An Empirical Analysis of Store Locations in Planned Regional Shopping Centres* DRAFT: Please do not quote or cite Zhen He Department of Economics University of Alberta May 2009 Abstract In Canada and the U.S., shopping centre leases may contain restrictive clauses that give a department store veto power over the admission of new tenants and power to influence the store locations in the shopping centre. Regarding the internal structure of shopping centres, the interests of shopping centre developers and department stores might not coincide. In the presence of conflict of interests, the internal composition of shopping centres would depend upon the relative bargaining positions of the developer and the department store. In this paper, I investigate the store configurations in an area close to department stores in planned regional shopping centres. Using maps showing the specific locations of stores in the shopping centres and data on characteristics of shopping centres, developers, and department stores collected from 148 planned regional shopping centres in the five westernmost Canadian provinces in 2007, I examine the relationship between the characteristics of stores near entrance of a department store and indicators of bargaining power of developers and department stores. This paper contributes to the literature in the empirical investigation of the store locations within shopping centres. * Acknowledgement: I’m grateful to my supervisors Dr. Douglas West and Dr. Andrew Eckert for their constant support and guidance. I also thank Dr. Robin Lindsey, Dr. Stuart Landon, and Dr. David Ryan for their valuable comments and suggestions and thank Dr. Benjamin Atkinson for his instruction for using Arcview. Any remaining errors and omissions are the author's responsibility. Correspondence: Zhen He, Department of Economics, University of Alberta, 8-14 HM Tory, Edmonton, AB, Canada T6G 2H4; Tel: 780-4281898; E-mail: zhenh@ualberta.ca. 1. Introduction As one of the most important retailing phenomena, shopping centres have been widely investigated since they appeared in the early 20th century. The theoretical work of Eaton and Lipsey (1979, 1982) and Stahl (1982a, 1982b) on the agglomeration of firms can be used to explain the formation of shopping centres: the clustering of stores selling similar goods can be explained in terms of the comparison-shopping tendencies of consumers and the locational response of profit-maximizing firms (Eaton and Lipsey, 1979; and Stahl, 1982a, 1982b), whereas the clustering of stores selling different goods can be explained in terms of the multipurpose shopping tendencies of consumers and the locational response of profit-maximizing firms (Eaton and Lipsey, 1982). Most existing studies of shopping centres have focused on the choice of tenant mix by the shopping centre owner (Dawson, 1983; and Brown, 1992) and the way in which shopping centre rents are set (Benjamin et al., 1990, 1992; Gatlaff et al., 1994; Gerbich, 1998; Gould et al., 2005; and Pashigian and Gould, 1998). Other studies have investigated the hierarchy of shopping centres (West et al., 1985, 1988; and Ryan et al., 1990) and shopping centre similarities (West, 1992; and Golosinski and West, 1995). The locational pattern of stores within shopping centres, however, has been largely overlooked. This is an interesting issue because the way in which retailers are located is not random. Within a shopping centre, neighbouring stores generate either positive or negative demand externalities for each other. When deciding on store locations, developers of shopping centres would take into account this issue. The location problem is further complicated by the possibly divergent interests of different parties regarding store locations within the shopping centre. Although there have been some studies in the internal composition of shopping centres (e.g. Brown, 1992; Carter and Haloupek, 2002; and Carter and Vandell, 2005), they are either descriptive or overlook some important factors. This issue needs more investigation, because shopping centre is the primary method of retailing for many industries and the internal composition of a shopping centre plays an important role in its success. This paper will fill this niche and contribute to the knowledge of shopping centres. In this paper, I investigate the locational pattern of stores in the proximity of department stores in planned regional shopping centres. Department stores carry a variety of comparison and multipurpose shopping goods. They are anchors, attract customers to visit the shopping centres where they are located, and enjoy substantial rent subsidies (Pashigian and Gould, 1998 and Gould et al., 2005). Locating non-anchor stores that sell comparison shopping goods near department stores could facilitate comparison shopping opportunities in such an area, attract comparison shoppers, and increase the profits of the non-anchor stores and the rental income of the developer. However, it is also possible that such a configuration could intensify competition and decrease profits of non-anchor stores. Thus, the interests of developers regarding store compositions near department stores are uncertain. With respect to department stores’ interests regarding locations of non-anchor retailers selling comparison shopping goods relative to them, they are expected to be ambiguous as well. Department stores might be harmed by the substitution effect but might also benefit from the market area effect generated by such retailers. Although the interests of developers and department stores regarding the location pattern of stores near department stores are ambiguous, their interests might not coincide, given the fact that the department stores only care about their own profits whereas developers 2 care about the rents they can extract from the entire shopping centre. It is the possible conflict of interest between developers and department stores that makes the store configuration close to a department store an interesting issue. In a planned shopping centre, a developer would be expected to have the power to decide where a store will be located in its centre. However, shopping centre leases may contain restrictive clauses that give department stores veto power over the admission of new tenants (Wunder, 1988) and power to influence the locations of other stores in the shopping centre (Harvard Law Review Association, 1973; and Mason, 1975). In the event of a conflict of interest, the locational pattern of stores in an area close to department stores is expected to depend upon the relative bargaining power between the developer and the department store. Using data collected from 148 planned regional shopping centres in 2007 in the five westernmost provinces in Canada, I examine the relation between variables that reflect locational pattern of stores close to a department store and variables that indicate the bargaining power of a developer. The results of estimation show that the fraction of spots near department stores that are leased to stores selling comparison shopping goods is bigger in regional shopping centres that have a larger gross leasable area and are opened earlier, and is negatively related to the number of department stores contained in a regional shopping centre. A regional shopping centre’s gross leasable area and age and the number of department stores in a regional shopping centre are expected to reflect a developer’s bargaining power. Hence, the findings that these variables have explanatory power in the composition of stores near department stores are consistent with the hypothesis that the locational pattern of stores in an area close to department stores would 3 depend upon the bargaining power of a developer. In addition, the site-specific variable indicating whether the observation is the main entrance of a department store and whether it is on a floor above the ground floor are estimated to have a significant impact on the locational pattern of stores near a department store as well. This paper contributes to the literature in the empirical investigation of shopping centres. While bargaining theory is now well developed 1 , the empirical literature on bargaining is limited. Most studies concerning bargaining focus on union contract negotiations and on labour disputes, i.e., strike activity and strike duration (Kennan and Wilson, 1993; and Morton, Zettelmeyer and Silva-Risso, 2004). This research will analyze the impact of factors related to the bargaining power of developers and department stores on store locations within shopping centres. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly reviews the existing studies in the literature that are related to the internal composition of shopping centres. Section 3 presents a discussion of the relevant economic theory. Section 4 describes data sources and the regression models. Section 5 presents the summary statistics and the results of the econometric estimation. Finally, Section 6 is the conclusion. 2. Existing Studies on Shopping Centre Composition In the shopping centre industry, it has been suggested that developers follow some rules of thumb when deciding on store locations in their shopping centres. As reviewed by 1 For a detailed survey of the theoretical models of bargaining, see Osborne and Rubinstein (1990), and Muthoo (1999). 4 Brown (1992, p. 386) and Carter and Haloupek (2002, p. 291-292), these rules include: keep department stores away from a centre’s main entrances; cluster service shops and put them close to the entrances; keep pet shops and dry cleaners away from food shops and keep food shops away from apparel shops; cluster men’s apparel shops, women’s and children’s shops, and food retailers; separate jewellery stores, record stores, and hardware stores; and locate fast food retailers, jewellery and electronics in high traffic areas. These recommended rules are mainly descriptive and lack relevant theoretical discussion. In addition, some rules are questionable. For example, one of the rules suggests that jewellery stores be separated. Yet, when shopping for jewellery, one might want to compare quality, style and price before purchasing. Thus, clustering jewellery stores would attract comparison shoppers. Brown (1992) studied the movement of shoppers in 250 malls in Belfast and found that customers who visit one store are likely to visit another store of this type when similar types of stores are located close to one another, such as food shops and ladies’ apparel shops. Such an extent of “customer interchange” is “substantially greater than that between similar, spatially separated shops and contrasting outlet types in close proximity” (Brown, 1992, p. 398). Brown’s findings support the conventional wisdom. He also found that service units benefit from customer traffic when located close to dissimilar shop types. Carter and Haloupek (2002) extended the spatial economic model of Ingene and Ghosh (1990) and investigated the dispersion of stores by store type in malls. Using data collected from nine malls across the US from 1991 to 1992, they found groupings of 5 stores of the same type for the following store types: men’s apparel shops, women’s apparel shops, and shoe stores. Stores of the other types exhibit dispersion. Other empirical studies that focus on the internal composition of malls include Carter and Vandell (2005) and Eckert and West (2008). Carter and Vandell (2005) assume that the centre of a mall has the highest customer traffic and different types of retailers bid for location and space. Assuming profit-maximizing behaviour on the part of mall developers and stores, they constructed a model in which the total profit of a mall is determined by variables including price per unit of goods sold, quantity of goods sold, size of a store, customer traffic and the proportion of customer traffic that purchases, miscellaneous costs (e.g., labour cost, maintenance cost, utility cost, etc.), and rent. Based on their model, Carter and Vandell developed the following hypotheses: (1) non-anchor store rents and sales volume decrease when the store is farther away from the mall centre, (2) the rents of different types of stores decrease at different rates with increasing distance from the centre, and (3) non-anchor store size increases with distance from the centre of the mall. In addition, Carter and Vandell predict that store types with high sales response to customer traffic (e.g. the food court) and high price per item (e.g. jewellery stores) will be smaller and locate close to the mall centre, because they are able to bid for the higher rent per square foot for the location, whereas store types with low sales response to customer traffic and lower-priced goods relative to their costs (e.g. family apparel and housewares) will locate away from the centre and near the anchors. Using data from a sample of 689 leases in eight regional and super-regional shopping centres of the US, Carter and Vandell tested the above hypotheses and provided supportive empirical evidence. 6 Carter and Vandell’s discussion is helpful in interpreting the locational pattern of stores in malls. Unfortunately, they ignore the demand externalities generated by the comparison-shopping tendencies of consumers and their impact on locational choice. Family apparel and housewares stores cater to comparison shoppers and provide merchandise that overlap with that of department stores. Locating these stores close to a department store is consistent with the incentive of developers to facilitate comparisonshopping opportunities. In addition, based on Carter and Vandell’s proposition, jewellery stores will locate in the centre of a mall. This proposition is questionable since jewellery stores are often found in an area close to department stores. Eckert and West (2008) analyzed the implications of the relative developer/retailer bargaining for the “radius restrictions”, a restrictive clause that is imposed by developers on tenants, prohibiting tenants in a particular centre from opening another store within a certain radius. Using data collected from regional malls in western Canada, they investigated the tenant mix of neighbouring shopping centres and estimated the probability that a retail chain appears in both centres as a function of chain characteristics, mall characteristics, and location characteristics. They provided empirical evidence that is consistent with the hypothesis that whether a chain enters neighbouring malls depends on the relative bargaining power of developers and retail chains. Although Eckert and West investigate another facet of the internal composition of regional malls, their discussion of demand externalities and bargaining powers sheds light on the issues analyzed in this paper. Theoretical studies that focus on the internal composition of malls include those by Brueckner (1993), Miceli et al. (1998), and Vitorino (2008). Brueckner investigated a 7 developer’s space-allocation problem in the presence of externalities among stores and proposed that developers allocate space to a store until its marginal revenue from an additional square foot equals the marginal cost of space minus the marginal increase in sales enjoyed by all other stores due to the spillover effect. Brueckner’s analysis, later supported by Miceli et al. (1998), explains why department stores with higher externalitygenerating ability will have a larger space than that of other stores in a shopping centre. Both studies emphasize the role played by demand externalities in determining the size of the space that a store type should be allocated in shopping centres. However, their models say nothing about where a store should be located in the presence of demand externalities. Vitorino (2008) constructed a model of entry that allows for either positive or negative externalities among firms and explained the joint entry decisions of department stores in a regional mall. She broke department stores into three categories: upscale department stores, mid-scale department stores, and discount department stores, and used an optimization approach, which includes maximizing the likelihood function subject to the constraint that the equilibrium conditions given by the economic model are satisfied, to estimate the impact of strategic effect (through positive or negative demand externalities) among different types of department stores, mall-specific demographic variables, and the store-specific characteristics on the profit and entry decision of a department store. Using data collected from all US regional malls, Vitorino (2008) found that, at the median level of the demographic variables, none of the department stores has incentives to enter a regional shopping centre on its own. This finding is consistent with the prediction of the model that it is beneficial for two different firms to enter together in the 8 same regional shopping centre in the presence of large and positive demand externalities. In addition, the results show that (1) mid-scale department stores are strategic complements, whereas upscale department stores are strategic substitutes, (2) upscale department stores benefit considerably from the presence of mid-scale department stores, but not vice versa, and (3) discount department stores have no positive effect on any other type of department store. Vitorino also found that several mall-specific demographic variables and storespecific characteristics are important in anchor stores’ profit and entry decisions. For example, the results show that the purchasing power (measured by the variable population × income) of the area surrounding a shopping centre has a positive effect for upscale stores and a negative effect for discount and mid-scale department stores. In addition, based on the results, a department store’s profits increase when it has a bigger square footage and is located in a shopping centre that is opened more recently. Upscale and midscale department stores prefer to anchor larger centres. 3. Theoretical Discussion 3.1. Planned Regional Shopping Centres and Department Stores Each city can sustain a hierarchy of shopping centres 2 , where the hierarchy has two important characteristics: (1) a small number of large centres and a large number of small centres; (2) centres at various levels differ in the choice of anchor tenants, the composition of store types, GLA (gross leasable area), and store counts. In addition, 2 A shopping centre hierarchy was originally derived on the basis of Christaller’s (1966) theory of central places. Eaton and Lipsey (1982) explain the formation of the shopping centre hierarchy based on the interaction of consumers’ multipurpose shopping behavior and firms’ profit maximizing locational response. 9 centres at each level contain all of the shop types that can be found in lower level centres, plus additional ones (West et al., 1985). Based on West et al. (1985), regional shopping centres have the following characteristics: (1) they have at least one department store, (2) contain a large variety of store types that include stores selling convenience goods or providing personal services (e.g. food, drugs, laundries, tailor’s shop), plus stores selling comparison shopping goods that could be purchased on a multi-purpose shopping trip (e.g. shoes, clothing, jewelry), and (3) have multiple stores selling similar comparison shopping goods (e.g. multiple ladies’ apparel shops and shoe shops). In this paper, I study how the pattern of store locations near department stores in a shopping centre is related to the relative bargaining power of a developer and a department store. For this purpose, the focus is on planned regional shopping centres. The reason for focusing on planned regional shopping centre is because department stores are largely found in such centres but rarely in centres at lower levels of the shopping centre hierarchy. Department stores are of vital importance to regional shopping centres, and they determine the size, character and success of a shopping centre (Vitorino, 2008). Such influence is expected to come from (1) the department store’s attractiveness to customers, and (2) its ability to help developers get outside financing for the centre (Harvard Law Review Association, 1973). Department stores provide a large variety of products and services, which attract customers to visit the shopping centres where they are located and increase the sales of the rest of the stores in the centre, as well as increasing their rent (Pashigian and Gould, 1998 and Gould et al., 2005). Gatzlaff et al. (1994) found that the rental rates of non-anchor tenants declined by an estimated 25% in response to the loss of an anchor. 10 Another source of department stores’ influence inside regional malls comes from their ability to help developers get outside financing (Harvard Law Review Association, 1973). To develop a shopping centre, outside financing is usually critical to a developer. Mortgage lenders typically require that 60 to 70 percent of total floor area be under longterm lease to firms with low credit risk before financing is approved (Kinnard and Messner, 1972). Leases with department stores allow developers to easily fulfill the term, floor area, and credit risk conditions imposed by lenders. At this point, other retailers cannot help developers as much as department stores. Because of the above two reasons, department stores are crucial to regional shopping centres. Developers attract department stores to mall locations by charging them lower rents (Pashigian and Gould, 1998; and Gould et al., 2005). Specifically, department stores “receive a per foot rent subsidy of no less than 72 percent that which other stores pay” (Pashigian and Gould, 1998, p. 115). Furthermore, department stores usually negotiate some privileges in shopping centres where they locate. Shopping centre leases may contain restrictive clauses, including “the right of approval or veto clause, which intends to give an anchor or major tenant veto power over the admission of new tenants” (Wunder, 1988, p. 30) and power to influence the locations of other stores in the shopping centre (Harvard Law Review Association, 1973; and Mason, 1975). 3.2. Conflict of Interests When a department store and a developer negotiate a new agreement, they enter a bargaining situation. They share a common interest, i.e. both of them wish the customer traffic for the shopping centre to increase, and hence have an incentive to co-operate. 11 However, their interests are possibly divergent: department stores only care about their own profits whereas developers care about the rents they can extract from the entire mall. In this section, the possibly divergent interest regarding store configuration near department stores between developers and department stores is discussed. (1) Developers’ Incentive Developers are expected to have a clear interest in increasing non-anchor stores’3 sales volume and profit. Firstly, because department stores enjoy substantial rent subsidies, developers’ income largely depends on non-anchor mall stores’ rental payments 4 . Secondly, developers would want to increase non-anchor stores’ profit due to the nature of their rent. Store rent generally consists of two parts: base rent, which is fixed, and percentage rent, which increases with sales volume after it passes a certain threshold (Benjamin et al., 1990, 1992). The rents of anchors are largely fixed and independent of sales volume, whereas the rents of non-anchor stores are based on sales volume (Gould et al., 2005). Hence, in order to increase rental income, one would expect developers to have an important incentive to increase the sales volume and profit of non-anchor stores. Inside a regional shopping centre, due to the attractiveness of department stores to customers, the area close to department stores would have high customer traffic and stores located near department stores would be important to developers because of their potential rental payments. The findings of Yeates et al. (2001) provide supportive 3 Non-anchor stores include all retailers except the department stores that one may find in a planned shopping centre. 4 Using data collected from 35 malls across the US in 1994, Gould et al. (2005) showed that anchors occupy over 58% of the total leasable mall space and yet pay only 10% of the total rent collected by the developer. 12 evidence. They investigated the impact of Eaton’s closure on the sales volume and profit of the other retail stores in the shopping centre. Using data collected from 18 regional centres in eastern Canada, they found that a store’s profit is related to how far it is located from a department store and that different store types are not affected equally. Their results show that, within 100 feet of Eaton’s entrance, merchandise categories most affected by Eaton’s closure are variety stores, food and ladies wear. In addition, stores offering fashion accessories, gifts/books/stationary, shoes and men’s wear are also greatly affected in their sales. The next question is in regard to the store types that a developer would want to locate close to department stores. Instead of looking at the specific store category (e.g. shoe stores and hair salons), I broke non-anchor stores into two types, C stores and M stores. These terms are defined by Golosinski and West (1995). C stores are defined as stores that cater to comparison shoppers on a multipurpose shopping trip. C stores sell merchandise that is both horizontally and vertically differentiated, and customers conduct comparisons before making a final purchase. Examples of C stores include clothing stores, shoe stores, and jewellery stores. M stores are defined as stores that cater to multipurpose shoppers on a multipurpose shopping trip. M stores sell products that are more frequently purchased, and consumers engage in little search across M stores of a given type. M stores tend to be the same or very similar. The exception is M stores that sell services, which vary in price and quality. Examples of M store types include bookstores, liquor stores, supermarkets, and dry cleaners (Golosinski and West, 1995). When shopping at C stores like apparel shops, customers may wish to visit different stores to compare price, quality and style. If comparison shopping goods are 13 carried in both department stores and non-anchor stores, a comparison shopper may wish to visit stores of both types. Locating C stores in an area close to a department store could therefore facilitate comparison shopping and increase a developer’s rental income. However, it might intensify competition in such an area and decrease profits of both the department store and the retailers. Concerning this matter, developers might want to locate other types of stores, for example, M stores, near department store. (2) Department Stores’ Incentive Regional shopping centres contain a variety of store types. The store types that department stores would want to have in their proximity are expected to be those that increase the sales volume and profit of department stores. Department stores provide products and services that cater to comparison shoppers as well as multipurpose shoppers. Having C stores in their proximity would enhance comparison opportunities in this area, generate positive demand externalities, and attract comparison shoppers. However, it is possible that the department stores’ sales volume and profit could be diluted by competition coming from these stores. In addition, being close to M stores that sell merchandise that is also carried by the department stores (e.g. beauty shops, houseware) could steal customers from the department store as well. Considering this, department stores might have an incentive to be close to non-retail firms (e.g. doctors, lawyers, or real estate firms) as their neighbours to avoid direct competition of any sort. However, it is uncertain whether such stores could generate positive demand externalities for department stores, because customers of such stores are expected to be “target shoppers” and might not visit other stores on the same shopping trip. Based on the above 14 discussion, department stores’ interests regarding location pattern of stores in their proximity is ambiguous. The interests of department stores and shopping centre developers might be divergent, and could therefore depend on bargaining power. If this is so, then variables measuring bargaining power of developers should be significantly related to the locational configuration around a department store. It is an empirical question as to whether such a relation exists, and this will be explained in Section 5 and 6. 3.3. Developers/Department Stores Bargaining As discussed in the previous section, to avoid being close to store types that might intensify competition and decrease the profits of department stores, department stores would want to negotiate restrictive clauses that give them the ability to determine store locations in the shopping centre. Such clauses are vertical restraints in economic terms. Whether a department store can successfully negotiate such clauses with a developer depends on the relative developer/department store bargaining power. A player’s bargaining power is its ability to influence the other players and to negotiate a bargaining outcome that is favourable to it. In the rest of this section, factors that are expected to influence the relative developer/department store bargaining will be discussed in the specific context of shopping centres. First, a department store might not be successful at imposing on large developers operating multiple regional shopping centres a restrictive clause that grants it power to determine the store configuration. A developer’s effort plays an important role in the success of its shopping centre. However, a developer may engage in an insufficient 15 amount of advertising and centre promotion, underinvest in the maintenance of common areas as well as in the maintenance of the centre’s structure and operating systems (Golosinski and West, 1995). Given the potential moral hazard problem, a developer that operates multiple shopping centres may be more attractive to department stores and therefore have a more favourable bargaining position than a developer that has a single centre, as it may have less incentive to shirk on advertising expenditures and centre maintenance in all of the shopping centres it owns. Another potential factor is a shopping centre’s GLA (gross leasable area). Centres with a large GLA can contain more stores, which facilitate comparison and multipurpose shopping and are attractive to customers and are, thus, attractive to department stores and giving the developer a more favourable bargaining position. Nevertheless, a smaller GLA could also give a developer a more favourable position. The reason is because there will be limited opportunities to serve a given geographic area, and a developer may control area within a centre with a smaller GLA. There may be more intense competition for a spot in that centre than a spot in a larger centre or in a centre where tenants have alternative locations nearby. Given the above discussion, the relation between the GLA of a regional shopping centre and the shopping centre developer’s bargaining power is indeterminate5. The age of a shopping centre could also show a developer’s bargaining power. A centre opened earlier might have built a reputation and customer loyalty. However, compared with newer ones, older centres “tend to embody older shopping centre technology and, in the absence of costly maintenance and renovation, will display more 5 Eppli and Shilling (1996) shows that the aggregate retail sales at regional malls are largely determined by centre size. 16 signs of deterioration than newer centres” (Ryan et al., 1990, p. 316), which are not appealing to retailers and customers. Thus, the relation between a developer’s bargaining power and the age of a centre is ambiguous6. A developer’s bargaining power would also depend on the competition it faces from neighbouring centres at the same level of the shopping centre hierarchy. If the developer owns every neighbouring regional shopping centre, one would expect it to exercise power to tenants that seek position in this type of shopping centre in this geographic area. A department store may compromise on locational pattern of stores in its proximity to seek locations in this area since it has no “outside option7”. Therefore, the competition a developer faces from its neighbouring centres could affect its bargaining power. The population that a shopping centre serves is expected to reflect a developer’s bargaining power because it signals the potential customer base and purchasing power, and hence, has implications for a department store’s profits. A department store may compromise on the composition of stores close to them in order to enter a shopping centre that serves a large population. In addition, the number of department stores in a shopping centre may indicate a developer’s bargaining power as well. There are only four department store chains in Canada. As the number of department store located in a regional mall increases, there are 6 Vitorino (2008) shows that, everything else held constant, department stores in regional shopping centres that are constructed more recently have larger profits than those located in older ones. The results of Eppli and Shilling (1996) show that the impact of the age of regional shopping centre on the centre’s aggregate retail is negative but is statistically insignificant. 7 According to Muthoo (2001), a player has an outside option if he/she can make a deal with a party outside the current negotiation. 17 less options available to the developer. In the extreme case, if the developer wants to have all of the four department stores chains in its mall, it has no outside options. One would expect that the developer might compromise during the process of negotiations with the department store chains. Given the above discussion, the relation between the number of department stores in a centre and a developer’s bargaining power is negative. For a department store chain, the yearly aggregate revenue of this chain would imply its customer-drawing ability and be a sign of its bargaining power relative to developers. In addition, the size of a department store chain, measured by the number of stores owned by this chain, would also indicate its bargaining power. This is because a department store chain with more locations would build a stronger brand name than one with less coverage. A department store chain’s reputation attracts customer traffic and is, therefore, attractive to developers. 4. Dataset Description 4.1 Shopping Centres As discussed in Section 3.1, the focus of this paper is on planned regional shopping centres with presence of department stores. Data on this type of shopping centre are collected from the 2008 Canadian Directory of Shopping Centres. Planned shopping centres that are enclosed, located in the five westernmost provinces of Canada (i.e. Alberta, British Columbia, Manitoba, Ontario, and Saskatchewan), and have at least one department store (i.e., Sears, The Bay, Zellers, and Wal-Mart) are initially included in the dataset. In addition, the actual store counts of a shopping centre are required to be greater 18 than 408. This procedure generates 183 shopping centres, with 35 from Alberta, 35 from British Columbia, 6 from Manitoba, 94 from Ontario, and 13 from Saskatchewan. In addition, to be included in the dataset, a shopping centre needs to have a detailed map showing the specific locations of stores in the shopping centre9. Shopping centre maps are obtained directly from the website of the centre or the developer where possible. For shopping centres that have no detailed map available online, I contacted their developers for the map10. For shopping centres located in Edmonton, I visited the centre and mapped store locations. The above steps yield a sample of 148 shopping centres, with 29 from Alberta, 29 from British Columbia, 6 from Manitoba, 74 from Ontario, and 10 from Saskatchewan. The actual store counts of these centres range from 40 to 589. In this paper, a firm is defined as the “developer” of a shopping centre if it is responsible for managing and controlling the centre. Based on this criterion, there are 26 developers in the sample. According to Table 4.1, the number of shopping centres that are operated by a developer in the sample ranges from 1 to 25. Of these, 54 percent operate only one regional shopping centre. Ivanhoe Cambridge Inc. is the largest developer in this sample and owns 25 regional shopping centres. Data on a shopping centre’s GLA and age are available in the 2008 Canadian Directory of Shopping Centres. There are shopping centres for which the age or GLA of the shopping centre is missing in the directory. In such a case, I contacted the developer 8 I set 40 as the threshold of actual store counts for regional shopping centres. Other thresholds will be used later for robustness check. 9 See Graph A.1 in the appendix for a map of a hypothetical regional shopping centre. 10 All of the shopping centre maps are collected from September 2007 to December 2007. The maps provided by developers were the most recent ones at that time. 19 of the centre to get the information. The population of the trade area that a regional shopping centre serves is based on the 2006 Census of Canada. Table 4.1 Developers Developer With Multiple Regional Malls Number of Regional Malls Developer with a Single Regional Mall Ivanhoe Cambridge Inc. 25 Bayfield Realty Advisors The Cadillac Fairview Corporation Limited 19 BOSA Development Corp. Oxford Retail Group 17 Boultbee Realty Limited Morguard Investments Limited 15 Chez Belle Limited 20 Vic Management Inc. 13 Colliers International RioCan Property Services 13 Doral Holdings Limited Redcliff Realty Management Inc. 12 First Gulf Development Corporation Bentall Retail Services L.P. 9 ICI Shopping Centres FCB Property Management Services 4 Londonderry Shopping Centre Inc. T&T Properties 3 Park Royal Shopping Centre Holdings Ltd. Calloway REIT 2 Shape Property Management Corp. Darton Property Advisors & Managers Inc. 2 Sterling Vanreal Ltd. Tanurb Developments Inc. West Edmonton Mall Property Inc. 4.2 Retailers Tenant lists of shopping centres in the sample are obtained directly from the website of centres or developers where possible. For the rest of the shopping centres in the sample, tenant lists are obtained from the maps that I received from the developers, since those maps show all tenants located in a shopping centre. In the 148 sample shopping centres, 20 there are altogether 17520 tenants, which include non-retail stores11 like doctors, lawyers, accountants, real estate firms and insurance companies. Out of the 17520 tenants, 3491 stores have only one location in the sample malls and fall into the category of independent stores. The remaining 14029 stores are members of chains that have two or more stores sharing a common name in the sample. Based on the definition of chains, there are 1356 chains in the data set. The Source by Circuit City is the largest chain in the dataset, which has 138 stores in the sample malls. Stores in the sample malls are assigned of store types used by the 2008 Canadian Directory of Shopping Centres. In some shopping centres, stores with the same name are put in different categories. To address this problem, a retailer’s website is searched to find out what products or services are provided by the retailer, which is then used to determine the store categories. Once the store categorization is made, stores are broken into C stores, M stores, and other stores by considering the types of merchandise sold by each store category, relying on the definitions of C store and M store that are discussed in Section 3.1. Table A.2 in the appendix shows the composition of C stores, M stores, and other stores, which is proposed by Golosinski and West (1995, p.467) and revised using the new categorizations of stores made by the 2008 Canadian Directory of Shopping Centres12. 11 Non-retail stores are included in the dataset, because they are located in an area close to department stores in some shopping centres and that might be a result of the relative developer/department store bargaining. 12 There are minor differences between the categorization of stores used by Golosinski and West (1995, p.467) and that of the 2008 Canadian Directory of Shopping Centre. Because I categorize stores using the categorization made by the 2008 Canadian Directory of Shopping Centre, to be consistent, I revised the composition of C stores, M stores, and Other Stores made by Golosinski and West (1995, p.467). For example, athletic apparel is listed as a category in the 2008 Canadian Directory of Shopping Centre. Therefore, I added it to the list of C stores suggested by Golosinski and West (1995, p.467). Footwear and 21 To check if the list of C stores proposed by Golosinski and West (1995, p.467) is well represented in the sample malls, the average fraction of stores that are a particular type of C stores (i.e. ladies’ apparel, footwear, menswear, etc.) in sample malls is calculated. C stores of a type are expected to be replicated in a shopping centre to facilitate comparison shopping. The average store counts of regional shopping centres in the sample is 117, which means that the average percentage of a type of C store needs to be at least 1.71% to ensure store replications and comparison shopping opportunity (117 1.71% 2, i.e. at least two stores of the same type). Table 4.2 shows the fraction of stores in the sample malls that are a particular type of C store. According to the table, on average, the types of stores that meet the replication threshold (i.e. greater than 1.71%) include: athletic apparel, footwear, gift, jewelry/fashion accessories, ladies’ wear, menswear, and unisex/men’s & Ladies’ wear. These stores will be defined as C stores in this empirical analysis. Although conceptually sound, the other C store types proposed by Golosinski and West (1995, p.467) (e.g. toy/game, camera, computer, children’s wear, electronics, etc.) are not well represented in the sample centres and are, hence, excluded. Table 4.2 The Fraction of Stores that is a Type of C Store in the Sample Malls. Avg. Fraction of Stores in the Sample Malls C Store Types Ladies' Wear Unisex/Men's & Ladies' Wear Jewellery/Fashion Access. 12.36% 7.87% 7.69% leather goods are listed as separate categories rather than a single one. Drapery is not listed as a category in the 2008 Canadian Directory of Shopping Centre and is therefore not listed as a C store. 22 Footwear Athletic Apparel Menswear Gift Children's Wear Furniture & Home Décor Leather Access. & Luggage Department/Mass Merchandiser Electronics Housewares Toy/Games Family Wear Camera Hobby/Craft Sporting Goods Computer Home Appliance Home Improvement Window Coverings 4.80% 2.24% 2.05% 1.89% 1.67% 1.64% 1.62% 1.56% 1.40% 1.32% 1.04% 1.00% 0.58% 0.21% 0.18% 0.14% 0.13% 0.02% 0.01% 4.3 Department Stores In this empirical analysis, department store chains include Sears, The Bay, Wal-Mart, and Zellers. Department store chains mainly differ in site selection, merchandise selection, target audience, and price level (Vitorino, 2008). Table 4.3 reports the characteristics of regional shopping centres where a specific type of department store chain is located. According to the table, in the dataset, compared with regional shopping centres anchored by other department store chains, shopping centres containing a Bay store, on average, have the largest number of tenants, the biggest GLA, the biggest share of C stores, and the smallest share of M stores. Shopping centres containing a Zellers store, in contrast, 23 have a store count and GLA that are below the sample mean. Regional shopping centres where Wal-Mart stores are located have, on average, the biggest share of M stores. According to Table 4.3, regional shopping centres where a particular department store chain is located have differences in the store counts, store composition, and GLA. Table 4.3 Characteristics of Sample Malls where a Department Store Chain Locates Department Store Chain Sears The Bay Wal-mart Zellers Sample Mean Store Counts 138 161 128 115 117 C Stores% 40.9% 41.6% 36.4% 34.8% 37.1% M Stores % 19.4% 18.6% 22.0% 21.7% 20.9% GLA 728,931 796,608 654,284 598,208 603,768 Table 4.4 Department Store Chains in the Sample Malls Department Store Sears The Bay Wal-mart Zellers Sample Size 80 67 22 83 AB 14 13 4 15 BC 15 16 4 15 MB 4 2 1 4 ON 43 33 12 42 SK 4 3 1 7 Table 4.4 reports the size of a department store chain and the provincial breakdown of a department store chain in the sample malls13. Zellers has 83 stores in the sample malls, which is the most among the four. Sears is second largest with 80 stores. 13 Table 4.4 only reports the size of a department store chain in the sample malls. A large number of WalMart and Zellers stores in the chain or some of them are not located in regional shopping centres. Such stores are not included. Therefore, the size of the Wal-Mart and Zellers stores may be underestimated. 24 Wal-Mart has only 22 stores, which is the least among the four department store chains. According to Table 4.4, in the sample, the distribution of the four chains across provinces follows a similar pattern. All of the chains have the most stores in Ontario, have about the same number of stores in Alberta and British Columbia, and have the least number of stores in either Manitoba or Saskatchewan. 5. Econometric Model In this part of the paper, the measure of “being close to a department store” will be discussed. Variables used to reflect the locational patterns of stores in an area close to department stores in a regional shopping centre will be explained. Then, the econometric method used to analyze how the locational patterns of stores in department stores’ proximity vary with the relative developer/department store bargaining power will be presented. 5.1 Variable Definitions (a) Dependent Variable In this paper, a store14 is defined as being close to a department store if it is located within a radius of 100 feet15 from the entrance of the department store, measured by the Euclidean distance16. 14 Kiosks and carts are excluded because they are movable. For example, kiosks and carts selling Christmas merchandise appear across shopping centres in November and December, and then are removed in January. 15 Yeates et. al (2001) investigated the impact of Eaton’s closure on the sales of stores located within 100 feet and within 200 feet of Eaton’s entrance. They found that sales of the stores located 100 to 200 feet from an Eaton’s entrance are remarkably insulated from the negative impact of Eaton’s closure, which implies that the influence of a department store may not go beyond 100 feet from its entrance. In this paper, I choose 100 feet as the benchmark, which may allow me to identify a department store’s main “power zone”. In sensitivity tests, I 25 Two variables are used to reflect the locational pattern of stores near department stores: ratio_Cr and ratio_Mr, which are defined in equation (1) and (2), respectively. _ _ _ _ ⁄ ⁄ _ (1) _ (2) where percnt_C100r is the fraction of stores that are C stores in an area within a radius of 100 feet from the entrance of a department store. Percnt_Ccentre is the fraction of stores in a regional shopping centre that are C stores. Percnt_M100r is the fraction of stores that are M stores in an area within a radius of 100 feet from the entrance of a department store. Percnt_Mcentre is the fraction of stores in a regional shopping centre that are M stores. Ratio_Cr and ratio_Mr show the fraction of C stores and M stores near department stores relative to the fraction of C stores and M stores for the entire shopping centre, respectively. The reason that a ratio is used is because the fraction of stores near a department store that are C stores (or M stores) could be reflecting the overall fraction of such stores for the entire mall. To capture the impact of the relative developer/department store bargaining power on the store composition near department stores, the store composition for the entire mall should be controlled. However, Percnt_Ccentre and percnt_C100r (or Percnt_Mcentre and percnt_M100r) could be jointly determined by the relative also adopt another definition of “being close to a department store” to test if the conclusions are robust to different measures. 16 There are 58 malls in the sample for which the exact measurement of distance or scale is not available in their maps. Fortunately, for these malls, the area of stores in squared footage is available either from the 2008 Canadian Directory of Shopping Centres or from their maps. So, the scale of a map can be derived by comparing the area of a store in the map and its actual area. 26 developer/department store bargaining power. If included as an explanatory variable, Percnt_Ccentre (or Percnt_Mcentre) would cause an endogeneity problem and lead to biased and inconsistent estimation. Based on the above considerations, ratio_Cr and ratio_Mr are used. A shopping centre may contain more than one department store and a department store may contain multiple floors and/or multiple entrances on the same floor. Since the locational pattern of stores close to a department store may vary across entrances and floors, the observation is set as each entrance of a department store17. A concern is that it could introduce some correlation between observations within a centre. However, only 11 out of the 148 sample centres (i.e. less than 7.5%) have more than two observations within a shopping centre. There are not enough observations to estimate the unobserved group effect within a regional shopping centre. To investigate the difference of location patterns across entrances, variables controlling for floor and the location of an entrance are included as explanatory variables. In the econometric specification, ratio_Cr and ratio_Mr are estimated as a linear function of variables indicating the bargaining power of developers and department stores and other determinants that are expected to have an impact on the locational pattern. The specification of the regression function is as follows: Y = β’X +ε, where Y = ratio_Cr or ratio_Mr, β is a vector of parameters, X is a vector of independent variables, and ε is a vector of error terms. OLS (Ordinary Least Squares) is used to estimate the two regression functions, respectively. 17 For a department store, any entrance facing a corridor that is inside a shopping centre is included in the analysis. Any entrance that is facing outside (for example, parking lot) is excluded from the analysis unless there are stores located close to it. 27 (b) Independent Variables The independent variables used in this econometric model include developer variables, department store dummies, and the other control variables. Developer dummy variables for all developers that operate two or more regional shopping centres in this dataset are included as independent variables. Such dummy variables will capture the idiosyncratic bargaining strength of a developer. In addition, the fixed effect of a developer across the shopping centres that it owns could be controlled in this way. GLA 18 is a shopping centre’s gross leasable area, measured in 100,000 square feet. The variable centrage measures the age of a shopping centre, which is calculated by subtracting the year that the centre was opened from 2009. As discussed in Section 3.3, the relation of GLA and centrage to a developer’s bargaining power are ambiguous. Population is the number of people, measured by 100,000, living in a regional shopping centre’s primary trade area. It is predicted to be directly related to a developer’s bargaining power, because a large population signals the potential purchasing power and is attractive to department stores. In this paper, a regional shopping centre’s primary trade area is defined as the intersection of the shopping centre’s Voronoi market area and a 25 mile radius circle around the centre. To estimate the Voronoi market area, the first step is to plot all 183 regional shopping centres (i.e. including regional shopping centres that have no detailed map and are excluded from the sample) in the maps of the five westernmost provinces, using the regional shopping centres’ geographic coordinates (i.e. longitude and latitude) that are obtained from the Google map. Then, for each regional 18 It is expected that both a centre’s GLA and its store counts could indicate the centre’s bargaining power. The correlation between a centre’s GLA and store counts is 0.91. Therefore, only one of them, GLA, is included as an explanatory variable. 28 shopping centre, a Voronoi market area19 is calculated by finding the set of points that are closer to the regional shopping centre than to any other regional shopping centre located within a province. Economically, this approach to calculate trade areas can be justified by the utilitymaximizing consumer’s tendency to minimize transportation cost and visit the nearest regional shopping centre20, given the assumption that regional shopping centres are the same and charge the same price. Although regional shopping centres are not in fact identical, a large fraction of their stores are chain store and they exhibit similarity in store brands, especially for those located within the same province (Golosinski and West, 1995). Therefore, many consumers are likely to visit the nearest regional shopping centre, as is assumed in the calculation of Voronoi trade area for shopping centres. The provincial boundary is chosen instead of the city boundary for the maximum outer boundary of a Voronoi market area. This is because regional shopping centres are frequently located in the suburb of a city and might attract customers outside the city. Using the city limits to bound the Voronoi trade area could lead to an underestimate of the market area of a regional shopping centre. After a regional shopping centre’s Voronoi market area is calculated, it is then intersected with a 25 mile radius circle around the shopping centre. The intersected area will be considered as the “primary” trade area of the regional shopping centre. The reason 19 This paper follows the methodology of Von Hohenbalken and West (1986) to calculate the Voronoi diagram. See Von Hohenbalken and West (1986) for a detailed discussion of the Voronoi diagram and its economic meaning. 20 Based on the discussion of Von Hohenbalken and West (1986), the assumption of the Voronoi diagram is that stores are homogenous and hence, equally attractive to consumers. 29 that a 25 mile radius threshold is chosen is because customers are not expected to visit a regional centre on a regular basis if it is located more than 25 miles away21. Once the primary trade areas of regional shopping centres are calculated, they are then overlapped with the census tracts. The population of a regional shopping centre’s trade area consists of the pieces of census tracts that fall into this area22. Graph 1 shows the Voronoi market areas of regional shopping centres and census tracts in Alberta. The black dots in the graph are location points of planned regional shopping centres. In Graph 1, Voronoi market areas have bold boundaries and the 2006 census tracts have light boundaries. The primary trade areas of regional shopping centres in Edmonton area are the shaded area, shown in Graph 2. At the left corner of Graph 2, there are two centres and each has a primary trade area with a half-circle shape. In the middle of the graph, there are a group of centres whose primary trade areas are either fan shaped or polygons. The variable competition measures the proportion of a regional shopping centre’s neighbouring centres that are at the same level of the shopping centre hierarchy and are managed by different developers. Two regional shopping centres are defined as neighbours when their primary market areas share a boundary segment and the distance between these two centres is less than 25 miles. This variable is expected to show the extent of competition that a regional shopping centre faces from its neighbours. Everything else constant, developers operating more neighbouring centres would have 21 A regional shopping centre’s primary trade area is not well defined in the literature. Vitorino (2008) defined it to be a circle that has a radius of 20 miles. The ICSC defines it to be a circle that has a radius of 5 to 15 miles for regional shopping centres and 5 to 25 mile for super-regional centres (i.e. regional shopping centres with 3 or more anchors). The Urban Land Institutes (1985) defines that the primary trade area as a circle that has a radius of 8 miles for regional centres and 12 miles for super-regional centres. All of these criterions are based on the U.S. regional shopping centres. 22 All calculations were done using the GIS (geographic information system software) Arcview 9.3. 30 Graph1. Voronoi Market Area of Regional Shopping Centres and Census Tracts in Alberta & & &&& & & && & && & & & & & & && & & & & & & & & & Graph2. Primary Trade Areas of Regional Shopping Centres in Edmonton Area & & && & & && & & & & & & & more control over this region and would have more bargaining strength. The value of competition ranges from 0 to 1. When competition is 1, it means that all of the neighbouring centres are owned by other developers. When competition is 0, it means that the developer owns all of the neighbouring centres. It is defined that competition has a value of 0 if a regional centre has no neighbouring centres. This variable is expected to be negatively related to the bargaining power of a developer. As discussed in Section 3, indicators of department stores’ bargaining power would include a department store chain’s annual revenue and size. However, including these variables as explanatory variables would be inappropriate, since the sample only contains four department store chains and these variables lack sufficient variation. To solve this problem, department store chain dummies (Sears, Walmart, and Zellers) are used. I expect them to pick up the systematic differences across department stores regarding their bargaining positions and the locational pattern in their proximities. The Bay stores are used as the base group. The location related variables include downtown, mainEntry, and upperflr. The variable downtown is a dummy, which equals 1 if the shopping centre is located in downtown area and 0 otherwise. In the dataset, all shopping centres located in downtown have multiple floors, which could be explained by the common fact that land in such an area is more expensive than that in the suburbs. Such a floor plan could have an impact on store configurations. MainEntry is a dummy which equals 1 if the observation is the main entrance to the department store, and 0 otherwise. The main entrance of a department store is defined as the entrance that faces a main corridor connecting anchors or leading to the main exit 31 of a mall, whereas a side entrance of a department store is defined as the one that faces an aisle leading to a side exit of a mall. One would expect the area close to a department store’s main entrance to have more customer traffic than that of a side entrance. As a result, the locational pattern of stores is expected to be different across entrances. The dummy variable upperflr indicates whether an entrance of the department store is located on a level higher than ground level. It is included to capture the difference in locations pattern of stores across floors. 5.2 Tests: RESET and the Breusch-Pagan Test Once the two regression functions are estimated, in addition to the regular t test and F test, RESET (Ramsey’s regression specification error test) will be conducted to test for functional form misspecification. In addition, the Breusch-Pagan test will be performed to test if heteroskedasticity exists. 6. Summary Statistics and Regression Results 6.1 Summary Statistics The first column of Table 6.1 lists the store types that are most frequently located within a 100 foot radius from the entrance of a department store in the sample malls, sorted in descending order, and the second column reports whether these store types are C Store, M store, Other Store, or Non-Retailer. Column (a) of Table 6.1 reports the share of each store type and Column (b) of the table reports the fraction of stores for each store type in the entire mall. According to this table, the four store types that are most often located in an area near department stores in the sample malls are stores selling ladies’ 32 wear, jewellery/fashion accessories, unisex clothing, and footwear. All of them are C stores. In addition, the fraction of these store types located near department stores is greater than the fraction of these stores for the entire mall. Among M store types, hairstyling/esthetic stores are most frequently located near department stores, while ratio_Mr is the highest for variety/convenience stores. The other store types and nonretail firms, with the exception of restaurant & fast food stores and wireless/telecommunication stores, are seldom located in a department store’s proximity in the sample. Table 6.1 The Composition of Stores: Near Department Stores Vs. Whole Mall23 Store Type (a) Within 100 Feet (b) the Whole Mall (c)=(a)/(b) Ratio Ladies' Wear C Store 15.42% 12.36% 1.25 Jewellery/Fashion Access. C Store 8.79% 7.69% 1.14 Unisex/Men's & Ladies' Wear C Store 8.79% 7.87% 1.12 Footwear C Store 5.56% 4.80% 1.16 Hairstyling/Esthetic M Store 5.47% 3.54% 1.55 Restaurant & Fast Food Other Store 5.18% 12.95% 0.40 Wireless/Telecommunication Other Store 3.28% 3.66% 0.89 Optical M store 2.86% 2.05% 1.39 Menswear C Store 2.82% 2.05% 1.37 Athletic Apparel C Store 2.65% 2.24% 1.19 / 2.24% 1.64% 1.36 Variety/Convenience M Store 2.07% 1.30% 1.60 Drug/Health & Beauty Aids M Store 2.07% 1.60% 1.30 Gift C Store 1.99% 1.89% 1.05 Non-Retail 1.99% 5.42% 0.37 Furniture & Home Décor Non Retail 23 Furniture & Home Décor, Leather Access. & Luggage, and Housewares are not C store in this paper, because they are not well represented in the sample malls. 33 Beauty Supply Leather Access. & Luggage Card/Stationery Financial Housewares M Store 1.91% 2.52% 0.76 / 1.70% 1.62% 1.05 M Store 1.70% 1.18% 1.45 Other Store 1.70% 1.69% 1.01 / 1.66% 1.32% 1.26 Table 6.2 reports the summary statistics for variables used in this empirical analysis. There are 383 observations in the sample. Ratio_Cr ranges from 0 to 6.095. There is an observation of Ratio_Cr which has a value of 6.095 and lies outside the range of the rest of the observation. This outlier (i.e. ratio_Cr = 6.095) will be dropped from the empirical analysis to test if it will significantly change the result. Ratio_Mr ranges from 0 to 4.454 and has an average value of 1.023. Regarding developers, the GLA of a shopping centre ranges from 1.52 to 38, measured by 100,000 square feet. On average, the age of a regional shopping centre is 35 years. The average population in a regional shopping centre’s primary trade area is 1.078, measured by 100,000 persons. There are two malls in the sample which have less than 10,000 people in their primary trade areas and are therefore substantially lower than that of the other regional malls in the dataset. One mall has neighbouring shopping centres located in its close proximity and the other is located in a town with small and relatively dispersed population. In the regression analysis, the models will be estimated using the subset of the dataset that excludes the two malls to test if these outliers will significantly change the result. Regional shopping centres in the sample face substantial competition from neighbouring regional centres. As shown in Table 6.2, on average, the fraction of neighbouring regional centres that are owned by other developers is about 80 percent. 34 Considering department store chains, 31.3 percent of observations are for Sears, which is slightly higher than Zellers. Only 7.6 percent of observations are for Wal-Mart stores. On average, shopping centres in the dataset contain two department stores. As to the other location related variables, only 6.5 percent of observations are in downtown areas, less than 10 percent of observations are on side entrances, and about 30 percent of observations are for a floor above the ground floor. Table 6.2. Summary Statistics (N=383) Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min Max ratio_Cr 1.102 0.722 0 6.095 ratio_Mr 1.023 0.910 0 4.454 GLA 7.587 5.202 1.52 38 centrage 35.337 9.256 13 59 population 1.078 0.666 0.034 2.965 competition 0.799 0.344 0 1 deptnumbr 2.089 0.798 1 4 Sears 0.313 0.464 0 1 WalMart 0.076 0.265 0 1 Zellers 0.292 0.455 0 1 downtown 0.065 0.247 0 1 mainEntry 0.919 0.273 0 1 upperflr 0.300 0.459 0 1 To detect if severe multicollinearity exists, the simple correlation coefficients between each two of the explanatory variables are examined. The value of the correlation coefficient between GLA and deptnumbr is 0.52, which has the highest absolute value 35 among the explanatory variables. The correlation coefficient that has the second highest absolute value is for population and deptnumbr, which is 0.36. The absolute value of the correlation coefficients of the other explanatory variables is below 0.3. Empirically, researchers become concerned about multicollinearity if the absolute value of a simple correlation coefficient exceeds 0.8. Since the value of the correlation coefficient between explanatory variables is well below 0.8, severe multicollinearity is not diagnosed. 6.2 Regression Results Table 6.3 reports the results of the two regression functions when ratio_Cr and ratio_Mr are used as the dependent variable, respectively. When ratio_Cr is the dependent variable, R2 is 0.12. The estimated coefficient on GLA is 0.015, which means that, everything else held constant, ratio_Cr is expected to increase by 0.015 units when the gross leasable area of the regional mall is increased by one unit (i.e. 100,000 square feet). Although the impact of GLA on ratio_Cr is estimated to be small, it is statistically significant at the 10 percent level. Since a regional shopping centre’s GLA is expected to be related to the centre developer’s bargaining power, this finding is consistent with the hypothesis that the locational pattern of stores in an area close to department stores would depend upon the bargaining power of a developer. The positive sign of the coefficient of GLA is consistent with the scenario that developers of large regional shopping centres possess greater bargaining power and are able to locate more C stores near department stores. The coefficient on centrage is significant at the 5 percent level, which supports the hypothesis that variables reflecting a developer’s bargaining power have explanatory power in the locational pattern of stores near department stores. The positive sign of the 36 coefficient of centrage implies that older centres may be attractive to department stores due to their reputation and customer loyalty. As a result, developers of older regional centres have a more favorable bargaining position and could locate more C stores near department stores. Table 6.3. Regression Results. Y = ratio_Cr Y = ratio_Mr 0.015* (0.009) 0.008** (0.004) 0.021 (0.060) -0.101 (0.110) -0.009 (0.086) -0.160 (0.141) -0.142 (0.093) -0.158*** (0.060) 0.335*** (0.129) -0.109 (0.170) 0.135* (0.080) 0.883*** (0.256) -0.006 (0.011) -0.011* (0.006) 0.038 (0.081) 0.064 (0.134) 0.044 (0.126) 0.111 (0.182) 0.172 (0.131) 0.064 (0.082) -0.446* (0.239) -0.092 (0.225) -0.246** (0.116) 1.455*** (0.350) 0.12 0.07 Variables GLA centrage population competition Sears WalMart Zellers deptNumbr mainEntry downtown uppflr Constant R2 *** Indicates significance at the 1 percent level. ** Indicates significance at the 5 percent level. * Indicates significance at the 10 percent level. 37 The coefficient on competition and population are not statistically significant, indicating that the impact of competition and population on ratio_Cr is not identified in this empirical analysis. The estimated coefficient on deptnumbr is -0.158, which means that ratio_Cr is expected to decrease by 0.158 unit when a regional shopping centre contains one more department store, all else held constant. Such an impact is statistically significant at 1 percent level of significance. This finding is consistent with the hypothesis that developers have more limited outside options as the number of department stores increases in a shopping centre and have, hence, less bargaining power and would not be able to locate more C stores near department stores. The coefficients on the department store dummies Sears, Walmart, and Zellers are negative. However, none of them is significant at any conventional significance level. Regarding the location related variables, the coefficient on mainEntry and upperflr are positive and statistically significant at 1% level and 10% level, respectively, which means that ratio_Cr is bigger for department stores’ main entrances than for their side entrances, and is bigger for floors higher than the ground level, holding everything else fixed. The coefficient on downtown is not statistically significant. Coefficients on developer dummy variables are suppressed. RESET (Ramsey’s regression specification error test) is conducted to test for functional form misspecification. To implement RESET and test whether important nonlinearities are missed, the squared and cubed terms of the fitted value are included in the OLS regression functions as extra explanatory variables. The null hypothesis is that the coefficients of the squared and cubed terms of the fitted value are equal to zero. The test result shows that F (2, 356) = 0.42 and the associated P-value is 0.66, indicating that 38 the coefficients of the squared and cubed terms of the fitted value are jointly insignificant. The result of RESET suggests that evidence of functional form misspecification is not detected. In addition, the Breusch-Pagan test for heteroskedasticity is conducted. The squared OLS residuals are regressed on all of the explanatory variables. The F statistic for all independent variables is F (23,359) =1.39 with P-value = 0.1118, suggesting that the test result fails to reject the null hypothesis and that heteroskedasticity does not exist at the 10 percent level of significance. When ratio_Mr is the dependent variable, the Breusch-Pagan test for heteroskedasticity yields F (23,359) =1.67 with P-value = 0.029, which provides evidence that heteroskedasticity exists at the 5 percent level of significance. The presence of heteroskedasticity does not cause OLS to be biased or inconsistent. In addition, the R2 is not affected as well. However, the t statistic and F statistic are no longer valid (Wooldridge, 2006, P.272). In the last two decades, a fashion to deal with heteroskedasticity is to adjust standard error and test statistic so that they are still valid in the presence of heteroskedasticity (Wooldridge, 2006, P.272). In this paper, for the regression where ratio_Mr is the dependent variable, the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are used to construct a heteroskedasticity-robust t statistic and F statistic. According to Wooldridge (2006), the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors have the following form: ∑ 39 ̂ (3) where ̂ the ith residual from regressing xj on all other explanatory variables, and SSRj is the sum of squared residuals from this regression. When ratio_Mr is the dependent variable, the R2 is 0.07. The heteroskedasticityrobust F statistic that tests the joint significance of all slope variables yields F (23,359) =1.39 with P-value = 0.1117, which means that the joint impact of the slope variables is not significantly different from zero at the 10% significance level, although the coefficient on centrage, mainEntry, upperflr, and constant are individually significant. The finding that the coefficient on centrage is significant at the 10 percent level coincides with the hypothesis that the locational pattern of stores is related to the indicators of a developer’s bargaining power. However, such a relation is not identified between ratio_Mr and the other indicators of a developer’s bargaining power. The results of estimation suggest that the interests between developers and department stores regarding the locations of M stores near department stores might not be substantially divergent. Or, instead of bargaining over store locations, developers might choose the locational configuration within the regional shopping centre that maximizes overall centre profit, and then compensate department stores through rents for having less than ideal stores located near them. To test for robustness of results, an alternative measurement of being close to department stores is used. A store is defined as being close to a department store when the entrance of the store is located within 100 feet of the entrance of a department store, measured by walking distance. When a person walks from a department store to another store in a shopping centre, he/she will presumably choose the shortest possible route. Here, the “possible route” means that a customer has to follow the pathway in a mall (e.g. 40 he cannot walk through walls etc.). The length of the shortest route is the walking distance. Using Euclidean distance, 2412 stores are defined as being close to department stores in the sample mall. When walking distance is used, there are only 2007 stores24. As the definition changes, the estimated coefficients do not exhibit big differences, which indicate that the econometric model is robust. When ratio_Cr is the dependent variable, the variables that are significant in both regressions include GLA, deptnumbr, and mainEntry. When different measurements of distance are used, there are minor changes in the level of significance for GLA. With the walking distance, the coefficient on GLA is more significant. The main changes are for centreage, upperfl, and WalMart. In the estimation, the coefficient on centreage and upperflr becomes insignificant. In addition, the coefficient on WalMart becomes significant, although only at the 10 percent level of significance. The coefficient on WalMart is -0.283, suggesting that ratio_Cr is about 0.283 units smaller for Wal-Mart stores than for the Bay stores. Regarding the estimation when ratio_Mr is the dependent variable, using walking distance, the estimated coefficients on mainEntry is significant at the 5 percent level rather than 10 percent. In addition, the coefficient on upperflr becomes insignificant at any reasonable levels of significance. In this paper, regional shopping centres with at least 40 retailers are focused on. To explore the robustness of the empirical findings, the models were estimated for a subset of the sample malls that have at least 60 retailers. In addition, alternatives of dependent variables are used. For example, instead of the ratio, the difference between the fraction of stores near department stores that are C stores (or M stores) and the 24 See Graph A.1 in the appendix, which discuss the group of stores that are identified as being close to department stores under the above two definitions. 41 fraction of C stores (or M stores) for the entire shopping centre are studied. The location patterns of stores near department stores are also compared with the rest of the shopping centre (i.e. areas that are not close to any department store in the regional shopping centre) instead of the entire shopping centre. The results of the above estimations show that changes in the results are minor, which means that the findings of this paper are robust. 7. Concluding Remarks Inside a regional shopping centre, the area near department stores is expected to have high customer traffic due to its attractiveness to customers. Regarding what types of stores should be located in such an area, the interests of developers and department stores may not coincide. Given the fact that department stores only care about their own profit while the developer cares about the rental payment it can extract from the entire centre, there might be a conflict of interests between their preferred store types for this area. In the presence of conflict of interest, the locational patterns of stores near department stores are expected to depend on the relative bargaining power of the two parties. In this paper, econometric models are constructed to examine the above problem. Variables indicating the composition of stores in an area close to department stores are used as the dependent variable. Indicators of bargaining power for developers are included as explanatory variables. Because there are only four department store chains in the sample, indicators of bargaining power for department stores are not used as independent variables in the analysis as they lack sufficient variation. Instead, department store dummies are included. In addition, location related variables are included as well. 42 The results of estimation show that ratio_Cr is bigger in regional shopping centres that have a larger gross leasable area and are opened earlier. The results also show that ratio_Cr is negatively related to the number of department stores contained in a regional shopping centre. A regional shopping centre’s gross leasable area, age, and the number of department stores in a regional shopping centre are expected to reflect a developer’s bargaining power. Hence, the findings that these variables have explanatory power in the composition of stores near department stores are consistent with the hypothesis that the locational pattern of stores in an area close to department stores would depend upon the bargaining power of a developer. In addition, the site-specific variable indicating whether the observation is the main entrance of a department store and whether it is on a floor above the ground floor are estimated to have a significant impact on the locational pattern of stores near a department store as well. The positive sign of the coefficient on GLA is consistent with the scenario that developers of large centres possess greater bargaining power because such centres can provide more comparison and multipurpose shopping opportunities and are attractive to customers and are, hence, attractive to department stores. The positive sign of the coefficient on centrage is consistent with the scenario that older centre may have built a reputation and customer loyalty and have a more favorable bargaining position. As a developer has more bargaining power, they would be able to locate more C stores near department stores. The estimated coefficient on deptnumbr is negative, consistent with the hypothesis that developers have more limited outside options as the number of department stores increases in a shopping centre and therefore have less bargaining power and would not be able to locate more C stores near department stores. 43 Ratio_Mr is estimated to be smaller in older centres. However, the relation between Ratio_Mr and the other indicators of a developer’s bargaining power is not identified. The results of estimation suggest that the interests between developers and department stores regarding the locations of M stores near department stores might not be substantially divergent. Or, instead of bargaining over store locations, developers might choose the locational configuration within the regional shopping centre that maximizes overall centre profit, and then compensate department stores through rents for having less than ideal stores located near them. To explore the robustness of the empirical findings, the models were estimated for a subset of the sample malls that have at least 60 retailers. In addition, alternative variables measuring the locational patterns of stores near department stores and alternative definitions of being close to a department store are used. The results of the above estimations show that changes in the results are minor, which means that the findings of this paper are robust. This paper investigates how the locational patterns of stores within 100 feet of a department store’s entrance are determined by the relative bargaining power between developers and department stores in a planned regional shopping centre. The locational patterns of stores in the rest of the shopping centre are not investigated. Such an issue will be explored in future research. 44 REFERENCES: Benjamin, J.D.; Boyle, G.W. and Sirmans, C.F. "Retail Leasing: The Determinants of Shopping Center Rents." American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association Journal, 1990, 18, pp. 302-12. ____. "Price Discrimination in Shopping Center Leases." Journal of Urban Economics, 1992, 32, pp. 299-317. Brown, S. "Tenant Mix, Tenant Placement and Shopper Behavior in a Planned Shopping Centre." The Service Industries Journal, 1992, 12, pp. 384-403. Brueckner, J. "Inter-Store Externalities and Space Allocation in Shopping Centers." Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 1993, 7, pp. 5-16. Carter, C.C. and Haloupek, W.J. "Dispersion of Stores of the Same Type in Shopping Malls: Theory and Preliminary Evidence." Journal of Property Research, 2002, 19, pp. 291-311. Carter, C.C. and Vandell, K.D. "Store Location in Shopping Centers: Theory and Estimates." Journal of Real Estate Research, 2005, 27, pp. 237-65. Christaller, W. Die Zentralen Orte in Suddeutschland. Translated by Baskin, C.W. (1966) to Central Places in Southern Germany. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1933. Dawson, J.A. Shopping Centre Development. London: Longman, 1983. Eaton, B.C. and Lipsey, R.G. "Comparison Shopping and the Clustering of Homogeneous Firms." Journal of Regional Science, 1979, 19, pp. 421-35. ____. "An Economic Theory of Central Places." Economic Journal, 1982, 92, pp. 56-72. Eckert, A. and West, D.S. "Radius Restrictions and the Similarity of Neighboring Shopping Centres," International Journal of the Economics of Business. 2008, 15, pp. 281-300. Eppli, M.J. and Shilling, J.D. “How Critical is a Good Location to a Regional Shopping Centre?” The Journal of Real Estate Research, 1996, 12, pp.459-468. Gatzlaff, D.H. ; Sirmans, G.S. and Diskin, B.A. "The Effect of Anchor Tenant Loss on Shopping Center Rents." Journal of Real Estate Research, 1994, 9, pp. 99-110. Gerbich, G. "Shopping Center Rentals: An Empirical Analysis of the Retail Tenant Mix." Journal of Real Estate Research, 1998, 15, pp. 283-96. 45 Golosinski, D. and West, D.S. "Double Moral Hazard and Shopping Centre Similarity in Canada." Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 1995, 11, pp. 456-78. Gould, E.D.; Pashigian, B.P. and Prendergast, C. "Contracts, Externalities, and Incentives in Shopping Malls." Review of Economics and Statistics, 2005, 87, pp. 411-22. Harvard Law Review Association, “The Antitrust Implications of Restrictive Covenants in Shopping Center Leases”, Harvard Law Review, 1973, 86, pp. 1201-1249. Ingene, C.A. and Ghosh, A. "Consumer and Producer Behavior in a Multipurpose Shopping Environment." Geographical Analysis, 1990, 22, pp. 70-93. Kennan, J., and Wilson, R. “Bargaining with Private Information”, Journal of Economic Literature, 1993, 31, pp. 45-104. Kinnard, W. N. Jr and Messner, S.D. "Obtaining Competitive Locations for Small Retailers in Shopping Centers." Journal of Small Business Management, 1972, 10, pp. 21-26. Mason, J.B. “Power and Channel Conflicts in Shopping Center Development”, Journal of Marketing, 1975, 39, pp. 28-35. Miceli, T.J.; Sirmans, C.F. and Stake, D. "Optimal Competition and Allocation of Space in Shopping Centers." Journal of Real Estate Research, 1998, 6, pp. 113-26. Morton, F.S.; Zettelmeyer, F. and Silva-Risso, J. “A Test of Bargaining Theory in the Auto Retailing Industry”, 2004. http://www.econ.yale.edu/seminars/apmicro/am04/scottmorton040928.pdf#search=%22empirical%20test%20of%20bargaining%20theory%22 Muthoo, A. “Bargaining Theory with Applications”. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999. Muthoo, A. “A Non-Technical Introduction to Bargaining Theory” World Economics, 2001, 1, pp. 145-166. Osborne, M.J. and Rubinstein, A. “Bargaining and Markets”. San Diego: Academic Press, 1990. Pashigian, B.P. and Gould, E.D. "Internalizing Externalities: The Pricing of Space in Shopping Malls." Journal of Law and Economics, 1998, 41, pp. 115-42. Ryan, D.L.; V., Hohenbalken B. and West, D.S. "An Econometric-Spatial Analysis of the Growth and Decline of Shopping Centers." Regional Science and Urban Economics, 1990, 20, pp. 313-26. 46 Stahl, K. "Differentiated Products, Consumer Search, and Locational Oligopoly." Journal of Industrial Economics, 1982a, 31, pp. 97-114. ____. "Location and Spatial Pricing Theory with Nonconvex Transportation Cost Schedules." The Bell Journal of Economics, 1982b, 13, pp. 575-83. Urban Land Institute. Shopping Center Development Handbook. Washington DC: Urban Land Institute, 1985. Vitorino, M.A. “Empirical Entry Games with Complementarities: An Application to the Shopping Centre Industry”, the Wharton School of Business, University of Pennsylvania, Working Paper, 2008. Von Hohenbalken B. and West, D.S. “Empirical Tests for Predatory Reputation”, Canadian Journal of Economics, 1986, 19, pp. 160-78. West, D.S. "An Empirical Analysis of Retail Chain and Shopping Centre Similarity." Journal of Industrial Economics, 1992, 40, pp. 201-21. West, D.S.; Von Hohenbalken, B. and Kroner, K. "Tests of Intraurban Central Place Theories." Economic Journal, 1985, 95, pp. 101-17. West, D.S.; Ryan, D.L. and V., Hohenbalken B. "New Competition in Shopping Centre Hierarchies: An Empirical Comparison of Alternative Specifications." Journal of Regional Science, 1988, 28, pp. 329-44. Wooldridge, J.M. “Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach”, Third Edition, Mason, OH: Thomson South-Western, 2006. Wunder, G.C., “Restrictive Clauses in Shopping Centre Leases: A Review”, Real Estate Issues, 1988, 13, pp. 29-34. Yeates, M.; Charles, A. and Jones, K., “Anchors and Externalities.” Canadian Journal of Regional Science, 2001, 24, pp. 465-484. 47 APPENDIX Table A.1. Shopping Centres that have Floors Dropped from the Analysis. Province AB AB AB AB AB AB MB ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON ON Name Chinook Centre Edmonton City Centre East Kingsway Garden Mall Northgate Centre Northland Village Westbrook Mall Polo Park Shopping Centre Billings Bridge Plaza Bridlewood Mall Burlington Mall Cedarbrae Mall Dixie Outlet Mall Dufferin Mall Hillcrest Mall Hopedale Mall Kozlov Centre Lansdowne Place Shopping Centre Northumberland Mall Oshawa Centre Place d'Orleans Sherway Gardens St.Laurent Centre Stone Road Mall The Promenade The Toronto Eaton Centre York Gate Mall Yorkdale Shopping Centre 48 Floor Dropped Basement floor Concourse floor and the 3rd floor. 3rd floor Upper floor Upper floor Professional building Basement floor Upper floor Lower floor 2nd floor Upper floor Upper floor Office floor and basement floor. Upper and lower floor 2nd floor Office building. Lower floor Upper and lower floor 2nd Floor, executive tower, office galleria. Upper floor Upper floor Lower floor Upper and lower floor Basement floor 1st and 4th floor Upper floor 2nd and 3rd floor Table A.2 Classification of C, M, Other Stores and Non Retail Stores by Golosinski and West (1995) C Stores Athletic Apparel M stores Other Stores Non-Retail Stores Beauty Supply Automotive Educational/Training Camera Book/Newsstand Business Services Insurance Children's Wear Card/Stationery Car & Truck Rental Medical/Dental Computers Drug/Health & Beauty Aids Financial Non Retail Department/Mass Merchandiser Dry Cleaner Fitness/Recreation Place Other Non-Retail Electronics Fabric/Sewing Access. Hardware/Paint & Paper Postal Services Family Wear Florist/Nursery Laundromat Real Estate Footwear Grocery Other Services Furniture & Home Décor Hairstyling/Esthetic Pet Gift Music/Video Printing Hobby/Craft Office Supply Rental Equipment/Furniture Home Appliance Optical Restaurant & Fast Food Home Improvement Photo Second Hand Merchandise Housewares Shoe Repair Specialty Food & Drink Jewellery/Fashion Access. Tailoring/Alterations Specialty Merchandise Ladies' Wear Travel Theatre/Entertainment Leather Access. & Luggage Variety/Convenience Ticket/Lotto Sales Menswear Wireless/Telecommunication Sporting Goods Toy/Games Unisex Clothing Window Coverings 49 Graph A.1. Floor Plan for a Hypothetical Regional Shopping Centre 10 12 11 C 4 Sears 8 5 9 B A 1 2 3 6 7 Zellers = 100 feet In this hypothetical regional shopping centre, there are two department stores: Sears and Zellers. Sears has a single entrance (i.e. point A) and Zellers has two entrances (i.e. point B and C). As defined in Section 5.1 (b), A and B are the main entrances, which face a main corridor connecting two anchors, whereas C is the side entrance, which faces an aisle leading to a side exit of a mall. There are three observations for the above mall. In this paper, a store is defined as being close to a department store if it is located within a 100 feet radius from the entrance of the department store, measured by the Euclidean distance. Based on this definition, the stores near Sears include store 1,2,3,4, and 5. Stores near the main entrance of Zellers include store 6, 7, 8, and 9. Stores near the side entrance of Zellers include store 10, 11, and 12. The alternative measurement defines that a store is close to a department store when the entrance of this store is located within 100 feet to the entrance of a department store, measured by walking distance (i.e. the shortest possible route a consumer would 50 choose). Based on this definition, the stores near Sears include store 1, 2, 4, and 5. Stores near the main entrance of Zellers include store 7, 8, and 9. Stores near the side entrance of Zellers include store 11 and 12. 51