Competition and Productivity: Evidence from Canadian Manufacturing Firms by Jianmin Tang and Weimin Wang* Micro Economic Policy Analysis Branch Industry Canada January 2002 Abstract In this paper we estimate the impacts of product market competition, competition for skilled workers, and market transparency on productivity performance of Canadian manufacturing firms. The regression analyses are based on firm-level data from Statistics Canada’s Survey of Innovation 1999, which was linked to the production data from the Annual Survey of Manufacturers. We find that product market competition has a positive and significant impact on productivity performance while competition for skilled workers has a negative and significant impact. However, we find no evidence that market transparency has a significant impact on productivity performance, which may be explained by its two opposing influences on productivity. JEL Codes: L0, O0 * We thank Frances Anderson, Brian Nemes, Guy Sabourin, and Susan Schaan for excellent support and facilitation of our access to the Linked 1999 Survey of Innovation database. We are also grateful to Someshwar Rao for helpful comments and suggestions. Views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect those of Industry Canada. All errors are our own. 1. Introduction Many policy makers and researchers believe that product market competition improves production efficiency because product market competition not only increases the pressure for firms to develop and adopt new technologies, but also induces managerial effort.1 However, the theoretical relationship between product market competition and productivity performance is ambiguous, as indicated in Nickell (1996). Supporters for a positive relationship argue that product market competition reduces managerial slack introduced by monopoly power, and that it generates incentives to improve production efficiency through product, process, or organizational innovation. The argument is often based on two observations. First, competition means more than one firm in the same market. Performance of firms in the same market can be compared with one another. The cross-comparison increases the pressure for firms to perform better than their counterparts, which leads to more efficacy-improving effort. Meyer and Vickers (1997) shown that in a two-period model, comparative performance information enhances efforts to cut cost. Second, an increase in product market competition may raise the demand elasticity and reduce demand for each individual firm. The higher demand elasticity implies that cost-reducing improvements in productivity will generate larger increases in profit. The increased potential profit induces higher managerial effort (see Willig (1987)), creating incentives for efficiencyenhancing activities such as innovation.2 On the other hand, the higher demand elasticity can quickly reduce the demand for the products of under-performers, which increases the probability of bankruptcy. To avoid such fate, firms have to be highly innovative and to improve their efficiency (see Schmidt (1994)). However, there are also some theoretical arguments in the literature against the positive relationship between product market competition and productivity performance. Hermalin (1992) and Horn et al (1994) claim that increased competition reduces managers’ expected income and hence tends to reduce their managerial effort. It has also been argued along the line 1 For instance, Porter (1990), Nickell (1996), Van de Lundert and Smulders (1997), Boone and Van Dijk (1998), and Tang (2001) show that more competition leads to more innovation. Tang and Wang (2001) examine the impact of organizational innovation on productivity performance of Canadian manufacturing firms. They find organizational innovation also generates a significant impact on productivity performance. 2 of Schumpeter (1942) that monopoly power enables firms to spend more on R&D because they face less market uncertainty and have more stable cash flow. Despite the theoretical debate, a few empirical studies suggest that product market competition improve technical efficiency and thus productivity. Based on cross-section data, Caves and Barton (1990), Green and Mayes (1991), and Caves et al. (1992) link technical efficiency to market structure. They find that an increase in market concentration above a certain threshold tends to reduce technical efficiency. Using survey data for 58 countries, Porter (2000) finds that the intensity of local competition is the most influential single variable on GDP per capita growth. Nickell (1996) confirms competition effects on productivity with panel data on 670 U.K. companies. Two relevant findings emerge from this study. First, competition, measured either by increased numbers of competitors or by lower levels of rents, is associated with higher rates of total factor productivity growth. Second, market power, as captured by market share, leads to a lower level of productivity. These findings are consistent with Lever and Nieuwenhuijsen (1999), using a panel data on nearly 2000 Dutch manufacturing firms. Gort and Sung (1999) compare the experience of AT&T long lines, operating in an increasingly competitive market, with that of eight local telephone monopolies. They show that AT&T improves its efficiency at a markedly faster rate than the local monopolies, in either total factor productivity growth or shifts in cost functions. Is Canadian experience consistent with those empirical findings? In this paper, we examine the impacts of product market competition, together with competition for skilled workers and market transparency, on productivity performance, using Statistics Canada’s Survey of innovation 1999. Competition for skilled workers is relevant since skilled workers have long been recognized as a crucial input of production. When it is difficult for firms to hire and retain qualified staff and workers, their economic performance will be adversely affected. After analyzing a survey data on over 700 U.K companies, together with a number of in-depth cases, Bosworth and Wilson (1993) show that there is a strong relationship among the deployment of highly qualified personnel, their role in strategic management of the company, and dynamic economic 2 Jagannathan and Srinivasan (1999) find that product market competition reduces managerial slack, using a panel data on 2970 U.S. firms over the period 1973 to 1990. 3 performance. Findings in Foley et al. (1993) suggest that skill shortages associated with craft workers can act as a barrier to the use of new technologies and lead to a reduction in productivity. Competitive environment has other aspects that are not included in product market competition and competition for skilled workers. In this paper, we also consider market transparency, an index representing the easiness for a firm to predict its clients’ demands and its competitors’ actions, and the flexibility for a firm to replace its suppliers. And to some extent, the inverse of this index reflects business uncertainty and riskiness. In general, market transparency exerts two opposite influences on productivity. Market transparency reduces uncertainty, which moderates firms’ wait-and-see attitude in investment in R&D and technology adoption. It improves firms’ efficiency by reducing unnecessary costs related to uncertainty. On the other hand, market transparency may induce managerial slack and reduce motivation to improve economic performance. Thus, beyond output competition, our analysis also takes into account the impacts of labour input competition and market transparency on productivity performance. A prominent feature of this paper is that we model product market competition, competition for skilled workers, and market transparency as unobservable variables. Each latent variable underlies multiple indicators. For example, we use four indicators to measure product market competition: how easy clients of a firm can substitute the firm’s products for the products of its competitors, whether the arrival of new competitors is a constant threat, whether the arrival of competing products is a constant threat, and how quick a firm’s products become obsolete. This approach is similar to the method used in Gu and Tang (2001) to measure innovation, but different from the competition measures usually employed in the literature.3 Our approach has three main advantages. First, it can provide us with a more comprehensive measure of each competition-related factor than a single indicator. Often, different indicators of a factor measure the factor from different perspectives. Second, it can avoid multi-collinearity problems associated with directly using multiple 3 Multiple indicators are usually added to an econometrical model directly as a measure of competition. For example, see Nickell (1996) and Lever and Nieuwenhuijsen (1999). The associated problem with this method is multi-collinearity because these indicators are usually highly correlated. 4 indicators in an econometrical model since some indicators are highly correlated. Finally, it reduces the number of variables in our analysis and helps us to summarize the data. The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 describes the data, Section 3 contains measurement issues, Section 4 discusses the sample profile and empirically links competition measures to productivity performance, and Section 5 concludes. The method of estimating unobservable latent variable is included in Appendix. 2. Data The data used for this study is Statistics Canada 1999 Survey of Innovation (SI), which has been linked to the production data from the 1997 Annual Survey of Manufacturers (ASM). The SI was conducted in 1999 for the Canadian manufacturing and selected natural resources industries for which the sample unit was the provincial enterprise. A provincial enterprise (firm thereafter) includes all its establishments in the same province and industry at the 4-digit NAICS (North American Industry Classification System) level. To reduce response burden, the SI surveyed firms with at least $250,000 gross business income and more than 19 employees.4 All information in the SI concerns firms’ innovation environment and related activities during the 1997-1999 period.5 After linkage to the 1997 ASM, the linked SI contains additional information on firms’ operational activities such as value added and employment in 1997. We use the linked SI database for this study. The linked SI database contains data on 5,455 in-sample manufacturing firms. Each firm carries a weight. The weight given to each in-sample firm allows that firm to represent other firms in the population having similar characteristics. Thus, if the weight given to firm X is 5, firm X represents five firms in the sample. To represent these five firms, the data obtained from the sampled firm is multiplied by the weight, 5 in this case. The total population has 8921 manufacturing firms, which is equal to the sum of population weights of the in-sample firms. 4 However, after linked to the 1997 ASM, some firms with less than 20 employees in 1997 were also in the linked database. 5 For the purpose of this study, however, we exclude 125 in-sample firms that have no complete information6 or are considered to be outliers.7 Thus, the final sample for this study contains data on 5,320 in-sample manufacturing firms. The first question of the Survey is regarding the competitive environment facing surveyed firms. The question is: “ For your firm, how strongly do you agree or disagree with each of the following statements?” There are 11 statements as follows: (1) My client’s demand are easy to predict; (2) My clients can easily substitute my products (goods or services) for the products of my competitors; (3) My competitors’ actions are easy to predict; (4) The arrival of new competitors is a constant threat; (5) The arrival of competing products (goods or services) is a constant threat; (6) My firm can easily replace its current suppliers; (7) It is difficult to hire qualified staff and workers; (8) It is difficult to retail qualified staff and workers; (9) My products (goods or services) quickly become obsolete; (10) Production technologies change rapidly; (11) Office technologies change rapidly. Firms are asked to indicate their opinions by using a scale from 0 to 5, where 0 for not relevant, 1 for strongly disagree and 5 for strongly agree. We use the first 9 statements to form our competition measures.8 3. Measurement Issues 5 6 7 8 For methodological issues and the overall description of the survey, please see Schaan and Anderson (2001). For instance, several in-sample firms have no employment information. For instance, we exclude firms with negative value added. We exclude the last two statements since they are not firm specific. 6 In this section, we deal with measurement issues associated with product market competition, competition for skilled workers, and market transparency. We first discuss product market competition. 3.1. Product Market Competition Product market competition can be characterized by a large number of firms and free entry & exit.9 A large number of firms in an industry implies that no single firm can have a significant influence on product price and that each firm takes the price as given when making decisions. In addition, with free entry & exit, firms’ economic profits are kept down near to zero. Thus, to measure product market competition for a firm, it is natural to use the number of competitors for the firm or the firm’s profit margin. Unfortunately, these data are hardly available. In this paper, we use the data from the SI. As described in Section 2, the linked SI contains data related to competitive environment facing firms. Let x i denote a firm’s response on statement i in question 1 of the Survey, where i = 1, 2, L , 11 . We choose easy product substitution ( x 2 ), arrival of new competitors ( x 4 ), arrival of competing products ( x5 ), and quick obsolescence of products ( x 9 ) as indicators of product market competition. The four indicators all measure product market competition, but from different perspectives. Table 1 reports the correlation coefficients between indicators of product market competition. As expected, arrival of new competitors ( x 4 ) and arrival of competing products ( x5 ) are highly correlated. Easy product substitution ( x 2 ) is positively correlated with both arrival of new competitors ( x 4 ) and arrival of competing products ( x5 ). When a firm’s products can be easily substituted, the firm will begin to worry about the arrivals of both new competitors and competing products. Quick obsolescence of products ( x 9 ) is positively but weakly correlated 9 Note, however, that the degree of competition may not necessarily relate to the number of rivals against which a firm compete but rather to the ever-present possibility that its rivals may innovate and gain a decisive cost or product-quality advantage (Metcalfe and Boden, 1993). 7 with both arrival of new competitors ( x 4 ) and arrival of competing products ( x5 ), and not correlated with easy product substitution ( x 2 ). With some of those indicators being highly correlated, the direct inclusion of those variables in a competition and productivity regression analysis will cause a serious multi-collinearity problem. To avoid such problem, in this paper we model product market competition as a latent variable (a latent variable model is included in Appendix). The latent variable underlies the four indicators. Let ξ p denote our measure of product market competition. The estimation of ξ p , ξ̂ p , can be written as a weighted sum of the four qualitative indicators: (1) ξˆ p = wˆ 2 x2 + wˆ 4 x 4 + wˆ 5 x5 + wˆ 9 x9 , where ŵi is the weight for indicator x i with i = 2, 4, 5 and 9, and is estimated based on the model in Appendix. The estimate weights are reported in Table 1. Based on these weights, we can compute the estimated measure of product market competition by using Equation (1). As shown in the table, the indicator of arrival of competing products ( x5 ) is weighted heavily, contributing the most to the measure of product market competition. The higher the value of this index, the higher is the perception of the degree of product market competition. 3.2. Competition for Skilled Workers In the Survey, there are three indicators that are associated with competition for workers: arrival of new competitors ( x 4 ), hardness to hire ( x 7 ) and hardness to retain ( x8 ) as indicators. Arrival of new competitors is an indicator of competition for skilled workers since the arrival of new competitors necessarily increases the demand for skilled workers. As a result, it leads to competition for skilled workers for a given supply of skilled workers. Hardness to hire and hardness to retain qualified staff and workers also indicate high degree of competition for skilled workers. When the competition for skilled workers is intensive, firms would feel difficult to hire and retain qualified staff and workers. 8 Table 2 reports correlation coefficients between indicators of competition for skilled workers. As expected, the two indicators of hardness to hire and hardness to retain are highly correlated. They are both positively correlated with the indicator of arrival of new competitors. Like product market competition, competition for skilled workers is also modeled as a latent variable. Let ξw denote our measure of competition for skilled workers. The estimation of ξw , ξ̂w , can be written as a weighted sum of the three indicators, (2) ξˆw = wˆ 4 x 4 + wˆ 7 x7 + wˆ 8 x8 , where ŵi is the weight for indicator x i with i = 4, 7, and 8, and is estimated based on the model developed in Appendix. Table 2 also presents the estimated weights of these three indicators. As shown in the table, the two indicators of hardness to hire and hardness to retain are weighted heavily, significantly contributing to the measure of firms’ competition for workers. The higher the value of this index, the higher is the perception of the degree of competition for skilled workers. 3.3. Market Transparency In the Survey, there are three indicators that are associated with market transparency: how easy a firm can predict its clients’ demands (easy to predict clients’ demands) ( x1 ), how easy a firm can predict its competitors’ actions (easy to predict competitors’ actions) ( x3 ), and how easy a firm can replace its current suppliers (flexible suppliers) ( x 6 ). As shown in Table 3, the three indicators are positively correlated. Like product market competition and competition for skilled workers, market transparency is also model as a latent variable. Let ξe denote the measure of market transparency. The estimation of ξe , ξ̂e , can be written as a weighted sum of the three indicators, 9 (3) ξˆe = wˆ 1 x1 + wˆ 3 x3 + wˆ 6 x6 , where ŵi is the weight for indicator x i with i = 1, 3, and 6. The weights are estimated using the model developed in Appendix, and the estimated weights are reported in Table 3. As shown in the table, the indicator of easy to predict competitors’ actions is weighted heavily, significantly contributing to the measure of firms’ market transparency. The higher the value of the index, the more transparency is a firm’s market. 4. The Empirical Linkage between Competition and Productivity In this section we use the Survey data on Canadian manufacturing firms to empirically study the relationship between competition-related factors and labor productivity. We first set up the regression model. 4.1. Regression Model Our framework utilizes a Cobb-Douglas production function with constant return to scale. The regression model is as follows: (4) 20 LPj = β0 + β1 LF j + β2 ξpj + β3 ξwj + β4 ξej + β5 SM j + β6 SL j + ∑ αn I nj + ε j , n =1 where LPj is labor productivity (in logarithm), defined as value-added output per worker for firm j ; LF j is fuel and power consumption per worker (in logarithm) for firm j ; ξ pj is the measure of product market competition for firm j ; ξwj is the measure of competition for skilled workers for firm j ; ξej is the measure of market transparency for firm j ; 10 SM j is a size dummy for medium-sized firms, 1 for firm j being medium-sized and 0 otherwise; SL j is a size dummy for large firms, 1 for firm j being large-sized and 0 otherwise; I nj is a binary industry dummy, 1 for firm j belonging to industry n and 0 otherwise; ε j is the error term for firm j . The competition variables are constructed in the previous section. Ideally, this regression model should include capital intensity as an independent variable. However, there is no such data in the linked SI. Because of the data limitation, we use fuel and power consumption per worker as a proxy for capital intensity. This is based on our observation that working capital stock is highly correlated with fuel and power consumption. Indeed, it has been used as a proxy for the same purpose in Globerman, Ries and Vertinsky (1994). Firm size and industry dummies are introduced to capture size-related and industry-related residuals that are not captured by other variables. To capture the size effect, we divide firms into three groups according to their size. The reference group in the regression model is a small-sized group in which a firm’s number of employees is not greater than 100. In the medium-sized group, the number of employees of each firm is greater than 100, but not larger than 500. In the large-sized group, the number of employees of each firm is larger than 500. Industries are grouped at the 3-digit NAICS level. The reference industry in the regression model is Miscellaneous Manufacturing (NAICS 339). 4.2. Sample Profile The sample for our analysis contains data on 5320 in-sample manufacturing firms, of which there are 3110 small-sized firms, 1860 medium-sized firms and 350 large-sized firms. Table 4 presents the percentage of firms that highly agree10 with a statement regarding competitive environment by size11 and by industry. Among the nine statements that we use as 10 11 A firm highly agrees with a statement if the firm scores 4 and 5 for the statement. Due to confidentiality, medium and large size groups are combined. 11 indicators of competition in this study, there are three statements that are highly agreed by more than 50% of all firms. The leading statement is “it is difficult to hire qualified staff and workers”. For all manufacturing industries, 61.8% of surveyed firms highly agree with the statement. This is followed by the two statements: “my clients can easily substitute my products for the products of my competitors” and “the arrival of competing products is a constant threat”. The two statements are highly agreed by 59.4% and 52.9% of firms, respectively. The statement with least support is “my products quickly become obsolete”, followed by “my competitors’ actions are easy to predict” and “my firm can easily replace its current suppliers”. Small-sized firms tend to have a different profile than medium- and large-sized firms. In terms of the percentage of firms that highly agree with a statement regarding their competitive environment, small-sized firms are less threatened than medium- and large-sized firms by the arrival of competing products and new competitors. They tend to be easier than medium- and large-sized firms to predict their competitors’ actions and to replace its current suppliers. However, it is more difficult for small-sized firms to hire and retain qualified workers. The profile at industry level is also significantly different. Paper, Beverage & Tobacco, and Petroleum & Coal are leading in “easy to predict clients’ demand”. Beverage & Tobacco and Paper are leading in “my clients can easily substitute my products for the products of my competitors”. Printing and Paper are leading in “my competitors’ actions are easy to predict”. Leather, Apparel, and Food are leading in “the arrival of new competitors is a constant threat”. Leather, Beverage & Tobacco, and Apparel are leading in “the arrival of competing products is a constant threat”. Petroleum & Coal and Printing are leading in “my firm can easily replace its current suppliers”. Machinery, Furniture, and Printing are leading in “it is difficult to hire qualified staff and workers”. Furniture and Computer & Electronics are leading in “it is difficult to retain qualified staff and workers”. Finally, Apparel, Computer & Electronics, and Printing are leading in “my products quickly become obsolete”. 4.3. Empirical Results 12 Table 5 reports the estimation results of Equation (4), based on ordinary least squares. As expected, fuel and power consumption per worker, as a proxy for capital intensity, is positive and significant. This is consistent with the fact that the higher the capital intensity, the higher the labour productivity. The most interesting results for this paper, however, are associated with competition-related variables. Product market competition has a positive and statistically significant impact on labor productivity. This is an important empirical result since it supports the view that higher product market competition leads to higher productivity. Product market competition not only increases the pressure for firms to develop and adopt new technology, but also to induce managerial effort, which in turn improves productivity. This result is also consistent with the findings by Baily and Gersbach (1995), Nickell (1996), Pilat (1996), and Rao and Ahmad (1996) that productivity is strongly correlated with the exposure to competition with best-practice firms. The estimation result also indicates that competition for skilled workers has a negative and statistically significant impact on productivity. Surly, firms with perception of high degree of competition for skilled workers tend to have a difficulty to fill their skilled positions. The skill shortage weakens productivity performance. Martin and Porter (2001) state that productivity is determined by the interplay of three broad influences: a nation’s political, legal and macroeconomic context, the quality of the micro-economic business environment, and the sophistication of company operations and strategy. Firms require skilled and experienced workers to develop systems that are associated with sophisticated products or production processes. And, they rely those workers to operate the sophisticated systems more efficiently. In addition, insufficient skills in a workforce will reduce the effectiveness of firms’ technology adoption, which further reduce those firms’ productivity performance. Market transparency is found to be negative, but insignificant. The insignificance may be explained by the fact that market transparency can exert two opposing influences on productivity. It improves efficiency by encouraging investment in R&D and technology adoption and by reducing unnecessary costs related to uncertainty. On the other hand, it induces 13 managerial slack, reducing innovation effort that is necessary for improving production efficiency. In addition to competition-related variables, our estimation results also indicate that larger firms are more productive than smaller firms. This result is consistent with the findings by Lee and Tang (2001). At the industry dimension, productivity is substantially different. After controlling for other variables, the most productive manufacturing industry is Beverage & Tobacco Products, followed by Chemicals and Computer & Electronic Products. The least productive manufacturing industry is Leather & Allied Products, followed by Textile Mills, Wood and Food, which are all resource-based industries. 5. Concluding Remarks Many policy makers and researchers believe that product market competition increases the pressure for firms to undertake product, process, or organizational innovation, which in turn improve productivity. The empirical evidence from this paper strongly supports this view. It shows that firms with a perception of higher degree of product market competition are significantly more productive than others. This finding strongly supports a competition policy, which is geared to encourage innovation and to improve productivity performance. This finding also indicates that Canada needs to rethink its regulations in areas such as foreign ownership restrictions that prevent entry and reduces the benefits of competition. In this paper, we also find that firms with a perception of higher degree of competition for skilled workers are significantly less productive than other firms. The result implies that skills and productivity go hand in hand, and that skill shortage weakens productivity performance. A good supply of skilled labour will be certainly helpful to boost the productivity performance of firms in Canada and to narrow the Canada-U.S. productivity gap.12 In this respect, lower taxes and 12 Canada is relatively scarce in highly skilled labour when compared to the United States. For instance, the labour force in Canada has a lower percentage of people with university or higher degrees than in the United States, although it maintains a higher percentage of people who have post-secondary or higher degrees than in the United States. 14 other means to retain and attract top skilled labour would be highly desirable. In addition, education and continuous learning should form the basis of the government’s policy agenda. 15 References Baily, M. and H. Gersbach, 1995, “Efficiency in Manufacturing and the Need for Global Competition”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, pp. 307-58. Baldwin, J., 1995, The Dynamics of Industrial Competition – A North American Perspective, Cambridge University Press. Boone, J. and Van Dijk, T., 1998, “Competition and Innovation,” De Economist 146, No. 3. Bosworth, D. and Wilson, R., 1993, “Qualified Scientists and Engineers and Economic Performance”, in New Technologies and the Firm, page 153 – 74, edited by Peter Swann, Routledge: London and New York. Caves, R. E. and Barton, D. R., 1990, Efficiency in U.S. Manufacturing industries, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT press. Caves, R. E., et al., 1992, Industrial Efficiency in Six Nations, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT press. Foley, P. D., Watts, H. D. and Wilson B., 1993, “New Technologies, Skills Shortages and Training Strategies”, in New Technologies and the Firm, page 131 – 51, edited by Peter Swann, Routledge: London and New York. Geroski, P.A., 1995, “Innovation and Competitive Advantage”, OECD working paper, vol. III, no. 85. Globerman, S., Ries, J. C., and Vertinsky I., 1994, “The Economic Performance of Foreign Affiliates in Canada”, Canadian Journal of Economics 27, page 141-56. Gort, M. and Sung, N., 1999, “Competition and Productivity Growth: The Case of the U.S. Telephone Industry”, Economic Inquiry, vol. 37, issue 4, page 678 - 92. Gu, W. and Tang, J., 2001, “A New Perspective on the Canadian Manufacturing InnovationProductivity Linkage”, Manuscripts, Industry Canada. Green, A. and Mayes, D. G., 1991, “Technical Inefficiency in Manufacturing Industries”, Economic Journal, vol. 101, page 523 - 38. Hermalin, B. E., 1992, “The effects of Competition on Executive Behavior”, Rand Journal of Economics, vol. 23, page 350 - 65. Horn, h., Lang, H. and Lundgren, S., 1994, “Competition, Long Run Contracts and Internal Inefficiencies in Firms”, European Economic Review, vol. 38, page 213 - 33. Jagannathan, R. and Srinivasan, S. B., 1999, “Does Product Market Competition Reduce Agency Costs?” The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, vol. 10, page 387 - 99. 16 Lee, F. and Tang, J., 2001, “Multifactor Productivity Disparity between Canadian and U.S. Manufacturing Firms”, Journal of Productivity Analysis 15, pp.115-28. Lever, M. and Nieuwenhuijsen, H., 1999, “The Impact of Competition on Productivity in Dutch Manufacturing”, in Innovation, Industry Evolution, and Employment, page 111 - 28, edited by David B. Audretsch and Roy Thurik, Cambridge University Press. Martin, R. L., and Porter, M. E., 2001, “Canadian Competitiveness: A Decade after the Crossroads”, C. D. Howe Institute working paper 2001-1. Metcalfe, J. S. and M. Boden, 1993, “Paradigms, strategies and the evolutionary basis of technological competition”, in New Technologies and the Firm: Innovation and Competition, edited by Peter Swann, New York: Roatledge. Meyer, M. A., and Vickers, John, 1997, “Performance Comparisons and Dynamic Incentives”, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 105, page 547 - 81, Nickell, S.J. 1996, “Competition and Corporate Performance”, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 104, page 725 - 46. Perrakis, S., 1989, Canadian Industrial Organization, Prentice Hall. Pilat, D., 1996, “Competition, Productivity, Efficency”, OECD Economic Studies 27, pp. 107-46. Porter, M., 1990, The Competitive Advantage of Nations, New York: Macmillan. Porter, M. 2000, “The Current Competitiveness Index: Measuring the Microeconomic Foundations of Prosperity,” in The Global Competitiveness Report 2000, World Economic Forum. Raith, M., 2001, “Competition, Risk and Managerial Incentives”, manuscript, University of Chicago. Rao, S. and A. Ahmad, 1996, “Canadian Small and Medium-sized Enterprises: Opportuniteis and Challenges in the Asir Pacific Region”, in The Asia Pacific Region in the Glabal Economy: A Canadian Perspective, Edited by R. Harris, Galgary: University of Calgary Press. Schaan, Susan and Frances Anderson, 2001, Innovation in Canadian Manufacturing: National Estimates, Cat. No. 88F0006XIE01010, Statistics Canada. Schmidt, Klaus M., 1994, “Managerial Incentives and Product Market Competition”, discussion paper # A-430, Bonn University. Schumpeter, J. A., 1942, Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, New York: Harper. 17 Soreskog, Karl and Dag Sorbom, 1996, LISREL 8: User’s Reference Guide, Scientific Software International, Inc. Tang, J., 2001, “Competition and Innovation Activities: Micro Evidence”, manuscript, MicroEconomic Policy Analysis, Industry Canada. Tang, J. and Wang, W., 2001, “Managerial Practices and Productivity: Evidence from Canadian Manufacturing Firms”, manuscript, Micro-Economic Policy Analysis, Industry Canada. Van de Klundert, T. and Smulders, S., 1997, “Growth, Competition and Welfare,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, pp.99-118. Willig, R. D., 1987, “Corporate Governance and Market Structure”, In Economic Policy in Theory and Practice, Edited by Assaf Razin and Efraim Sadka, London: Macmillan. 18 Table 1: Weights and Correlation Coefficients between Indicators of Product Market Competition Indicators x 2 : easy product substitution x 4 : arrival of new competitors x5 : arrival of competing products x 9 : quick obsolescence of products Estimated Weights x2 x4 x5 x9 1.000 0.224 1.000 0.265 0.604 1.000 0.044 0.140 0.202 1.000 0.007 0.030 0.243 0.006 Source: The Linked SI Table 2: Weights and Correlation Coefficients between indicators of Competition for workers Indicators x4 x7 x8 x 4 : arrival of new competitors 1.000 x 7 : hardness to hire 0.159 1.000 x8 : hardness to retain 0.180 0.478 Estimated Weights 0.057 0.247 1.000 0.350 Source: The Linked SI Table 3: Weights and Correlation Coefficients between Indicators of Market transparency Indicators x1 x3 x1 : easy to predict clients’ demands 1.000 x3 : easy to predict competitors’ actions 0.388 1.000 x 6 : flexible suppliers 0.115 0.161 Estimated Weights 0.145 0.325 x6 1.000 0.046 Source: The linked SI 19 Table 4: Percentage of manufacturing firms that highly agree*** with a statement by industry NAICS Industry x3 x1 x2 easy to predict clients’ demand easy product substitution easy to predict competitors’ actions Small* M&L** Total x4 x5 arrival of new competitors arrival of competing products Small* M&L** Total Small* M&L** Total Small* M&L** Total Small* M&L** Total 311 Food 31.6 29.8 30.8 66.5 60.6 63.9 21.1 21.7 21.4 48.9 59.6 53.6 56.7 63.9 59.9 312 Bever. & tobacco 36.8 41.9 39.6 66.1 83.3 75.5 14.7 17.1 16.0 48.0 45.6 46.7 67.0 64.7 65.8 313 Textile mills 7.8 19.2 12.9 65.2 64.8 65.0 18.0 16.3 17.2 43.9 62.9 52.5 55.4 71.5 62.6 314 Textile product 22.9 43.8 29.3 55.9 67.0 59.3 16.2 14.6 15.7 46.2 45.1 45.9 55.5 66.2 58.8 315 Apparel 25.7 24.7 25.3 48.6 59.4 52.6 21.1 15.9 19.2 52.6 56.2 53.9 62.8 66.2 64.1 316 Leather 27.8 28.5 28.1 57.3 49.5 53.5 22.5 16.4 19.5 54.2 74.8 64.2 72.2 62.6 67.6 321 Wood 34.1 39.7 36.1 62.5 67.7 64.3 22.9 24.4 23.4 51.5 51.7 51.6 54.9 54.3 54.6 322 Paper 38.7 44.0 42.0 63.1 80.0 73.5 37.6 25.5 29.9 30.2 52.1 43.6 40.7 55.6 49.9 323 Printing 32.4 36.2 33.3 65.9 59.4 64.3 31.4 39.6 33.5 50.1 40.9 47.8 52.3 48.7 51.4 324 Petroleum & coal 31.4 48.0 39.6 56.9 80.0 68.3 35.3 12.0 23.8 33.3 48.0 40.6 45.1 52.0 48.5 325 Chemical 39.0 34.5 37.2 62.7 57.5 60.6 22.0 21.3 21.7 43.3 52.4 46.9 49.7 58.2 53.1 326 Plastics & rubber 31.8 28.6 30.5 58.5 51.8 55.8 24.6 22.2 23.6 49.6 42.3 46.6 57.0 55.9 56.5 327 Nonmetal. mineral 36.4 35.9 36.3 63.4 67.4 64.3 26.8 25.9 26.6 44.8 43.3 44.4 47.6 53.0 48.8 331 Primary metal 27.0 34.1 31.0 66.1 59.7 62.4 22.6 12.7 17.0 51.5 41.9 46.0 56.3 50.8 53.1 332 Fabricated metal 32.5 31.8 32.4 59.2 47.2 56.8 28.4 16.0 25.9 48.5 55.0 49.8 41.7 49.0 43.2 333 Machinery 24.3 24.5 24.4 54.4 66.6 58.1 21.3 17.5 20.1 42.9 47.8 44.4 47.8 50.2 48.5 334 Comp. & electro. 26.3 22.9 24.7 46.2 46.6 46.4 20.4 10.7 15.9 42.4 46.8 44.4 55.7 64.5 59.8 335 Electrical equip. 21.8 25.0 23.4 54.6 68.9 61.6 27.4 20.8 24.2 49.4 46.1 47.7 55.5 54.2 54.9 336 Transpor. Equip. 34.0 36.0 35.1 49.7 51.3 50.6 18.7 18.8 18.8 40.9 44.3 42.8 46.5 44.9 45.6 337 Furniture 34.0 21.3 30.4 55.4 55.5 55.4 25.6 21.6 24.5 44.8 51.5 46.7 48.5 53.0 49.8 339 Misce. Manuf 33.5 29.2 32.5 57.9 53.9 57.0 13.6 26.0 16.5 47.7 61.0 50.7 56.5 58.8 57.0 31.1 31.5 31.3 59.0 60.0 59.4 23.9 20.5 22.7 47.0 50.7 48.3 51.1 55.9 52.8 Total Manufacturing 20 Table 4: Continued NAICS x6 Industry Small* x7 flexible suppliers M&L** Total x8 Small* hardness to hire M&L** Total Small* x9 hardness to retain M&L** Total quick obsolescence of products Small* M&L** Total 311 Food 27.9 22.4 25.5 54.2 47.8 51.4 34.1 36.1 35.0 16.8 15.5 16.3 312 Bever. & tobacco 22.4 25.6 24.1 26.4 54.4 41.6 31.4 25.7 28.3 12.4 10.3 11.3 313 Textile mills 22.4 16.3 19.6 62.4 60.7 61.6 38.1 37.3 37.8 13.4 16.6 14.8 314 Textile product 20.9 16.3 19.5 67.9 70.6 68.7 31.2 20.6 28.0 11.0 18.9 13.4 315 Apparel 21.5 20.1 21.0 60.3 69.3 63.6 38.9 30.7 35.8 22.3 33.3 26.4 316 Leather 10.1 5.6 7.9 70.5 53.3 62.1 54.6 24.3 39.9 17.6 16.8 17.2 321 Wood 27.1 24.5 26.2 59.7 52.0 57.0 32.5 34.2 33.1 9.5 7.8 8.9 322 Paper 18.1 22.8 21.0 46.8 53.6 51.0 20.3 27.1 24.5 9.4 7.8 8.4 323 Printing 33.2 29.5 32.3 72.3 60.8 69.4 33.2 29.4 32.3 18.2 22.6 19.3 324 Petroleum & coal 31.4 36.0 33.7 60.8 48.0 54.5 13.7 20.0 16.8 23.5 12.0 17.8 325 Chemical 24.0 14.1 20.1 46.5 49.5 47.7 27.2 28.6 27.8 11.1 5.8 9.0 326 Plastics & rubber 22.6 19.2 21.2 62.8 65.9 64.1 37.3 36.7 37.1 12.5 6.8 10.2 327 Nonmetal. Mineral 28.8 21.2 27.0 53.1 52.3 52.9 27.0 28.9 27.5 7.2 6.0 6.9 331 Primary metal 25.0 21.0 22.7 63.1 46.2 53.5 28.6 29.1 28.9 7.7 2.6 4.8 332 Fabricated metal 26.2 19.7 24.9 70.1 60.5 68.3 31.2 21.2 29.3 4.4 9.5 5.4 333 Machinery 31.7 23.9 29.3 73.7 68.0 71.9 34.7 34.2 34.5 6.6 9.5 7.5 334 Comp. & electro. 28.2 20.9 24.8 59.4 68.3 63.5 42.4 43.6 43.0 20.2 20.1 20.2 335 Electrical equip. 15.7 17.0 16.3 54.4 59.8 57.1 34.4 29.9 32.2 9.8 9.4 9.6 336 Transpor. Equip. 18.7 19.6 19.2 60.6 60.0 60.2 37.8 33.6 35.5 9.7 7.4 8.4 337 Furniture 23.1 17.2 21.4 70.1 72.0 70.7 46.2 40.9 44.7 12.5 7.3 11.0 339 Misce. Manuf 20.9 12.5 19.0 71.7 57.0 68.4 34.6 35.6 34.8 8.3 12.4 9.2 All industries 25.7 20.7 23.9 63.6 58.6 61.8 34.0 32.2 33.4 11.0 11.8 11.3 * Small-sized firms. ** Medium- and large-sized firms. *** A statement is highly agreed by a firm if the firm scores 4 or 5. Source: The linked SI. 21 Table 5: Estimated Effects of Competition on Productivity Variables Intercept Fuel & power consumption Product market competition Competition for workers Market transparency Medium-sized firms Large-sized firms Food Bever. & tobacco Textile mills Textile product Apparel Leather Wood Paper Printing Petroleum & coal Chemical Plastics & rubber Nonmetal. mineral Primary metal Fabricated metal Machinery Comp. & electro. Electrical equip. Transpor. Equip. Furniture R-Square Parameter Estimates 4.335 0.237 0.061 -0.087 -0.015 0.080 0.210 -0.242 0.397 -0.359 -0.329 -0.245 -0.360 -0.285 -0.151 -0.056 0.251 0.371 -0.147 -0.199 -0.082 -0.058 0.129 0.278 0.048 -0.005 -0.185 t Values 67.80 25.44 2.45 -5.91 -0.75 4.35 5.84 -4.42 4.77 -4.93 -4.02 -4.19 -3.75 -5.20 -2.38 -0.92 2.47 6.36 -2.54 -3.19 -1.21 -1.08 2.38 4.47 0.70 -0.09 -3.07 .2570 P values* 0.000 0.000 0.014 0.000 0.454 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.018 0.359 0.013 0.000 0.011 0.001 0.227 0.282 0.017 0.000 0.482 0.927 0.002 * The P value (or marginal significance level) is the probability of observing a test statistic no less extreme than the one actually observed. 22 Appendix: Estimation of an Unobservable Latent Variable Let ξ denote an unobservable latent variable that is to be estimated from its indicators. The empirical relationship between these indicators and the latent variable can be written as: (A1) x = ëξ + ä . Where x = ( x1 M x 2 M...M xn ) is the vector of indicators, ë = ( λ1 M λ2 M...M λn ) is the vector of coefficients of x on ξ , and ä = (δ1 Mδ2 M...Mδn ) is the vector of error terms. Assume that the error terms ä = (δ1 Mδ2 M...Mδn ) are orthogonal to the latent variable ξ , the covariance matrix of x can be written as: (A2) xx T ≡ ∑ = ë ξξ T ë T + ää T . Normalize the variance of ξ to 1, i.e., var (ξ) ≡ ξξ T = 1 . As ∑ is known, we can derive the estimate of ë , denoting ë̂ , by minimizing the determinant of (A3) È ≡ ää T = ∑ −ëë T . Thus, the parameters of the model are estimated by minimizing the difference between the sample co-variances of all indicators and the co-variances predicted by the model. The estimation is done by generally weighted least squares method since all observed variables are ordinal. The weight matrix is the inverse of the estimated asymptotic covariance matrix of the polychoric correlations of the observed variables in this paper. Here it is important to use the generally weighted least squares method. When other methods such as Maximum Likelihood or Generalized Least Squares are used, parameter estimates may be distorted and the chi-square goodness-of-fit measure and standard errors may not be reliable (Soreskog and Sorbom, 1996). Replacing ë by ë̂ in equation (A1) gives x = ëˆ ξ + residual. The estimation of ξ is ˆ = ëˆ ëˆ T , we have wˆ ∑ ˆ = ( ëˆ T ëˆ ) -1 ëˆ T ëˆ ëˆ T = ëˆ T ξˆ = ( ëˆ T ëˆ ) −1 ëˆ T x ≡ w ˆ x , with wˆ = ( ëˆ T ëˆ ) −1 ëˆ T . As ∑ which implies (A4) ˆ −1 . ξˆ = ŵx , with wˆ = ëˆ T ∑ 23 It is clearly for equation (A4) that an indicator is not only weighted by its correlation with the latent variable, reflected by ë̂ , but also by the variance of the correction and its co-variances with other indicators. The smaller the variance of the correlation, the higher is its weight. 24