supplier analysis on a monthly basis to capture changes in the applicant’ s market power.5 But for the Commission’ s decision to use a native load proxy reflecting the average peak loads in the peak month, MBR Order P 91, the pivotal suppler analysis would measure only the most extreme and rare situation in which a suppler can single-handedly reduce operating reserves margins to levels that trigger emergency procedures or even require load shedding. As Dr. Kirsch has pointed out: “ This ability to cause system distress is certainly sufficient to establish the ability to exercise market power; but there are many other situations in which a supplier can exercise market power without having such an ability.”Kirsch SMA Affidavit at 9. See also Tr. at 11 (Bushnell). A monthly analysis is particularly important to gauge the effect of outages. Both the seller’ s and its competitors’planned outages could have dramatic effects on the pivotal supplier result. More generation should be on-line during peak seasons, and the larger amount of supply 4 February 4, 2004 “ Post-Technical Conference Comments of the American Public Power Association and the Transmission Access Policy Study Group,”filed in Docket No. PL02-8-000, Conference on Supply Margin Assessment (“ February 4, 2004 SMD Comments” ), available at http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/opennat.asp?fileID=10057963 (last visited March 11, 2005). APPA and TAPS filed Dr. Kirsch’ s affidavit in RM04-7-000 on June 30, 2004. 5 Conference on Supply Margin Assessment, Notice of Technical Conference, Staff Paper at 6-7 (December 19, 2003) available at http://www.ferc.gov/EventCalendar/Files/20040112104841-PL02-8-000-notice.pdf (last viewed March 11, 2005). Given the data that applicants must already gather, running the Pivotal Supplier Screen for each month represents an insignificant amount of additional work. -7available to the market presents competitive conditions different from the supply situation when plants are on scheduled outage.6 A monthly Pivotal Supplier Screen is also needed to help ensure that suppliers with market power, but that pass the Market Share Screen because they have less than 20 percent market share in any season, are captured. In the MBR Order (P 104), the Commission observed that: “ While a supplier with less than a 20 percent market share, in certain circumstances, can affect the market price during periods of limited supply alternatives, our pivotal supplier analysis addresses such situations by examining whether there are sufficient competing supply alternatives to meet the market’ s peak load.”However, the Pivotal Supplier Screen will only do this if the supplier happens to be pivotal during the peak month. It is plainly insufficient under the FPA for the Commission to needlessly narrow its Pivotal Supplier Screen to just the single peak month, ignoring the potential for exercise of market power in other months. C. The Market Share Screen Should Be Made More Accurate and Robust 1. The Market Share Screen’ s Calculation of Uncommitted Capacity Ignores Generation Available to Compete in the Wholesale Market The Market Share Screen’ s calculation of Uncommitted Capacity uses a native load proxy based upon the minimum peak demand day in a given season. MBR Order P 92.7 The 6 The MBR Order (P 97) does not require that the annual peak-based Pivotal Suppler Screen reflect scheduled outages. If conducted on a monthly basis, the Pivotal Supplier Screen should reflect planned outages. 7 As explained below in Part V.B., the Commission’ s blunt elimination of native load obligations is analytically insupportable. However, if the Commission continues to examine just a portion of a seller’ s total capacity, that capacity must in turn define the extent of the MBR authorization. MBR sellers wanting the freedom to sell from all of their capacity at MBRs must be willing to have the impact of that capacity on wholesale markets considered. MBR sellers that insist on denominating part of their generation holdings as “ committed”to serve retail native load must live with the consequences –cost-based rates for sales from such capacity. Native load will still benefit from cost-based sales revenues (assuming the state regulatory authority requires revenue crediting). If dominant MBR sellers want a bigger upside potential associated with market-based sales, and they succeed in their attempt to convince the Commission to enact generation market power screens that do not fully capture the extent of their potential to exercise generation market power, they should not be authorized to make MBR sales from capacity they themselves claim is unavailable to make such sales. -8Commission claimed in the MBR Order (P 90) that this proxy is conservative, but in fact it is inconsistent with the Commission’ s desire for a proxy that reflects “ all of the capacity that is available to compete in wholesale markets at some point during the season.”Id. P 92. To fulfill the Commission’ s intent, the proxy should be the minimum load day of each season. The Commission stated: By subtracting the generation needed to serve native load on the minimum load day of the season, we identify all of the capacity that is available to compete in wholesale markets at some point during the season. In other words, the use of this proxy for native load reflects the fact that the rest of the applicant’ s generation was uncommitted and available at some point during that season to sell in wholesale markets. For the purpose of constructing a reasonably balanced conservative screen, we will consider all such available capacity for both applicants and competing suppliers. Id. P 92 (emphasis added); see also P 89 (quoting Louisville Gas & Elec. Co., 62 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,016, at 61,146 (1993)). However, the MBR Order’ s proxy –minimum peak day load in a season –identifies only some of the capacity available to compete in wholesale markets during the season. It considers only the capacity measured by the difference between the needle peak and the minimum peak while ignoring the capacity measured by the difference between the minimum peak and the minimum load. It thus fails to reflect the Commission’ s intent that the Market Share Screen measure market power during off-peak times. Id. P 72. 2. The Market Share Screen Needs a Concentration Metric, Such As HHI, to Assess Collusion Risks The Commission intends the Market Share Screen to measure the risk of “ coordinated interaction with other sellers”and an “ applicant’ s size relative to others in the market.”MBR Order P 72. However, the Commission has left out the critical ingredient needed to assess the risk of coordinated interaction among sellers: a concentration measure. To complete the recipe, the Commission should incorporate the HHI metric into the Market Share Screen. -9A seller’ s market share alone gives an incomplete picture of collusion risk. Professor Bush explains that (Aff. ¶ 15): HHI recognizes that differences in the relative size of the market participants matter. Concentration measures utilized prior to the adoption of the HHI methodology did not account for the presence of dominant firms in a market. In contrast, HHIs explicitly recognize that disparities in power between firms may lead to heightened market power –firms may merely follow the behavior of the firm with the greatest market share, for example. Collusion risk in a 2-seller market where one seller has 25% market share and the other seller has 75% market share looks far different from a 6-seller market where the 25%-share seller competes against 5 other sellers each having 15% market share. In the first market, the 25% seller may not be dominant vis-à-vis the 75% seller, but the collusion risk will be very high. In the second market, the 25% seller is dominant, but the collusion risk is relatively lower because of the existence of five competitors. See also Tr. at 189 (Wroblewski). Thus, the Commission needs to incorporate a concentration measure. HHI is widely accepted, including by the Commission, and easily calculated once market shares are known. It is simply the sum of the squared market shares. For the reasons discussed in Part I.F. below, the Commission should use the Horizontal Merger Guidelines and FERC Merger Policy HHI thresholds: Unconcentrated < 1000 < Moderately Concentrated < 1800 Highly Concentrated. In the first market above, the HHI would be 6250, indicating very high concentration with great collusion risk. In the second, the HHI is 1750, indicating close to high concentration with potential collusion risk –enough that the Commission should take a closer look –but not nearly as high as the first market. - 10 The Commission, while retaining the current rebuttable presumption associated with passing or failing the Market Share Screen, should incorporate the HHI in the following manner:8 A seller with a market share of 20% or more, regardless of concentration, would fail the screen, because of the risks posed by its dominance. See MBR Order P 103. A seller with a market share of less than 20% in a highly concentrated market may be deemed to pass the screen if it also makes a showing that collusion risks are not elevated despite the concentration level. A seller with less than 20% market share in a moderately or unconcentrated market would pass the screen. Id. P 102. D. The Commission Should Not Adopt a “Contestable Load Analysis” EEI, along with a number of its members, have promoted an approach labeled “ Historical Contestable Load Analysis”(“ HCLA” ) as an alternative to the Market Share Screen and as additional evidence in Section 206 investigations where an applicant has failed one or both screens. According to EEI, HCLA “ focuses on the determination of the relationship between the wholesale loads that were actually seeking competitive supply alternatives (contestable loads) in the relevant market and the competitive generation resources that were available to serve those 9 loads.” Another version of HCLA, propounded by AEP, reduces the capacity shares of the applicant and competing suppliers to the extent that estimated capacity of each exceeds the amount of contestable load.10 The Commission should reject HCLA and its variants. It is 8 As demonstrated in Part I.F. below, in applying the HHI component of the Delivered Price Test, the Commission should not use a 2500 HHI, but instead use 1800, unless it also uses a 15% market share threshold. 9 Testimony of Louis R. Jahn, Director, Wholesale Market Policy, Edison Electric Institute, Before the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission on Generation Market Power Screens, distributed at January 27, 2005 Technical Conference, at 2 (hereafter “ Jahn” ). 10 AEP Power Mktg, Inc., 109 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,276, P 23 (2004); November 19, 2004 Response of AEP to October 29, 2004 Deficiency Letter, at 8, Docket No. ER96-2495-023, et al. - 11 analytically flawed, provides applicants with too much discretion to define the analysis,11 and is unnecessary to overcome claimed shortcomings in the Market Share Screen. 1. Contestable Load Analysis Has Fatal Analytical Flaws HCLA suffers from a number of insurmountable flaws that make it an unacceptable approach to market power analysis. These flaws cause HCLA to present a distorted picture of the applicant and its place in the market. It thus provides no basis for concluding that an MBR applicant lacks market power. In the form EEI proposes, HCLA ignores the applicant’ s capacity altogether. It compares the “ ratio of total competitive generation resources to total contestable load by product and season during the historical test period.”Jahn at 14. The applicant’ s own capacity does not enter the analysis, even if it is the dominant seller. However, ignoring the elephant in the room does not prevent it from breaking the furniture. Professor Darren Bush explains in the attached affidavit that the size and make-up of firms’supply portfolios, as well as a firm’ s position vis-à-vis other firms, matters greatly in competitive analysis (Affidavit ¶ 12): One limitation of the contestable load analysis is that it ignores differences among potential suppliers of products desired by buyers. In particular, buyers may seek to purchase multiple products from what are typically not homogenous suppliers. Such products include capacity, energy, load-following service, and the like. It is possible that some generation assets are able to provide all of these products, but others are unable to do so. In such a situation, it cannot be said that merely because a generator owns an asset that could provide some of the buyer’ s needs (e.g., energy) that it necessarily is a competitor to a generation owner that is able to supply all of these products (e.g., load following service). Rather, it is the combination of products that the buyer may seek. The buyer, in seeking to purchase these products, will take offers 11 Even if applicant discretion could be reined in, HCLA’ s analytical flaws cannot be fixed. - 12 from firms that can provide them. Thus, buyers could only turn to a subset of the firms that would be included in either the AEP or EEI contestable market analysis for supply. The effect of supply portfolios on a firm’ s ability to compete is evident in the marketplace. The fleet of a dominant seller allows it to compete for a wider variety of products, whether load-following type contracts or firm capacity sales.12 Sellers with these capabilities can economically add a new 25 MW wholesale load (backed by reserves) to their existing load obligations, providing both firm power and load-following type services. By contrast, if an IPP has just a single plant, it may have trouble “ firming up”the sale to ensure deliveries at times of plant outages. Further, an IPP with a single, 500 MW combined cycle plant often can’ t make a 25 MW unit capacity sale unless it has an “ anchor tenant”to purchase the bulk of its plant output and ensure efficient plant operation. The 25 MW sale will not be a viable option. The IPP is also unlikely to be in a position to provide a load-following type service and is subject to substantial energy imbalance penalties under the Order No. 888 Open Access Transmission Tariffs (“ OATTs” ) that the dominant seller with its own control area (usually the transmission provider) doesn’ t have to worry about. Professor Bush further explains “ contestable load analysis dispenses with both structural and effects analysis, instead favoring an ‘ add ‘ em up’approach to calculating market shares for 12 These combined merchant and rate base fleets together support wholesale marketing activities. According to The Cruthirds Report, Southern Company reported that “ it earned about $220 million from its ‘ competitive generation’ business in 2004 - $111 million from Southern Power´s generation (unregulated affiliate — a large percentage of those sales are to Southern Company regulated utility affiliates resulting from questionably managed RFPs) and $109 million from Southern’ s‘ embedded’(rate based) generation. Southern projected profits of $200 million from the competitive generation business for 2005 - $90 million from Southern Power and $100 million from the embedded generation. Southern earned about $53 million in “ opportunity sales”(trading floor profits) during 2004, but is only projecting earnings of $35-38 million during 2005. The other $166 million expected to be earned by the competitive generation business in 2005 is attributable to capacity payments under long-term PPAs.”See “ Special Report: Southern Company Conference Call - 4th Quarter 2004 Financial Results,”The Cruthirds Report, January 26, 2004, available at http://www.thecruthirdsreport.com. - 13 only the capacity that is excess to the supplier’ s own when it is the supplier’ s own capacity that is of interest,”and in so doing “ forgos the hard work of determining whether a firm has the incentive and ability to exercise market power.”Bush Aff. ¶ 20. Calculations of market share serve a particularly important role in providing enforcement agencies with insights into a market— insights that would be lost under a contestable load approach. First, the Guidelines’method of calculating market shares (i.e., HHIs) recognizes that differences in the relative size of the market participants matter. Concentration measures utilized prior to the adoption of the HHI methodology did not account for the presence of dominant firms in a market. In contrast, HHIs explicitly recognize that disparities in power between firms may lead to heightened market power–firms may merely follow the behavior of the firm with the greatest market share, for example.12 The contestable load analysis, however, misses the whole point of calculating HHIs in the first place. As EEI proposes it, the dominant firm drops out of the picture altogether. As AEP proposes it, competitors are truncated down to the same size. Another important component of the Guidelines approach to market share calculation is the focus on the merging parties (in merger cases) or the firm whose conduct is alleged to violate Section 2 of the Sherman Act (as monopolization or an attempt to monopolize). The focus is on the firms that are of the most competitive concern because the determination of the anticompetitive effects/procompetitive benefits often arises from their conduct. In other words, the purpose of the calculation of market share is to determine whether the firms under antitrust scrutiny might exercise market power. It is typically not the mouse frolicking across the competitive field that is the problem, but rather the elephant undaintedly stomping everything in its path that the Guidelines seek to examine. By ignoring the disparate roles of the firms in question and compiling only aggregate (and therefore poor) indicators of a market’ s competitiveness, EEI’ s approach to market analysis would not prove useful in detecting, preventing and restraining exercises of market power.13 __________________________ 12 An example from my antitrust course is helpful. In Industry X, suppose there are five equally sized firm, each controlling 20 percent of the market. 20² + 20² + 20² + 20² + 20² = 2000 HHI. In Industry Y, suppose there is one firm with 60% of the market, and the rest are relatively small. 60² + 10² + 5² + 5² + 5² + 5² + 5² + 5² = 3850 HHI. A traditional measure of concentration (the four- - 14 firm concentration ratio known as “ CR4") would indicate that the first market is equally as troublesome as the second (CR4 would equal 80 in both). The HHI, however, indicates that the second market is far more troublesome. 13 While the EEI approach purports to examine concentration among the competitive suppliers, Jahn Testimony at 8, such an examination would be meaningless because it leaves out the firm whose market power potential is the subject of the inquiry. Bush Aff. ¶¶ 15-16. Another failing of the contestable load analysis is its focus on the preferences of sellers, rather than buyers, when defining markets. According to Professor Bush (Aff. ¶ 13): The EEI contestable load analysis ignores the question that drives market definition analysis under the Guidelines. Specifically, the market definition portion of the Guidelines “ focuses solely on 9 demand substitution factors—i.e., possible consumer responses.” In order to determine to whom the customers might turn for supplies of these multiple products, antitrust enforcers would typically ask the consumer to answer these questions, not the supplier. “ Supply substitution factors—i.e., possible production 10 responses—are considered elsewhere in the Guidelines.” However, it appears that the contestable load analysis gets it exactly backwards. The EEI analysis requires identification of the “ all loads within the relevant market that were actually subject to competition (contestable loads),”but only after relevant markets have been identified from the perspective of a supplier looking at which market it can sell its product and who else is selling it. Under the EEI analysis, it would be difficult for an antitrust investigator to unearth whether buyers were subject to market power by a small number of firms offering the full range of products the buyer seeks. ____________________________ 9 Guidelines at § 1.0. 10 Id. In the form AEP proposes, the contestable load analysis also wrongly assumes that potential alternative suppliers are equally able to compete. Claimed support for this approach includes the Horizontal Merger Guidelines, § 1.41 n.15, which states: “ Where all firms share, on a forward-looking basis, an equal likelihood of securing sales, the Agency will assign firms equal - 15 shares.”Professor Bush explains that this provision of the Guidelines provides no support for the use of a contestable load analysis in the electric utility industry. Proponents of the AEP version of contestable load analysis point to Guidelines Section 1.41 Footnote 15.14 As one of the Guideline’ s authors points out, the “ one-over-n market”approach is useful when the market in question has “ two essential characteristics:” (1) a finite number of entitities possess a readily identifiable set of assets essential for successful competition; and (2) the extent of ownership or control over the essential assets does not distinguish among these entities in any important way. In the clearest case, all competitors have the same costs, and each can supply the entire market demand.15 Dr. Werden’ s discussion of the “ one-over-n market”takes place in a section titled “ market shares based upon intangible assets”and is essentially a discussion of auction markets. In contrast, Dr. Werden’ s discussion of electricity takes place in a section titled “ capacity-based market shares.”In that section, Dr. Werden notes that there is substantial cost heterogeneity across generation units, in part due to the type of facility (base load as opposed to peaking), 16 but also due to “ differences in fuel choice and unit age.” Both the AEP and the EEI forms of contestable load analysis ignore this heterogeneity. ____________________________ 14 Footnote 15 describes a “ one-over-n market”in which market shares are assigned equally to all sellers in the market when “ all firms have , on a forward looking basis, an equal likelihood of securing sales.”Guidelines Section 1.41 n. 15. Examples of such markets include “ markets for technologies or innovation and Schumpetarian industries, in which competition occurs largely through the introduction of new products or technologies and competition is apt to be more ‘ for the market’than ‘ in the market.’ ”Gregory Werden, Assigning Market Shares, 70 Antitrust L.J. 67, 86 (2002). While not limited solely to intangible goods, the “ one over n market’approach has in fact been quite limited in application. For a rare glimpse at the analysis, see United States v. Ingersoll-Dresser Pump Co., 65 Fed. Reg. 55,271 (Sept. 13, 2000). 15 Gregory Werden, Assigning Market Shares, 70 Antitrust L.J. 67, 86 (2002). 16 Id. at 84. - 16 As noted by Professor Bush, markets where the competitive interaction would support use of the equal market share approach often involve auctions. For example, in United States v. Ingersoll-Dresser Pump Co., 65 Fed. Reg. 55,271 (Sept. 13, 2000), the DOJ assigned, after an extensive factual investigation of the relevant market,13 equal market shares “ based on capability and bidding history”of the three or four pump manufacturers that could compete for contracts to provide, among other things, pumps for power plants.14 DOJ also uses the equal market share approach to assess competition in school milk auction markets where the competing dairies all have sufficient route structures in a school district to supply the district’ s school milk needs. In measuring the level of concentration within each of the affected districts, all dairies and distributors that have sufficient route structure in a school district to allow them to bid competitively on that district’ s contract have been attributed an equal market share for such school district. Merger Guidelines, at ¶ 1.41 n.15. This is because all milk processors and distributors with an adequate route structure in place within a school district may win such school district’ s milk contract in any given year.15 Use of the equal market shares approach in MBR proceedings would require the Commission to assume that in each of the possible product markets for which MBR authorization would apply –long-term load following contracts, unit capacity sales, short-term energy, to name just a few –all competitors are equally positioned to provide the product or service. Such a picture of electricity markets strays far from reality. Particularly in the case of vertically integrated, control area-operating public utilities holding MBR authority, other 13 The case involved a DoJ challenge to a proposed merger of two pump manufacturers. In the typical merger case that results in a DoJ challenge, a complaint is filed only after the Department has conducted an investigation, including through the use of its Second Request authority. See Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 18a(e), 25 (2000). 14 15 65 Fed. Reg. 55,271, at 55,272 (quoting PP 23-26 of Complaint). United States v. Suiza Foods Corp., “ Memorandum of United States in Support of its Motion for Preliminary Injunction,”at 11 (Mar. 1999), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f2300/2328.pdf (last viewed December 6, 2004). - 17 competitors do not have the necessary fleet of generation units to provide the full array of products many wholesale purchasers (including APPA and TAPS members) require or the necessary route structure, i.e., transmission access, to compete on an equal footing in that control area. As Anne Kimber testified,16 the inability of network customers to change Network Resources materially limits the ability of competing supply to access contestable loads on an equal basis with the transmission provider MBR applicant.17 Finally, there is no evident support for EEI’ s proposed criterion that: “ If the total competitive generation resources were at least twice the total contestable load, the applicant will be deemed to have passed the Historical Contestable Load Analysis.”Jahn at 14. Even if one assumed that customers could cobble together a supply portfolio from among competing generation resources, there is no logic or reason for selecting twice the contestable load as the decisional rule. Contestable load could be 500 MW and non-applicant generation could be 2000 MW. If no one customer’ s demand exceeded 100 MW and the minimum amount of capacity the competitive supplier had available for sale was a 200 MW block, the fact that supply exceeded load by twice or more would not mean that load had meaningful alternatives. 16 Written Statement of Anne Kimber on Behalf of MMTG and TAPS for the December 7 Technical Conference, filed December 7, 2004 available at http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=10328815 (last viewed March 13, 2005). 17 While EEI says that the applicant would “ provide a demonstration that transmission constraints would not have limited access by the contestable loads to competitive generation during the historical test period,”Jahn at 14, having the OATT on file cannot be deemed a sufficient demonstration. In addition to Ms. Kimber, Terry Huval at the January 28, 2005 Technical Conference made clear that the Order No. 888 OATT is not sufficient to overcome MBR applicant’ s transmission market power. Written Statement of Terry Huval on Behalf of the Lafayette Utilities System and the Transmission Access Policy Study Group, prepared for the January 28, 2005 Technical Conference, at 5, available at http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=10391023 (last viewed March 12, 2005). - 18 2. Contestable Load Analysis Affords Excessive Discretion, Allowing All Applicants to Pass HCLA is a test that no savvy applicant should fail. According to EEI: “ the applicant would have the opportunity to develop specific methodologies to meet the evidentiary thresholds contained in the guidelines.”Jahn at 6. The only apparent “ bright line”evidentiary threshold is the requirement that competitive generation resources exceed contestable load by two. Jahn at 14. All of the inputs are otherwise determined by the applicant. Given the discretion afforded to an applicant to “ customize”these inputs, few, if any, competent applicants would fail the HCLA. According to EEI, “ the applicant is given the opportunity under the guidelines to define multiple product markets for use in the analysis, e.g., on-peak, off-peak, short-term, long-term, etc.”Jahn at 6. While EEI says that where “ the total competitive generation resources were at least twice the total contestable load, the applicant will be deemed to have passed the Historical Contestable Load Analysis for the specified product and seasons,”Jahn at 14, EEI does not say that the applicant’ s MBR authorization would be limited to just those products and seasons. So, for example, the applicant could, at least in theory, claim blanket MBR authorization simply by having “ passed”the HCLA performed for off-peak markets. The ease with which an applicant could pass a tailor-made HCLA would make the now-discarded hub and spoke test look difficult. Applicants would also get to “ identify all loads within the relevant market that were actually subject to competition (contestable loads) by product for the historical test period.”Jahn at 6. Determining just what wholesale customers are shopping for any particular product at some point in time would be a difficult and imprecise undertaking. There is no central clearinghouse for RFPs. The specific loads buying short-term energy could change day-to-day, or even hourto-hour, depending upon the economics of generation. The opportunities for creative counting would be limited only the applicant’ s imagination. In fact, testimony at the January 27th - 19 Technical Conference attested to the “ challenge”of calculating native load obligations, Tr. at 97 (Henderson). This implies that calculation of loads subject to competition will be similarly challenging. The burden will inevitably lead HCLA’ s proponents to claim that the Commission should defer to the applicant’ s calculation. Further, while HCLA purports to impose a requirement that transmission be available to the competing supply, it also allows the applicant to determine how transmission access is measured. Jahn at 7. As described below, applicants have already found ways to perform the simultaneous import capability studies required under the MBR Orders so that they overstate actual transmission capacity. APPA/TAPS expect that the wide discretion given to applicants under the proposed HCLA would result in even greater overstatements. In sum, the extreme discretion that EEI proposes to allow applicants under its HCLA to customize the assumptions used in their analyses all but assures each would pass. The track record so far bears this out. EEI conceded at the January 27th Technical Conference that each company that had included an HCLA or one of its variants in its MBR compliance filing had passed. Tr. at 79-80 (Jahn). The 100% pass rate is no coincidence. EEI’ s proposal is truly an illustration of the old saying, “ if you can’ t raise the bridge, lower the river,”thus allowing all of its members’ships to pass unimpeded. 3. HCLA is Not Needed to Overcome Claimed Flaws in the Market Share Screen EEI objects not only to what it believes to be the Market Share Screen’ s excessive flunk rate. Tr. at 5-6 (Jahn), but it also claims that the “ Screen does not take into account the relative size of total market demand to total uncommitted generation capacity which is a major factor in assessing whether the applicant can exercise market power.”Jahn at 3-4. However, there are very good reasons not to do as EEI suggests. The applicant that fails the Market Share Screen - 20 can perform the DPT which examines supply and demand factors at peak, shoulder and off-peak periods and examines what generation is in the market through the economic capacity measure. EEI also claims that the “ native load proxy in the Market Share Screen seriously understates the generation capacity actually required by the applicant to meet seasonal native load obligations and therein overstates the generation capacity available to the applicant for wholesale market sales.”Jahn at 4. In fact, the Market Share Screen suffers from the opposite problem: it understates the capacity available to the applicant to compete. See Part I.C.1. above. E. Historical Data Should Supplement, Not Supplant, the Delivered Price Test The MBR Orders specified that if an applicant failed either of the Interim Screens and did not go straight to mitigation, it must submit a DPT. With respect to Southern Companies’request for guidance concerning the additional types of data applicants may submit to rebut the presumption [arising from failure of either of the indicative screens], we clarify that applicants and intervenors may present historical data including analyses that they believe most accurately represent market conditions. With respect to forwardlooking analyses or studies, however, the Delivered Price Test is the only market power study applicants may submit. MBR Rehearing Order at P 27. While applicants and intervenors “ may also present evidence based on historical wholesale sales or transmission data,”MBR Rehearing Order at P 25 (emphasis added), the MBR Orders makes clear that applicants that fail one or both screens and do not proceed directly to mitigation “ must present a more thorough analysis using the Commission’ s Delivered Price Test.”MBR Order at P 105. The Commission should not accept historical data as a substitute for the DPT. The DPT provides a known framework, based upon the well-accepted Horizontal Merger Guidelines, to allow the Commission to make judgments about the risk of market power exercise on a forward- - 21 looking basis. This perspective is appropriate. The MBR authorization is a forward-looking authorization that is supposed to last three years. Historical data, along with other actual experiences in the market, have a role: they serve as vital, real world checks on the DPT. For example, the results of RFPs offer evidence about whether customers have, in fact, found the supply options suggested by the DPT. The Commission should consider such factual evidence. However, it needs to be considered as part of a record that includes the DPT, not instead of the DPT. F. The 2500 Threshold for the HHI Component of the Delivered Price Test is Unjustified and Too High Applicants failing the Pivotal Supplier and Market Share Screens that submit a DPT to demonstrate they lack market power must show an HHI of less than 2500 in the relevant market for all seasons/load conditions, as well as show they are neither pivotal nor possess more than 20% market share. MBR Order P 111. The Commission’ s adoption of the 2500 HHI standard is an unsupported, unjustifiable departure from its prior reliance on HHIs, and is contrary to accepted antitrust economics. The Commission should instead establish 1800 as the threshold. If the Commission retains a 2500 threshold, then consistency demands that it be used with the 15% market share standard the DoJ advocated in the oil pipeline industry comments from which the 2500 HHI was lifted.18 There is no basis for using in the electric utility industry an HHI threshold proposed in the context of the oil pipeline industry. Electricity generation markets present far different economic characteristics. For example, oil pipeline transportation can be substituted with truck 18 See Comments of the United States Department of Justice in response to Notice of Inquiry Regarding MarketBased Ratemaking for Oil Pipelines, Docket No. RM94-1-000 (January 18, 1994) (“ Comments” ); U.S. Department of Justice, Oil Pipeline Deregulation: Report of the U.S. Department of Justice (May 1986) (“ Oil Pipeline Report” ). - 22 or ship transportation. Oil can be stored. Substitutability and storability, characteristics that do not appear in electric generation markets, both provide means for market participants to defeat an attempted price increase, which would make use of the higher 2500 HHI less risky for consumers. The Commission should adhere to the “ Unconcentrated < 1000 < Moderately Concentrated < 1800 Highly Concentrated”schema set forth in its Merger Policy, which is based upon the Horizontal Merger Guidelines. With respect to the Merger Guidelines’1800 threshold, “ there has been fairly little quibbling about the precise thresholds that the government has selected for creating presumptions about legality.”IV PHILLIP E. AREEDA ET AL., ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 932a, at 154 (Revised Ed. 1998).19 In specific circumstances where justified by facts, applicants or intervenors can seek to demonstrate that HHIs above or below 1800 do not or do raise market power concerns.20 However, if the Commission does retain the 2500 standard, it should at least be consistent with the DoJ Comments, which advocated a 15% — as opposed to the proposed 20% — market share as the standard for presumption of no significant market power. See DOJ Comments at 13. Nothing in the DoJ Comments suggests that the Commission gets to play pick and choose. From a consumer protection standpoint, if a more generous HHI level is selected, it must be married to a less generous market share threshold. 19 Even an 1800 HHI may be higher than appropriate. See, e.g., Thomas E. Kauper, The 1982 Horizontal Merger Guidelines: Of Collusion, Efficiency, and Failure, in ANTITRUST POLICY IN TRANSITION: THE CONVERGENCE OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 171, 189 (Eleanor M. Fox & James T. Halverson eds., 1984) (“ This [1800] level … is both higher than economic analysis dictates, and too great a departure from judicially developed standards.” ) 20 Cf. Horizontal Merger Guidelines, § 1.5 (noting that thresholds provide a framework, not precise lines of demarcation). - 23 II. THE COMMISSION MUST TAKE REALISTIC ACCOUNT OF TRANSMISSION CONSTRAINTS, NOT GIVE THEM LIP SERVICE A. Geographic Market Definition Must Reflect Market Reality The MBR Orders noted the role that transmission constraints play in defining geographic markets, whether outside of ISO/RTO markets or in them. For example, in the MBR Rehearing Order (P 177), the Commission expressly recognized that even in an RTO with Commissionapproved market monitoring and a single energy market, an RTO-wide geographic market is rebuttable on a case-specific basis: [S]ome parties claim that the Commission should not have allowed participants in ISO/RTO markets to use that region as the default relevant geographic market because internal transmission constraints can give rise to relevant geographic areas smaller than a single control area and/or an entire ISO/RTO. We recognize, however, that the ISO/RTO footprint or control area will not always be the appropriate geographic area to consider and have afforded the opportunity for the default relevant geographic market to be rebutted on a case-specific basis. This rebuttable presumption is consistent with prior Commission recognition of the role that transmission constraints can play in separating markets, even in ISO/RTOs. For example, in Wisvest-Connecticut, LLC, the Commission rejected arguments that the entire ISO-NE footprint should serve as the relevant geographic market, citing the role of transmission constraints in creating smaller geographic markets: Clearly, during periods when transmission becomes so constrained such that no additional imports from outside the region are possible and generators located inside the region are the only suppliers that can sell inside the region (i.e., the region is a "load pocket"), the region should be defined as a separate relevant geographic market. Wisvest Connecticut, LLC, 96 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,101, at 61,401 (2001). See also Tr. at 38 (Goulet). Despite statements that it would take transmission constraints into account in determining relevant geographic markets, Commission practice so far reveals those statements to be empty - 24 promises. For example, the Commission has ruled that sellers into MISO’ s Day-2 markets can assume that the entire MISO footprint represents the relevant geographic market, without even considering clear evidence and Commission findings that sub-regions of MISO were cut-off from the rest of the market because of transmission constraints. See Alliant Energy Corporate Services, Inc., 109 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,289 (2004), reh’ g pending. If known load pockets such as the Wisconsin Upper Michigan System, the Delmarva Peninsula, Southwest Connecticut, or the City of San Francisco do not rebut the geographic market presumption, or at least make the issue appropriate for investigation, the rebuttable presumption effectively becomes irrebuttable.21 Indeed, ignoring the effect of these constraints on price separation in ISO/RTO regions is inconsistent with the locational pricing that is Commission policy in RTO markets. Pricing becomes locational because generation from outside an area cannot compete with generation within an area due to transmission constraints. Prices then separate between the areas. In Merger Guidelines parlance, buyers within the constrained area cannot turn to suppliers outside the area in response to a price increase caused by sellers within the area, thus making the area a separate geographic market. Horizontal Merger Guidelines, § 1.21. Failure to take account of the economic realities of the Commission’ s LMP-policy renders the geographic market presumption irrebuttable. B. The Simultaneous Import Capability Study Fails to Reflect Actual Transmission Constraints In the MBR Orders (P 82), the Commission announced that it would make a more realistic evaluation of transmission capability: Given the experience we have gained regarding market power issues and competitive markets in general, and in concert with our 21 See also Tr. at 133 (Solomon noting that the “ hurdle is fairly steep”for overcoming the presumption). - 25 improved and more robust generation market power studies adopted herein, we find that a more realistic evaluation of transmission in general is warranted. Thus, rather than continuing to assume an unrealistically high degree of transmission access for competitors, we will adopt a more realistic measure for such import capability. We will require a transmission-providing applicant to conduct simultaneous transmission import capability studies for its home control area and each of its interconnected first-tier control areas. These studies will be used in the pivotal supplier screen and market share screen to approximate the transmission import capability. While this innovation was certainly well intentioned, experience so far with the actual implementation of the simultaneous import capability study requirement is that it largely fails to provide “ a more realistic evaluation of transmission.”APPA and TAPS understand that in MBR compliance filings so far, transmission providers have claimed significant amounts of simultaneous import capability. At the same time, the Commission has heard from market participants that transmission capacity needed for economic transactions cannot be obtained from the same transmission providers. For example, on behalf of TAPS and MMTG, Anne Kimber testified at the December 7, 2004 Technical Conference to the inability of loads of less than a megawatt to secure firm transmission paths into the MidAmerican Energy system in Iowa.22 Terry Huval, appearing on behalf of TAPS and Lafayette Utilities System at the January 28, 2005 Technical Conference, described Lafayette’ s difficulty bringing power into the Entergy system from CLECO, despite Lafayette’ s having a firm path.23 In other instances in the West 22 Written Statement of Anne Kimber on behalf of MMTG and TAPS for the December 7 Technical Conference, filed December 7, 2004 available at http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=10328815 (last viewed January 21, 2005). 23 Written Statement of Terry Huval on Behalf of the Lafayette Utilities System and the Transmission Access Policy Study Group, prepared for the January 28, 2005 Technical Conference, at 5, available at http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=10391023 (last viewed March 12, 2005). - 26 and Midwest incumbent utilities have fully reserved key interfaces in both directions, yet still reflect that transmission as available to competitors. The simultaneous import capability study requirement is failing to present a realistic picture of transmission availability. The Commission therefore needs to switch to a measure that does: Simultaneously Available Transmission Capacity (“ ATC” ). The Commission already requires ATC for the Appendix A merger analysis. In the MBR context, it must also base its analysis on what market participants must rely upon when seeking to transact in the market. OASIS sites post ATC for both firm and non-firm transactions. While ATC measures are not perfect, they reflect the transmission capacity market participants are told is available when they determine the feasibility of a transaction. The requirement that Commission MBR decisions be based on empirical proof means that the Commission must take markets as it finds them. If the Commission looks at markets as they operate today, it will find ATC as the measure of transmission capability. Thus, the Commission should require sellers to calculate the simultaneous available import capability of their systems, which would take account (and deduct) existing firm reservations, CBM, TRM and other transmission commitments.24 III. REMEDIES SHOULD BE TARGETED TO ELIMINATE THE INCENTIVE AND ABILITY OF THE MBR APPLICANT TO EXERCISE MARKET POWER At the outset, APPA and TAPS urge the Commission to convene a separate technical conference on the issue of remedies. Such a conference should explore how remedies can be tied to the specific market power concerns associated with a particular MBR applicant. The need to carefully craft the remedy to the facts presented is the flip-side of the Commission’ s obligations 24 Consideration could be given to adjusting firm ATC figures where it can be shown that a reserved path represents a genuine source of competing supply into the relevant geographic market. However, if the path is committed to a long-term power sale, an adjustment would be inappropriate. - 27 to make factual finding that an MBR applicant does not possess or has adequately mitigated its market power. The factual record regarding a seller’ s market power should give rise to mitigation that is effective to address that market power. In addition to being targeted, remedies need to be effective. Thus, the Commission should develop a compliance process to ensure that remedies are actually implemented as intended. Remedies should also be monitored to ensure that they achieve the desired ends. The Commission clearly has the authority to condition the grant of market-based rates on the adoption of appropriate mitigation, including the structural remedies described below. “ The authorization to sell power at market-based rates . . . –as opposed to traditional, cost-based rates –is a privilege, and granted if, and only if, the Commission determines that an applicant’ s use of such rates will be just and reasonable.”Enron Power Mktg., Inc., 106 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,024, P 13 (2004).25 Where a seller seeks the privilege to sell at market-based rates and where the Commission is pursuing its goal of regulation through reliance on competitive forces, the 26 Commission’ s conditioning authority is at “ zenith.” Particularly in the context of market-based rates, the Commission must include conditions that ensure that underlying competitive circumstances support reliance upon market forces to adequately discipline rates. If those conditions do not obtain, it cannot approve the rate.27 25 See generally, Pennsylvania Water & Power Co. v. FPC, 343 U.S. 414, 418 (1952) (“ A major purpose of the whole Act is to protect power consumers against excessive prices.” ). 26 Niagara Mohawk Power Corp. v. FPC, 379 F.2d 153, 159 (D.C. Cir. 1967). See also Northern Natural Gas Co. v. FERC, 785 F.2d 338, 341 (D.C. Cir. 1986). 27 Farmers Union, 734 F.2d at 1509; Interstate Natural Gas Ass’ n v. FERC, 285 F.3d 18, 34 (D.C. Cir. 2002) (relying upon Commission “ monitoring and assurance of remedies in the event of insufficient competition, on which Farmers Union set great store” ). See also Revised Pub. Util. Filing Requirements, III F.E.R.C. Stats. & Regs., ¶ 31,127, at P 111 (2002), 67 Fed. Reg. 31,043, 31,054 (May 8, 2002) (“ [T]he Commission’ s market-based rate findings do not absolve the Commission from its continuing responsibility to assure that rates are just and reasonable.” ). - 28 The D.C. Circuit’ s decision in California Indep. Sys. Operator Corp. v. FERC, 372 F.3d 395 (D.C. Cir. 2004) strongly supports the Commission’ s authority to establish structural conditions that must be met prior to award of market-based rate authorization. The court confirmed that if the California ISO did not meet FERC’ s conditions for qualification as an ISO, FERC need not approve it as one. If FERC concludes that CAISO lacks the independence or other necessary attributes to constitute an ISO for purposes of Order No. 888, then it need not approve CAISO as an ISO. ISO membership is not an end in itself; it is merely a method jurisdictional utilities can use to comply with Order No. 888’ s mandate for those entities to file nondiscriminatory open access tariffs.… The Commission, in Order No. 888 and other rulings made pursuant thereto, has defined ISOs according to the terms it wishes. FERC has the authority not to accept something which it does not deem an ISO. 372 F.3d at 404. The court specifically recognized the Commission’ s power to condition jurisdictional utility rate filings. Id. at 402 (citing Central Iowa Power Coop. v. FERC, 606 F.2d 1156 (D.C. Cir. 1979)). The same analysis applies to the privilege of charging market-based rates. The Commission has the authority to identify the conditions under which it will authorize marketbased rates, and it is up to the applicant to decide whether to accept them. If the competitive conditions necessary to make market-based rates just and reasonable do not exist, and the applicant refuses to accept ameliorative conditions, the Commission need not –indeed, cannot – authorize them. A. Remedies Should Focus on Ensuring Structurally Competitive Markets The Commission should give priority to remedies that promote structurally competitive markets. APPA and TAPS members want to be able to choose a power supplier in a competitive - 29 market, but need the protection of cost-based rates if that choice is illusory. Remedies focused on fostering structurally competitive markets will help to ensure that the choice is real. A hallmark of competitive markets is many buyers and many sellers. The Commission can aid in increasing the number of sellers by encouraging diverse ownership and control of generation. If the record indicates that the seller holds a dominant position in the market, the Commission must condition the MBR authorization on the seller’ s taking steps to reduce its dominant position. The MBR applicant can choose to accept the condition or not. The seller can put control of capacity necessary address its dominance into the hands of competitors through sales of capacity, whether by selling the capacity outright (i.e., divestiture) or turning control of that capacity over to a third party (e.g., long-term contract with full-dispatch rights, auction of capacity rights, tolling agreements). The Commission has required such remedies in the merger context to address market power concerns. See American Elec. Power Co., Central and South West Corp., 90 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,242 (2000), order on reh’ g, 91 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,129, at 61,489 (2000) (capacity sale); Allegheny Energy, Inc., 84 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,223 (1998) (divestiture). Similar remedies could be made condition to MBR authorization. The seller can also invite market participants, especially wholesale customers who may be captive to the seller’ s transmission system, to participate in new generation projects. In many cases, the position of a dominant MBR seller that also operates a transmission system is attributable to the inadequacy of that transmission system, an inadequacy that the seller itself may have contributed to by failing to adequately plan for the needs of network customers and eschewing efforts to develop regional solutions to transmission problems. If the presence of substantial and continuing transmission constraints in a dominant transmission provider’ s control area allow it to charge supra-competitive “ market-based”rates for generation in its control area, - 30 it is appropriate for the Commission to require these constraints to be addressed, if it is going to allow that transmission provider to charge MBR. The appropriate structural remedy is expanding transmission capacity, access and ownership to create a more robust grid that enables buyers and sellers to reach one another. In such circumstances, the Commission should impose mitigating conditions on MBR authority to increase access to existing facilities as well as investments in new transmission. For existing facilities, an MBR applicant that controls transmission should set aside capacity for use by wholesale customers trapped in the applicant’ s control area by transmission constraints, so that the customers can obtain access to alternative suppliers. Such capacity can also be created through redispatch, at least as a temporary remedy until new transmission is built.28 Other solutions involving existing grid capacity include clarifying and strengthening network customer rollover rights under OATT § 2.2, so that those rights encompass reasonable access to sources other than those from which the customer is currently served.29 Such rights would reinforce an obligation to plan to enable more flexible usage of the system. They would also be consistent with the assumption underlying the Commission’ s control area-based approach to relevant markets—that transmission is readily available within the host control area if there is access to the border. The Commission should also enforce the OATT’ s existing requirement (§ 28.2 and Preamble to Part III) that the transmission owner plan and construct the system to accommodate a network customer’ s existing and planned designated network resources. A vertically-integrated transmission owner that fails to do so should be held accountable, e.g., by conditioning MBR authority on the transmission owner’ s willingness to accommodate the 28 See Oklahoma Gas & Electric Company, et al., 108 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,004 (2004) (requiring redispatch under 600 MW transmission “ bridge”was in place). - 31 network customer’ s timely designation of a new network resource even where such accommodation would, pending construction of the needed transmission upgrades, require redispatching of the TO’ s own resources. The associated redispatch costs could be shared on a load ratio basis similar to OATT § 34.1). Longer term solutions require transmission expansion so that the transmission grid enables willing buyers and sellers to make deals. The Commission can tie the grant of MBR authority to vertically-integrated transmission owners seeking MBR rates to their demonstrated commitment to make upgrades that allow their wholesale customers cost-effective access to competitive alternatives. Cf. Oklahoma Gas & Electric Company, et al., 108 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,004 (2004) (construction of transmission “ bridge”as remedy to market power concerns). It can also tie the grant of MBR authority to the demonstrated willingness of such vertically-integrated transmission owners to jointly plan transmission with their network customers, to participate in collaborative and inclusive regional transmission planning processes,30 and to permit such customers to invest in the transmission system on a comparable basis. Customer investments must be treated comparably to the transmission provider’ s own through credits and recovery of costs through the transmission owner’ s revenue requirement. B. The Commission Correctly Requires Cost-Based Sales Until a Seller Mitigates its Market Power In the MBR Orders, the Commission correctly adopted revocation or denial of marketbased rates and default cost-based mitigation for those sellers that do not show they lack or have adequately mitigated market power. Cost-based rates may be necessary during the period that an 29 30 See also Kimber Affidavit. At minimum, the Commission should reduce the current incentive for TOs to avoid joint planning, by modifying OATT § 30.9 so that where the transmission owner declines to engage in joint planning needed to serve the customer, credits will be deemed appropriate if the facilities are constructed by the network customer. - 32 MBR applicant is undertaking transmission upgrades that will give wholesale customers trapped by transmission constraints within its control area access to the larger market. The Commission’ s default mitigation for short-term transactions (caps reflecting marginal costs plus 10% for sales of less than a week) also works in RTO-administered spot markets, because offers in competitive spot markets should reflect marginal costs.31 The Commission should not be swayed by inevitable claims from generators that the default mitigation somehow undermines its efforts to foster competitive markets in regions with ISOs and RTOs. While cost-based rates address the problem of the exercise of market power through economic withholding, there remains the problem of physical withholding. An MBR applicant, particularly one that is also a transmission provider and thus controls transmission access in its control area, may respond to a cost-based rate requirement for sales in that control area by simply refusing to sell to customers located in its control area. If that were to occur, and wholesale customers in the control area therefore lacked sufficient supply alternatives due to the withdrawal from the market of a dominant supplier (if, for example, they were located in a transmission-constrained load pocket), the predicate underlying Order No. 888’ s elimination of a wholesale obligation to serve –that captive transmission customers have a choice of suppliers – would no longer exist.32 Under those circumstances, the Commission would be justified in 31 Bids reflecting marginal costs are consistent with the theory underlying RTO spot markets. In a competitive market, the incentive should be for the seller to bid its marginal cost, because failure to do so could cause the seller to price itself out of the market when it otherwise would have been profitable to make a sale. Further, bids that do not reflect marginal cost can distort economic dispatch, and thus raise consumer costs, by causing inefficient units to be called before more efficient ones. 32 Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non-discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities; Recovery of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities, FERC Stats. & Regs., Proposed - 33 requiring the dominant supplier to offer cost-based sales to captive customers located in its control area. However, such an obligation to sell should not be a permanent solution. APPA and TAPS would much prefer to see the structural changes necessary to support competitive wholesale markets implemented, rather than to return to a cost-based wholesale rate regime.33 Customers and markets will be better off if the Commission enforces the obligation under Order No. 888 on transmission providers to plan and build sufficient transmission facilities so that captive customers can access the broader wholesale market beyond such an MBR applicant’ s control area. C. In Appropriate Cases, the Applicant Should Be Denied MBR Authority Outside Its Control Area Unless It Provides Wholesale Customers Embedded in Its Own Control Area Adequate Access to the Broader Regional Market There may be cases where denying MBR authority within an applicant’ s control area will still not remedy the market power problem. By choosing to maintain a constrained transmission system and refusing to sell power to wholesale customers embedded in that system, such a transmission provider denies these wholesale customers access to regional power markets and prevents otherwise willing buyers and sellers from transacting business. Such acts also weaken the regional power markets that the Commission must rely on to keep market-based rates just and reasonable, by reducing the number of active buyers and sellers. If the transmission provider also competes with the embedded wholesale customers on its system for end use loads (as is the Regs., ¶ 32,514, at 33,110 (1995). 33 Nor do APPA and TAPS want to see a new wave of unjustified stranded cost claims based upon public utilities having to undertake generation construction for trapped wholesale customers. - 34 case in many instances), anticompetitive concerns, including price/supply squeeze issues, are also raised. To remedy the market power problem in these instances, the Commission should deny MBR authorization even outside such a dominant vertically-integrated utility’ s own control area, until such an applicant provides customers that must use its transmission system cost-effective access to competitive alternatives.34 Where transmission customers are foreclosed access to the broader market, the resulting wholesale rate the transmission provider charges outside its control area cannot be deemed lawful.35 That wholesale rate is unduly discriminatory and preferential, because it is available only to purchasers who do not depend upon the transmission provider’ s system and unavailable to those on-system customers that have been foreclosed by the transmission provider’ s failure to maintain a sufficient transmission system.36 IV. THE COMMISSION MUST AVOID HARMFUL ANALYTICAL SHORTCUTS A. The Commission Should Eliminate the Automatic Exemption for Post1996 Generation Units In its recent final rule, Reporting Requirement for Changes in Status for Public Utilities with Market-Based Rate Authority, 110 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,097, P 38 (2005), the Commission said it would address in this proceeding “ whether the Commission should retain the exemption for post- 34 Self-build is not necessarily an alternative, as the Commission found in the MBR Order (P 155 and n.151). 35 See also Testimony of Steve Schleimer for Calpine Corporation, December 7, 2004 Technical Conference, Tr. at 207: “ But I also think that, you know, there is potential FERC angle, and that is to the extent that the utility wants to have market-based rates and participate in the wholesale competitive markets outside of its service territory, it has to have a wholesale competitive market inside its service territory.” 36 Cutting off the embedded customer from the broader market can also distort that market by artificially reducing its size and scope, including through blocking competitive merchant generators’access to potential wholesale customers, which produces unjust and unreasonable rates. - 35 1996 generation in section 35.27 of the Commission’ s regulations.”The Commission should eliminate the exemption, because there is no principled basis for maintaining it. At first blush, one would not expect an applicant entering a market for the first time to raise competitive concerns. After all, new entry and increasing output in a market is generally pro-competitive. However, simply because the generator’ s action de-concentrates ownership in the market does not mean there is no risk of market power exercise. The new facility could be going into a market where there are too few competitors. The addition of a new competitor, while helpful, may not be sufficient to eliminate the market power risk such that the FPA’ s standards for market-based rates are satisfied.37 The issue is more clear-cut where the applicant is adding generation to a market where it already owns or controls other facilities. In the MBR Order (at P 38) the Commission stated that “ if an applicant sites generation in an area where it or its affiliates own or control other generation assets, the applicant must address whether its new capacity, when added to existing capacity, raises generation market power concerns.”In the MBR Reh’ g Order (P 110), the Commission clarified that “ in circumstances where construction on all of an applicant’ s generation commenced after July 9, 1996, no interim generation market power analysis need be performed.”There should be no blanket exemption for facilities built after 1996.38 That the 37 The Commission should not import merger principles into the analysis here. The typical issue in a merger case is whether a transaction will lessen competition. New entry into a market increases competition, and merger law would not condemn it. However, under Section 205 of the FPA, the question is not whether the transaction lessens competition. It is whether the applicant has no market power, or has adequately mitigated it. A new entrant could possess such market power, even if its entry does incrementally improve conditions in a market. 38 See PJM Interconnection, LLC, 110 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,053, P 53 (2005). - 36 facilities were built before or after 1996 is immaterial to whether market power may be exercised.39 The addition of a new plant increases a seller’ s market share in either case. Instead of a blanket exemption, the applicant should be permitted to demonstrate that the pro-competitive benefits of its adding generation to the market outweigh any risk of market power exercise. Such a showing will depend upon the underlying competitive conditions. If there is a risk of market power exercise, mitigation measures can be developed that are targeted to the risk presented, taking into account the pro-competitive benefits of the new entry. B. The Commission Should Not Automatically Accept RTO Mitigation Regimens as Adequate Mitigation of an Applicant’ s Market Power In the MBR Orders and in recent cases, the Commission has expressed a willingness to rely upon Commission-approved ISO/RTO market mitigation measures as sufficient to address the market power harm posed by an MBR applicant. See MBR Order P 189; MBR Rehearing Order P 174; AEP Power Marketing, Inc., 109 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,276, P 21 (2004). The Commission also said in the MBR Rehearing Order (P 174) that it “ must independently verify the effectiveness of any alternative mitigation measures, including the ISO/RTO mitigation, which would serve to replace the default mitigation adopted in the April 14 Order.”However, in practice the Commission has not undertaken the promised independent verification. In Alliant Energy Corporate Services, 109 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,289, P 35, the Commission ruled, without any particularized inquiry, that MISO’ s mitigation measures addressed intervenor concerns about the applicant’ s market power in the load pocket. There was no record on whether and how the MISO mitigation measures in fact addressed the applicant’ s market power. If the Commission is 39 See also Tr. at 39 (Goulet) (“ There’ s no reason to distinguish between an entity’ s ability to exert market power based on unit age, a factor that really bears no nexus to the potential to exert market power” ). - 37 going permit reliance on ISO/RTO mitigation, then it must be shown that the mitigation is effective at addressing the particular MBR seller’ s market power.40 ISO/RTO mitigation regimes are typically designed to allow the exercise of some market power with the expectation that competitive market response, rather than a mitigation measure, will step in to make the market power exercise unprofitable. For example, in parts of MISO, ISO-NE/and the NYISO, prices can rise by up to the lesser of $100 per MWh or 200 percent before market mitigation measures apply. In some parts of these ISO/RTO markets, the tolerance is smaller but still substantial. However, much smaller increases in price, if sustained, as well as short-lived but large increases, can cause considerable consumer harm. The Merger Guidelines use a 5% non-transitory price increase as an indicator of market power exercise when defining markets. Merger Guidelines, § 1.11.41 If a five percent increase in price can represent an anticompetitive price increase, a threshold that tolerates a price increase of more than 200 percent clearly leaves room for consumer harm. Where a market is not competitive, the market response will not occur or will be too weak to remedy the seller’ s market power. Under those circumstances, the Commission cannot rely upon the mitigation regime. The foregoing concerns are confirmed in the February 4, 2004 affidavit of Dr. Laurence Kirsch,42 which explained that the failure of ISO/RTO mitigation to look at bilateral markets or for collusion, combined with the generous conduct and market impact thresholds applied under 40 Reliance on market-based pricing requires empirical proof that market power is absent or is mitigated. See Part I.A. above. The Commission is also expected to make specific inquiry into the market power risks posed by an applicant. See Cal. ex rel. Lockyer v. FERC, 383 F.3d at 1013. Unless the Commission makes factual findings regarding the market power risk posed by an applicant and the mitigation necessary to address those risks, the Commission cannot approve market-based rates. Generic reliance upon ISO/RTO mitigation does not satisfy the Commission’ s legal obligations. 41 Note that 5% is not a tolerance level for permissible competitive harm. Merger Guidelines, § 1.0. Consumers can suffer competitive harm when prices increase by less than 5%, if such price increases are sustained. 42 See Kirsch SMA Affidavit at 7. - 38 ISO/RTO mitigation regimes, “ means that concentrated generation ownership will allow generation firms to raise prices in spot markets above competitive levels without triggering mitigation, and will allow such firms to raise prices in forward markets to whatever abovecompetitive level that the market will bear.”He further concluded (at 7) that failure of these regimes to mitigate market power could cost consumers millions of dollars in excessive prices and that current market monitoring regimes are poorly equipped to provide the consumer protection the FPA demands: [I]t is difficult for market monitors to identify misbehavior by market participants and costly for market monitors to force participants to change their behavior. While the infrequency of market monitors’disciplinary actions has been touted by some as an indication of the success of the market monitoring in RTO and ISO markets, the truth may be that this infrequency arises also (or instead) from the difficulties and costs of identifying and mitigating the exercise of market power. Another risk of relying on ISO/RTO mitigation measures is that the measures approved by the Commission apply only to short-term markets and do not address market power in longterm markets. The Commission correctly concluded in the MBR Order (P 155) that long-term markets present distinct competitive concerns to which the FPA requires attention. An absence of available long-term transmission service or existing congestion hedges, as well as generation siting barriers, could render long-term market power concerns quite real. Finally, ISO/RTO state of the market reports reveal that withholding behavior often goes unchecked. The charts labeled Figures 18 and 19 (below) are taken from the 2003 State of the Market Report, New York Electricity Markets, prepared by Potomac Economics, Ltd., the NYISO independent market advisor.43 The figures show how an “ output gap”varies by load 43 Available at http://www.nyiso.com/topics/articles/news_releases/2004/patton_report/2003_state_of_the_market_report_final_full - 39 level, where “ The output gap is the quantity of generation capacity that is economic at the market clearing price, but is not running due to the owner’ s offer price or is setting the LBMP with an offer price substantially above competitive levels.”Id. at 27. In other words, the output gap is the quantity of capacity that should be running (because it is in-merit) but is not running because the supplier bid “ well above”(that is, at least $50/MWh or 100% above) the proxy for the generator’ s marginal cost. Id. at 27-28. In plainer English, the “ output gap”is economic withholding. Figure 19, presented first below, shows the hours where offers exceeded the actual NYISO conduct threshold in East New York –the lesser of $100/MWh or 300 percent.44 (Each dot is an hour.) Figure 18 (shown second), shows the number of hours offers would exceed a lower threshold of the lesser of $50/MWh or 100 percent. Dr. Patton took comfort in the fact that in both cases the output gap declined as load (and therefore prices) increased. However, what provides Dr. Patton solace should deeply disturb the Commission. The chart shows the consistent presence of numerous hours of economic withholding in East New York (just one part of the state) in amounts ranging from a couple hundred megawatts to nearly 1500 MW. The chart also shows that generous thresholds mask withholding. Such a mitigation regime plainly does not suffice to remedy market power sufficient to support a lawful grant of MBR authority. _text.pdf (last viewed March 11, 2005). 44 In parts of New York where this generous conduct threshold applies, generator bids are not mitigated unless they increase prices by the lesser of $100 per MWh or 200 percent. - 40 - C. The Commission Should Organize MBR Reviews on a Regional Basis, But Should Not Rely Upon General Findings that a Region is Competitive to Grant of Market-Based Rates to Specific Sellers The Commission can better manage MBR reauthorizations,45 which will both streamline the process and make needed data more readily available. One potentially valuable tool is to 45 Most public utilities currently have MBR authority, so the most pressing task facing the Commission is how to - 41 synchronize consideration of renewals for a specified geographic region, such as a regional reliability council (“ RRC” ). Among the greatest benefits of such coordination would be the likely improved quality and availability of data. Regional proceedings provide a means to require applicants to simultaneously produce data for the region, thus allowing such data to be used to develop a more complete picture of the market in which the applicants compete. Certain common issues in a region could also be consolidated for decision. For example, differing regional practices (e.g., RRC rules on calculation of TTC) might affect how much transmission capacity is practically available along an interface shared by multiple applicants, and transmission data from several adjacent systems would facilitate resolution of any transmission capacity discrepancies among operators of common transmission interfaces. By contrast, other issues, especially ones involving seller-specific facts, may require separate decision. For example, a seller’ s geographic market, market shares, or load obligations, and the effect of retail rate regulation on the seller’ s incentive and ability to exercise market power, would fall into this category. Similarly, the proper mitigation to apply where a market power problem exists will depend on a specific analysis of that seller’ s market power.46 While MBR review can be coordinated on a regional basis, such an approach does not translate to the conclusion the relevant geographic market is that specific region. Proper competitive analysis requires that the Commission define the relevant geographic market based upon factual evidence, such as transmission constraints, control area boundaries, and trading address triennial updates. 46 Further streamlining could come from consolidation of reauthorizations of affiliated sellers. Instead of multiple, repetitive applications, a company with affiliated sellers in a market or in several markets should be required to consolidate applications for Commission consideration. This step would also address the problem of the Commission’ s authorizing MBR applications for which market participants had inadequate notice of affiliate relationships due, for example, to creative naming. Even if this consolidation is not required, at minimum an applicant’ s draft notice of filing should identify all affiliated sellers with MBR authorization (or seeking it). - 42 patterns.47 A regional approach does not relieve the Commission of its obligations to make a fact-based inquiry regarding a specific seller’ s potential to exercise market power. The requirement that a seller lack or have mitigated market power remains. D. The Commission Should Not Extend the Market Power Screens to Ancillary Services Markets The January 27, 2005 Technical Conference agenda also asked whether the Commission should extend its generation market power screens “ to cover capacity and generation based ancillary services, such as reserves and regulation.”Such extension is premature. While the Commission has made substantial progress in developing workable screens in the context of energy and capacity markets, extension of the screens to ancillary services markets presents additional complexity. Where a MBR seller that also owns or operates a transmission system seeks to sell ancillary services at MBRs in its home control area, the Commission should undertake a full investigation and not rely upon the results of indicative screens. The fundamental problem is that ancillary services markets remain very much dependent upon control area operation and are closely connected to the operation of the transmission system. This is reflected, inter alia, in the Commission’ s policy of authorizing MBR outside a transmission provider’ s system. Avista Corp., 87 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61, 223, order on reh’ g, 89 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,136 (1999). Capacity on automatic generation control (“ AGC” ) cannot easily sell regulation service in its home market today and switch to sales in an adjoining market tomorrow. With respect to reserves markets, the Commission has been pushing ISO/RTOs to adopt locational reserve markets which, because of the effect of transmission constraints, can 47 Tr. at 124 (Wroblewski) (“ Using a regional approach makes sense if this means that FERC will examine all the applicants for market-based rate authority in a particular region at the same time. Doing so will allow FERC to properly delineate product and geographic markets within that particular region. If using a regional approach means using one geographic region as the geographic market, then I’ d say this is no more accurate than using control areas - 43 limit the ability of capacity to compete outside of its “ home”market. Thus, limitations of transmission and technology counsel against adopting short-cuts for assessing the appropriateness of market-based pricing of ancillary services. While some ISOs/RTOs have moved to implement market-based pricing for some ancillary services, concerns remain.48 For example, PJM recently sought and the Commission allowed to take effect by operation of law market-based rates for regulation services in PJMWest and PJM-South,49 despite the fact that PJM’ s market monitor recommended against adoption of market-based rates without further study given highly concentrated markets in these regions.50 Even if the Commission finds that conditions exist to permit market-based pricing of some ancillary services in ISO/RTO-administered markets, such pricing would not be appropriate where vertically-integrated utilities with MBR authority are also control area operators, because of the increased risk of competitive harm associated with such operation. E. Neither Market Participants nor the Commission Are Receiving Timely and Sufficient Data to Perform Market Analyses 1. Market Participants Continue to Face Great Difficulty in Obtaining and Analyzing Data in a Timely Manner APPA and TAPS member experiences with the Interim Screens so far have revealed serious issues regarding the availability of data and the sufficiency of time to make productive use of data. The Commission must address these problems if intervenors are going to as the geographic market for assessing market power.” ). Accord Tr. at 133 (Solomon). 48 Tr. at 37 (Goulet). 49 See, generally, record in PJM Interconnection, LLC, Docket No. ER05-10-000. It is not clear that the Commission has satisfied its obligations to undertake a fact-based inquiry into the permissibility of market-based rates if such rates are allowed to go into effect by operation of law. 50 The Commission’ s handing of the filing can only be called Kafkaesque. After allowing the rate to go into effect by operation of law, the Commission dismissed the rehearing petition of American Municipal Power-Ohio, Inc., stating “ the pleading does not lie because the Commission did not issue an order in the proceeding.”PJM Interconnection, LLC, Docket No. ER05-10-001, “ Notice Dismissing Pleading,”(January 31, 2005). - 44 meaningfully participate in MBR proceedings. At a minimum, the Commission needs to grant intervenor requests for a longer response time, e.g., 60 days, for MBR authorization filings.51 One of the problems is the widespread designation of simultaneous import capability studies as CEII. Our experience indicates that most such studies are labeled CEII, and sometimes the CEII designation may bleed over to the entire MBR filing. It seems highly unlikely that every element of the simultaneous import capability study is CEII. However, by so designating their studies, applicants erect a significant road-block to the ability of intervenors to review and respond to the filings. While we do not have specific evidence suggesting that applicants are purposefully abusing CEII designations, the extent of such designations in the context of time sensitive MBR filings should prompt the Commission to investigate the problem. Commission procedures for the designation of CEII do not solve this problem. As APPA and TAPS have explained previously,52 even if the timelines established by the CEII request procedures work flawlessly, most of the standard 21 days permitted for responding to an MBR filing would be consumed, leaving no time to use CEII data once obtained.53 However, it does not appear that those procedures do in fact work flawlessly. Undersigned counsel’ s request for CEII access in one case took nearly two months to process.54 Further, it does not appear that the 51 As noted above, most such filings are MBR updates for which a 60-day time limit on Commission action does not apply. 52 See March 25, 2002 Comments of the American Public Power Association on the Commission’ s Notice of Inquiry and Guidance for Filings in the Interim (Docket Nos. RM02-4-000 and PL02-1-000); November 14, 2002 Comments of the Transmission Access Policy Study Group (Docket Nos. RM02-4-000 and PL02-1-000); March 21, 2003 Petition for Rehearing of the Transmission Access Policy Study Group (Docket Nos. RM02-4-001 and PL021-000); May 16, 2003 Comments of the American Public Power Association and Transmission Access Policy Study Group (Docket No. RM03-6-000); May 27, 2003 Motion of Transmission Access Policy Study Group to Supplement and For Reconsideration (Docket Nos. RM02-4-001 and PL02-1-001). 53 Further, in many cases intervenors do not have the full 21 days. While the Commission starts the clock from the time the filing is made, interested parties often do not receive notice of the filing until several days later. 54 See Docket No. CE05-69-000. Even allowing for the fact that the time period ran over the Christmas and New Year holidays, the processing would have taken longer than the time contemplated by the CEII procedures. - 45 Commission staff reviews CEII designations until a request for CEII access is submitted. Thus, a Commission check on over-designation of CEII is not automatic. The current 21-day response time is also not enough for intervenors to prepare a DPT to rebut the results of the Interim Screens. In the MBR Rehearing Order (P 28), the Commission correctly clarified that intervenors could submit a DPT to rebut an applicant’ s passage of the Interim Screens. However, even assuming there are no problems obtaining and using the data needed to perform a DPT –an assumption that likely never applies –more than three weeks is required to prepare the DPT. Indeed, the Commission itself has given applicants for whom it has ordered Section 206 investigations 60 days to submit a DPT. See, e.g., AEP Power Marketing, Inc., 109 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,276, Order Paragraph (E). To give intervenors a fighting chance, the Commission should expand its “ standard” notice period for MBR triennial updates or at least grant an extension of up to 60 days at the request of intervenors seeking CEII or intending to perform a DPT. 2. The Commission Must Require Regular Reporting of Needed Information The FPA’ s requirement that rates be just and reasonable demands that the Commission and market participants have sufficient analytical and data resources to support the assessment of market power. Simply performing a Google search will not yield data on peak loads, transmission reliability margins, maintenance outages and the like required to perform Interim Screens and the DPT. Rather, the Commission needs to update its information reporting requirements so that they fully support the MBR program. The Commission must require public utilities to submit the data necessary to permit proper market analysis. The Commission’ s authority to impose information filing requirements on utilities is more than adequate to obtain such data. 16 U.S.C. §§ 824l(b), 825 (2000). As a - 46 condition attached to their MBR authorizations, sellers should regularly provide transaction data necessary to perform the Screens and DPT.55 The quarterly transaction reports required under Order No. 2001 are inadequate for the task, because the information is too aggregated. Similarly, the Commission should impose a condition on transmission providers with MBR authorization that requires production of transmission capacity and operation data sufficient to assess transmission capacity and its availability. V. THE APPA/TAPS GENERATION MARKET POWER TEST IMPROVES UPON THE INTERIM SCREENS As noted at the outset, APPA and TAPS believe that the Interim Screens, in combination with the rebuttable presumptions, the DPT, and the default mitigation, come closer to providing the Commission with the kind of MBR test the FPA requires. Nonetheless, two important shortcomings in the screens increase the risk of false negatives. One involves the absence of any kind of analysis of supply or fuel curves to determine whether a generator owns or controls capacity in a market that allows it to profitability raise prices, even where it is neither pivotal nor dominant. Testimony at the January 27, 2005 Technical Conference confirmed that fuel cost curves do matter. Tr. at 60-61 (Bushnell). The second involves how native load and long-term contractual obligations affect a seller’ s ability and incentive to exercise market power. The Technical Conference also showed that while these obligations are important, they impact specific sellers differently. Tr. at 63-64 (Bushnell, Hegedus). However, the Commission’ s current approach of deducting native load obligations from installed capacity to calculate 55 The Commission can use protective orders to address concerns about confidential information while making it available to intervenors. However, it should not avoid collecting and sharing this information out of excessive concern for confidentiality. - 47 Uncommitted Capacity uses an axe to account for these obligations when only a carving knife is necessary and appropriate. The APPA/TAPS Generation Market Power Test addresses these shortcomings by explicitly incorporating fuel or supply curves into the analysis and requiring the applicant to explain with specificity how its retail native load and long-term contractual obligations affect its incentives and ability to exercise market power. The APPA/TAPS Test retains (though in slightly revised forms) the Interim Screens’use of pivotal supplier and market share metrics. The APPA/TAPS test also calibrates filing requirements to the market power risk a particular applicant poses, to ease burdens on both sellers and the Commission. A. The Commission Must Incorporate Supply Curve Analysis To Capture the Dynamic Nature of Electricity Markets An assessment of supply curves reveals incentives and abilities of a specific seller to exercise market power by providing information about the shape and composition of the supply curve and the seller’ s place on it. Neither pivotal supplier nor concentration/market share metrics provide this important perspective. In its August 2002 Strawman on Market Metrics, the FERC Staff explained the need for some measure of structural incentives for withholding, where firms with units near the market clearing price (typically peaking units) hold large amounts of lower priced (typically baseload) capacity that could profit from economic withholding of the marginal units, or from physical withholding of small amounts of baseload capacity that would force the peaking units to set the marginal price.56 56 See “ Strawman”Staff Discussion Paper on Market Metrics SMD Staff Conference on Market Monitoring, Docket No. RM01-12, Remedying Undue Discrimination Through Open-Access Transmission Service and Standard Electricity Market Design, at 12, available at http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=9567029 (last viewed March 11, 2005). - 48 In his article, Analyzing Gas and Electricity Convergence Mergers: A Supply Curve is Worth a Thousand Words, FERC OMTR Staffer David Hunger explained that “ [e]stimating supply curves for the downstream electricity market gives analysts an additional tool for predicting 57 future market outcomes.” Professor Bush notes that “ [a] straight-up counting of capacity may not detect market power arising from a fuel curve problem. Bush Aff. ¶ 22. Paul Joskow and Edward Kahn, when examining withholding behavior in California markets, recognized the importance of supply curves:58 whether withdrawing capacity is in the self-interest of a portfolio generator will depend critically upon the slope of the supply curve. It must be steep enough to result in MCPs sufficiently high so that the increase in profit on generation still tendered to the market more than offsets the profits lost on the capacity withdrawn. Analysis of the supply curve involves its composition and shape, the elasticity of supply along the curve, and the location of the seller’ s own units on the curve. Consider the example of an applicant with a baseload unit and a peaker unit in a load pocket subject to LMP. The applicant is not a pivotal supplier nor has a market share of greater than 20%. Its peaking unit, an aero-derivative combustion turbine, is located on the rightward portion of the curve as it starts to slope steeply upward. Other peaking units, such as frame units and diesel generators, are less efficient and located further to the right on the curve. The marginal cost difference between the applicant’ s peaking unit and the next one further up the curve is $15 per MWh. Because of the relative efficiency of the applicant’ s peaking unit, it is in-merit, even at times other than the 57 David Hunger, Analyzing Gas and Electric Convergence Mergers: A Supply Curve is Worth a Thousand Words, 24:2 JOURNAL OF REGULATORY ECONOMICS 161 (2003). 58 Paul Joskow and Edward Kahn, A Quantitative Analysis of Pricing Behavior in California’ s Wholesale Electricty Market During Summer 2000: The Final Word, at 20 (February 4, 2002), available at http://www.ksg.harvard.edu/hepg/Papers/Joskow-Kahn%20Final%20Word%20Feb2002.pdf (last viewed March 10, 2005). - 49 system peak, on days when the load pocket is cut off from the larger market. The $15 per MWh difference between the applicant’ s unit and the next peaker on the curve provides the applicant with the ability to raise price in the market by raising its offer by up to $14.99 per MWh without worry about a competitive response.59 The applicant’ s inframarginal generation, which earns the increased LMP due to the applicant’ s economic withholding, provides the applicant with an incentive to withhold. Neither the Pivotal Supplier Screen nor the Market Share Screen would capture this market power risk. However, examining the supply curve reveals that the applicant has market power within a portion of the supply curve and has the incentive to exercise it.60 Data needed to construct supply curves should be readily available to most applicants.61 A key piece of information is heat rate data, because the efficiency of a unit gives a good approximation of the likely order in which the units should be dispatched, if the units are bidding based upon marginal costs. Sources of this data include the Environmental Protection Agency (because heat rate data is also used to monitor air emissions) and commercial sources, such as RDI and Platt’ s. B. The Commission Should Assess the Impact of Native Load on Market Power Rather than Exclude It Entirely The second major shortcoming in the Interim Screens is the use of an Uncommitted Capacity measure derived by deducting from an applicant’ s installed (or total nameplate) capacity the capacity used for operating reserves, native load commitments (including 59 Let us also assume that the peaking unit has a marginal cost of $60 per MWh such economic withholding would be possible in a number of RTO markets, for example, in ISO-NE where the market’ s mitigation measures permit offer increases of the lesser of $25 per MWH or 50 percent, or NYISO and MISO where offers exceeding reference levels by the lesser of $100 per MWh or 300 percent are tolerated. In contrast, if the example market were in PJM, the unit would presumably be subject to a marginal cost plus 10% bid cap when transmission constraints bind. 60 As described below in Part V.C., the supply curve analysis is incorporated into the Generation Market Power Test. 61 January 27, 2005 Tr. at 60 (Bushnell). - 50 requirements sales). Any gain in administrative simplicity associated with using the Interim Screens’“ standard deduction”causes too much harm to consumers. The Commission should instead require applicants to take “ itemized deductions”for native load and long-term commitments. Capacity deducted because it is claimed to be dedicated to native load is clearly part of the market. According to Dr. Rodney Frame, a chief proponent of the adjustment, if capacity “ dedicated”to native load were not permitted to make sales into wholesale markets, prices in those markets would go up, because there would be less supply competing for the market’ s demand: And if you draw your supply and demand curves, if you take some supply out of the market, the prices are going to rise. And when the prices rise, that's what I call anti-competitive. It's harmful to customers. January 13, 2004 PL02-8-000 Technical Conference, Tr. at 243-44. Dr. Frame’ s testimony demonstrates that capacity “ dedicated”to native load competes in wholesale markets and should not be excluded. The wholesale deduction of capacity dedicated to native load is also suspect analytically. In the context of antitrust analysis, the issue of how to treat a vertically integrated firm’ s internal consumption is analogous, if not identical, to the native load capacity question. The Antitrust Division’ s treatment of such capacity is instructive. In a case presenting industry characteristics similar to the electric utility industry,62 the Antitrust Division counted capacity used for internal production (downstream production of aluminum) in a vertically-integrated firm’ s share of capacity for the production of alumina (the product of refining bauxite ore). United States v. 62 Report of the Antitrust Committee, 23 ENERGY L. J. 211, 245 (2002). - 51 Alcoa, Inc., 152 F. Supp. 2d 37, 41-42 (D.D.C. 2001). The alumina market was characterized by vertically integrated firms that used a significant portion of their capacity (about two-thirds) for internal consumption as well as an active third-party spot and forward (long-term) market.63 In addition, demand for alumina was highly inelastic, barriers to entry were high, and the industry showed a susceptibility to collusion.64 In concluding that the alumina market was highly concentrated, the Antitrust Division included both capacity used for internal consumption and that used for third party sales in the relevant product market.65 The Alcoa decision is consistent with competition authorities’approaches to the treatment of internal production capacity. According to the United Kingdom Office of Fair Trading, the question is one of “ the ease with which production can or could be switched from 66 internal to external sales.” The Horizontal Merger Guidelines (§ 1.4) state that the Agency will not include such “ capacity to the extent that the firm’ s capacity is committed or so profitably employed outside the relevant market that it would not be available to respond to an increase in price in the market.”If capacity is sometimes available and sometimes not, the answer is not to pretend that it is never available. Rather, a more refined approach, as described in the Generation Market Power Test, is required. In this regard, the December 19, 2003 Staff Paper correctly asked about “ the ability of the applicant and vertically integrated utilities to segregate 63 United States v. Alcoa, Inc., et al., Civil No. 00-CV-954 (RMU), Complaint of the United States, ¶ 11 (available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f4600/4663.pdf) (last viewed March 13, 2005). 64 Id. at ¶¶ 18-21. 65 Id. at ¶¶ 11, 16-17. 66 Assessment of Market Power, Office of Fair Trading, Publication OFT 415, ¶ 4.6 (September 1999) (available at http://www.rail-reg.gov.uk/upload/pdf/oft415.pdf) (last viewed March 14, 2005). - 52 wholesale opportunity sales from retail sales and the reasonableness of seeking to isolate 67 wholesale and retail supplies.” The Interim Screens blunt deduction of these commitments does not work. Professor Bushnell stated at the January 27, 2005 Technical Conference (Tr. at 13): Concentration measures and even pivotal supply measures just don't accommodate consideration of net position [effect of native load obligations] very well. You can't just plug net position into a formula. That really makes sense if you try to develop a modified concentration measure that utilizes net position in a way that is consistent with underlying economic power the way the original concentration methods are consistent with an underlying model. In contrast, the APPA/TAPS Generation Market Power Test adopts a Native Load Obligation Factor.68 This Factor considers how a seller’ s obligations to native load and other long-term customers affects its incentives and ability to raise prices. For example, the ability of a seller to use the capacity to cause competitive injury in the wholesale market will depend on facts such as the extent to which price increases in the wholesale market caused by the seller’ s anticompetitive activity must be borne by the seller or may be passed along to the seller’ s native load customers, such as through a fuel and purchased power adjustment clause. Similarly, the retail ratemaking regime may permit the seller to pass along to shareholders increased profits from sales at supra-competitive prices in wholesale markets.69 67 Conference on Supply Margin Assessment, Notice of Technical Conference, Staff Paper at 9 (December 19, 2003) available at http://www.ferc.gov/EventCalendar/Files/20040112104841-PL02-8-000-notice.pdf (last viewed March 11, 2005). 68 See Part V.C. below. 69 Professor Bushnell described variables associated with these factors. Tr. at 63. - 53 C. The Commission Should Adopt the APPA/TAPS Generation Market Power Test The APPA/TAPS Generation Market Power Test is predictable and practical, includes filing requirements calibrated for the market power potential of the applicants, and yields relevant, probative and substantial evidence for assessing market power, while minimizing the potential for false negatives and false positives that can leave consumers and market participants exposed to harm.70 The Horizontal Market Power Screen prescribes examination of three indicative, complementary metrics –market share and concentration, pivotal supplier and supply curves –to reveal the underlying market structure and a seller’ s place in it. Where looking at structure alone may not reveal a clear or complete picture, evidence on Effects Factors (load and sales obligations, entry conditions, transmission control, demand elasticity and other regional or local factors) are examined. The resulting market-specific evidence generated by the Screen and the Effects Factors will permit the Commission to exercise its best judgment to decide whether a seller’ s market-based rates would be just and reasonable. The proposed framework permits streamlined applications and, in appropriate case, expedited consideration of a seller’ s request. Pure power marketers and generators who have sold the entirety of their capacity and all rights to dispatch it qualify for a Safe Harbor involving minimal filing requirements. Sellers that have generation dispatch rights but that are not likely to hold dominant or pivotal positions in a market, such as a load pocket, may file using an Abbreviated Application that requires only a Horizontal Market Power Screen conducted using simplifying, conservative assumptions designed to ease filing burdens while avoiding false 70 The framework is not, however, intended to be a regulatory smorgasbord. For example, that the Safe Harbor discussed below may reasonably apply to some power marketers does not mean it should be available to dominant vertically integrated sellers. - 54 negatives. Sellers filing these applications will be presumed to pass the Generation Market Power Test if the Horizontal Market Power Screen indicates that they are neither dominant nor pivotal and there is no substantial evidence to the contrary. Where the risk of market power exercise is higher, e.g., applications by dominant, vertically integrated public utilities or merchant generators with a fleet of plants in the same market, the framework prescribes a more probing inquiry, the Standard Application, requiring submission of the Horizontal Market Power Screen as well as evidence on Effects Factors. The calibrated filing requirements envisioned by this framework are entirely appropriate to the stakes: application costs will pale compared to the billions of dollars of MBR sales authorized by the Commission as well as the hundreds of millions, if not billions, of dollars of higher rates paid by consumers if firms with market power sell without FPA-required mitigation.71 Below we summarize the key elements of the Generation Market Power Test. In the Appendix attached hereto, we provide greater detail and justification for each element. APPA/TAPS Generation Market Power Test Filing requirements based upon market power risk posed by the applicant. o Safe Harbor Application: Qualifications: Seller that does not operate or control transmission facilities and that is: A power marketer that does not own generation, that has no capacity with dispatch rights and that has no tolling agreements; or A generator that has sold the entirety of its capacity and all rights to dispatch it. 71 Filing Requirements: Certification of facts qualifying seller for Safe Harbor. Meaningful review upfront helps to nip potential market power problems in the bud, making it less likely that the Commission and market participants will have to endure the pain and suffering of after-the-fact refund proceedings. - 55 o Abbreviated Application: Qualifications: Seller that does not operate or control transmission facilities, that has not otherwise sold the entirety of its capacity and all rights to dispatch it and that in each properly defined geographic market is: A seller that owns or controls either a single plant or total capacity of less than 100 MW; or A seller into an ISO/RTO market that does not own or control generation located in a load pocket or having a significant effect on whether a transmission constraint is binding. Filing Requirements: Horizontal Market Power Screen conducted using conservative, simplifying assumptions. o Standard Application: Qualifications: Seller that does not qualify for Safe Harbor or Abbreviated Application or seller that filed Abbreviated Application but failed the Screen. Filing Requirements: Horizontal Market Power Screen and Effects Factors. Expedited consideration of MBR applications: o Applications that do not present disputed or missing facts and that involve straight forward questions of interpreting proffered evidence (e.g., absence of disputes over geographic market definition or passage of Screen) will be decided “ on the pleadings.” Generally, Safe Harbor and Abbreviated Applications should be decided on the pleadings. Depending upon the record and issues presented, Standard Applications may also qualify. o Applications with disputed or missing facts or with complex questions of evidentiary interpretation should be set for Section 206 investigation with opportunities for discovery. Where possible, hearings should be expedited. Meaningful Generation Market Power Test: o A Horizontal Market Power Screen and Effects Factors provide the Commission the relevant, probative and substantial evidence it must have to make a reasoned decision about seller market power. Based upon the evidentiary record, the Commission will exercise its judgment regarding the just and reasonableness of the seller’ s proposed market-based rates and the need for mitigation. o Geographic Market Analysis (required for Abbreviated and Standard applications): Applicant will file the Screen using its home control or transmission area as the geographic market and will address whether the control area or transmission area, - 56 or a smaller or larger area, is the correct geographic market. The analysis will focus particularly on the role of transmission constraints in defining geographic markets. Transmission capacity should be calculated based upon Simultaneous Available Transmission Capacity (“ ATC” ). Applicants operating transmission must also submit data on Total Transmission Capacity (“ TTC” ), Transmission Reliability Margin (“ TRM” ), Capacity Benefit Margin (“ CBM” ), the incidence and extent of Transmission Loading Relief (“ TLR” ) and other transmission curtailments, and their own transmission reservations. o Horizontal Market Power Screen Conducted for the Geographic Market(s) (required for Abbreviated and Standard Applications): Screen uses three indicative, complementary metrics to provide a more accurate picture of market structure and seller’ s place in it. Abbreviated Application Provisions: Sellers filing an Abbreviated Application may run the Horizontal Market Power Screen assuming no import capability for competing supply. Absent contrary evidence, sellers filing Abbreviated Applications will be presumed to pass the Generation Market Power Test if the Horizontal Market Power Screen demonstrates (a) the Applicant has less than 20% of the capacity in the total market as well as in any portion of the supply curve,72 (b) the market is not concentrated, and (c) the Applicant is not a pivotal supplier, either singly or jointly, in any month. Market Share and Concentration Metric: A metric such as HHI is needed to assess overall market structure and risks of collusion. Based on the horizontal merger Appendix A analysis, the framework requires calculation of market shares and concentration for a properly defined geographic market for Economic Capacity and Available Economic Capacity in off-peak, shoulder and peak periods. The data burdens of the Appendix A analysis are reduced significantly through use of a no-competing–imports-assumption (in the case of Abbreviated Applications), and use of appropriately defined geographic markets rather than Destination Markets. 72 For example, a seller may have a concentration of units within, straddling or throughout baseload, intermediate or peak portions of the supply curve. - 57 Pivotal Supplier Metric: In recognition of the heightened market power concerns during peak periods, applicant will submit a pivotal supplier metric, the “ pivotal supplier HHI,”that assesses whether it is pivotal singly as well as jointly with other sellers to gauge potential for coordinated exercises of market power. The pivotal supplier metric should be run for the peak hour of each month to provide evidence of seasonal variations of supply and demand. Supply Curve Metric: The shape and composition of the supply curve allows the Commission to assess whether an applicant’ s generation fleet provides it with an incentive and ability to exercise market power. The same data sources that support the HHI metric will allow construction of the supply curve. o Effects Factors Analysis to permit interpretation of Horizontal Market Power Screen (required for Standard Applications only). Sales and Transaction Factor: The factor examines actual activity in the relevant market as a real-world test of the Horizontal Market Power Screen results. It allows the applicant and intervenors to show whether the sales and transaction experience in the market is consistent with what the structural metrics show. One kind of evidence that could be examined is RFP results, particularly to gauge how many sellers responded to an RFP and difficulties the respondents might have encountered, such as difficulties of securing transmission paths. The Factor also allows an examination of the applicant’ s level of sales activity to understand better whether an applicant is active in making third party sales, to whom, at what prices and, where the seller is not active, why not. Load Obligation Factor: Applicant will describe its native load and long-term sales obligations, the rate-setting mechanism for its obligations, including distribution of profits from opportunity sales and the ability of the seller to pass through wholesale purchased power costs to customers. This factor allows the applicant to explain, and the Commission to analyze, any differences between the Economic Capacity and Available Economic Capacity results of the Appendix A analysis to determine their affect on the ability and incentive to exercise market power. With this specific information, the Commission can determine the appropriate treatment of the Native Load Obligation. Entry Conditions Factor: Entry that is timely, likely and sufficient can lessen or defeat a seller’ s market power. An applicant will submit evidence on entry conditions, such as planned entry (projects under construction), past entry, site availability and control, siting authority and procedures, transportation infrastructure (electricity transmission and natural gas transportation) and the applicant’ s control over fuel inputs (e.g., natural gas pipelines). Applicants should address both short-term and long-term markets. Transmission Factor: An applicant will address whether transmission operations have been turned over to an independent entity. Where they have not, the applicant should address the prospect for and barriers to independent operation. - 58 The applicant will describe expected changes in transmission capacity, either due to future reservations from the applicant itself (or others, if known) or the construction of new transmission facilities. Demand Elasticity Factor: Generally, the Commission should assume that demand elasticity is very low, unless evidence suggests otherwise. An applicant in a market where demand response programs exist will address the extent to which buyers can reduce usage or shift to other sellers or products in response to a price increase. Optional Regional and Local Factors: The applicant may introduce other relevant and probative evidence that affects a seller’ s ability to exercise market power or the interpretation of the Horizontal Market Power Screen results. For example, an applicant in a market where hydropower is prevalent would want to address the effect of high- and low-water years. Other relevant evidence includes the applicant’ s prior anticompetitive activity in the market. With the evidentiary record produced by the Generation Market Power Test, the Commission can exercise its judgment about whether the applicant has market power. If the Commission concludes that the seller has market power, the record provides a basis to consider mitigation measures specifically targeted to the market power concerns revealed through the analysis. Possible mitigation measures are described above in Part IV above. CONCLUSION APPA and TAPS believe that their Generation Market Power Test improves upon the Commission’ s current generation market power test for MBR authorizations in ways that will ensure that the Commission’ s decisions about market-based rates are supported by empirical proof that a seller does not possess market power or has adequately mitigated it. At a minimum, the Commission should refine the existing Interim Screens and application of the DPT, as described above. The Commission must also genuinely consider the role that transmission constraints play in defining geographic markets and determining who may compete within a market. Finally, the Commission should focus on structural remedies so that wholesale APPENDIX TO COMMENTS OF AMERICAN PUBLIC POWER ASSOCIATION AND THE TRANSMISSION ACCESS POLICY STUDY GROUP IN MARKET-BASED RATES FOR PUBLIC UTILITIES, DOCKET NO. RM04-7-000 MARCH 14, 2005 The APPA/TAPS Generation Market Power Test The APPA/TAPS Generation Market Power Test is designed to be a workable test with filing requirements calibrated for the market power potential of the applicants. It should yield relevant, probative and substantial evidence for assessing market power, while minimizing the potential for false negatives and false positives that can leave consumers and market participants exposed to harm.1 The Test utilizes a Horizontal Market Power Screen and Effects Factors framework. The Horizontal Market Power Screen prescribes examination of three indicative, complementary metrics –market share and concentration, pivotal supplier and supply curves –to reveal the underlying market structure and a seller’ s place in it. Where looking at structure alone may not reveal a clear or complete picture, evidence on Effects Factors (sales and transactions, native load obligations, entry conditions, transmission control, demand elasticity and other regional or local factors) are examined. The resulting market-specific evidence generated by the Screen and the Effects Factors will permit the Commission to exercise its judgment to decide whether a seller’ s market-based rates would be just and reasonable. 1 The framework is not intended to be a regulatory smorgasbord. For example, that the Safe Harbor discussed below may reasonably apply to some power marketers does not mean it should be available to vertically integrated sellers seeking MBR authorization. - ii Where appropriate, the proposed framework permits streamlined applications and expedited consideration of a seller’ s request. Pure power marketers and generators who have sold the entirety of their capacity and all rights to dispatch it qualify for a Safe Harbor involving minimal filing requirements. Sellers that have generation dispatch rights but that are not likely to hold dominant or pivotal positions in a market, such as a load pocket, may file using an Abbreviated Application that requires only a Horizontal Market Power Screen conducted using simplifying, conservative assumptions designed to ease filing burdens while avoiding false negatives. Sellers filing these applications will be presumed to pass the Generation Market Power Test if the Horizontal Market Power Screen indicates that they are neither dominant nor pivotal and there is no substantial evidence to the contrary. Where the risk of market power exercise is higher, e.g., applications by dominant, vertically integrated utilities or merchant generators with a fleet of plants in a market, the framework prescribes a more probing inquiry, the Standard Application, requiring submission of the Horizontal Market Power Screen as well as evidence on Effects Factors. The calibrated filing requirements envisioned by this framework are entirely appropriate to the stakes: application costs will pale compared to the billions of dollars of MBR sales authorized by the Commission as well as the hundreds of millions, if not billions, of dollars of higher rates paid by consumers if firms with market power sell without FPA-required mitigation.2 2 Meaningful review upfront helps to nip potential market power problems in the bud, making it less likely that the Commission and market participants will have to endure the pain and suffering of after-the-fact refund proceedings. - iii I. THE GENERATION MARKET POWER TEST IS WORKABLE A. The Test Defines Filing Requirements Based Upon the Risk of Market Power Exercise The Commission faces the challenge of ensuring that its test for generation market power is effective in determining whether it may, consistent with the FPA’ s just and reasonable rate mandate, authorize a public utility to sell at market-based rates, while at the same time not overwhelming its administrative resources and over-taxing the financial resources of market participants. The Commission should calibrate applicants’ filing requirements based upon the risk they pose for the exercise of market power. The Generation Market Power Test features the following calibration of application requirements: o Safe Harbor Application: Qualifications: Seller that does not operate or control transmission facilities and that is: A power marketer that does not own generation, that has no capacity with dispatch rights and that has no tolling agreements; or A generator that has sold the entirety of its capacity and all rights to dispatch it. Filing Requirements: Certification of facts qualifying seller for Safe Harbor. o Abbreviated Application: Qualifications: Seller that does not operate or control transmission facilities, that has not otherwise sold the entirety of its capacity and all rights to dispatch it and that in each properly defined geographic market is: A seller that owns or controls a single plant or total capacity of less than 100 MW; or A seller into an ISO/RTO market that does not own or control generation located in a load pocket or have a significant effect on whether a transmission constraint is binding. - iv Filing Requirements: Horizontal Market Power Screen conducted using conservative, simplifying assumptions; demonstration of facts to qualify seller for Abbreviated Application. o Standard Application: Qualifications: Seller that does not qualify for Safe Harbor or Abbreviated Application or seller that filed Abbreviated Application but failed the Screen. Filing Requirements: Horizontal Market Power Screen and Effects Factors. The Safe Harbor category recognizes that certain applicants pose so little risk of market power exercise that requiring them to make more than the most basic filing would waste both their and the Commission’ s resources. Sellers eligible for the Safe Harbor must not have control over transmission facilities. Such sellers must not possess rights to control dispatch of generation, so that they cannot withhold supply, either physically or economically, from the market. Power marketers that have no generation, have no capacity with dispatch rights or have no tolling agreements, as well as generators that have sold their capacity and all rights to dispatch it, are the mostly likely sellers eligible for the Safe Harbor. An Abbreviated Application would be available to sellers with small amounts of generation relative to the size of the geographic market, because of the reduced risk of market power harm they are likely to pose. If such sellers own transmission assets, they must have turned control of them over to an independent entity (e.g., an ISO/RTO) to ensure that transmission cannot be used to favor their own generation. In any properly defined geographic market, eligible sellers could own or control only one facility or less than 100 MW of generation in order to minimize the risk of withholding some or all of the output of a plant so as to raise price and earn additional profit on other sales in the -vsame market. Where a seller owns or controls generation in multiple geographic markets, it must qualify for the Abbreviated Application in each market. Eligible sellers would also include firms selling into ISO/RTO markets with no generation located in load pockets or no generation that has a significant effect on whether a transmission constraint is binding. To examine the potential market power risks they pose, sellers eligible for the Abbreviated Application would prepare the Horizontal Market Power Screen, described below, for the relevant geographic market and could do so using a conservative, simplifying assumption that no competing generation could be imported into the market.3 A seller filing an Abbreviated Application would be presumed to pass the Generation Market Power Test if the results of the Screen showed that the seller has less than 20% market share in an unconcentrated market, both in the total market as well as along any portion of the supply curve,4 and that it is not a pivotal supplier, either singly or jointly with other sellers. Intervenors would be permitted to demonstrate that, despite passing the Horizontal Market Power Screen, the seller otherwise qualified for the Abbreviated Application poses a more serious risk of market power and should be required to file the Standard Application. The 20% threshold is similar to the one proposed in the December 19, 2003 Staff Paper (at 7-9) for the Market Share Screens,5 3 Such applicants would not prepare the Effects Factor Analysis, unless they failed the Horizontal Market Power Screen. 4 For example, a seller may have a concentration of units within, straddling or throughout base, intermediate or peak portions of the supply curve. 5 Staff Paper, Attachment to December 19, 2003 Notice of Technical Conference on Supply Margin Assessment Screen and Alternatives, available at http://www.ferc.gov/EventCalendar/Files/20040112104841-PL02-8-000-notice.pdf (last viewed March 11, 2005). - vi but unlike that proposal the threshold as applied under the Horizontal Market Power Screen would significantly reduce the chances of an erroneous result by requiring that the market be unconcentrated, that the seller not be pivotal, and that the seller not exceed 20% of the entire market or any portion of the supply curve. The effect of the threshold, as applied here, is to ensure, for example, that an owner of a large plant in a load pocket is not in a position to profitably exercise market power. The Standard Application sellers are those that do not qualify for the Safe Harbor or the Abbreviated Application and for whom the results of the Horizontal Market Power Screen cannot or should not be interpreted without an assessment of the Effects Factors outlined below. Standard Applications would be filed by “ big fish,”including those in large or small ponds, whose market characteristics raise the risk of market power exercise, namely dominant sellers: vertically integrated utilities that have not divested generation, merchant generators with fleets of facilities and retained rights to dispatch their capacity, and sellers in concentrated load pockets. If in a position to exercise market power, such sellers stand to earn hundreds of millions if not billions of unwarranted profits from sales at supra-competitive rates. It is both appropriate and obligatory for the Commission to examine such sellers’market-based rate requests closely. Through this more probing inquiry, the Standard Application should reduce the likelihood of false positives and false negatives, which benefits both sellers and consumers. These filing requirements work in conjunction with the Horizontal Market Power Screen and Effects Factors to provide a robust Generation Market Power Test that protects buyers and sellers. Treatment of the elements of the Test in à la carte fashion, - vii however, can seriously jeopardize that protection. For example, the Commission should not make the Safe Harbor available to a power marketer that controls the dispatch of generation. Nor should the Commission make the Abbreviated Application available to a merchant generator with a fleet of units in a geographic market. Both examples have presented the Commission with serious market problems.6 Such problems could be overlooked if the Generation Market Power Test were disaggregated and applied without consideration for the relationship among its constituent parts. B. The Test Provides for Expedited Treatment of Straight-Forward MBR Applications Depending upon the complexity of an application, the Generation Market Power Test contemplates (1) summary decision based upon pleadings of applications or (2) an FPA Section 206 investigation. Applications presenting factual disputes, lacking needed data, or involving complex or difficult issues concerning the interpretation of evidence (e.g., disputes over geographic market definitions or passage of the Horizontal Market Power Screen) should be set for hearing. However, the Commission can expedite the hearing process itself by encouraging settlement conferences at the outset to identify missing data, to determine means of obtaining it, and to identify issues subject to resolution via stipulation. After settlement discussions, outstanding disputes and issues can be addressed through hearing, including on an expedited basis. Decisions based upon the application and pleadings (as well as responses to any deficiency letters) could be appropriate for those cases that do not present factual disputes or do not involve complex interpretative questions. Safe Harbor and Abbreviated 6 See Enron Power Marketing, Inc., et al., 106 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,024 (2004), and Wisvest-Connecticut, LLC and NRG Connecticut Power Assets, LLC, 96 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,101 (2001). - viii Applications are the most likely candidates for this kind of procedural treatment, although Standard Applications would not be excluded. To help develop a factual record that could permit summary disposition, the Commission should make use of deficiency letters where applications are incomplete or do not appear to qualify for a specific procedural category (for example, the application should be filed as a Standard rather than Abbreviated one). After the applicant responds and intervenors have an opportunity to assess the response, the Commission may then be able to decide the case without a hearing. II. THE GENERATION MARKET POWER TEST PRODUCES RELEVANT, PROBATIVE AND SUBSTANTIAL EVIDENCE TO ASSESS SELLER MARKET POWER A. The Test Examines a Range of Metrics and Factors, Because Reliance on a Single Metric Will Not Yield Reliable Results The Generation Market Power Test, which is supported in the affidavit of Dr. Laurence Kirsch attached to APPA/TAP’ s February 4, 2004 Post-Technical Conference Comments in PL02-8-000 (hereafter “ Kirsch SMA Affidavit” ),7 reasonably captures various aspects of a seller’ s market power and permits the Commission to make evidence-backed decisions.8 According to Dr. Kirsch, a reasonable market power test should include the following: 7 Dr. Kirsch’ s Affidavit originally accompanied the February 4, 2004 “ Post-Technical Conference Comments of the American Public Power Association and the Transmission Access Policy Study Group,” filed in Docket No. PL02-8-000, Conference on Supply Margin Assessment (“ February 4, 2004 SMA Comments” ), available at http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=10057963 (last viewed March 11, 2005). APPA and TAPS also filed it in this docket on June 30, 2004. 8 The Test will permit examination of evidence relevant to market power in ancillary services markets, or can be adapted to that purpose. It builds on the approach set forth in the October 23, 2002 Comments of the American Public Power Association and Transmission Access Policy Study Group on Market Power, Market Monitoring, and Market Mitigation Issues in Supply Margin Assessment and Standard Market Design, Docket Nos. PL02-8-000 and RM01-12-000, at 15, 48-54 (available at http://ferris.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=9581911) (last viewed on March 11, 2005). - ix Screens should be able to identify situations in which suppliers, alone or through parallel or coordinated behavior (tacit or express collusion) with other suppliers, are able to raise prices significantly above competitive levels. *** Screens should recognize that the ability to exercise market power changes over time with changes in load levels, generation output, and the availability of generation and transmission facilities. At a minimum, screens should examine market power for the on-peak and off-peak periods of the different seasons and, as appropriate, for forthcoming years. Kirsch SMA Affidavit at 8-9. He concludes that: “ At the present time, there is no single screen that can serve all of these purposes.”Dr. Kirsch also warns about the dangers of relying on a single metric. The proposed SMA, for example looks only at the most extreme situations in which a supplier can single-handedly reduce operating reserve margins to levels that trigger emergency procedures or even require load shedding. This ability to cause system distress is certainly sufficient to establish the ability to exercise market power; but there are many other situations in which a supplier can exercise market power without having such an ability. The tests for market power therefore need to include a variety of screens that together provide a range of evidence needed to assess the ability and incentives to exercise market power. Kirsch SMA Affidavit at 9. B. The Horizontal Market Power Screen Provides Structural Evidence of the Potential for Market Power Exercise To make an informed decision about seller market power, the Commission must have evidence revealing the relevant market’ s structure and the seller’ s place in it. Because of the insufficiency of a single structural metric to provide this evidence, the Horizontal Market Power Screen employs three metrics: Market Share and -xConcentration, Pivotal Supplier and Supply Curve. The Commission Staff’ s Strawman Discussion Paper on Market Metrics included similar metrics for assessing market structure (Strawman at 18), and observed (at 11-12, footnote omitted):9 Concentration measures form the principal measure of market structure, with the HHI being used most commonly by the DoJ and in FERC analyses for mergers and market based rates. In the analysis of market based rates, FERC also employs the concept of a pivotal supplier, measuring the degree to which the supply of a single firm is needed to meet market demand in an area. These measures are designed to provide an indication of market power for a defined market, with market power being defined as the ability to raise the price above the competitive level. Although it can be argued that the link between concentration and market power is not always conclusive, it still provides a useful measure of competitive market structure, particularly when used in conjunction with other measures. These metrics, or similar ones, are also employed by market monitors to assess market power.10 Market share and concentration evidence, as produced by metrics such as HHI, builds upon the Commission’ s familiarity with such metrics as part of the Appendix A Analysis required by its merger regulations, 18 C.F.R. Part 33, as well as upon acceptance of the metrics by the antitrust agencies and courts. See, e.g., FTC v. H.J. Heinz Co., 246 F.3d 708, 716 n.9 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (noting judicial acceptance of HHI 9 See “ Strawman”Staff Discussion Paper on Market Metrics SMD Staff Conference on Market Monitoring, Docket No. RM01-12, Remedying Undue Discrimination Through Open-Access Transmission Service and Standard Electricity Market Design, available at http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=9567029 (last viewed March 11, 2005). 10 See ISO New England, Annual Markets Report, May –December 2002, at 34-45 (August 13, 2003) (available at http://www.isone.com/smd/market_analysis_and_reports/public_forum_and_annual_report/2003_Annual_Forum/2002_A nnual_Market_Report_Final.pdf) (last viewed on March 11, 2005). - xi based upon DoJ, FTC and economist use of same). As adapted from the Appendix A analysis, the Horizontal Market Power Screen will be easier to perform. The number of geographic markets should, in most cases, be fewer with the Screen because it will not have to be performed for every Destination Market. Rather, in many instances, a properly calculated geographic market will capture several relevant Destination Markets.11 The Screen would reflect Appendix A’ s use of seasonal and load level calculations to “ recognize that the ability to exercise market power changes over time with changes in load levels, generation output, and the availability of generation and transmission facilities.”Kirsch Affidavit at 8-9. More acute market power concerns arise during periods of peak demand,12 and so the Horizontal Market Power Screen uses a pivotal supplier metric to determine the extent to which a supplier’ s output is required to meet the market demand. The particular metric urged here, the “ pivotal supplier HHI,”explained by Dr. Kirsch in his October 2002 affidavit (at 3-11) included with APPA/TAPS October 23, 2002 Market Power Comments,13 measures pivotal supply at peak, like other similar metrics, but also examines the collusion risk associated with suppliers who may be jointly pivotal. The pivotal supplier HHI can also measure pivotal supply in non-peak hours, and so like the 11 There may be situations, however, where a load pocket within a destination market, will produce the opposite result. This may occur when a single load-serving entity has customers inside and outside a load pocket. In those cases, the load pocket must be analyzed as a separate geographic market. 12 13 Kirsch SMA Affidavit at 9. See October 23, 2002 “ Comments of American Public Power Association and Transmission Access Policy Study Group on Market Power, Market Monitoring, and Market Mitigation Issues in Supply Margin Assessment and Standard Market Design,”Docket Nos. PL02-8 and RM01-12, available at http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=9581912 (last viewed March 11, 2005). - xii December 19, 2003 Staff Paper’ s monthly peak approach (at 6-7),14 it can capture the variations in potential market power that accompany seasonal variations in load and supply.15 The Horizontal Market Power Screen also uses a supply curve metric to gauge the incentives and abilities of a seller to exercise market power based upon the shape and composition of the supply curve and the seller’ s place on it. A supply curve metric serves the need identified by Staff’ s September 20, 2002 Strawman for “ some measure of structural incentives for withholding, where firms with units near the market clearing price (typically peaking units) hold large amounts of lower priced (typically baseload) capacity that could profit from economic withholding of the marginal units, or from physical withholding of small amounts of baseload capacity that would force the peaking units to set the marginal price.”Strawman at 12. See also APPA/TAPS October 23, 2002 Market Power Comments at 51-52.16 Data from commercial sources, such as RDI, provide basic information (plant ownership, fuel source, costs, location) that allows construction of a straight forward supply curve to assess whether its composition and shape, including the location of the seller’ s own units on the curve, can provide the seller with the ability and incentive to profitably withhold. 14 The Staff Paper’ s recommendation to adjust capacity calculations for planned outages merits further analysis so that it produces a more accurate picture of the market. For example, outages that reduce a seller’ s market share during shoulder months should not similarly reduce its market share during peak months when the outage has ended. Outages of both the applicant and other sellers are relevant as well. In addition, the Commission should understand what effects an outage (including forced) has on transmission constraints and whether the seller can dispatch its units to profitably raise prices above competitive levels. 15 See Kirsch SMA Affidavit at 8-9. 16 See n.13 supra. - xiii It bears noting that the framework set forth here creates other opportunities to make the Horizontal Market Power Screen practical and not unduly burdensome. First, sellers eligible to file Abbreviated Applications may perform the Screen using the conservative assumption that no transmission capacity exists to permit imports from competing capacity.17 This assumption reduces considerably the amount of transmission price and capacity data required to run the Screen. Second, the same data set should enable an applicant to calculate all three metrics, especially when the no-competitiveimports assumption applies. Third, the Commission itself can facilitate the availability of data to run the Screen, and make the Screen results more robust, if it adopts the regionbased MBR review described in the main body of the APPA/TAPS March 14, 2005 Comments. C. Sellers Posing Higher Market Power Risk Must Submit Evidence Regarding “Effects Factors” As emphasized above, market power analysis is not mechanistic. The Horizontal Market Power Screen, while providing indicative data, is not determinative of the market power question, especially where a seller’ s market position suggests a greater or a lesser ability or incentive to exercise market power. Like competition authorities,18 the Commission should view the structural data as a starting point of the analysis and continue with an assessment of the role of other factors. These Effects Factors are not duplicative of the Screen metrics, but complement the screen by allowing consideration 17 Sellers which are neither dominant nor pivotal with diminished competitor presence will not become dominant or pivotal when a larger amount of competing capacity is included in the calculation of the metrics. 18 See Horizontal Merger Guidelines, § 2.0; Assessment of Market Power, Office of Fair Trading, Publication OFT 415, ¶ 3.6 (September 1999) (available at http://www.railreg.gov.uk/upload/pdf/oft415.pdf) (last viewed March 11, 2005). - xiv of market-specific facts that would suggest that the screen results understate or overstate a seller’ s ability and incentive to exercise market power. As such, sellers and purchasers should view the Effects Factors as a meaningful and important addition to the Generation Market Power Test to ensure the Commission reaches the right result. The Sales and Transaction Factor examines actual activity in the relevant market as a real-world test of the Horizontal Market Power Screen results. It allows the applicant and intervenors to show whether the sales and transaction experience in the market is consistent with what the structural metrics show. One kind of evidence that could be examined is RFP results, particularly to gauge how many sellers responded to an RFP and difficulties the respondents might have encountered, such as difficulties of securing transmission paths. The Factor also allows an examination of the applicant’ s level of sales activity to understand better whether an applicant is or is not active in making third party sales, to whom, at what prices and, where the seller is not active, why not. The Load Obligations Factor considers how a seller’ s obligations to native load and other long-term requirements customers affects its incentives and ability to raise prices. For example, it is clear that capacity “ dedicated”to serve native load often is available to and does participant in wholesale markets. The ability of a seller to use the capacity to cause competitive injury in the wholesale market will depend on facts such as the extent to which price increases in the wholesale market caused by the seller’ s anticompetitive activity must be borne by the seller or may be passed along to the seller’ s customers, such as through a fuel and purchased power adjustment clause. Similarly, the retail ratemaking regime may permit the seller to pass along to shareholders increased - xv profits from sales at supra-competitive prices in wholesale markets. The structural metrics described above cannot be satisfactorily adjusted to account for these facts. Thus, it is appropriate to assess them as Effects Factors to determine based upon sellerspecific facts haw they should be accounted for in the market analysis. The Factor also allows the applicant to explain, and the Commission to analyze, any differences between the Economic Capacity and Available Economic Capacity results of the Appendix A analysis to determine their affect on the ability and incentive to exercise market power. The Entry Conditions Factor considers where entry can defeat an attempt to increase prices and help to deconcentrate markets.19 An applicant should submit evidence on entry conditions, such as planned entry (projects under construction), past entry, site availability and control, siting authority and procedures, and transportation infrastructure (electricity transmission and natural gas transportation), control over fuel inputs for electric generation (e.g. natural gas pipelines or capacity contracts) and profitability of entry.20 Assessment of entry conditions should address both short-term and long-term horizons. As Dr. Kirsch details, the Commission cannot assume that entry will be likely, timely and sufficient to defeat seller market power.21 Among other things, “ generation investment may be lumpy,”“ transmission access may be insufficient,”and “ access to fuels may be insufficient.”Kirsch SMA Affidavit at 5-6. LSEs in many parts of the 19 APPA and TAPS also addressed entry conditions in their October 23, 2002 Market Power Comments (at 52-54). 20 The price necessary to make entry attractive may be high and leave considerable room for a dominant incumbent to exercise market power. 21 See Horizontal Merger Guidelines, § 3.0. - xvi country feel the impact of the entry difficulties described by Dr. Kirsch. According to Mr. Jesse Tilton at the Commission’ s January 13, 2004 Technical Conference on the Supply Margin Assessment, Docket No. PL02-8-000:22 While in other parts of the Southeast there is a generation glut, we can’ t access it. Meanwhile, building our own plant in eastern North Carolina is not economically justified because of the absence of basic transportation infrastructure -- pipes and wires. Purchases from merchants are not a viable alternative, because there is very little merchant capacity in the CPL-East control area. It is clear from the SMA record that the Generation Market Power Test must consider entry conditions. The Transmission Factor: An applicant should address whether transmission operations have been turned over to an independent entity. Where they have not, the applicant should address the prospect for and barriers to independent operation. The applicant should describe expected changes in transmission capacity, either due to future reservations from the applicant itself (or others, if known) or the construction of new transmission facilities. This Factor also provides evidence to assess the credibility of a transmission owning seller’ s data on transmission capacity, especially where the seller has not turned over control of its transmission to an independent entity. Vertically integrated generators should demonstrate that transmission limits do not now and will not in the future impose binding limits on the geographic market. Probative evidence in this regard includes the availability of firm transfer capability for imports and exports along major interfaces as well as the frequency with which transmission is constrained in the 22 Conference on Supply Margin Assessment, Statement of Jesse C. Tilton III for the January 13 Technical Conference at 4 (available at http://ferris.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=10040946) (last viewed March 11, 2005). - xvii geographic market, for example as indicated by the frequency of TLR calls. The applicant should describe expected changes in transmission capacity during the authorization period, though the Commission must take care to separate promised upgrades from ones that are certain to be constructed. The Commission should also look at evidence regarding whether available transmission capacity will change over the long term (e.g., as a result of load-growth, generation location decisions, transmission expansion). The Demand Elasticity Factor examines the extent to which buyers can reduce or shift consumption in response to a price increase, because it affects whether a seller may profitably exercise market power. Where demand response programs have developed, sellers can choose to submit evidence that demand elasticity limits their ability to exercise market power. For sellers choosing not to submit evidence on this factor, demand elasticity will be assumed to be very low. Sellers choosing to address this factor should include information on both short-term and long-term elasticity. The Optional Regional and Local Factors allow introduction of other relevant and probative evidence that affects a seller’ s ability and incentive to exercise market power. For example, an applicant in a market where hydropower is prevalent would want to address the effect of high- and low-water years, as well as license conditions and regional agreements governing hydro dispatch. Other possibly relevant evidence includes past anticompetitive behavior in which the seller has engaged.23 23 See Horizontal Merger Guidelines, § 2.1; City of Cleveland, 68 F.3d 1361, 1368 (D.C. Cir. 1995). - xviii D. The Generation Market Power Test Is Applied to a Properly Defined Geographic Market Any market power metric must be applied to a properly defined, rather than assumed, geographic market. The Generation Market Power Test sets forth a practical, fact-based mechanism to define the geographic market. It requires the applicant to apply the Horizontal Market Power Screen to its control area or transmission service area and to examine whether the control area or transmission service area, based upon marketspecific evidence, should be defined as the relevant geographic market. In some cases, the geographic market will be larger,24 or smaller,25 than a control area or transmission service area. Dr. Kirsch’ s discussion of relevant considerations for geographic market definition supports not assuming a control area as the market. Screens should recognize that the ability to manipulate market prices critically depends upon transmission limitations, because transmission constraints (and, to a lesser extent, losses) limit generators’ability to compete with one another. Consequently, although control areas may be a reasonable starting point for drawing the geographic boundaries of electricity markets, they in fact define the physical boundaries only for regulation and frequency control service. The physical boundaries for energy and reserve services markets, by contrast, are determined primarily by prevalent transmission constraints. Institutional boundaries such as those established by control areas, RTOs and ISOs, and state lines can also inhibit trade in these services, however, and thus need to be considered in determining market boundaries. Kirsch SMA Affidavit at 8. 24 25 DeSoto County Generating Co., 105 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,245 (2003). Wisvest-Connecticut, LLC and NRG Connecticut Power Assets, LLC, 96 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,101, at 61,399400 (2001). - xix Proper geographic market definition matters not only from the perspective of performing the Test correctly, but also to ensure that market participants subject to competitive injury due to the seller’ s market power have access to the mitigation remedy. For example, a control area focus inappropriately may exclude consideration of, and potentially relief for, small systems whose loads are dynamically scheduled out of the control area but who nevertheless are economically in the market and are affected by physical transmission limitations into the service area. In some other instances, analyses of sub-regional markets will be necessary to detect market power problems in areas that comprise more than an applicant’ s control or service area but less than an entire region. Not only will some applicants fail the applicable metric for their own areas, they will also fail it in the wider region. For example, when Progress Energy Corporation sought authorization for its generating and power marketing affiliates to sell at market-based rates in Peninsular Florida, the companies not only would have failed the SMA for the control area of Florida Power Corp., Progress Energy’ s retail subsidiary in Florida (in which control area Progress did not seek MBR authority), but also failed the SMA for entirety of Peninsular Florida.26 However, if the Commission had adhered to a predetermined, control area application of SMA, the harm in Peninsular Florida would be ignored, and rates outside the Florida Power Corp. control area would have been 26 See October 16, 2003 “ Motion to Intervene, Motion to Consolidate, and Protest of Seminole Electric Cooperative, Inc. and Florida Municipal Power Agency”filed in Docket Nos. ER03-1389-000 and ER031838-000 (available at http://ferris.ferc.gov/idmws/File_list.asp?document_id=4144938) (last viewed March 11, 2005). - xx adversely affected.27 This example underscores the need to define the geographic market by reference to market-specific facts. E. The Geographic Market Power Test Uses Transmission Capacity Available to Competitors: Simultaneous ATC Because TTC in no way reflects transmission capacity actually available to competing suppliers, a realistic figure such as ATC must be used. The inquiry must also examine other data, such as TTC, TRM, CBM, the incidence and extent of TLRs and other transmission curtailments, and the applicant’ s own reservations, for their effects on capacity.28 Another problem with TTC is that it can double count capacity available to import competing supply to the market. Holders of long-term firm transmission rights usually use such rights to import firm capacity into a market, which means that the capacity supported by the transmission reservation should be reflected in the importing firm’ s market share. However, TTC calculations do not deduct that reserved capacity but assume that it available for more competing supply to be brought into the market. As a result, the TTC calculation causes an overstatement of the amount of competing supply. Mr. Tilton also testified to the need not to rely solely on ATC:29 The Commission needs to be open to further adjustments as the facts require. Unfortunately, long-term ATC is not regularly available, and the Commission should work to find a way to make such information available. 27 The Commission set Progress Energy’ s request for hearing, including on the issue of the appropriate geographic market. DeSoto, 105 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,245 (2003). Progress Energy subsequently withdrew its MBR request. 28 See also Tilton SMA Statement at 9. 29 Id.at 9. - xxi The Commission can best deal with the issue of transmission capacity measures if it has before it information necessary to make an informed calculation. ATC is clearly better than TTC, should be readily available from OASIS sites and is the measure used by the Commission’ s Merger Regulations.30 However, as Mr. Tilton observed, ATC provides limited insight on longer term availability. Thus, the Commission should also require that owners/operators of transmission include data on TTC, TRM, CBM, the frequency and extent of TLRs, as well as long-term reservations, so that the Commission and intervenors can have an accurate picture of transmission actually available to support competition in the market. With the evidentiary record produced by the Generation Market Power Test, the Commission can then exercise its judgment about whether the applicant has market power. If the Commission concludes that the seller has market power, the record provides a basis to consider mitigation measures specifically targeted to the market power concerns revealed through the analysis. Possible mitigation measures are described in the APPA/TAPS March 14, 2005 Comments. 30 18 C.F.R. § 33.3(c)(4)(i)(C).