Flat of the Curve Medicine – A New Perspective Johannes Schoder and Peter Zweifel* ---Preliminary version--- May 28, 2008 Abstract: Until now, economists have solely focused on the determinants of the expected value of health status as a function of medical inputs on one side and nonmedical inputs on the other. However, this study suggests that both medical and nonmedical inputs may have an additional benefit, viz. enabling individuals to better stabilize their health status. The hypothesis is tested empirically using OECD health data for 24 countries between 1970 and 2004. First evidence suggests that a one percent increase of medical and nonmedical factors contribute to a reduction of the variability of life expectancy, reflected in the Gini coefficient of the distribution of length of life. Surprisingly, the effect of nonmedical factors has been somehow higher than the effect of medical factors on the Gini coefficient, around 0.08 percent (death numbers are 0.08 percent more concentrated compared to 0.06 percent). *University of Zurich, Socioeconomic Institute, Hottingerstr. 10, CH-8032 ...Zurich. Phone: +41 44 6340614, email: johannes.schoder@soi.uzh.ch (J. Schoder), pzweifel@soi.uzh.ch (P. Zweifel). 1. Introduction and motivation Industrialized countries have spent a rising share of total economic resources on healthcare. Healthcare expenditure (HCE) in percent of GDP increased from 3.8 percent in 1960 to 8.9 percent in 2004 for the OECD countries. Over the same period, health has improved. The average life expectancy of the OECD countries increased from 68.4 in 1960 to 78.5 years in 2004. However, the increase of life expectancy slowed down during the past years. E.g. in the U.S,. the annual growth rate of life expectancy slowed down to less than 0.19 percent between 1980 and 2004 compared to an annual growth rate of 0.3 percent between 1960 and 1980. Since HCE increased at an annual growth rate of 7.7 percent between 1980 and 1998 this is often interpreted that modern medicine has to fight against decreasing marginal returns (‘flat of the curve medicine’). However, the literature provides further explanations for this observation (see ZWEIFEL and BREYER, 1997). Maybe individuals reduced health enhancing efforts or changed their preferences over time in favor for unhealthy products therefore countervailing the positive effect of medical care on life expectancy. Another explanation may be that especially for an aging population the effects of medicine on prolonging life might be limited although productivity in relative terms (compared to nonmedical inputs) might be high. Finally, the choice of output indicator is of crucial importance. Since neither life expectancy nor mortality rates provide direct information on health status the real effects of medical inputs are not captured entirely and therefore their effect may be over- or underestimated. The following study is devoted to the latter explanation. Constructing a variable that reflects the uncertainty surrounding individuals health status we investigate whether medical factors generate an additional benefit, viz. reducing the fluctuation of one’s health capital stock. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In section 2, a review of the relevant literature is provided. Section 3 is devoted to econometric specification, a description of the data base, and variable selection. The new empirical evidence is presented in Section 4. Section 5 contains a discussion and summery of our findings. 2 2. Survey of the literature 2.1 Effect of healthcare on different measures of health status At the aggregate level the choice of output variable in a production function of health is limited by the availability of statistical data. Traditionally, studies have focused on the influence of medical care and other ‘inputs’ on mortality rates or life expectancy as a proxy for the healthcare status. The seminal article continues to be AUSTER, LEVESON and SARACHEK (1969), who related age- and sex-adjusted mortality rates of U.S. states of 1960 to medical inputs (viz. number of physicians, pharmaceutical outlay, capital stock of hospitals and medical auxiliary staff), economic factors (income, years of schooling and degree of urbanization), factors related to consumption (alcohol consumption, smoking) and organizational factors (share of group practices and medical schools). Schooling and income was negatively related to mortality, but both variables were not significantly different from zero. Only medical auxiliary staff was reducing mortality rates. The variable number of physicians even increased the mortality rate. However, the effect of this variable maybe due to reverse causality because physicians tend to work in areas where people are exposed to an increased risk of death. Controlling for reverse causality the authors performed a two-stage least squares estimation. Medical inputs now got the expected sign but all effects were not significant from zero. THORNTON (2002) refined the approach of AUSTER, LEVESON and SARACHEK (1969) using U.S. data from 1990. He chose HCE as the only medical input variable and included additional health-related factors such as married households, race and crime rates. Instead of choosing years of schooling he included the share of individuals with higher education. In addition, he treated HCE and income as endogenous variables. HCE, income, education, married households, and urbanization had a negative but not significant impact on mortality. Only education and married household were significantly different from zero. Cigarette and alcohol consumption, the crime rate and the degree of manufacturing had an positive effect on mortality whereas only the first two factors were significant. In all, he confirmed the flat of the curve medicine hypotheses On the other side, studies based on OECD health data provide some evidence on the effect of medical inputs on the production of health. In a cross-section study MILLER and FRECH (2000) investigated the production of health in 21 industrialized countries for the 3 year 1996 using OECD health data. They related life expectancy at birth, at age 40 and age 60 to pharmaceutical and non-pharmaceutical healthcare outlays, cigarette and alcohol consumption, animal fat consumption, and the share of women. They found evidence on the effectiveness of medical inputs on life expectancy. A doubling of pharmaceutical expenditure results in a 1.7 percent increase of life expectancy at the age of 40 and 4 percent at the age of 60. SHAW, HORRACE and VOGEL (2005) confirmed the results of MILLER and FRECH (2000) using a panel of 29 countries between 1960 and 1999 based on OECD health data from 2000. However, the uncertainty surrounding the expected level of life expectancy or point of death has not been analyzed to our knowledge. The following studies provide preliminary evidence that in industrialized countries both medical and nonmedical inputs may have an additional benefit, viz. enabling individuals to better control their health status. Negelcting this dimension may under- or overestimate the effect of medical inputs on the production of health. 2.2 Evidence on increased control over health status HELIGMAN and POLLARD (1980) analyzed Australia’s age-specific mortality and its development over time. They split this mortality into components due to infant mortality, excess mortality among young adults, and a ‘pure’ age-related factor. They identified a variance parameter in the infant mortality and traced the development of this parameter over time. This method was also applied by the FEDERAL STATISTICAL OFFICE (1996) to Swiss data. The result is that the variance parameter decreased more strongly from 1881 to 1993 than did general age-related mortality. One can therefore infer that uncertainty reduction over time may have developed differently from expected health status. Disparities at the aggregate level can be interpreted as a reflection of underlying individual variance in health status. Analyzing Swiss data, BOPP and GUTZWILLER (1999) find considerable differences in standardized mortality rates between cantons and regions. While these disparities have not changed much over time, relative rankings of cantons did. Another aggregate indicator of health status variability is excess mortality of certain professional groups. E.g., after controlling for age and sex, Swiss construction workers are estimated to have a rate of mortality due to respiratory disease that exceeds the average by 56 percent, followed by farmers with 31 percent (GASS and BOPP, 1997). 4 GERDTHAM and JOHANNESSON (2000) relate individual disparities of life expectancy and quality-adjusted life years (QALYs) to income disparities and age groups in Sweden. The difference in QALYs between the highest and the lowest income decile turns out to be marked, up to 3.6 years for the age group of 20 to 29. This confirms that income differences are associated with differences in healthy life years (expected value reduction hypothesis). However, the evidence does not show that e.g. higher income results in a decrease of health status uncertainty, reflected by a decrease in variance of QALYs between individuals (variance reduction hypothesis). Also with higher age, disparities in QALYs among individuals of the same age group are still low but increase markedly compared to younger individuals. According to this study, variability in life years therefore tends to rise with age and decreases with income. To what extent these results are affected by the availability of high-quality medical care remains to be seen. SHKOLNIKOV, ANDREEV and BEGUN (2003) use life table information from several industrialized countries to estimate the difference in longevity characterizing individuals of a given country or region. In analogy to applications to income distribution, they favor the so-called Gini coefficient, which represents the concentration of the distribution of life years. The lower the Gini coefficient, the more equal this distribution, which implies that death must be heavily concentrated (among the aged) within a given population. In the following we extent the work of SHKOLNIKOV, ANDREEV and BEGUN (2003) in analyzing the factors driving the decrease of the Gini coefficient. First we calculate the Gini coefficient for 24 OECD countries. Then we relate the development of the Gini coefficient over time to medical and nonmedical inputs. Section 3 and 4 are devoted to the specification and estimation of this model. 5 3. Measuring inequality of the distribution of length of life Usually the Gini coefficient is used for the analysis of inequality in income distribution. Following Hanada (1983) we show how the standard concept can be applied to the distribution of length of life. The Gini coefficent is defined as an area between the diagonal and the Lorenz curve, divided by the whole area below the diagonal is based on the Lorenz curve. The Lorenz curve in turn, represents the cumulative income share as a function of the cumulative population share. Let f(x) be a population-density function of income x. Then the cumulative share of the population with income less or equal to x is, x F ( x) = ∫ f ( y )dy , where y = income (1) 0 and the share of the total income received by this part of the population is, Φ( x) = 1 µ x ∞ 0 0 ∫ yf ( y)dy , where µ = ∫ yf ( y)dy (2) The Lorenz curve as a function varies from 0 to 1 and is defined on the interval of variation of F(x) values [0,1]. In a situation of perfect equality for any income x Φ(x) = F(x), the Lorenz curve is simply a diagonal, connecting points (0,0) and (1,1). The higher the variability in income across a population, the greater the divergence between the diagonal and the Lorenz curve. Following the definition of the Gini coefficient above we receive, 1 G0 = 1 − 2∫ Φ ( p )dp , where p = F(x) (3) 0 Applying this framework to mortality-by-age schedules, one can imagine a person’s years lived from birth to death to be ‘income’ and cumulative death numbers to be ‘population’. The density and the distribution functions can be redefined as, f ( x) = d ( x) / l (0) , where d(x) = number f death, l(0) = number of survivors of year 0 (4) F ( x) = 1 − l ( x) / l (0) , where l(x) = number of survivors year x (5) And therefore we receive, 6 x Φ( x) = 1 td (t )dt , where e(0) = life expectancy at birth e(0)l (0) ∫0 (6) Using (4) to (6) together with (3) we finally receive the Gini coefficient for the distribution of length of life, G0 = 1 − ∞ 1 ⋅ [l ( x)]2 dx e(0)[l (0)] 2 ∫0 (7) The Gini coefficient varies between the limits of 0 (perfect equality) and 1 (perfect inequality). For a length of life table distribution it is equal to zero if all individuals die at the same age, and equal to 1 if all people die at age 0 and one individual dies at an infinitely old age. The mortality by age schedules are obtained from the Human Mortality Database. Using equation (4) we calculated Gini coefficients for 24 countries between 1960 and 2004. Table 1 shows the development of the Gini coefficients over time. Obviously, they tend to decrease over time. The highest effect can be found for Portugal. The Gini coefficient decreased from 0.21 in 1960 to 0.1 in 2003, confirming our presumption that death became heavily concentrated among the aged. In countries like Sweden or Norway the decrease has been less distinct. However, if one considers life table information earliest available decrease has been substantial. The Gini coefficient declined from 0.36 in Sweden and 0.39 in Norway down to around 0.09 in both countries. Table 1: Development of the Gini coefficient over time for 24 countries country Austria Australia Belgium Canada Suisse CZ Germany Denmark Finland France Hungary Iceland Italy Japan LUX 1960 0.1478 0.1315 0.1368 0.1388 0.1144 0.1264 0.1377 0.1211 0.1337 0.1377 0.1524 0.1185 0.1528 0.1509 0.1401 1970 0.1332 0.1294 0.127 0.1311 0.1105 0.1281 0.1292 0.1183 0.1239 0.1292 0.1403 0.1185 0.1325 0.1186 0.1362 1980 0.1199 0.1161 0.116 0.1181 0.1048 0.1193 0.1196 0.1142 0.112 0.1196 0.1351 0.1099 0.1135 0.1015 0.1153 7 1990 0.1068 0.1061 0.1066 0.1067 0.0982 0.1166 0.1116 0.111 0.1098 0.1116 0.1364 0.1045 0.1034 0.0942 0.1096 2003 0.0956 0.0941 0.0973 0.097 0.0878 0.102 0.1008 0.0998 0.0971 0.1008 0.12 0.0828 0.0895 0.0923 0.0961 NL Norway NZ Portugal Slovak Spain Sweden UK US 0.1162 0.1188 0.1243 0.2071 0.1356 0.1542 0.1144 0.1255 0.1438 0.1143 0.1127 0.1242 0.1749 0.1351 0.1302 0.1105 0.1213 0.1409 0.1063 0.106 0.1176 0.134 0.1278 0.1099 0.1048 0.1127 0.1264 0.1002 0.1047 0.1125 0.1181 0.1255 0.1071 0.0982 0.1053 0.1204 0.0925 0.0918 0.0934 0.1013 0.1127 0.0942 0.0878 0.0964 0.1128 4. Econometric Model, Estimation Methods, and Data Base Using macro-panel data one has to decide between different methods of estimating the model. In general panel models are of the following form yit = xit β + ci + u it (8) where β measures the partial effect of xit in period t for country i. The most fundamental idea of modeling panel data is to view the unobserved factors affecting the dependent variable yit as consisting of two types. Those that are constant over time but specific to the individual cross sectional unit (here the country) ci, and those that vary over time uit.. One may simply estimate equation (8) with pooled ordinary least squares (OLS), treating vit=ci+uit as the composite error. However, to receive consistent estimators the exogenous variables xit have to be uncorrelated with the error term uit and the country specific effect ci. Even if there is no correlation pooled OLS exibits serial correlation, since ci is fixed over time (Boes, 2008). Less restrictive asumptions are required for the estimation of β using the FE (fixed effects) and RE (random effects) model. In the FE model one includes a dummy for each country characterizing their heterogeneity. These dummys guard against the bias discussed above. But instead of explicitly using dummy variables for each country, FE is applied on transformed data. The data is transformed by subtracting for each country the averages of all the observations for that country. Applying OLS on the transformed data delivers the desired estimator. For the FE model it is possible that the unobserved country specific effect ci, and and the observed explanatory variables xit are corrleated. However, for the RE model we need the country specific effect ci to be uncorrleated with the xit. The country specific effects are treated as random. Using the RE model one can avoid the loss of observation due to the implicit use of dummy variables in the FE model. Therefore the RE 8 model produces more efficient estimator than the FE model. Furthermore, the technique used for the RE estimation procedure does not wipe out the explanatory variables that are time invariant (ci). Using a log-log functional form (in analogy to MILLER and FRECH, 2000) we receive the following specification which will be estimated with the methods described above, giniit = hce / gdpit β 1 + hospbed it β 2 + gdp it β 3 + pop 65 it β 4 + tabacit β 5 + bmiit β 6 + ci + u it (9) The variables are defined as follows, • GINI: Gini coefficient of the distribution of length of life • HCE/GDP: HCE in percent of GDP • HOSPBED: Number of beds per 1000 inhabitants • GDP: GDP per capita in purchasing power parity • POP65: Percent of population over 65 • SMOKERS: Regular smokers in percent of the population • BMI: Percent of population having a body mass index (bmi) higher than 25kg/m2 Since the present study focuses on industrialized countries, data is obtained from the OECD health data base 2007 (for the exogenous variables) and the Human Mortality data base 2008 (for the endogenous variable). However, the OECD health data is known for some difficulties. One of them is national differences with regard to the delimitation of the healthcare sector, resulting in different baskets of benefits, another, the lack of comparability and precision of healthcare deflators. In view of the second difficulty HCE as percent of GDP is used, whereas the first difficulty cannot be avoided. Spanning the years 1970 to 2004 and including 30 countries it results in a macro-panel with 1,020 observations. Due to limitations of the human mortality data base and missing values in the OECD health data base six countries had to be excluded (viz. Greece, Ireland, Mexico, Poland, South Korea, and Turkey) resulting in a maximum of 417 observations. The descriptive statistics is summarized in table 2. The variable of interest, the Gini coefficient of the distribution of length of life, varies around 0.226 and 0.083 and already indicates a high level of concentration with a mean of 0.115. Healthcare expenditure in percent of GDP represents the medical input variable. It should be expected that the higher the 9 healthcare expenditure the more concentrated the death numbers should be due to improved control over health status. However, we have to consider reverse causality. High spending of healthcare expenditure can also be a result of high variability of death numbers over time. As can be seen in table 2 the average share of healthcare expenditure for the OECD countries is around 7,12 percent over the time period of 1970 to 2004. The standard deviation of 2.04 percent is divided into the within standard deviation and between standard deviation. Here the within deviation is higher than the between standard deviation, suggesting that the variation in healthcare expenditure as a percent of GDP is higher for one country followed over time than the variation between the countries to a given point of time. Table 2: Descriptive Statistics Variable GINI overall between within Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Observations 0.11521 0.016 0.010 0.013 0.083 0.101 0.072 0.226 0.140 0.202 N=1112 N=24 T=46.3 HCE/GDP overall between within 7.116 2.040 1.200 1.650 1.500 5.272 2.244 15.300 9.791 12.625 N = 852 n= 24 T = 35.5 HOSPBED overall between within 6.926 2.526 2.463 1.309 3.200 4.150 2.732 15.600 14.838 10.731 N = 456 n= 21 T = 21.714 GDP overall between within 13740.72 10348.88 2668.054 10012.53 728 8177.739 -5596.757 70600 21910.48 62430.24 N = 999 n= 24 T = 41.625 POP65 overall between within 12.495 2.712 1.887 1.971 5.700 9.893 7.334 20.000 15.787 21.634 N = 1078 n= 24 T = 44.917 SMOKERS overall between within 32.439 9.050 6.120 6.290 15.9 19 14.753 61 43.686 53.440 N = 439 n= 24 T = 18.292 BMI 40.658 10.869 7.891 18.600 21.841 66.300 59.980 N= n= overall between 10 185 24 4.140 within 21.893 52.318 T = 7.708 Another medical input variable is reflected in the number of beds per 1,000 inhabitants. The higher the density of hospitals the faster individuals should be treated and the lower should be the mortality rates. The average of hospital beds per one thousand inhabitants is around 6.9. Nonmedical factors are included in the variable GDP per capita and percent of population over 65. GDP should contribute to a reduction of variability whereas a higher share of aged people should increase variability of life expectancy. The overall average GDP per capita is 13,740 with a high standard deviation of 10,348. The standard deviation is mainly due to the variation of GDP over time. The average population over 65 in our sample is around 12.5 percent. Behavioural risk factors are reflected in the variables SMOKERS and BMI. Unhealthy people are supposed to die earlier and therefore both variables should increase the variability of the point of death. In the following we estimate our model with pooled OLS, FE and RE. The Hausman (1978) test is applied to select the preferred model. 5. Estimation results and discussion Following a general to specific approach (CAMPOS, ERICSSON and HENDRY 2005) we first estimate equation (1) including all variables with pooled OLS, FE and RE. The results are shown in Table 3. Table 3: Determinants of the Gini coefficient for 24 countries between 1970 and 2006a) COEFFICIENT a) HCE/GDP HOSPBED GDP POP65 SMOKERS BMI Constant Observations Pooled OLS 0.176*** (0.0370) 0.0946*** (0.0198) -0.129*** (0.0218) -0.118*** (0.0359) -0.00885 (0.0362) 0.175*** (0.0379) -1.848*** (0.377) 103 FE 0.00767 (0.0267) 0.147*** (0.0247) -0.0693*** (0.0184) -0.0257 (0.0299) -0.0343 (0.0268) -0.0426 (0.0335) -1.549*** (0.246) 103 11 RE 0.0243 (0.0274) 0.106*** (0.0222) -0.107*** (0.0163) -0.0581* (0.0301) -0.0392 (0.0271) 0.0113 (0.0313) -1.211*** (0.233) 103 R-squared 0.653 Number of v1 Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 a) Natural logarithm 0.024 20 0.189 20 Due to missing values the number of observations is reduced to only 103 observations. The overall fit indicated by the overall R2 of the estimated models is high for pooled OLS but low for FE and RE. In the following the results are discussed in detail. In all three models HOSPBED and GDP are significant on the one percent level. However only the variable GDP has the expected negative sign in every model. A one percent increase of GDP e.g. reduces the Gini coefficient about 0.07 per cent in the FE estimation meaning that more people die around one certain point of time. A one percent increase of the number of hospital beds increase the Gini coefficient by around 0.1 percent in all three models. Surprisingly the number of hospital beds increase the Gini coefficient implying that less people die at the same point of time. The effect of the variable HCE/GDP points into the same direction, but the values are only significant for the pooled OLS estimation. Here a one percent increase of the share of healthcare expenditure increases the Gini coefficient about 0.2 percent. Only one of the two behavioural factors has the expected sign and is significant. A one percent increase of the share of obese individuals increases the Gini coefficient around 0.18 percent in the pooled OLS model. This effect is considerable high compared to the effects of the other variables. However, the effect of the variable BMI fades away in the FE and RE estimation. Since the assumptions for the pooled OLS estimation are too restrictive (see above) we considered only FE and RE for further specification. The Hausman test is applied to test whether the individual effects are correlated with the regressors. In this way it provides information about which model, RE or FE, is more suitable for the further estimation. Its basic idea is that under the null hypothesis of zero correlation, the RE estimator is consistent and efficient. Under the alternative, the RE estimator is inconsistent. The FE estimator is consistent under both alternatives, but inefficient under Ho The test statistics are presented in the table below. 12 Table 4: Hausman test ---- Coefficientsa) ---(b) (B) fxd rnd HCE/GDP .0434927 .0536858 HOSPBED .1230723 .0854148 GDP -.0796382 -.1085391 POP65 -.0350072 -.0569391 TABAC -.0321573 -.0238801 BMI -.0559412 .0007109 (b-B) sqrt(diag(V_b-V_B)) Difference S.E. -.0101931 . .0376575 .0072914 .0289009 .0040858 .0219319 . -.0082772 . -.0566521 .0080816 b = consistent under Ho and Ha; obtained from xtreg B=inconsistent under Ha, efficient under Ho; obtained from xtreg Test: Ho: difference in coefficients not systematic chi2(6) = (b-B)'[(V_b-V_B)^(-1)](b-B) = 23.32 Prob>chi2 = 0.0007 (V_b-V_B is not positive definite) a) Natural logarithm Ho can be rejected on the 1 percent significance level suggesting that the individual effects are correlated with the explanatory variables. This implies that the RE model does not give us consistent estimators and therefore we take the FE model for further estimation. To sum up the obtained results above differ depending on which model is used for estimation. Furthermore the explanatory variables have only partially the expected sign. To increase the number of observations and to test the sensitivity of our estimated model we exclude stepwise several explanatory variables. Moreover we only take the FE estimation, since the Hausman test prefers FE over RE estimation. Including different explanatory variables we receive the following results shown below. Table 5: Different specifications of our model estimated with FE COEFFICIENTa) HCE/GDP HOSPBED GDP POP65 SMOKERS (1) 0.00767 (0.0267) 0.147*** (0.0247) -0.0693*** (0.0184) -0.0257 (0.0299) -0.0343 (2) -0.103*** (0.0186) 0.141*** (0.0221) -0.0381*** (0.0108) -0.0428 (0.0283) -0.0312 13 (3) -0.0806*** (0.0132) 0.121*** (0.0122) -0.0348*** (0.00737) -0.119*** (0.0202) (4) -0.0954*** (0.0134) 0.125*** (0.0125) -0.0493*** (0.00720) (5) -0.0559*** (0.0151) -0.0781*** (0.00524) 0.0905*** BMI Constant Observations Number of v1 R-squared Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 a) Natural logarithm (0.0268) -0.0426 (0.0335) -1.549*** (0.246) 103 20 0.878 (0.0216) -1.697*** (0.148) 217 21 0.084 (0.0132) -1.641*** (0.0787) 398 21 0.323 -1.788*** (0.0765) 402 21 0.251 -1.693*** (0.0799) 417 24 0.463 The first specification is equivalent to the FE model estimated in table 4. The second specification excludes the variable with the least number of observations, the BMI. The number of observations more than doubles up to 217 observations. Interestingly, the variable healthcare expenditure has the expected significant negative effect. The value of the variable HOSPBED is similar to the first specification and still has the positive impact on the Gini coefficient. The effect of GDP reduces to 0.03 but is still significant with the expected negative sign. The variables POP65 and SMOKERS are not significant as in the first specification. In the third specification we dropped the variable SMOKERS again leading again to a nearly doubling of the sample size. Now the most important change can be found in the variable POP65. A one percent increase of the share of people above 65 leads to 0.12 percent decrease of the Gini coefficient. There is no significant change when POP65 is exluded in the fourth specification. Finally, the last specification focuses just on the basic determinants of the variability of life expectancy. It includes healthcare expenditure as the medical input variable, the share of regular SMOKERS as the socioeconomic variable, and the GDP as the nonmedical variable. All variables have the expected sign and are significant on the one percent level. This model provides evidence in favour of our hypotheses stated at the beginning, viz. that medical factors as well as nonmedical factors contribute to a decrease of volatility of life expectancy. The impact of the nonmedical factors is even higher than the impact of the medical factors. However, the fit of the model is subject to further econometric inquiery. 14 5. Conclusion To be written 15 6. Literature ANAND (1983). Inequality and poverty in Malaysia: Measurement and Decomposition. New York: Oxford University Press. AUSTER, R., I. LEVESON and D. SARACHECK (1969). “The Production of Health, an Exploratory Study.” The Journal Of Human Resources 4(4): 411-436. BOPP, M. and F. GUTZWILLER (1999). Entwicklung der Mortalität in der Schweiz seit 1950. Swiss Medical Weekly(129): 799–809. FEDERAL STATISTICAL OFFICE (1996). Life tables for Switzerland 1988/1989. GASS, R. and M. BOPP (1997). Berufsspezifische Mortalitätsrisiken der Männer in der Schweiz 1979/83. Bern. Bundesamt für Statistik. GERDTHAM, U.-G. and M. JOHANNESSON (2000). Income-related Inequality in Life-Years and Quality-Adjusted Life-Years. Journal of Health Economics 19: 1007–1026. GREENE (2003). Econometric Analysis, Pearson Education. HANADA, K. (1983). A Formula of Gini’s concentration ratio and its application to life tables. Journal of Japan Statistical Society 13: 95-98. HELIGMAN, L. and J. H. POLLARD (1980). The Age Pattern of Mortality. Journal of the Institute of Actuaries 107: 49-80. HUMAN MORTALITY DATABASE. University of California, Berkeley (USA), and Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research (Germany). Available at www.mortality.org or www.humanmortality.de (data downloaded on the 25th of March 2008) MILLER, R. and FRECH, H. I. (2000). Is There a Link Between Pharmaceutical Consumption and Improved Health in OECD Countries?. Pharmacoeconomics 18: 33–45. OECD (2007). OECD Health Data 2007. SHKOLNIKOV, V., ANDREEV, E. and A. BEGUN (2003). Gini coefficient as a life table function: computation from discrete data, decomposition of differences and empirical examples. Demographic Research 8: 305-357. THORNTON, J. (2002). Estimating a health production function for the US: Some new evidence. Applied Economics 34: 59–62. 16 VERBRUGGE, L. (1984). Longer Life But worsening Health? Trends in Health and Mortality of Middle-aged and Older Persons. Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly 62: 475–519. ZWEIFEL, P. and BREYER, F. (1997). Health Economics. Oxford University Press. 17