Reviews/Comptes rendus BOOKS REVIEWED Roy J. Adams, Gordon Betcherman and Beth Bilson Good Jobs, Bad Jobs, No Jobs: Tough Choices for Canadian Labour Law reviewed by Jane Friesen 92 Alice H. Amsden, Jacek Kochanowicz and Lance Taylor The Market Meets Its Match – Restructuring the Economies of Eastern Europe reviewed by Konrad W. Studnicki-Gizbert 98 Peter Aucoin The New Public Management: Canada in Comparative Perspective reviewed by Stanley Winer 110 John N.H. Britton (ed.) Canada and the Global Economy: The Geography of Structural and Technological Change reviewed by G.T. Bloomfield 109 Elizabeth Brubaker Property Rights and the Defence of Nature reviewed by Dan Usher 84 Manon Cornellier The Bloc reviewed by Herman Bakvis 97 Roy Culpeper and Andrew Clark High Stakes and Low Incomes: Canada and the Development Banks reviewed by André Martens 100 Ronald J. Daniels (ed.) Ontario Hydro at the Millennium: Has Monopoly’s Moment Passed? reviewed by Robert D. Cairns 107 Laurent Dobuzinskis, Michael Howlett and David Laycock (eds.) Policy Studies in Canada: The State of the Art reviewed by Peter W.B. Phillips 105 Keith Fitzgerald The Face of the Nation: Immigration, The State, and the National Identity reviewed by Don J. DeVoretz 106 Reviews/Comptes rendus 83 C.E.S. Franks, J.E. Hodgetts, O.P. Dwivedi, Doug Williams, V. Seymour Wilson (eds.) Canada’s Century Governance in a Maturing Society – Essays in Honour of John Meisel compte rendu par Guy Lachapelle 87 Robert E. Goodin Utilitarianism as a Public Philosophy reviewed by Charles Jones 92 Stephen R.G. Jones The Persistence of Unemployment: Hysteresis in Canadian Labour Markets reviewed by Pierre Fortin 104 Neil Nevitte The Decline of Deference: Canadian Value Change in Cross-National Perspective reviewed by Harry H. Hiller 102 Giancarlo Pola, George France and Rosella Levaggi (eds.) Developments in Local Government Finance: Theory and Policy reviewed by Douglas Auld 112 Anthony A. Peacock (ed.) Rethinking the Constitution: Perspectives on Canadian Constitutional Reform, Interpretation, and Theory reviewed by Alan Cairns 96 Richard Stubbs and Geoffrey R.D. Underhill (eds.) Political Economy and the Changing Global Order reviewed by Kenneth Woodside 108 Gene Swimmer (ed.) How Ottawa Spends 199697: Life Under the Knife reviewed by Malcolm Grieve 91 Gary Teeple Globalization and the Decline of Social Reform reviewed by Peter Eglin 95 Dan Usher The Uneasy Case for Equalization Payments reviewed by Harry Kitchen 94 CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 84 Reviews/Comptes rendus Property Rights and the Defence of Nature by Elizabeth Brubaker. Toronto: Earthscan Publications Ltd., 1995. This is a high-spirited, well-written and informative book on the law as the protector of the environment, a book to be recommended to students in environmental studies and law and economics, a book made more interesting, challenging and useful because its prescriptions are, in my opinion, largely wrong. The flavour of the book is evident in its main headings: “the golden age of property rights,” “the erosion of common law property rights,” “common law failings” and “nature’s case for restoring strong property rights.” The book is a little treasure house of instructive law cases and public decisions, some admirable, some dreadful. The worst of all, in my opinion, is Canada’s Nuclear Liability Act (discussed in Chapter 6, “The Defence of Statutory Authority”) limiting liability of manufacturers and suppliers of atomic power to a total of $75 million in the event of a nuclear accident, even if the accident is caused by willfulness or wrongdoing. Less potentially catastrophic but no less indefensible is Ontario’s recent encouragement of deforestation as described in Chapter 10, “The Taxman’s Axe.” There are two heroes and two villains. The heroes are the great principle of the common law that (for those who remember their high school Latin) sic utere tuo, ut alienum non laedas, or (for the rest of us) “use your own property so as not to harm another,” and the judges who are guided by that principle in deciding who is entitled to what. The villains are the principle of pro bono publico and the government, seen as at best incompetent and at worst downright evil, that adheres to its conception of the public good to thwart nature and justice. Elizabeth Brubaker comes down foursquare with the judgement in Stephens v. Richmond Hill (1955, discussed on p. 85) that it “is not for the judiciary to permit the doctrine of utilitarianism to be used as a makeweight in the scales of justice.” I see the book as supporting five key propositions: CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, • that there is often a good case for the privatization of the commons, • that nature can sometimes be defended through compensation for the taking of property, • that private rights to pristine nature be subject to “property rules” rather than “liability rules”1 so that the remedy for the violation of nature is an injunction on the violator to desist rather than compensation to the victim after the fact, • that people have a right to nature as it was before the intervention of mankind, and • that the defence of nature is to be entrusted to the courts, not the government. I have reservations, some minor, some serious, about each of these propositions. That “there is often a good case for the privatization of the commons” is a proposition with which few economists nowadays would disagree, but there is no prescription about which commons should be privatized and no recognition that, as practised, privatization may be in violation of the common law. Why the West Coast fishery but not the entire ocean or, for that matter, the air? This is not in my opinion an unanswerable question, but it is not discussed. Nor is it recognized that privatization is a reassignment by the muchmaligned “government” of rights “from time immemorial” from one lot of people to another. It is a decree that henceforth my right to fish when I please on certain rivers is terminated, and that, “in the public interest,” the government has reassigned those rights to certain people who may be chosen by lot, by auction or by race; and whose property the right to fish will henceforth become. I can accept this, but there is some question as to whether Brubaker ought to do so. That “nature can sometime be defended by compensation for the taking of property” is also broadlyspeaking correct in my opinion, but the main justification for compensation is not to protect nature at all, and compensation can sometimes be perverse VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus in its effect upon the environment. The main justification for compensation is to protect citizens against victimization by the government of the day and, consequently, to maintain the support for democratic government among citizens who might otherwise fear expropriation at the hands of a hostile majority. A right not to be a victim of pollution might be protected along the way. But an entrenched right to pollute might also be protected. I produce and sell a substance which is harmless to users and, in doing so, emit into the air a by-product which has hitherto been supposed to be harmless as well, but is now discovered to be dangerous. Can my production be stopped by the government or its agencies in the common good (as some uses of asbestos have been stopped), or have I a property right protected by the courts? This question leads immediately to Brubaker’s third proposition. The standard remedy for the taking of private property by the government is compensation, not injunction. The courts do not say to a city planning to build a school on the land where my house now stands that the land may only be acquired if I am prepared to sell and at a price I am prepared to accept. The court empowers the city to acquire the land at “a fair market price,” whether or not I want to sell at that price. The reason is to prevent hold-ups, to stop the owner of the last unacquired property in the path of a road from holding out for the entire value of the road to all potential users. Similarly, if everybody had a right to the enjoyment of pristine nature and if courts were to secure that right by injunction, then the right to pure water of an aristocratic owner of a fishing lodge downstream would take precedence over the cost of sewage disposal to millions of city folks upstream,2 and the owner of the lodge could hold up the city for far more than his fishing rights could ever be worth. We might have to close down Toronto altogether. Useful as it would be to Environment Probe, the injunction is the wrong remedy for the alleviation of pollution or the defence of nature. The fourth proposition is just mistaken. Sic utere tuo, ut alienum non laedas is an ideal, never a com- 85 plete reality. The reality is that there is little I can do with my property (with things designated by the law as mine) that does not affect my neighbour to some extent and it is a large part of the business of government, especially municipal government, to determine what I can do with my property and what I cannot. May I grow yellow roses even though my neighbour detests them? May I convert my house into a store? What about a blacksmith shop, the subject of some interesting litigation? The right to dump sewage in Lake Ontario may or may not belong to the people of Toronto. Some rights can be acquired by ancient use, others may be conditional on, for example, how nearby properties are utilized. Strands in the bundle we call property rights may be added or subtracted by municipal regulation. The boundary between rights that may be extinguished by legislation and rights that may not be extinguished except with just compensation is the subject of much dispute among lawyers and economists.3 At present, courts typically enforce rights as they find them on the understanding that the legislature may move the boundary posts between rights from time to time. Brubaker would reassign the guardianship of the boundaries from the legislature to the courts. Rights belong to people, not nature. The government specifies the content of those rights. Among our rights are the right to impose certain externalities on others. Virtually all legislation entails a change in the boundaries of rights, with legislation about tax schedules as the obvious example. We need not fear the imminent closing of the city of Toronto because the people of Toronto have acquired the right to pollute Lake Ontario to some extent. If we are to control the pollution on the St. Lawrence at all, it will be because governments — weighing costs and benefits to residents of Toronto, to other users of Lake Ontario, and to the entire population of the world insofar as it is affected by pollution in Toronto — impose some degree of control in the common interest. In fact, the judges say precisely that. As quoted in Brubaker, the judge in Stephens v. Richmond Hill CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 86 Reviews/Comptes rendus (1955, cited on p. 85) goes on to say that “It is the duty of the State (and of statesmen) to seek the greatest good for the greatest number ... It is for the government to protect the general by wise and benevolent enactment. It is for me, or so I think, to interpret the law, determine the rights of the individual and to invoke the remedy required for their enforcement.” be subsumed under the heading of property rights to be enforced by the courts. That is implicit in the rhetoric of this book and if it is not what Brubaker means, she should have said so explicitly. The common law never stood alone. In the nineteenth century, it coexisted with the rules of equity and was always subordinate to the legislature in that rules of the common law could always be overturned by legislative action. The common law would otherwise have been intolerable. In the midnineteenth century, it granted husbands complete and absolute authority over the property of their wives, a rule overturned by legislation in the latter half of the century. Earlier on, the law had sanctioned judicial torture, horrendous punishments and the burning of witches. Brubaker celebrates the common law as a whole on the strength of bits of the fabric that she wishes were still in place today. Recommendations and suggestions are scattered throughout the book, but there is no concluding chapter where Brubaker’s program of reform is set out in its entirety. That is unfortunate because, as it stands, the book is open to a maximalist or minimalist interpretation. The maximalist interpretation is the advocacy of the complete displacement of the legislature by the courts in the belief that the environment is best protected by judicial injunction with no guidance outside the accumulated wisdom of the common law, a beautiful thesis for classroom discussion but a recipe, in my opinion, for chaos. The minimalist interpretation is that there is more room for privatization as a defence of nature, a quite defensible proposition that is weakened considerably by the absence of discussion about when the “legal” solution is likely to be preferable to taxation and when not. From the discussion of the taxation of forests in Chapter 10, it is difficult to tell whether the author is opposing all taxation upon owners of forests who use their resources nicely, or is advocating an income tax rather than a wealth tax because the latter induces owners to cut prematurely. 4 From Brubaker’s discussion of taxation and from her less than complementary remarks about “government” as the protector of the environment, one might infer that she has no room for either in her ideal regulatory program. One might infer that the privatization of the West Coast fishery is the appropriate model for the entire defence of nature. The sale and use of asbestos, the emission of toxic chemicals from automobiles and factories, the degradation of the ozone layer of the atmosphere, the preservation of biodiversity and the entire range of commonlyrecognized externalities of modern life would no longer be regulated or taxed by agencies of government acting in accordance with their misguided conceptions of the public good. All such matters would The fifth proposition is an instance of a dangerous vice, the writing off of democracy as the basis for public decision making. Of course, you do not oppose democracy per se. You oppose government. “Thus governments have given polluters a prize defence” (p. 96). “Governments soon discovered a new reason to raze their forests” (p. 140). “Governments use carrots as well as sticks to pressure owners to deforest their land” (p. 160). “Governments have shown that they are not up to the task of preventing resource degradation” (p. 161). “Governments have also destroyed resources they don’t own” (p. 161). All topped off with an apt quotation from Ronald Coase (p. 106). This would be music to the ears of a reactionary economist like me if it were in aid of a greater reliance on the market, and, to some extent, it is. But the primary focus of the argument is elsewhere. The primary focus is to redirect what is essentially public decision making from the legislature to the courts. Government per se cannot be trusted, but government can be trusted to appoint CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus judges who, through the principles of the common law, will get environmental policy right. Never mind that the judges are appointed by those very legislators we have come to mistrust, that many of judges served their apprenticeship as lawyers for the very polluters against whom injunctions must now be served,5 that the common law has always been subordinate to legislation, that the traditional content of the rights of property may need to be modified from time to time and that, by its very nature, the judiciary is ill-suited to draw a balance of competing interest or to recognize the public good. We have faith in our judges and in the efficacy of the common law as a defence of nature. Elizabeth Brubaker is by no means alone in her disenchantment with the normal processes of democracy. I am especially sensitive to that disenchantment because I see it as a great failing in many scholars whose work I otherwise admire and because I believe there is in the end no shortcut through the courts, no alternative to ordinary politics, if we are to get the environment right and if any semblance of a good society is to be preserved. I return to where I began. This is a lively and useful book. Most readers will probably disagree with much of it, and, in articulating their disagreement, will clarify their own opinions. The book raises important questions about the role of the courts in the protection of nature, questions of what the courts should do and what they should desist from doing. NOTES 1 The distinction was introduced in G. Calabresi and A.D. Melamed, “Property Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability: One view of the Cathedral,” Harvard Law Review (1972): 1089-128. 2 “[P]ublic works must be so executed as not to interfere with private rights of individuals.” Attorney General v. Birmingham (cited on p. 282). 3 See, especially, J. Sax, “Takings and the Police Power,” Yale Law Journal (1964):36-76; and F. Michelman, “Property, Utility and Fairness: Comments on the Ethical 87 Foundations of ‘Just Compensation’,” Harvard law Review (1967):1165-258. 4 Suppose a forest yields either $100 if cut entirely now or $11 forever if cut selectively each year, and suppose the interest rate is 10 percent. The efficient procedure is to cut selectively forever. Under an income tax, that is what the owner is inclined to do, for his gross present value is $100 if he cuts the forest entirely now or $110 if he cuts selectively forever, and his net present values are 95 percent of these. But with a wealth tax of, say, 3 percent of the gross present value, he would cut the entire forest immediately. His net present value would be $97 if he cuts the entire forest now, but only $80 ($(11-3)/(0.1)) if he cuts selectively. The same argument could be made against all property taxation if there were a way to realize the flow of benefits of housing all at once. 5 See J.A.G. Griffith, The Politics of the Judiciary, 3d ed. (Huntington, NY: Fontana Paperbacks, 1985). One who is inclined to place his faith in the courts as the protectors of the environment should consider JDR-MacDonald Inc v. Canada (Attorney General), 1994, in which we are informed by the Supreme Court of Canada that “no direct evidence of a scientific nature showed a causal link between advertising bans and decrease in tobacco consumption” and that “the prohibition of advertising ... violated the right to free expression.” D AN U SHER , Department of Economics, Queen’s University Canada’s Century Governance in a Maturing Society - Essays in Honour of John Meisel sous la direction de C.E.S. Franks, J.E. Hodgetts, O.P. Dwivedi, Doug Williams, V. Seymour Wilson. Montreal et Kingston, McGill-Queen’s University Press, 1995. Pp. Viii, 369. $49.95. Comme son titre l’indique, cet ouvrage veut souligner la contribution exceptionnelle de John Meisel à la science politique canadienne et québécoise. Il demeure pour plusieurs d’entre nous l’un des premiers commentateurs et observateurs assidus de la vie politique québécoise, un symbole de la dualité canadienne, un homme d’une très grande générosité. Léon Dion décrit fort bien la personne: “La constitution, le fédéralisme canadien CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 88 Reviews/Comptes rendus ou l’indépendance du Québec, il (John Meisel) les juge en dernière analyse à travers le prisme des valeurs de liberté, d’égalité, de justice, de compassion et d’amour qui le guident dans tout ce qu’il vit et entreprend et qu’il ne cesse d’approfondir dans les dimensions multiples et secrètes qu’elles revêtent” (110). Fidèle à lui-même, John Meisel maintiendra le cap tout au long de sa carrière flanqué d’un esprit humaniste et d’une intégrité intellectuelle à toute épreuve. La longue route de John Meisel débute alors qu’il est l’un des directeurs de la recherche pour la Commission royale sur le bilinguisme et le biculturalisme (Commission Laurendeau-Dunton). Peter M. Leslie souligne d’ailleurs comment John Meisel, qui estimait que l’harmonie entre francophone et anglophone devait être au centre des discussions sur le fédéralisme canadien, fut profondément bouleversé par une remarque d’André Laurendeau qui lui dit: ce qui est important ce n’est pas l’harmonie mais l’égalité des chances, “equality of opportunity” (342). Cet échange aura un effet canon sur la pensée de John Meisel et modifiera sa conception de la démocratie, du rôle de l’État, des partis politiques et des citoyens, thèmes que cet ouvrage aborde coup sur coup. Cinq thématiques guident le dialogue entre les collaborateurs de cet ouvrage et John Meisel: la gouverne politique, les relations Canada-Québec, en particulier les politiques linguistiques et le multiculturalisme, le rôle des partis politiques, la fonction de régulation de l’État et l’influence des médias et des communications comme outil de façonnement de nos esprits autant que sur le rôle social des politologues. À travers son parcours, entre l’enseignement de la science politique et ses diverses fonctions publiques, en particulier celle au C.R.T.C. au début des années quatre-vingt, John Meisel a toujours gardé un oeil attentif sur les maux de la société canadienne et proposé des solutions qui, si elles avaient été retenues, auraient sans doute permises CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, de régler plusieurs difficultés. C’est dans cet état d’esprit qu’il faut lire ce livre, en se demandant comment il se fait que les divers problèmes politiques et sociaux évoqués ne sont toujours pas résolus à l’aube du 21ème siècle. Toutes les solutions sont là, il s’agit de savoir pourquoi elles n’ont pas été mises en oeuvre et pourquoi les instances politiques et bureaucratiques fédérales résistent aux changements proposés. Le premier grand thème de ce livre est celui de la gouverne politique. Trois auteurs, Richard Simeon, Alan C. Cairns et C.E.S. Franks posent la question suivante: Comment faire en sorte que les institutions politiques puissent répondre aux demandes et aux besoins des citoyens? Richard Simeon note que le pouvoir au Canada est de plus en plus concentré entre les mains du premier ministre, plutôt qu’au sein des partis politiques, du parlement ou du cabinet (32). L’une des conséquences immédiates de ce phénomène est qu’en terme de loyauté, le gouvernement fédéral a de moins en moins la confiance des citoyens, ceuxci ayant le sentiment qu’Ottawa a de moins en moins d’écoute à leur endroit (35). De plus, la globalisation des marchés fait subir une pression supplémentaire aux sociétés en facilitant la naissance de nouveaux conflits, l’État fédéral étant de moins en moins capable d’assurer le maintien de ses politiques redistributives, les facteurs internationaux nivellant les demandes. La question du Québec, ou plutôt l’incapacité du gouvernement fédéral à donner une réponse claire aux aspirations des québécois par la reconnaissance de la dualité canadienne et de l’existence du peuple québécois, constitue un autre exemple parmi d’autres. À ce propos, le texte d’Alan C. Cairns permet de comprendre l’évolution du fédéralisme canadien et comment l’histoire, certains clichés et certaines visions nostalgiques constituent souvent des éléments contraignants, rendant impossible la création de nouveaux modes de gestion. Reprenant le commentaire de Pierre E. Trudeau qui écrivait en 1968: “English-speaking Canadians have long VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus behaved in national politics as though they believed that democracy was not for French Canadians,” Cairns souligne que la réaction normale du Québec fut de se sentir assiéger par un Canada anglais qui considéraient les québécois tout au plus comme une minorité ethnique. Il note d’ailleurs que deux visions s’opposent: l’une centralisatrice à la Macdonald au Canada, l’autre dualiste à la Duplessis au Québec. C.E.S. Franks estime lui aussi que la difficulté provient essentiellement de la dominance de l’exécutif, tant à Ottawa qu’à Québec, ce qui provoque régulièrement des crises de légitimité. Les premiers ministres des provinces ont d’ailleurs trop tendance, selon lui, à amplifier les mésententes entre le fédéral et les provinces, afin de nourrir la loyauté de leurs électeurs. Francks propose d’ailleurs de créer, comme le chapitre 23 de l’Accord de Charlottetown le suggérait, un “Conseil de la fédération” qui verrait à replacer les demandes des citoyens à l’avant-scène des débats. Pour ce qui est du second thème, celui des relations binationales et culturelles, Léon Dion, Gérard Bergeron, William P. Irvine, Jean Laponce et V. Seymour Wilson soulignent tous l’ambivalence canadienne et l’incapacité du gouvernement fédéral de proposer des solutions cohérentes répondant aux véritables aspirations des citoyens. On sent cependant, une certaine morosité des auteurs, chacun cherchant des solutions respectueuses du cadre binational canadien. Léon Dion le premier, son texte ayant été écrit en 1989, soit avant les échecs successifs de Meech et Charlottetown, témoigne de son impatience devant des solutions qui tardent. Le titre de son chapitre est révélateur de ses intentions: “Propos désabusés d’un fédéraliste fatigué.” S’inspirant de John Meisel qui écrivait en 1978 “J’ai le goût du Québec, But I Like Canada,” Léon Dion lui affirme: “le Canada est mon pays, mais le Québec est ma patrie” (88). Il écrit que s’il avait à choisir entre le Québec et le Canada, il n’hésiterait pas: “je choisirais le Québec, déjà ma patrie, comme pays” (88). Et pourtant, lors du référendum de 1995, Léon 89 Dion a choisi le Canada en votant NON même s’il avait voté OUI en 1980 “pour éveiller le Canada anglais à l’urgence de s’attaquer enfin sérieusement à une réforme véritable du fédéralisme” (91). Léon Dion a donc opté en 1995 pour la solution Meisel! Gérard Bergeron et William P. Irvine présentent de leur côté des points de vue opposés. Si le premier, dans la lignée des travaux du professeur Meisel, insiste sur la spécificité de la société québécoise et l’importance pour tout gouvernement d’obtenir l’appui des citoyens, le second prêche pour une gouverne politique plus centralisée. Irvine affirme que le mouvement nationaliste québécois est essentiellement guidé par ses élites et qu’il ne reflète nullement l’opinion des citoyens puisqu’il y a, selon lui, une forte convergence d’opinion entre Québécois et Canadiens sur les principaux enjeux politiques. Toutefois, sa démonstration empirique demeure peu convaincante soutenant qu’il est difficile de mesurer l’opinion publique: “public opinion on public policy is inconsistent and unstable — a poor guide to what should be done” (139). L’argumentaire demeure hésitant et contradictoire puisque tout en reconnaissant les valeurs démocratiques de la décentralisation administrative, Irvine maintient son allégeance au fédéralisme exécutif. C’est la vision élitiste du Canada qui refait surface comme si les citoyens ne pouvaient savoir ce qui est bon pour eux. Jean Laponce reprend quant à lui le débat autour d’un thème qui a toujours passionné John Meisel: le bilinguisme ou la recherche d’un équilibre social et communautaire stable entre francophone et anglophone au Canada. Laponce affirme que les deux principaux groupes linguistiques au Canada jouent un rôle spécifique et bien défini, les deux communautés étant dans une situation de diglossie. C’est pourquoi il favorise une gestion territoriale de la langue afin de minimiser les conflits tout en offrant au Québec le plein contrôle de sa politique culturelle. Sa proposition est claire: donner au Québec le droit exclusif de légiférer en matière linguistique, pouvoir qui serait également accordé à toutes les autres provinces, et ce dans la lignée CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 90 Reviews/Comptes rendus des recommandations de la Commission PépinRobarts (162). Quant à V. Seymour Wilson, il souligne toutes les ambiguïtés du multiculturalisme au Canada et il y voit une tribalisation de la société canadienne. À son avis, le choix du gouvernement du Québec de parler davantage de pluralisme culturel que de multiculturalisme est heureux puisque la question du Québec n’est pas une question ethnique mais bien une de race (180). Le troisième thème est celui de la place des partis politiques et des élections comme élément structurant de l’évolution des sociétés. R.K. Carty cherche en premier lieu à vérifier si l’hypothèse d’une ère d’alternance entre gouvernements minoritaire et majoritaire, formulée par John Meisel en 1963, s’était avérée exacte. Carty démontre que cette hypothèse est confirmée pour la période 19651979. D’autre part, la seconde hypothèse de John Meisel, soit que les partis politiques canadiens sont incapables d’agir comme des agents de cohésion sociale, d’arbitrer les intérêts régionaux et de classes pour devenir des partis plus idéologiques, démontre bien qu’il n’existe pas au Canada une culture politique commune. Quant à Vincent Lemieux, il soutient que John Meisel accorde trop d’importance à l’espace partisan et qu’il faudrait sans doute resituer les partis politiques dans leurs relations avec les gouvernements et la société, les travaux de John Meisel offrant à ce chapitre plusieurs pistes utiles. Jane Jenson explique que le modèle politique dominant au Canada est essentiellement élitiste et que les chercheurs n’ont pas assez insisté sur la pratique de la démocratie, ce qui expliquerait pourquoi on craint souvent de donner plus de responsabilités aux citoyens. Un exemple intéressant à ce sujet est celui de la Commission royale sur la réforme électorale et le financement des partis (Commission Lortie) qui n’a pas réussi, malgré bien des efforts, à faire accepter par les élites politiques du Canada anglais la nécessité de réformer le système partisan, plus particulièrement les règles de financement des partis. Dans le même sens, Hugh G. Thorburn mentionne qu’un système de représentation CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, proportionnelle et la création de fondations liées aux partis politiques constitueraient des changements institutionnels nécessaires. Le quatrième thème est celui de la réglementation. Richard Schultz, Liora Salter et O.P. Dwivedi soulignent, chacun à leur manière, que John Meisel avait bien prédit, en avril 1982, que l’idée de déréglementation qui emballait les américains allait bientôt se répandre au Canada. Quant au dernier thème de l’ouvrage, celui de la culture et du rôle des sciences sociales dans le développement des connaissances, il s’inscrit lui aussi nettement dans une réflexion tant sur l’utilité des recherches des politologues que de leur influence sur les gouvernements. James I. Gow souligne l’importance de l’intuition et de la création comme outil pour faire contre poids aux approches empiristes dominantes. À son avis, le plus important pour un chercheur est d’être capable de pouvoir faire osciller sa pensée entre des modes rationnels et créatifs, de faire travailler les deux hémisphères du cerveau. John Meisel représente l’un des rares chercheurs qui soit capable d’opérer ce transfert. Dans le même sens, Edwin R. Black souligne comment les nouvelles technologies de la communication risquent de modifier profondément les mécanismes de la pensée humaine et la vie politique. Quant à Peter M. Leslie, il mentionne en bout de piste comment John Meisel a toujours estimé que les recherches américaines avaient et ont toujours une trop grande influence sur les politologues du Canada anglais sans compter que ceux-ci ont souvent négligé de participer aux débats publics, préférant laisser aux politiciens le monopole de l’action politique. En somme, cet ouvrage nous permet à la fois de décoder certains mécanismes des relations de pouvoir au sein des sociétés canadienne et québécoise mais surtout de bien saisir quels sont les problèmes qui devront être résolus pour faire face aux différents défis, en particulier celui des relations Canada-Québec. Comme le titre du livre l’indique, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus le Canada est un pays en transition, en évolution, en émergence; il restera à savoir qui acceptera d’être au rendez-vous. Mais la chose la plus essentielle de cet ouvrage, c’est qu’il nous permet de lever le voile sur la carrière et les réflexions d’un des politologues les plus appréciés au Canada et au Québec, d’un politologue qui fut au rendez-vous de tous les débats de la société canadienne. GUY LACHAPELLE, Département de science politique, Université Concordia How Ottawa Spends 1996-97: Life Under the Knife edited by Gene Swimmer. Ottawa: Carleton University Press, 1996. Pp. viii, 478. A new running title for the Carleton series might be “How Ottawa Spends Less.” The need will surely persist to analyze the sea-change of downsizing the federal government, although this collection covers many of the more prominent government programs including HRDS, Public Works, Defence, and Treasury Board itself. (The book returns to an earlier format of reviewing government operations on a departmental basis.) Perhaps next year’s edition will include chapters on trimming expenditures in Foreign Affairs, Natural Resources, and Health? Many readers will appreciate a chronology of the federal deficit reduction program as well as coverage of the variety of ways and degrees of success with which departments have responded and adapted to the directives to make cuts to their programs and personnel. In addition to pursuing the theme of retrenchment, several chapters offer original research into the operations of major departments: Lindquist, for example, examines the organizational structure and operational reforms to the Treasury Board and questions whether the cuts imposed on its own operations may render it less effective as one of the key players in the Program Review process (p. 207). The new editor of the series, Gene Swimmer, provides a useful background to Program Review and 91 a commentary on the three Liberal budgets to date. A theme in his overview, echoed in several chapters, is that while “subsidiarity” of government to private initiatives offered the promise of a change in governance, Program Review has instead stressed efficiency and affordability above all. Nevertheless, this book does not broach policy alternatives: Swimmer notes almost laconically that the corporate sector “has succeeded in convincing government that control of the deficit must be achieved through spending cuts rather than tax increases” (p. 33). This avoids criticism from those such as the Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives who claim that measures such as increased corporate tax or taxation on financial transactions have not been seriously considered, let alone adopted by the Liberal administration. The contributors to this book are, as usual, among the leading analysts of Canadian public policy. All adhere to the theme of tracing the impact of Program Review. Doern explains the program cuts in Industry Canada while Toner accounts for the surprising resilience of Environment Canada’s budget. Bakvis makes concise work of the lengthy and politically convoluted process of subordinating Axworthy’s Social Security Review to the broader Program Review, which in turn was obstructed by the sensitivity of UI reform. Maslove takes just 16 pages to discuss the Canada Health and Social Transfer and only highlights the key issues of downloading the federal deficit, but raises an interesting proposal to make the CHST a conditional revenue-sharing scheme, so as to preserve some federal leverage in an increasingly decentralized political economy (p. 297). Going beyond departmental specifics, the theme of deficit reduction is pursued to some interesting conclusions in Lee and Hobb’s chapter on the process and politics of trimming the public service. Cardozo’s chapter on the reduction in support for public advocacy groups is a valuable reminder that downsizing has implications for governance and for the political economy which transcend the particularities of pain in the civil service. CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 92 Reviews/Comptes rendus The seventeenth edition of How Ottawa Spends should achieve its goal of generating informed debate about agendas and priorities in the era of deficit reduction. We need companion volumes on how the provincial governments have been forced or have elected to pursue deficit and debt reduction objectives with apparently similar underlying assumptions. MALCOLM G RIEVE, Department of Political Science, Acadia University Good Jobs, Bad Jobs, No Jobs: Tough Choices for Canadian Labour Law by Roy J. Adams, Gordon Betcherman and Beth Bilson. Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute, 1995. Pp. vii, 198. $14.95. This volume includes three essays addressing different areas of labour law. The particular issues of concern to each author differ, but all three share the conviction that more extensive labour law can and should be used to shape labour-market opportunities and outcomes. In the first piece, Roy Adams advocates fostering a more cooperative relationship between management and organized labour in Canada. He draws on evidence from the experiences of other countries to support this position, and searches for lessons on how to achieve such a change in Canada’s industrial relations system. Unfortunately, he does not provide a very satisfactory bridge between the rather lengthy historical summaries and the relatively brief lessons he gleans from them, leaving the reader wishing for further elaboration of his reasoning in order to put his conclusions on a firmer footing. Much of this elaboration is available elsewhere in Adams’ writings. Gordon Betcherman begins with a brief but useful summary of Canada’s current labour-market woes: high rates of unemployment, rising earnings inequality, increasing economic insecurity, low levels of private sector training and a deteriorating labour market for youth. These outcomes, he argues, CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, would be ameliorated by policies that encourage firms to choose internal labour-market structures that foster greater worker-firm attachment. The relationship between labour-market policies, the internal labour-market structures chosen by firms, and labour-market outcomes is an important piece of the labour-market policy puzzle that warrants greater attention than it has received. In spite of its simplicity, Betcherman’s framework provides a useful and interesting basis for further consideration of the way policy affects economic insecurity through its influence on firms’ adjustment strategies. Beth Bilson provides a carefully reasoned and articulate argument in favour of using the law to achieve greater equity in the Canadian workplace. Her most difficult challenge lies in confronting two powerful and pervasive economic contentions: that equity policies are unnecessary in market economies because markets are indifferent to gender and race, and that the current economic environment renders further regulation of firms prohibitively expensive. Although she may not persuade many economists, she makes her case with care and breathes some much-needed life into the position that we must take a broader view than is afforded by simple economic models when considering equity legislation in the workplace. Bilson provides a clear statement of what that broader view should incorporate and situates her position nicely in a legal and historical context. The volume concludes with interesting commentaries by John O’Grady, who provides a perspective from organized labour and Roger Phillips, who writes from the perspective of a free market advocate. J ANE F RIESEN , Department of Economics, Simon Fraser University Utilitarianism as a Public Philosophy by Robert E. Goodin. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1995. Pp. xii, 352. Over the past few decades, Robert Goodin has established himself as one of the foremost defenders VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus of utilitarianism in political philosophy, and, in addition, he has published numerous books and articles dealing with specific public policy issues (nuclear disarmament, incomes policy, smoking, the policy implications of environmental degradation, and more). In Utilitarianism as a Public Philosophy, Goodin gathers together 17 previously published articles on assorted topics, adding a new piece in which he defends his distinctive approach to thinking about politics in general and public policy in particular. What is the gist of Goodin’s theoretical position? In short, he defends a variant of utilitarianism, the view that the moral rightness of actions or institutions is determined by consequences, and that consequences themselves are judged by the extent to which they promote happiness for everyone affected. Goodin concedes that utilitarianism is unsatisfactory as a moral guide for individual conduct, but insists that we nonetheless have very good reasons to accept utilitarianism as our guide to public policy making: it is as a public philosophy that utilitarianism finds its natural home. For instance, utilitarianism has been criticized for being excessively impersonal, for denying that we are justified in believing that we have strong personal commitments and local attachments. After all, it tells us simply to maximize happiness, counting each for one and no one for more than one. While this might constitute a strong objection to utilitarianism as an individual moral guide, it tells in favour of the theory when we consider the public sphere: “public servants must not play favourites” (p. 9). Goodin’s argument, played out in Chapters 1 and 4, goes to the heart of the ethical issues at stake and addresses most of the standard objections to utilitarianism as a moral theory. Most importantly, he identifies and attempts to answer the (very different) charges that (i) utilitarianism is too demanding, and that (ii) it is too permissive, since it fails to rule out any act — such as punishing the innocent — before considering the consequences of that act. Some critics will remain unconvinced by Goodin’s replies, but one must admit that both the difficulties and strengths of this 93 approach to political theorizing are clarified enormously. Readers of this journal will be most interested in part four, entitled “Shaping Public Policies,” in which Goodin addresses three large themes: the role and importance of preferences in public policy formation, some arguments for social security, and several important areas of international ethics (patriotism, nuclear weapons, and the environmental crisis). The essays address specific issues, but it is instructive to see them as exemplifying Goodin’s “public” utilitarianism: it must be said that the book constitutes the working out of a coherent moral and political outlook. As an example of Goodin’s argumentative strategy, consider Chapter 14, “Basic Income,” in which he defends an unconditional, universal basic income on the grounds that such a strategy makes fewer presumptions than its condition-based alternatives, and is therefore better able to achieve the goal of benefiting those in need of help. Current means-tested family benefits necessarily make assumptions about social life, and such assumptions are often based on inaccurate sociological claims or on empirical claims rendered false by changing social circumstances. (Consider pension schemes that assume full employment, or social security policies that presuppose stable families within which wealth is shared equitably.) A basic income policy is bound to be minimally presumptuous, thereby averting the injustices produced under alternative schemes. In response to the obvious objection that a basic income benefits undeserving individuals — the lazy able-bodied — Goodin the utilitarian appeals to the relevance of the actual numbers involved: “the harm done by deserving cases being denied benefit by errors that accompany a more discriminating policy are ... worse than is that done by undeserving cases being granted benefits by a less discriminating policy” (p. 241). The book is worth reading both for its general defence of “public” utilitarianism and for its often CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 94 Reviews/Comptes rendus unexpected arguments for specific policy recommendations. CHARLES JONES, Department of Philosophy, University College Cork and London School of Economics and Political Science The Uneasy Case for Equalization Payments by Dan Usher. Vancouver: The Fraser Institute, 1995. Pp. viii, 163. This book is sectioned into five parts. Part one describes the Canadian program of equalization payments. Parts two, three, and four address the three E’s of the equalization formula — equality, efficiency and equity. Part five suggests ways in which the equalization program could be reformed. While there is a general impression amongst most policymakers that equalization payments in Canada have narrowed the distribution of income (inequality), led to increases in national income (efficiency) and improved equity, Professor Usher offers some compelling arguments that seriously challenge these impressions. He argues that the effects of the equalization program are mixed, that there are opposing tendencies and that commonly asserted propositions about the virtues of equalization payments are unproven. In particular, he makes extensive use of arithmetic examples to demonstrate that income transfers from rich provinces to poor provinces may not lead to a transfer of income from rich to poor people. This may be nothing more than a transfer of income from one group of rich people to another group of rich people with very small and incidental benefits for the poor. Further, he notes that the benefits to poor people are likely to be substantially less than if federal equalization payments were targeted directly at the alleviation of poverty. As well, his meticulous and detailed examination of the potential impact of equalization payments on the allocation of labour and other factors of production across provinces, the social cost of taxation, the amount and composition of public expenditures, CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, insurance against province-wide misfortune and administration costs seriously question whether this program has increased the level of national income. He suggests that, at best, the evidence is speculative and inconclusive. It may have led to efficiency improvements or it may not. We simply don’t know! Similarly, his analysis questions whether equalization payments have led to overall improvements in equity. It may have, but it may not have. His hunch is that it has not! Perhaps the most interesting part of this book is the author’s proposed reforms. He argues that any reform of equalization payment cannot be considered in a vacuum. Amongst other things, it must be linked with other policies and programs and may depend on whether Quebec remains part of Canada. With this in mind, he examines five possible changes to the equalization program. First, replacing the current formula which is based on a shortfall in the average tax base with a macro formula based on a shortfall in gross domestic product would, in the author’s view, more likely funnel money to poor provinces and would leave provinces with far less opportunity to influence their equalization revenues through their ability to adjust their tax rates. Second, equalization payments should be financed by taxing rich provinces directly rather than from the general revenues of the federal government. Third, a province should only be eligible for equalization if its average income is substantially less than the Canadian average. His fourth and fifth reforms represent his preferred options and are much more dramatic and potentially interesting. One of them is for a Canada without Quebec. Here, the federal government would assume all ownership of natural resources and accept all responsibility for income distributional programs including health, education, and social welfare. There would be no role for provinces and hence no role for equalization. Local governments would be responsible for local services and the federal government for those services of a more national VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus interest. On the other hand, for a Canada that includes Quebec, the author makes a stronger case for equalization payments although at a level less than currently exists. This rests on the premise that there would be a decentralized federation with provincial jurisdiction over natural resources and a good deal of income redistribution. Professor Usher’s careful, critical, and insightful examination of Canada’s federal-provincial equalization scheme is a “must read” for any student of equalization programs or any policymaker involved in intergovernmental transfers. His neverending and meticulous (some might even say tedious, at times) use of arithmetic examples to illustrate potential inequalities, inefficiencies, and inequities in the existing system sheds considerable light on the potential for problems and the necessity for seriously considering possible reforms. This is not to suggest that his reforms should be adopted; indeed, there are others. What cannot be underscored, however, is the importance of engaging in a detailed and comprehensive examination of the $10 billion program. HARRY K ITCHEN, Department of Economics, Trent University Globalization and the Decline of Social Reform by Gary Teeple. Toronto: Garamond Press, 1995. Pp.ix, 189. $18.95. We live in a transitional time between the nationally based Keynesian welfare state and the emerging self-generating system of the global economy. As a new phase in the development of capitalism the global economy makes national economies, national sovereignty, indeed the nation state, and thereby the possibility of reforming capitalism through social democracy obsolete. Global sovereignty of a form of economic organization — a ruling class of transnational corporate and financial actors — without a corresponding global political authority threatens the world with a new tyranny. Such is Teeple’s thesis. It is argued with impressive 95 cogency and authority, and with some urgency. As a work in political economy by a sociologist, it is extraordinarily well documented with relevant technical literature in economics and political science. A colleague has used it as a text in a fourth-year seminar on Economic Sociology, and I also intend to use it in a similar seminar on the ethics of sociological inquiry in a “globalized” world. The book’s six chapters accomplish three tasks. These are (i) an analytic description of the relationship between capitalism and social democracy in the 1945-70s “interregnum” of advanced Fordist or welfare capitalism known as the Keynesian Welfare State, (ii) an analytic description of the same relationship in post-Fordist or global capitalism since the mid-1970s, including an excellent delineation and deconstruction of the neoliberal policy package that is the ideological counterpart of the material changes in social relations constituting globalization, and (iii) a concluding summary plus outlining of the political dilemmas and possibilities posed by globalization for those seeking a world fit for human beings to live in. Why is the welfare state declining? It was always a “grand compromise” between national capitals and their working classes, designed to offset the worst effects of capitalism and as a bulwark against socialism, and made possible by postwar prosperity and capital’s need for the state in a period of recovery. Though it raised workers’ standard of living, it never seriously reduced economic inequality. Indeed Teeple argues there was a net transfer from workers to the corporate sector (recall Chomsky’s “military Keynesianism” in the US) via the tax system. With the coming of the global economy of “denationalized capital” brought on by well-known technological changes, the huge growth in international trade and investment and concomitant globalization of financial markets, capital no longer needs the compromise. It can find labour and profits anywhere and forces nations to compete for its largesse. Global financial markets become the final arbiter of national economic policies. The familiar downward spiral of CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 96 Reviews/Comptes rendus national economic growth, average rates of profit, corporate taxation, real wages, government revenue, and the corresponding growth of public debt and deficits, structural unemployment, superexploitation, notably of women and children, and general economic inequality set in. control over the ideological and political systems remains a monopoly of the powers that be” (p. 149), and (ii) that “it has been more the poverty of opposition leadership than the will of the people that has prevented this resistance from developing” (p. 150). More than ever, it’s up to you and me. At the same time neoliberal policies are advanced and gradually adopted throughout the world. And what an agenda it is. Founded on the principle of the “primacy of private property rights” it comprises: the market as panacea (translation: corporate concentration and corporate welfare and minimal corporate competition plus opening of non-market property to capital); free economic zones as a model for the global economy; deregulation of national economies; privatization of public corporations; “popular capitalism;” lowering of the corporate share of taxation; reduction of national debt; downsizing of government; restructuring of local government; dismantling of the welfare state; promotion of charities; circumscription of civil liberties, human rights, trade union powers and democracy itself; and the expansion of the “crime control industry” (Nils Christie) to deal with the consequences. Designed to justify and advance the trends in place, neoliberal policies are used to beat down the last bastions of non-private property — from state property in the former second world to communal property in the former third world to public property in the (former?) first world — and open them up to corporate capitalist exploitation. Social democracy, wedded to the increasingly obsolete nation state and a trade union movement in crisis, becomes indistinguishable in power from its opponents. The welfare state disappears. Spectacular profits ensue. PETER EGLIN, Department of Sociology and Anthropology, Wilfrid Laurier University Resistance is everywhere, but lacking organization and often latent. I agree with Teeple (i) that “[b]oth the resistance and the alternatives face enormous odds as long as, first, the current system continues to provide a tolerable material existence for the majority [but outside the “first” world, and increasingly within it, it fails to do this] and, second, CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, Rethinking the Constitution: Perspectives on Canadian Constitutional Reform, Interpretation, and Theory edited by Anthony A. Peacock. Don Mills: Oxford University Press, 1996. Pp. xxix, 286. $26.95. The problem to which this volume is a response is that “no longer is the [Canadian] constitution considered to reflect a permanent order or as maintaining fixed constitutional forms. Rather it is a register of social pressures that must change and adapt to changing circumstances ... The challenge to democracies is to respect constitutional forms” (pp. xii-xiii). The symbol and prime agent of our constitutional malaise is the Charter. That malaise is underlined in the recurring references to our lack of a unifying national idea, the absence of a common myth, that we have no sense of why we exist, and that we have failed to constitute ourselves as a people — in brief, the absence of legitimacy, the very failing the Charter was to redress. The appearance of this volume confirms and consolidates what shrewd observers had already detected, that the Charter’s honeymoon period is over, and that a minority but growing critique of the Charter has a significant academic base. Charter criticisms, including its alleged contribution to our constitutional stalemate, are a healthy sign that the debate we didn’t have in 1980-82 when the Charter’s opponents were vanquished is now taking place. The criticisms are the standard ones — that policy-making power has inappropriately passed to the courts; that judges are poor legislators; that rights VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus are destructive of community; that selfish Charter Canadians frustrate the possibility of constitutional reform; that the Charter has become a policy instrument wielded by interest groups (Watson, p. 89 — the Court Party of Morton and Knopff, ch. 4) to expand state intervention; that the law schools with their trendy hostility to “liberal constitutionalism” are the intellectual villains generating the ideologies that have set us adrift (Martin, ch. 13); and more generally that we are asking too much of the constitution (Manfredi, ch. 3). Canadians who think that we took a wrong turn in 1982 when the Constitution Act, including the Charter, came into effect, and who in particular see the Charter as an unwelcome departure from the time-honoured principle of parliamentary supremacy will be delighted at this book’s appearance. Those who feel more generally that our quarter-century of constitutional introspection has almost destroyed us, and who sense a weakening of our moral fibre, even a sickness of the Canadian soul will nod appropriately at many of the (often purple) passages. Before succumbing to the book’s overall message, however, they should reflect on the one essay that disturbs the general tenor of the volume. In “Trudeau’s Moral Vision,” H.D. Forbes applauds Trudeau’s courage and vision manifested in his policy triumvirate of bilingualism, multiculturalism, and the Charter — by which he “called upon Canadians to embark on a noble experiment for the sake of increasing mankind’s political knowledge” (p. 34). The book is divided into three parts — Constitutional Reform (three articles), Constitutional Interpretation (seven articles), and Constitutional Theory (three articles). However, in spite of its title, the “Quebec problem” receives scant attention; and in spite of its apparent breadth, the main focus of the book is on the Charter. Rethinking the Constitution will upset many of the “chattering classes” who are its targets. They 97 should remember that, for scholars, our critics are our best friends. A LAN C AIRNS , School of Policy Studies, Queen’s University The Bloc by Manon Cornellier. Toronto: James Lorimer & Co., 1995. Pp. xi, 180. $19.95. The success of the Bloc Québécois and the Reform Party in the 1993 Canadian election can be seen as significant on several grounds, including consideration of issues such as the perverse effects of our firstpast-the-post electoral system and the possible end of the traditional parties on the left and right. Most crucially, however, the success of Reform and the Bloc represents a significant escalation in the clash between Quebec and the rest of Canada over Quebec’s position in, and possible exit from, the Canadian federation. The Bloc’s raison d’etre, of course, is to promote the breakup of the country, although Reform’s claim to want to save the country is to a considerable degree belied by its hardline position on provincial equality. Any work, therefore, that examines the paradoxical role played by one of the two new protagonists, the Bloc, the political party that is at one and the same time Her Majesty’s Loyal Opposition and an important instrument of the sovereignist movement in Quebec, is especially welcome. How that role is played, the centrality of leadership, the nature of the Bloc’s electoral support, and the long-term viability of a party based on the premise of a single albeit very broad issue are all areas that warrant scrutiny. In these respect The Bloc, by Manon Cornellier, parliamentary correspondent with Canadian Press, will likely disappoint a number of political scientists and others. It lacks the kind of analysis of the Bloc’s electoral base that voting behaviour specialists, for example, might expect in a book seeking to explain the origins and success of the new party. Furthermore, no effort is made to place the Bloc in the context of linguistic or nationalist parties in other CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 98 Reviews/Comptes rendus settings, Belgium, for example, where similar developments have occurred. Nor is there much theorizing about party and party system change. Nonetheless, there is much that is valuable in the book, and anyone seeking to understand the party’s present dilemma and future fate will find reading it worthwhile. Written before the October 1995 referendum and Bouchard’s departure for Quebec City, Cornellier is remarkably prescient. She notes how precariously dependent the party has been on Bouchard’s profile and leadership, and how in good part Bouchard’s and the general movement’s success resided in his capacity to present and put Quebec’s case to English Canada, using Parliament as the stage. She discusses the possibility of the party coming unstuck through defections and early retirements should the referendum fail and describes the individual contrasts within the party. In many respects ideological differences between Bloc MPs on economic issues, for example, are much greater than those found within the large catch-all Liberal Party. The book also provides a useful corrective to the notion that the Bloc is simply the federal wing of the Parti Québécois (PQ). While officials in both parties essentially “came from the same mold” (p. 76) and while, according to polling data, the views of supporters are very similar, the Bloc has been able to attract new support. Thus, when the Bloc and the PQ compared membership lists it was discovered that 60 to 65 percent of Bloc members were not members of the PQ (p. 78). In addition, the Bloc provided Bouchard with an organizational power base to challenge Jacques Parizeau over the issue of soft versus hard nationalism. In brief, although this relatively short book lacks depth and detailed analysis, it provides useful insights on the several issues germane to an understanding of the role of the Bloc and where it, and the country as a whole, might be going. HERMAN BAKVIS, Department of Political Science/ School of Public Administration, Dalhousie University CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, The Market Meets Its Match - Restructuring the Economies of Eastern Europe by Alice H. Amsden, Jacek Kochanowicz and Lance Taylor. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1994. Pp. 250. Contrary to the common illusion, economics is a laboratory science — with numerous experiments around the world — that should provide the basis for understanding economic systems. The market reforms in Eastern Europe are an important recent experiment, from which much can be learned. In contrast with medical science, where the evaluation of experiments is conducted with utmost scepticism and where not only the results of a therapy but also its side-effects are critically evaluated, the assessment of economic experiments is often done by those who have intellectual or ideological interests in drawing certain conclusions, quite often by those who have been directly involved in policy reforms as advisors or advocates. Therefore, the book by Amsden, Kochanowicz and Taylor should be regarded as an important event. The authors are sympathetic to the general objectives of market reforms, have direct knowledge of the problems encountered, yet are quite critical about the assessment of the policies adopted. It should also be stressed that the authors are not on the “fringes” of economic science, but respected scholars from leading academic institutions (Amsden is professor at MIT, Taylor at the New School for Social Research, and Kochanowicz is professor at the University of Warsaw, with a number of very respectable publications) and their book has been enthusiastically received by Wassily Leontief, Robert Heilbroner, Janos Kornai, and Lester Thurow. A particularly interesting aspect of Eastern European economic reforms stems from the fact that the reforms were, to a very large extent, guided by Western economists and that the ideas of neoliberal economics have been almost totally accepted by both the policymakers and the intellectual establishment of the countries concerned. In this important respect VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus Eastern Europe differed very much from China, where some inputs from the Western advisors were adopted selectively. Because of the impact of the current “mainstream” Western economics was so great and so direct, the assessment of the results is not only important for the understanding of Eastern Europe but has a number of potential implications for the evaluation of our prevailing theories of economic policy. The main theme of criticism by Amsden et al. can be summarized as follows. Proposed and largely applied therapy was not preceded by an adequate diagnosis of the situation. In fact, little was known — and even less understood — of the actual working of the communist system. To some extent this can be explained by the fact that a critical review of the system was subdued by political censorship and thus appeared in a very fragmentary manner. Nonetheless many important contributions did appear and should not have been ignored. Even less excusable was the fact that the Western advisors and national policymakers tended to ignore industry and enterprise studies which were commissioned during the early reform phases. Amsden, who participated in a number of such studies provides an ample and depressing evidence of such disregard for facts about the economies to be reformed. There was a general feeling that a major problem of the enterprises in Eastern Europe was overstaffing and high labour costs. In fact, although labour was used ineffectively, total labour costs were not excessive, because of relatively low wages (e.g., wage costs in Poland in 1990 were lower than in India, Philippines, Kenya, and Egypt). Therefore, the primary effect of the depression of real wages, which was supposed to make Eastern European industries more competitive, was the rapid shrinking of the domestic demand, which could not be compensated by increases in export earnings. Furthermore it was not realistic to expect that the reduction of overstaffing in major state enterprises could be 99 compensated by an increase in activities in the emerging private sector. The consequence of the policy adopted was a major surge of unemployment, with the subsequent increase of fiscal burden and ad hoc subsidies. In general, the difficulties of transition were vastly underestimated and projections made by the new governments, as well as by international institutions, were grossly overoptimistic. One could have excused lack of experience of the national governments, but the international experience related to much milder economic reforms in Latin America provided ample evidence of the depressions that follow radical changes. On the other hand, the authors tend to be rather unfair regarding anti-inflation policies in Eastern European countries and ignore the existence of “inflationary overhang,” which particularly affected Poland and even more so Russia. This “inflationary overhang” (which in Poland was due to desperate price and wage policies of the collapsing government) had to be dealt with immediately and under conditions of disorganized administration, which meant that only crude measures could be adopted (a later and more sophisticated Russian monetary reform collapsed through the absence of adequate administration). The authors devote a great deal of space to the subject of industrial restructuring. Here, their criticism is well founded both theoretically and empirically. The accepted doctrine was that the opening of the market, the strict adherence to the rules of the price mechanism, and the privatization will create a viable, even if not optimal, industrial structure. This doctrine lacked any serious theoretical basis and its application showed it to produce adverse results. For example, during the communist regime, there existed a strict administrative boundary between industrial R&D and enterprises. Whether the existence of autonomous R&D institutes made sense or not was a relatively minor institutional problem, as long as R&D and the enterprises were under the same control; it definitely did not make sense under the conditions of market economy. CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 100 Reviews/Comptes rendus However, instead of integrating R&D with the enterprises, the old system was maintained, depriving the industries of its technological backup. This proved to be easy to overcome in the case of “new industries” (particularly electronics), but was fatal for the old ones. Secondly, the success of the reforms required filling the “investment gaps” as a part of restructuring and quality improvement programs — this was not done. Instead the accepted doctrine was “to force the inefficient enterprises into bankruptcies” — a strange policy, when one considers that in the mature capitalist economies all sorts of “restructuring” and “protection” devices are built into bankrupty laws to prevent collapse of potentially viable enterprises (the experience of Chrysler which was supported until the K-models could be introduced should have served as an example — but doctrine prevailed over experience). Furthermore, under the pressure of international institutions and Western advisors, ministries dealing with industries were dismantled and instead of a modernized “Ministry of Industry and International Trade” a weak “Ministry of International Cooperation” was established in Poland. The authors are correct in criticizing “privatization schemes” (other than the first wave of privatization, which made sense and was successful) as well as the naive faith in foreign investments as the engine of progress. Privatization in Eastern Europe, without a developed stock market and in the absence of domestic capital, was infinitely more difficult than in the West and such difficulties were misunderstood. The problem was not only valuation of the enterprises to be transferred, but also selection of responsible owners. Also attracting foreign investors proved to be more difficult than anticipated. Stories about inefficiency in the existing enterprises, poor work habits, and bad management — illustrated by horrific examples of obsolete production lines (incidently, similar examples can be found in Iacocca’s description of Chrysler), had a deterrent effect on foreign investors. In fact, a serious inflow of foreign investments occurred — first to the Czech Republic, then to Hungary, and at present to Poland — after the first foreign investors found the CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, conditions there much better than described, which provided encouragement for other firms to enter the market. The story of foreign investments also contains interesting lessons: later successes have been largely due to the establishment of credible democratic institutions and demonstrated ability to deal with social and political problems of transition, while the major obstacle proved to be lack of adequate administrative apparatus; thus pro-foreign investment policies were nullified by administrative chaos and lack of clear lines of responsibility. In general, lack of attention to administrative, institutional, social and political factors was one of the major failings of foreign advisors in developing a transition strategy. Obviously, the book by Amsden et al. is not the final assessment of the Eastern European experiment; it also lacks analysis of the recoveries in 199496 and of the emergence of an efficient financial administration in the Czech Republic and Poland. Nonetheless it is one of the first serious critical attempts to test the validity of the prevailing doctrines in real-life situations and as such it is definitely worth reading, preferably in conjunction with other studies on Chinese reforms and critical reviews of restructuring in Third World countries. KONRAD W. STUDNICKI-GIZBERT , Quebec High Stakes and Low Incomes: Canada and the Development Banks by Roy Culpeper and Andrew Clark. Ottawa: The North-South Institute, 1994. Pp. 109. If you have always wanted to know what multilateral development banks (MDBs) are and what is in them for Canada but never dared to ask, read this wellresearched little book whose authors are with the North-South Institute, an Ottawa-based non-profit corporation that conducts policy-relevant research on relations between developing and developed countries. MDBs are international public financial institutions whose primary function is to lend to developVOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus ing member-country governments their capital being subscribed by both developed and developing countries. The five MDBs which are under scrutiny are the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (better known as the World Bank), the African Development Bank, the Asian Development Bank, the Inter-American Development Bank, and the Caribbean Development Bank. Canada is a major shareholder in all of them and has a seat on the board of executive directors of each one. Traditionally, the MDBs’ lending was for specific development projects, but since the early 1980s, an increasing portion has gone to support structural adjustment programs in exchange for policy reforms at both the macro- and microeconomic levels. The loans are funded by borrowing on the international financial markets and are thus made at nonconcessional, that is, market, terms which disqualify them as Official Development Assistance (ODA). However, each of the MDBs has a “soft window” which makes loans available on a concessional basis to its least-developed members. In this case, donor countries are directly responsible for providing the resources that are to be lent, these contributions being part of their ODA. Over the years, the five MDBs have mobilized no less than 20 percent of global net resource transfers to developing countries. They also shaped, and in particular the World Bank, what might be called the philosophy of development assistance. As such, they can hardly be ignored. The relatively strong involvement of Canada in the MDBs’ funding, especially at the soft windows of the African and Asian Banks, and activity can be explained by the fact that the MDBs’ development objectives were never all that different from those of our country (originally the build-up of basic infrastructures and food security and, since then, poverty alleviation, environment preservation and policy reforms), by the genuine concern of Canada in making the MDBs effective and responsible lending institutions and, last but not least, by the multiplier effect on the Canadian economy of the contributions made. For example, over the 1986-92 period, each dollar contributed generated domestically 92 cents 101 through MDB contracts awarded to Canadian firms (as opposed to 68 cents for Canadian aid in general). Let it also be reminded that Canada’s contributions are largely made by the issue of notes, and what is considered as ODA, according to the accounting conventions in use, is the amount issued and not the amount encashed (which can take up to ten years). As correctly pointed out by the authors: “because it does not cost a budgetary penny to issue an MDB note, one could argue there is a built-in bias in favour of the MDB channel when a country wishes to quickly increase its ODA levels” and more so, of course, in times of budget restraint. Despite its involvement, the influence of Canada at the MDBs, though not ineffective, has never been overwhelming. For example, Canada was successful in 1988 at making environment protection a new and major dimension in the analysis of World Bank projects, but achieved little results at promoting gender issues at the Asian Bank or improving management transparency at the African one.1 Moreover, though Canadian firms have obtained a fair amount of MDB contracts through international competitive bidding — especially in the field of engineering — and thanks to various trust funds held by Canada at these institutions — mainly for consultancies on project identification and preparation — other countries have generally been more aggressive in their procurement lobbying as, for instance, Korea at the African Development Bank (where it is represented at the board of directors by ... Canada). The authors attribute this limited Canadian influence mainly to the weak presence of Canadian nationals on the MDBs’ staff and to a lack of accountability of MDB management towards their shareholders, including Canada. Management, in practice, has control over vital information, project selection, and operations confining shareholders’ representatives, that is, the executive directors, mainly to the discussion of general policy issues. Accountability has not been greater towards the Canadian public. The report on MDBs’ annually submitted to our House of Commons does not em- CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 102 Reviews/Comptes rendus phasize key issues and is even blatantly incomplete. The only MDB it reviews is the World Bank, the four other banks being omitted, though information exists on them but appears to be restricted for official use only. Finally, the Canadian executive directors rarely meet the Canadian public to explain what MDBs do and try to achieve (when such meetings took place in the past, they were generally limited to the presentation of guidelines on MDBs’ procurement procedures to the Canadian business community). As a general conclusion, the authors share the view of most bilateral donors that the MDBs, despite their shortcomings, remain effective vehicles for development financing, “well positioned to take on a growing proportion of overall aid flows, at the expense of bilateral donors.” Not surprisingly, they call for more MDB accountability and suggest that Canada allies itself with the Nordic countries, the Netherlands, and other “like-minded” donors in an effort to press for such improvements. In this reviewer’s mind, there subsist three questions: Is Canada willing to put additional money into multilateral financing at a time when its government seems to consider foreign aid more and more as an instrument of its external and commercial policies, the implementation of which is essentially bilateral in nature? Given the present trend of government decentralization observed all over the world, how well prepared are the MDBs to go into lending not only at the central government level of the borrowing countries, as it has mainly been the case until now, but also at their subnational levels (provinces, municipalities, etc.)? In view of the large programs of public enterprise divestiture implemented in many borrowing countries, the MDBs will have to lend increasingly to the private sector. But, in that case, what will make them basically different in the long run from ordinary commercial banks with international ventures? Culpeper and Clark may want to make, in a future up-dated edition of their very useful book, more room for discussion on these issues. CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, NOTE 1 The book was written, to our knowledge, before the appointment to the presidency of the African Development Bank of Mr. Omar Kabbaj, a Moroccan national. Mr. Kabbaj has since undertaken the rather perilous task of making the bank, which had largely become a haven for various rent-seekers, a more operational and responsible institution. A N D R É M A RT E N S , Centre de recherche et développement en économique et Département de sciences économiques, Université de Montréal The Decline of Deference: Canadian Value Change in Cross-National Perspective by Neil Nevitte. Peterborough: Broadview Press, 1996. Pp.xx, 369. $26.95. This is an important book. It asks big-picture questions about what is happening in Canadian society and indeed in the Western world. It overwhelms the reader with enormous pools of survey data and manipulates variables to tease out multiple explanations in sophisticated analyses. It is amazing in its breadth ranging from substantial discussions of family and workplace to religion and polity. But the book is also provocative. It prompts the reader to raise questions about the adequacy of particular survey measures and the interpretation of comparative data. It breaks new ground with a thesis that both challenges and supplements existing knowledge. In sum, The Decline of Deference cannot be ignored and will be a benchmark referent for a long time. The data for the book comes from the 1981 European Values System Survey and the 1990 World Values Survey largely coordinated by Ronald Englehart of the University of Michigan. Consequently, 44 countries are represented in the database, though Nevitte restricts his discussion to the 12 advanced industrial states of Western Europe (France, West Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Denmark, Belgium, Spain), the British Isles (Britain, Ireland, and Northern Ireland), and North America (Canada and the United States). The survey VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus questions are listed at the back of the book, but there is no discussion in the book itself on methodological issues — particularly, as they relate to the measures adopted or their interpretations. The reader is referred to other writers in this regard and the data is taken at face value. It is important to make this point because, as Nevitte himself points out in the last chapter, national context is indeed a significant factor, and a nation-specific explanation is particularly important when the results suggest a convergence between different national entities. The first chapter makes the case that the 1980s was a particularly volatile decade in Canada as evidenced by the debate on constitutional issues and free trade but also including other issues such as the de-alignment of the party system, the vitality of environmental issues, the women’s movement, and multicultural concerns. While Nevitte acknowledges that most of these issues were unresolved by the end of the decade, he argues that the 1980s was a decade of significant value change. It is indeed debatable whether the 1980s was any more stormy than any other decade (e.g., what about the 1960s?) for, at this point, there is no baseline data to prove that value change is unique to any particular decade. What Nevitte does have is data to demonstrate that responses differed in 1990 and 1981, and he chooses to refer to these as a value shift. In actuality, he is measuring opinion and behaviour which is then wrapped together and labelled “values” — a slippery and often controversial concept which has divided social scientists for many years. Consequently, the thesis of this book will likely be debated for some time because it marshals evidence to argue that a fundamental shift has occurred or is occurring. Providing Canadian and cross-national empirical evidence of this change in itself makes this book a landmark. What is less developed and virtually ignored is how or why other countries have experienced these value shifts. In other words, is there anything uniquely Canadian about this decade of turmoil (as he refers to it) or is it a global process that just happens to be more advanced in the nations under review? 103 In evaluating this value shift, Nevitte begins with the political domain where he finds ample evidence of partisan de-alignment, declining levels of voter turnout, declining confidence in governmental institutions and yet paradoxically greater interest in politics, and the emergence of non-traditional forms of political participation (e.g., petitions, demonstrations, new movements, etc.). In the economic domain, Nevitte finds increasing support for meritocratic principles, shifts to self-actualization in employment rather than the old work ethic, and greater demand for employee participation in decision making. In issues of morality, he sifts evidence showing weakening authority of traditional churches, greater moral permissiveness, higher levels of tolerance, and greater egalitarianism in spousal and parent-child relations. In spite of the variations, Nevitte finds that the direction of this shift is the same in all 12 countries and that background variables such as age and education level are the most powerful predictors. In other words, the younger and better educated the respondent, the more likely this value change becomes evident. Inglehart’s distinction between materialism (preoccupation with material security) and post-materialism (preoccupation with belonging, selfesteem, and quality of life issues) is also highly correlated with this value shift where post-materialism represents the world view of the younger generation. Most central to Nevitte’s argument is the provocative idea that the value shift which he describes is not merely a matter of lifecycle, but that this is a generationally driven permanent change. He argues that values like ideologies are generationally driven and that this shift has enormous implications. Does this mean that our societies are doomed to increasing turmoil and instability he asks? Or, how do we restore faith in governments, institutions, and leaders? Nevitte finds hope in the increased interest and more knowledgeable capacity of citizens to deal with these things — albeit in a less authoritarian or topdown manner than in the past. Three general arguments are proposed to explain his perceptions of the value shift. He finds little CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 104 Reviews/Comptes rendus evidence of support for the continentalist American influence argument or for the impact of New Canadians on changing Canadian values. Instead, he finds more evidence to support the late industrialism argument whereby structural shifts (e.g., workforce changes, education levels) which are concurrent in all of the 12 countries produce similar value transformations. Yet Nevitte is very careful in the concluding chapter to avoid simplistic or deterministic explanations, and acknowledges the importance of structural differences warning that the issue of values leading or values reflecting structural change remains an unresolved issue. So what is the primary contribution of the book? From a Canadian perspective, Nevitte argues that this value shift challenges the entrenched image promoted by the variants of the counter-revolution thesis that Canadians are passive, conservative, orderdriven, and elite directed, often encapsulated in the word deference. While Nevitte would not go as far as Peter Newman who describes the shift as from “deference to defiance,” he does argue that deference no longer characterizes Canadians because of the new empowerment of individual citizens. The only problem is that the shift is not unique to Canadians and also characterizes the populations of other advanced industrial states. Does this convergence suggest that there is nothing unique about Canadian values? Nevitte provides ample evidence on a wide range of items that there is both convergence and divergence on specific matters. In fact, the book is a significant comprehensive contribution to the debate with S.M. Lipset on Canadian-American differences. In contrast to Lipset, Nevitte provides data to show that Canadians are not more deferential to authority than Americans and that indeed Canadians are among the most protest-oriented of all advanced industrial states. Or, instead of Lipset’s thesis of American exceptionalism, Nevitte finds evidence of North American exceptionalism in support of meritocratic principles in economic value orientations in comparison to Western Europe. The thesis, however, still leaves the CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, reader with questions about what all of this means about the distinctive features of Canadian society. Perhaps Nevitte’s work convinces us of the complexity of any answer. There is really something for everyone in this book. If you are interested in free trade, nationalism, work habits, religion, family, politics, ecology — there are data on all of these topics, and more data is available for secondary analysis. Nevitte has made a major contribution to Canadian scholarship through the provision of the database, and his insights will undoubtedly stimulate discussion and debate for years to come. In fact, he has invited us to do so. HARRY H. HILLER, Department of Sociology, University of Calgary The Persistence of Unemployment: Hysteresis in Canadian Labour Markets by Stephen R.G. Jones. Montreal and Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University Press, 1995. Pp.xii, 170. $42.95. This book by Stephen Jones is a useful contribution to our understanding of unemployment, particularly unemployment in Canada. It is a study of how persistently unemployment can be affected by even temporary shocks — an oil price rise or a sudden slowing of the money supply — that hit the economy from time to time. In the limited case of hysteresis or path dependence, the temporary shock can have a permanent effect on the equilibrium, or natural, unemployment rate where the economy eventually tends to stabilize. Jones begins by surveying the leading theories of unemployment persistence and hysteresis. These provide reasons why equilibrium unemployment might be affected by the past history of actual unemployment. Among the reasons are various bargaining theories, underinvestment in physical capital, workers’ loss of skills in prolonged recessions, workers’ discouragement, employers’ biases against VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus the long-term unemployed, and distortionary effects of unemployment insurance programs. Jones also looks at theories of matching, search behaviour or other mechanisms behind macroeconomic coordination that can generate multiple economic equilibria, some of which could be high-unemployment equilibria. Two chapters are then devoted to reviewing the existing international and Canadian evidence on hysteresis in labour markets. Methodologies alternate between univariate or multivariate studies, and microeconomic or macroeconomic studies. Jones finds the international evidence “at best mixed,” and the Canadian evidence “conflicting and patchy.” The remainder of the book presents a more detailed and new appraisal of the evidence on hysteresis in Canadian labour markets. He agrees with Bank of Canada researchers that hysteresis is “emphatically not supported” by macroeconomic evidence and that the only Canadian study presenting such empirical support is marred by a total lack of robustness. 105 porary costs and permanent benefits of disinflation, and to address the problem of unemployment persistence in the range of very low rates of inflation we have begun to experience in the 1990s. P I E R R E F O RT I N , Département d’économique, Université du Québec à Montréal Policy Studies in Canada: The State of the Art edited by Laurent Dobuzinskis, Michael Howlett and David Laycock. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1996. Pp.vii, 442. $24.95. This book presents 19 survey articles by 21 academics in an effort to summarize the “art, craft and science” of policy analysis in Canada. I approached this collection from the perspective of a practising government policy analyst and advisor, with a research background in multidisciplinary policy study. I hoped the volume would provide me with a new and broader understanding of various alternate approaches to policy studies. I was disappointed. Jones goes on to investigate large Canadian microdata sets for the presence of hysteresis. He gets “mixed” evidence of a small degree of duration dependence among the unemployed, but nothing that could be of macroeconomic significance. Finally, he finds no clear indication of increasing returns in the job-worker matching process that could lead to high unemployment multiple equilibria. The articles are grouped into four sections. Part I examines the 30-year evolution, study and approaches to policy studies while Part II outlines the practice of policy studies in and outside universities in Canada. Although the articles provide some useful context, they suffer from a lack of concrete examples from actual policy studies (which is partly, but not totally, offset by the extensive bibliography of recent studies). The study is very convincing that full hysteresis (or 100 percent persistence) was not a characteristic of industrial countries over the period 1960-90. It reassures central bankers that, starting from inflation rates between 5 and 20 percent, permanent reductions in inflation can be engineered through temporary increases in unemployment. However, it does not determine whether such a disinflation policy is socially worthwhile. It remains for others to pin down the exact degree of unemployment persistence (if less than 100 percent), to obtain more reliable quantitative comparisons between the tem- Part III on contemporary approaches to Canadian policy studies was perhaps the greatest disappointment. Many of the articles appeared to be almost deliberately crafted to exclude non-specialists — the authors focused on their highly technical and specialized theoretical approaches and made no obvious effort to translate for non-specialists or practitioners. The works on rational choice theory and discourse analysis provide little insight for those not already familiar with their approaches. The chapters on network analysis and comparative policy studies, in contrast, should provide practitioners CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 106 Reviews/Comptes rendus with a useful perspective on the theoretical bases, strengths, and weaknesses of their approaches. The final section provides two short but pointed analyses of the prospects for policy studies. Nevertheless, the analyses miss a few critical points. As a provincial policy advisor, I was somewhat dismayed to find that I had to read to the sixteenth chapter and the three-hundredth page to find the first significant reference to policy analysis of provincial or local issues. Based on this survey, the bulk of policy analyses would appear to have focused on national issues. If Pal and Simeon are seriously looking for areas of comparative advantage, Canada would seem a logical leader in policy studies of subnational issues (and not simply federalprovincial relations). I believe Bruce Doern points out the fatal flaw in this volume. He concludes his introductory survey article on the art, craft, and science of policy studies with the caution that “policy studies must be a profoundly interdisciplinary enterprise if it is to flourish.” In spite of the repeated references to the critical role in policy studies for economists and other social scientists, the contributions to this volume are drawn almost exclusively from the political science discipline. PETER W.B. PHILLIPS, Agricultural Economics, University of Saskatchewan The Face of the Nation: Immigration, the State, and the National Identity by Keith Fitzgerald. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1996. Pp.xii, 285. $39.50. Keith Fitzgerald argues that one of the primary policy tools a nation state has at its disposal to portray its national face is a well articulated immigration policy. This is no doubt true; witness the vitriolic immigration debates based on ethnicity in Italy, Germany, France, and Nordic Europe where the face is well worn with deeply embedded cultural furrows. But how could one presume to explain the political CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, motivations for an immigration policy in newly settled regions such as the United States or Canada? Moreover, Fitzgerald faces an even more daunting task since he attempts to explain or rationalize the underlying political forces which shaped immigration policy in the United States; a country which in essence maintains three conflicting immigration policies. The primary entry gate or the so-called US “front door” is a legislated policy based upon family reunification which can best be described as a quintessential example of Max Weber’s “iron cage” of bureaucracy in the extreme. The “back door” for US immigration is a term used by Fitzgerald to describe the movement from Mexico to the United States. This entry gate represents an apparent total collapse of statist-based immigration policy given the large number of illegal or undocumented immigrants that enter through this doorway. This flow makes a mockery of Congressional inspired quotas and enforcement initiatives. Finally a third entry door — perhaps the side door — is available to refugees, and it opens or closes depending upon US foreign policy or military failures. The author claims to have a revised version of political institutional theory to explain this apparently contradictory three-door entry scheme. Under Fitzgerald’s revised or updated institutional theory, an argument is made that each successive historical epoch of US immigration policy is a by-product of institutions that interest groups lobbied for in the more or less distant past. Two critical points must be made about the efficacy of this theoretical paradigm. First, an explanation of the current state of US immigration policy based upon a lagged distribution of past events begs for a complete theoretical paradigm for the earlier period. Fitzgerald clearly does not provide us with this initial or historically based comprehensive model. Next, attempting to explain US immigration policy without recognizing periodic outbursts of national xenophobia fostered by “know nothings” in the nineteenth century or Pat Buchanan in the twentieth century is to ignore the unfortunate but persistent element of racism in US politics and immigration policy in particular. VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus In sum, this reader can only recommend this book to specialists in comparative immigration policy or to those who are genuinely intrigued by the absence of a coherent immigration policy in the largest immigration-receiving nation in the world. DON J. DEVORETZ, Department of Economics, Simon Fraser University Ontario Hydro at the Millennium: Has Monopoly’s Moment Passed? edited by Ronald J. Daniels. Montreal and Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University Press, 1996. Pp.xiii, 409. $19.95. Has monopoly’s millennium passed? Among the participants in this symposium sponsored by Ontario Hydro — the monopoly itself — only Myron Gordon defends a system delivering, in Stephen Probyn’s words, “power at whatever it costs Hydro.” If Gordon cries hold, enough, his discussants’ sword is in their voice, especially in Probyn’s observation that “the President of Hydro has stated that deregulation is coming — for sure...” A more appropriate subtitle of this lengthy volume might be “How might monopoly pass at this moment?” There are few brown-outs in these pages; I have discerned but two major ones. The first is not having a detailed summary of the ten useful papers and of the uneven comments. The editor’s introduction is quick. It gives no hint that the deck of paper topics has been well shuffled. There is, however, no difficulty in dividing the issues addressed among labour, environment, and industrial structure. Ronald Daniels and Michael Trebilcock provide a very helpful triplet of models of demonopolization. All involve divestiture of Hydro’s generating assets, perhaps gradually for nuclear assets through normal depreciation, and reduction of the corporation to a transmission grid. (Public or private, to them it matters little.) Model I envisages competitive access to the grid for private domestic producers and importers. Model II allows for wholesale contract- 107 ing between large producers and consumers or distributors, with the grid serving as common carrier and with the new Hydro acting as in Model I with respect to retail consumers. Model III allows for direct retail contracting. The authors perceive Model III as the ultimate goal, with Model II as a waystation. The papers by Adonis Yatchew and Hudson Janisch also address the structural and regulatory issues and can profitably be read in conjunction with that of Daniels and Trebilcock. The structural subproblems include the pricing of access (by generators or else by consumers) to the grid and what to do about stranded capital, nuclear facilities whose high costs will preclude the recovery of book value after monopoly passes. According to British experience as well as to reflection, even successful nuclear facilities will be very difficult to unload to the private sector at any price, because of regulatory uncertainty. O Canada, thou art not entirely unlike the Thane of Glamis: What thou wouldst highly, that wouldst thou liberally. Therefore, in this industry, pricing is a central issue. Neil Freeman admits that “an economist could spell this out in more detail than I.” The want of economic analysis of the structural issues is the book’s other brown-out. Daniels and Trebilcock’s valiant attempt will not allay the public’s apparent, if unjustified, fear of higher electricity bills and cynicism about executives’ compensation. There is no real review of British experience with privatization. There is no attempt to deal with the many types of cross subsidization inherent in the present model of “power at cost-plus” (Karl Wahl’s phrase), nor to come to grips with the issues of access pricing. Indeed, until Janisch’s challenge, there is very little reference to the obvious benchmark, which is both more advanced in dealing with all these issues and arguably more complicated: telecommunications. Inescapably for a land with a political superiority complex, the requisite deference to the political is evident. A discussant from Hydro-Québec strikes CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 108 Reviews/Comptes rendus a chord with some by raising a California bungalow syndrome: despite these bungalows’ aesthetic appeal, he claims, it would be inappropriate “to build them, with their slippery courtyard tiles,” in our cold climate. Rather, home-grown solutions are to be preferred to global, imported ones. One might as easily ponder a Quebec duplex syndrome: exterior main staircases of wrought iron spiralling to the second storey, in our cold climate. No, where technologically feasible, competition is the universal generator of the wealth that will afford us, if we wish, expression of idiosyncratic preferences. Still, there may be differences in local situations. Yatchew points to a transitional advantage that Canada’s public systems (inadvertently) may have over California’s regulated monopoly: it will be easier to separate generation and transmission into independent corporate forms without having to disentangle private, vertically integrated firms. The working of any of Daniels’ and Trebilcock’s three models would benefit from this feature of our history. Yatchew avers that making the correct regulatory and policy transition would be of great social benefit. For Janisch’s money, though, that may be too much to ask of our political process. Able reviews of environmental regulation, of first conventional then nuclear pollution, are provided by Donald Dewees. His analysis of the problems thrown up by thermal (mainly fossil-fuel-based) generating units is nicely complemented by Andrew Muller’s sophisticated perspective. However, his second paper is weakened by his or his editor’s choice to take a “just-the-facts-ma’am” approach to the existing literature, rather than to tackle a critical review. This problem is largely overcome by some very good commentary by Stephen Allen, Keith Dinnie, and Duane Pendergast, who help to place the environmental problems of nuclear and thermal generation into context. A major transitional problem is what to do about stranded labour. Security may well be mortals’ chiefest enemy. Two chapters by Peter Warrian try CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, to work through the foul-and-fair issue of the passage of a labour force accustomed to monopoly’s privileges toward more toil and trouble. No easy solution emerges for those with monopoly-specific skills. Society may grope about for as long as labour remains stranded, something to make us all shudder who fear the ingredience of the efficient chalice to our own lips. As many participants seem to realize, and a few hope, words to the heat of deeds too cold breath give. Still, this volume will provide benefits not just to Ontario’s consumers and taxpayers, but to those of other provinces where demands for privatization and greater competition will have to be met before long. R OBERT D. C AIRNS , Department of Economics, McGill University Political Economy and the Changing Global Order edited by Richard Stubbs and Geoffrey R.D. Underhill. Toronto: McClelland & Stewart Inc., 1994. Pp.553. $31.95. This volume incorporates 33 chapters that seek to provide an overview of how political and economic forces have interacted over the last several decades in the increasingly international economy. There is a section of chapters that cover the changes in the global economy and another that focuses on specific issues and the international economy. A third section examines regional economies and relates these developments to the international economy. The fourth and final section concentrates on the trade policies of particular states. Overall, one gets an interesting overview of the trends in global economic change and how these trends relate to existing theories about how and why this economic system has evolved. One of the strongest features of the volume and one that all collections of essays by many authors should emulate is the use of “introductions” for each of the four sections. These introductions allow the VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus editors to summarize the readings in the section and to highlight the most important points made by the authors. A second useful feature is the focus on the political implications of increasing global trade, investment, and integration. The volume has many useful and interesting articles. The articles are relatively short; on average they are about 15 pages long including references. They also have a point to make. Maureen Appel Molot’s chapter describes the Canadian move toward free trade in the 1980s and why it occurred. Pierre Martin has an excellent chapter on US “unilateralism” in trade policy, a problem that the WTO and the Uruguay round agreement were supposed to curtail. There are many other valuable articles on a range of topics from the regulation of banking and the role of the IMF to agricultural trade and trade issues in the Asia-Pacific region. While the book was published in 1994, this volume will have value for years to come. As we get past the first phases of trade liberalization, many readers will want to reexamine the hows and whys of the many decisions and assess whether the results have proven beneficial. KENNETH WOODSIDE, Department of Political Studies, University of Guelph Canada and the Global Economy: The Geography of Structural and Technological Change edited by John N.H. Britton. Montreal and Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University Press, 1996. Pp.x, 458. $32.95. This volume is the third to be published in the Canadian Association of Geographers’ Series in Canadian Geography. With contributions from 24 academics and geographers in private consulting, the book is organized thematically and generally covers issues in the decade before Canada entered the North American Free Trade Area. Part one, the open economy, has four chapters providing an international perspective on foreign trade, inward and out- 109 ward direct investment and the Canadian financial system. The new staple economy, also with four chapters, examines the traditional resources sector in an era of increased competition. Much of the focus in the six chapters on manufacturing industry is on the significance of economic and technological change. A fourth section on services and the spatial organization of the economy has four chapters covering transportation, consumer markets, business, and financial services. Three final chapters review political economic questions such as the role of governments and the restructuring of labour markets. All parts of Canada and the Global Economy have a strong public policy interest. Several chapters emphasize the shallowness and vulnerability of economic development not only in the resource periphery but also in core cities such as Toronto. The substantial role of the public sector in the Canadian economy is also clearly developed in various sections of the book. The editor, well-known for his work on technological innovation, makes a strong case for future policy initiatives in the continued development of the national telecommunications network and enhanced training in information technology if the present standard of living is to be maintained. With only eight maps in the book, changing spatial patterns and spatial relationships are not always easy to follow, although tables and graphs offer some guidance. For readers seeking an integrated view of the effects of macro forces of change on provinces, regions, and communities, the absence of any regional chapters leaves a serious void. While recognizing many excellent individual contributions in this volume, the overall effect of the emphasis on thematic issues somehow reduces the colour and texture of the Canadian economic landscape to a high-altitude monochrome vista. G.T. BLOOMFIELD, Department of Geography, University of Guelph CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 110 Reviews/Comptes rendus The New Public Management: Canada in Comparative Perspective by Peter Aucoin. Montreal: Institute for Research on Public Policy, 1995. Pp.vi, 274. Over the last two decades, as Peter Aucoin ably demonstrates in this book, governments in the parliamentary democracies of Canada, the United Kingdom, New Zealand, and Australia have embarked on substantial restructuring of their public management systems. In varying degrees, according to the author, the central governments in these countries have sought to reassert control over the state apparatus in order to direct change in accordance with political priorities, to reconfigure the balance of power within Cabinet government so as to allow greater strategic direction and discipline in public policy management, and to devolve responsibilities for policy implementation in order to improve the performance and responsiveness of government operations (p.4). The general pattern in the restructuring that has subsequently emerged in these countries is what Professor Aucoin refers to as “the new public management.” The analysis focuses on developments in the system of public management in the federal government of Canada. Comparison with experiences in other countries that share our Westminister style of government is used to identify broadly based trends and to generalize the discussion of underlying causal factors, as well as to provide a firmer basis for the author’s well-considered assessment that public management in Canada can be improved by making careful use of selected ideas that have been tried elsewhere. Important developments in the structure of public management in Canada that are investigated in separate chapters include changes in the degree of partisanship of the federal public service, a movement to centralize policy decision making within the executive while, at the same time, devolving administrative authority, responsibility, and accountability for the management of operations, and a heightCANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, ened emphasis on responsiveness and efficiency in the delivery of public services. Attempts, both here and abroad, to simultaneously centralize responsibility for policy making while devolving responsibility for government operations appear to be at the centre of the “new public management.” The discussion of this issue in the book is extensive and interesting. At the risk of oversimplification, the explanation Aucoin offers for the emergence of reforms that are intended to centralize policy and at the same time decentralize operations may be put in the following way: central governments have been under pressure to recapture authority to set policy from the bureaucracy, in part to deal with traditional principal-agent problems and partly as a way of insuring budgetary restraint. At the same time, the increasing complexity of the public sector has made it difficult for ministers to handle both policy and operations, leading to greater reliance on delegation of authority for service delivery. Increased delegation of responsibility for such operations has also been seen as a way to make public service delivery more responsive to a citizenry that has become increasingly disenchanted with the public sector. The comparative analysis of recentralization of policy making along with decentralization of service delivery reveals that in the United Kingdom and New Zealand, delegation of service delivery has evolved so far as to involve specific contractual relations with heads of quasi-independent agencies (outside traditionally defined departments) who report directly to the minister. This experience stands in contrast to that in Canada where similar developments have been more limited in scope and still involve reporting through deputy ministers. Aucoin suggests at various points that Canada can benefit from more structural change of the sort that the UK and New Zealand have adopted. The implication of the trend toward centralization of policy making along with decentralization of service delivery for the accountability of public VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus servants is not ignored. Professor Aucoin emphasizes the centrality of the accountability issue in the parliamentary system of government. He stresses that maintaining accountability while delegating responsibility for operations outside traditional departmental boundaries presupposes the existence of better methods of monitoring and enforcing standards of public service delivery. The establishment of such methods forms an important part of his recommendations for reform. Aucoin’s analysis, which is presented with an admirable style, prompts many questions including this one: If it is really possible to write a well-defined contract with the head of a quasi-independent agency for the delivery of public services, what reason is there to keep the people providing that service within the public sector in any meaningful sense? To put this in another way, one can ask if what Aucoin observes in the UK and New Zealand is a long-lasting restructuring of public management, or, rather, an intermediate step in the redrawing of the boundary between public and private sectors? Aucoin implicitly recognizes the ambiguity in the analysis of public management reform introduced by such questions, most notably in his discussion of the Australian experience, though he does not tackle the issue as directly as I think is warranted. It seems that, as in Canada, there is a reluctance in Australia to accept radical separation of policy and operational responsibilities, though in both countries there has been some devolution of managerial authority within traditional departmental boundaries. In this respect Aucoin quotes the Australian Malcolm Holmes who points out, in an analysis of some recent reform proposals, that in contrast to reforms in the UK and New Zealand: “bringing [policy and delivery] together has been one of the planks of FMIP and Program Management and Budgeting” (p.145). Aucoin continues by noting the two arguments for this position that Holmes offered: first, to have the “needs of clients better advanced in the policy 111 process by those who have the most direct contact with clients, namely service providers; and second, to promote on the part of those who deliver services a greater focus on achieving outcomes costeffectively” (p.145). In the absence of private-market type contracts with public service providers, Holmes’ position strikes me as a reasonable one. My guess is that further work, beyond that presented in the book, will be required in order to sort out opposing views about the efficacy of greater separation of policy and operations with devolution of responsibility for the latter, and to permit further progress on the closely related question of where to draw the line between the private market and those matters that properly require the assistance of public bureaucracy. This work probably should include a consideration of the impact on the structure and scope of the public sector of ongoing, steep declines in the costs of information transmission and processing, an issue not addressed in the book. In addition to developments concerning the management of policy and operations, Professor Aucoin deals at length with the politicization of the bureau and with specific issues of service delivery, as I noted above. I cannot do justice in this short review to all of the material presented here concerning public management in Canada and other countries. Although I do not share all of the views expressed, agreement with all parts of a book can never be the basis for an overall recommendation about it. A good book, in my view, is one that informs, stimulates discussion and even controversy, and ultimately provokes further research. This is a good book by a thoughtful scholar. I recommend it to anyone who is interested in public management in Canada, or who is concerned with the future of public management in general. STANLEY WINER, School of Public Administration, Carleton University CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 112 Reviews/Comptes rendus Developments in Local Government Finance: Theory and Policy edited by Giancarlo Pola, George France and Rosella Levaggi. Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar, 1996. Pp.xxi, 333. $79.95. At a period in Canada’s history when federal and provincial governments are frantically examining how to reduce debt, provide public services more efficiently and reorganize the provision of public goods, this is a timely volume. Several contributions in this book address topics that are at the centre of the debate in Ontario on restructuring local government. The book is divided into four sections: New Solutions to Old Problems; Applying Theory to the Real World; Local Government and Local Policy Making: Autonomy and Constraints; and finally, Fiscal Issues for Existing and Future Federations. As with any collection of scholarly papers, it is sometimes difficult to collect several papers under a short section title that captures the content of the individual contributions. The 15 papers cover a very wide range of topics pertaining to local government in several countries although one is disappointed to see that both Australia and Canada, two of the most complex federal systems in the world, are excluded from the volume! Of the 15 papers, eight involve the specifying and testing, empirically, of hypotheses regarding local government finance. Glen Bramley’s paper examines who uses local public services in Britain and concludes that services are clearly not “pro-poor.” Alan Duncan and Peter Smith are interested in the concept of territorial equity; the idea that regions with equal need receive equal support in a federal system. They review two empirical models and conclude that the framework for measuring such effects accurately is lacking. When certain aspects of welfare spending were transferred to the local level in France, expenditure slowed. Gilbert and Rocaboy developed an econometric model to determine if decentralization was the cause for the slowdown in spending. Their conclusion is that it was not a factor. CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, The transfer of local spending and taxation power to local governments in Italy in recent years has led to speculation that additional tax bases will be given to local government. Rosella Levaggi constructs a social welfare maximizing model of local spending and uses the empirical results to simulate the impact of new tax bases. The result? Local governments will likely raise spending in response to a new tax base. In the US, Howard Chernick and Andrew Reschovsky argue that fiscal interest groups at the local level determine the degree of tax progression at the local level. They also hypothesize that tax incidence and mobility are related. An expenditure determination model is constructed that includes such variables as fiscal need, politics, local resource base, and personal wealth. The empirical results support the first hypothesis but not the second one. A model for Switzerland by Pommerehne, Kirchgassner and Feld looks at whether or not local tax rates influence location and their results support the hypothesis for those in higher income groups. At the macroeconomic level, Laramie and Mair construct a Kaleckian macro model (allowing for institutional prices and less than full employment) to examine the incidence of state and local taxes in the US. Their results indicate a very different pattern of incidence for state and local business taxes than similar taxes at the federal level. Such taxes have no effect on corporate profits and no short-run impact on personal savings rate. The book includes two theoretical papers. The first by David King is a somewhat traditional model of the optimum local authority size. Several variations in the model with respect to homogeneous and heterogenous preferences within a jurisdiction and between jurisdictions are examined and all results point to the trade-off between cost per unit of service and control over quantity and quality of public services. Peter Else uses a “bureau manager” maximizing model to look at changing perceptions of VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus local government in the UK. The model points up the sources of failure of local government to meet the preferences of voters. Other papers in the book examine how local governments will operate within the European Union (George France, Erich Thonki), the importance of a balanced budget at the local level (Dafflon) and developing indexes of deprivation for grant purposes in the UK (Paul Chapman). The impact of the “taxe professionale” in France is examined by Remy Prud’homme. In this case, local governments were given a new tax base and the freedom to impose rates. In the end, the central government had to place 113 limits on how it was to be used because of the burden created by the local use of the tax base. For academic public finance students, the variety of models should be stimulating and some could be adapted to test certain hypotheses about local spending in Canada. For the practitioner and policymaker, the general and specific issues raised in several papers will remind one that local government reform, and hence reform of local finance is complex and can have lasting incidence and allocative effects on the economy. DOUGLAS AULD, President, Loyalist College CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997 114 Reviews/Comptes rendus NEW BOOKS André-J. Bélanger and Vincent Lemieux. Introduction à l’analyse politique. Montréal: Les Presses de l’Université de Montréal, 1996. Pp. 326. $32.00. Canadian Ethnic Studies Special Issue: Racial and Ethnic Inequality. XXVI, 3, 1994. Pp. 204. Tom Courchene. Redistributing Money and Power: A Guide to the Canada Health and Social Transfer. Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute, 1995. Pp. 120. $12.95. Jim Harding (ed.). Social Policy and Social Justice: The NDP Government in Saskatchewan during the Blakeney Years. Waterloo: Wilfrid Laurier University Press, 1995. Pp. xii, 484. $29.95. Claus Hofhansel. Commercial Competition and National Security: Comparing U.S. and German Export Control Policies. Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers, 1996. Pp. viii, 232. $59.95. John F. Mahon and Richard A. McGowan. Industry as a Player in the Political and Social Arena: Defining Competitive Environment. Westport, CT: Quorum Books, 1996. Pp. xiii, 216. $59.95. Bruce Mitchell (ed.). Resource and Environmental Management in Canada: Addressing Conflict and Uncertainty. Toronto, Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press, 1995. Pp. ix, 445. $24.95. Kristen Renwick Monroe. The Heart of Altruism: Perceptions of a Common Humanity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1996. Pp. xix, 292. $29.95. National Council of Welfare. A Pension Primer. Ottawa: Supply and Services Canada, 1996. Pp. 54. CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, National Council of Welfare. A Guide to the Proposed Seniors Benefit. Ottawa: Supply and Services Canada, 1996. Pp. 34. Thomas Michael Power. Environmental Protection and Economic Well-Being: The Economic Pursuit of Quality (2d ed.). Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1996. Pp. xv, 251. $24.95. Christopher A. Sarlo. Poverty in Canada (2d ed.). Vancouver, BC: The Fraser Institute, 1996. Pp. xviii, 290. Pierre Sauvé and Daniel Schwanen (eds.). Investment Rules for the Global Economy: Enhancing Access to Markets. Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute, 1996. Pp. viii, 332. $19.95. Savoie, Donald J. (ed.). Budgeting and the Management of Public Spending. Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar Publishing Co., 1996. Pp. xx, 387. Snell, James G. The Citizen’s Wage: The State and the Elderly in Canada, 1900-1951. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1996. Pp. xxii, 286. $18.95. Sheryl R. Tynes. Turning Points in Social Security: From ‘Cruel Hoax’ to ‘Sacred Entitlement.’ Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1996. Pp. viii, 253. $39.50. White, Joseph. Competing Solutions: American Health Care Proposals and International Experience. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1995. Pp. xv, 392. US$16.95. VOL . XXIII, NO . 1 1997