Sharing Private Information with Customers: Strategic Default and Lender Learning Gerardo Pérez Cavazos Working Paper 16-033 Sharing Private Information with Customers: Strategic Default and Lender Learning Gerardo Pérez Cavazos Harvard Business School Working Paper 16-033 Copyright © 2015 by Gerardo Pérez Cavazos Working papers are in draft form. This working paper is distributed for purposes of comment and discussion only. It may not be reproduced without permission of the copyright holder. Copies of working papers are available from the author. Sharing private information with customers: Strategic default and lender learning Gerardo Pérez Cavazos∗ The University of Chicago Booth School of Business April 24, 2015 Abstract I use a unique data set of loans to small business owners to examine whether lenders face negative externalities when they share private information with borrowers. When lenders grant debt forgiveness to borrowers, borrowers communicate that information to other borrowers, who are then more likely to strategically default on their own obligations. This strategic default contagion is economically large. When the lender doubles debt forgiveness, contagion causes the default rate to increase by 10.9% on average. Using an exogenous shock to the lender’s forgiveness policy, I further show that as the lender learns about the extent of borrower communication it tightens its debt forgiveness and origination policies to reduce information spillovers and mitigate the default contagion. Collectively, these results provide new evidence on the strategic interactions between a firm and its customers in a dynamic information environment. JEL No.: D10, D83, G21, M41 Keywords: Information transmission, communication, strategic default contagion, learning ∗ I am grateful to my dissertation committee: Douglas Skinner (Chair), Phil Berger, Christian Leuz, and Haresh Sapra. I also thank Ray Ball, Andreas Bodmeier, Alejandro Cavazos, Hans Christensen, Merle Erickson, John Gallemore, Joseph Gerakos, Mark Maffett, Mike Minnis, Adair Morse, Valeri Nikolaev, Antonio Picca, Andreya Silva, and Anastasia Zakolyukina for helpful comments. I received valuable feedback from seminar participants at Duke Universiy, Harvard Business School, London Business School, Massachusetts Intitute of Technology, New York University, Stanford University, University of California at Los Angeles, University of Chicago, University of Illinois, University of Pennsylvania, and Washington University, as well as conference participants at the 2014 AAA/Deloitte/J. Michael Cook Doctoral Consortium. Finally, I am extremely grateful to Financiera Ayudamos for providing their data. 1 Introduction A large accounting literature discusses the role of proprietary costs in firms’ disclosure decisions. Because observing proprietary costs is difficult, however, empirical evidence on the magnitude of those costs is limited. I examine how information externalities in small business lending affect the actions of borrowers and lenders, and in particular, how private information about lenders’ debt forgiveness policies is transmitted to other borrowers, a form of information contagion that is costly to lenders. The debt forgiveness negotiation process creates a dynamic information environment in which lenders and borrowers both share private information. Although the information exchange can help both parties achieve a more efficient outcome, there is a risk of sharing too much information (Crawford and Sobel, 1982). Theoretical work shows that economic agents can strategically use a firm’s proprietary information to their advantage (Verrecchia, 1983; Dye, 1986; Wagenhofer, 1990). My research provides evidence on the costs that firms incur when they share private information with customers. I present two key findings. First, I show that lenders face strategic default contagion when granting debt forgiveness to borrowers. This unintended consequence results from borrowers communicating the private terms of their debt forgiveness agreements to other borrowers, who are then more likely to strategically default on their own obligations. Second, I show that lenders learn about the extent of borrower communication and alter their operating policies to reduce information spillovers and mitigate the default contagion. I use a detailed data set from Financiera Ayudamos (FA), a Mexican credit institution that grants small business and consumer loans. FA selectively grants debt forgiveness in cases of default in an effort to reduce losses on delinquent loans by incentivizing defaulters to continue repaying their loans.1 I use these debt forgiveness events to analyze whether 1 For example, consider a borrower who is four weeks late on his payments and is only able to pay half of his deficiency. This borrower may not make any payments, because he knows he will remain in default. By contrast, if the lender offers to forgive two payments, the borrower can commit to paying the remaining two installments and become current on his loan. 1 FA incurs costs due to private information transmission between borrowers regarding its forgiveness policy. The idea is that a borrower who is granted debt forgiveness learns private information regarding the extent of the lender’s willingness to give a discount on the loan repayment and can subsequently share this information with other borrowers. Financially able borrowers can strategically use this information to their advantage to get a reduction on their loan balance. Any information asymmetry regarding a borrower’s ability to pay exacerbates this issue. If the lender is unable to clearly distinguish between borrowers who can and cannot repay their loans, it is more likely that he will unknowingly offer debt forgiveness to strategic defaulters. A distinct feature of this setting is that lenders only share private information through private contracts with select borrowers. Although these borrowers can communicate with others, the extent of communication is unknown ex-ante. It is therefore unclear whether the information externalities are substantial enough for the lender to alter its operating decisions to reduce the amount of private information shared with borrowers. Alternatively, borrowers may not share the details of this forgiveness event with others, because unlike a publicly disclosed event such as foreclosure, a default and the subsequent renegotiation with the lender are private. To identify costs due to information externalities it is necessary to disentangle strategic defaults from defaults that are the result of economic adversity. My empirical approach is based on the simple premise that borrowers’ primary economic shocks occur at work, whereas communication among borrowers occurs in the home neighborhood. I am able to draw this important distinction because of the particularities of the Mexican setting. First, many individuals commute over an hour to work. This allows me to separate the default rate in the work area from that in the home neighborhood. A high default rate in the work area indicates that borrowers have suffered shocks to income, whereas a low default rate indicates stable economic conditions. If an individual defaults but does not suffer a shock to his income, I then attribute the default to events within his home neighborhood. 2 Defaults that originate in the home neighborhood have two possible explanations: (i) an event that causes a shock to expenses or (ii) strategic default due to communication between borrowers. Communication is high within Mexican neighborhoods because they comprise tight-knit groups of families and friends who have lived there most of their lives and interact through weekly community activities (Keefe, 1984).2 Therefore, to determine whether the default stems from communication about the lender’s forgiveness policy, I examine the forgiveness rate within the home neighborhood. A high forgiveness rate within a neighborhood indicates more borrowers have experienced the debt forgiveness process. As these informed borrowers communicate about the lender’s willingness to forgive, neighborhoods with a high forgiveness rate will have many defaults. I then control for the contemporaneous default rate, inflation, and natural disasters to rule out any shocks to the neighborhood’s expenses. My first set of results measures the extent of strategic default in a neighborhood after the lender grants debt forgiveness to a borrower. I find evidence of strategic default contagion resulting from communication among borrowers regarding the lender’s forgiveness policy. If FA doubles its forgiveness rate in a neighborhood, the default rate increases by 1.7% in the following month. This default contagion is equivalent to a 10.9% increase in FA’s monthly default rate. These results are robust and valid for a wide range of econometric tests. In addition to controlling for economic shocks, I include various fixed effects and complement the regression analysis with an instrumental variables (IV) approach. My findings have three critical implications. First, firms not only release information through disclosure, but also through their operating actions. In my setting these operational decisions are private internal policies; however, firms also make public operational decisions, such as expanding their operations or releasing new products, which likely reveal proprietary information to outsiders. Second, firms incur significant informational costs when negotiating with customers. Although theoretical models define customers as potential opponents of 2 Keefe (1984) finds that Mexican Americans families “have relatively large kin networks with high rates of visiting and exchange. Even immigrant Mexicans, who have experienced disruption of their kin group due to migration, surpass Anglos in the number of relatives living nearby and their frequency of visiting kin.” 3 a firm, the extant empirical literature has focused almost exclusively on competitors as users of firms’ proprietary information. Third, the evidence I provide raises questions about whether increasing renegotiations is an optimal strategy to attenuate the high foreclosure rate. This issue is important because of the recent foreclosure crisis. In 2008 the U.S. government instituted the Home Affordable Modification Program (HAMP), which, in an effort to solve the foreclosure crisis, provides lenders with incentives to renegotiate more loans. Consistent with the conjecture of Posner and Zingales (2008), my results illustrate that there are negative externalities associated with increasing loan renegotiations. To provide additional evidence on the causal link between debt forgiveness and strategic default, I exploit a plausibly exogenous event that caused a change in FA’s debt forgiveness policy. In late August 2012, FA’s director of risk management unexpectedly resigned to accept a position at a larger financial institution. While FA searched for a replacement, responsibility for approving debt forgiveness was transferred to executives in the marketing department who then granted debt forgiveness more freely. In September 2012, a borrower in default was twice as likely to receive debt forgiveness as in the prior month. As a result, within the following six months, the percentage of loans in default increased from 41.1% to 47.3%. Consistent with strategic default, the increase was concentrated in the group of loans that were one to 29 days delinquent. By contrast, adverse economic conditions would affect default across all delinquency groups. Next, to further investigate the communication mechanism driving strategic default I analyze borrower interconnectedness within neighborhoods. I expect that highly interconnected borrowers communicate more and thus exhibit higher strategic default contagion after forgiveness has been granted within their home neighborhood. To test this conjecture, I construct multiple measures of borrower interconnectedness: (i) the fraction of borrower referrals within a neighborhood, (ii) the geographic concentration of loans within zip codes surrounding each branch, (iii) a size-adjusted geographic concentration measure, and (iv) the average time that the borrowers of each branch have spent living in their current home. 4 I find that after the change in forgiveness policy, branches holding a more concentrated loan portfolio or a portfolio with a higher referral rate suffered a higher incidence of strategic default. Taken together, my results provide evidence that communication among borrowers results in information contagion that is costly to lenders. Finally, I examine whether the lender learns from strategic default contagion. The motivation behind this analysis is to understand whether firms recognize that privately disclosed information spreads between their counterparties and the extent to which they adjust their policies to mitigate the negative externalities. Studying firm learning is challenging because equilibrium outcomes are typically observed. However, the surge in defaults after FA’s exogenous event provides an ideal setting to examine lender learning. I test whether the lender adjusts its origination and forgiveness policies to limit the spread of its private information. I find that FA’s branches learn from strategic default contagion and react by increasing the strictness of their forgiveness and origination policies within nine months of the event. The policy changes are stronger for those branches that experienced higher strategic default contagion. These results illustrate that lenders recognize the informational trade-off they face when making operational decisions that reveal proprietary information. As such, they alter their policies to mitigate the negative externalities resulting from communication about their willingness to modify loans. These findings also shed light on the observation that a low incidence of loan renegotiations occurred during the financial crisis. Prior studies by Piskorski et al. (2010) and Adelino et al. (2013) investigate whether institutional frictions arising from securitizations explain the small number of loan renegotiations. I show that although the expost observation that lenders did not increasingly renegotiate during the financial crisis might seem counterintuitive, lenders limit the number of renegotiations because they recognize the informational costs ex-ante. My study makes several contributions. To my knowledge, this study is the first to measure the information externalities of sharing a lender’s private information with customers. I use 5 a unique approach to show that although the lender shares information privately, borrowers communicate what they learn to other borrowers. This result provides empirical evidence that supports the theory that customers can play the role of a firm’s strategic opponent. In addition, although I study the lender-borrower relationship, my findings are applicable to other settings where two parties transact with one another privately, such as supplier negotiations, government-firm negotiations, or a central bank offering capital infusions to a particular bank. Lastly, I am able to isolate the effect that a lender’s operating policies have on borrowers’ decisions to strategically default. Disentangling this effect is a step toward finding appropriate solutions for default and foreclosure contagion. Section 2 reviews the relevant literature. Section 3 describes the data. Section 4 presents results on the impact of forgiveness on strategic default contagion; and Section 5 further explores communication as the mechanism driving strategic default. Section 6 examines creditor learning. Section 7 concludes. 2 Related Literature Customers are traditionally regarded as economic agents who contribute positively to the firm’s bottom line; however, they can also play the role of a strategic opponent if they use the firm’s private information to their advantage (Verrecchia, 1983; Dye, 1986; Wagenhofer, 1990). In particular, firms constantly share information with customers in negotiations (Crawford and Sobel, 1982), and the spread of this information can impact the firms’ bargaining power and the outcome of other negotiations. For example, customers may demand a discount if they learn that a price concession was granted to another customer. Therefore, understanding whether information shared during private negotiations spreads and measuring the resulting costs for the firm is important. Although offering debt forgiveness is not a disclosure choice in the traditional sense, it is an operating decision that reveals private information to outsiders. In this respect, 6 my study is related to the literature on proprietary information, which analyzes whether sharing information with outsiders is beneficial for the firm. In particular, the majority of proprietary information studies extensively analyze the effect of competition on different disclosure decisions, such as product development information (Guo et al., 2004; Jones, 2007), material contract filings (Verrecchia and Weber, 2006), sales and cost information (Dedman and Lennox, 2009), and customer information (Ellis et al., 2012). These studies find that despite market pressures, firms do not fully disclose all private information because of competitors. My study is similar in that firms face a trade-off when deciding whether to release more or less information in negotiations with customers. A unique feature of my study is that I examine information sharing through a private contract. Therefore, the firm cannot perfectly anticipate whether and to what degree information will spread, making it difficult to set optimal policies ex-ante. I exploit this feature to analyze whether the lender learns about the extent of proprietary costs resulting from information transmission among its borrowers and how the lender alters its policies in response. A recent study by Ali et al. (2014) shows that firms with high proprietary costs prefer financing options that allow them to circumvent disclosure requirements. My study complements their findings by providing evidence that a financial institution modifies its debt forgiveness and origination policies because of the high cost of sharing private information. My work also relates to two recent streams within the mortgage literature. Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales (2013) use survey data to examine the moral and social determinants of homeowners’ attitudes toward strategic default. They find that homeowners are more likely to default if they know of other strategic defaulters, in part because they perceive the bank is less likely to pursue them. Further work examines how foreclosure spreads within neighborhoods, performing an analysis within Maryland (Towe and Lawley, 2013), an analysis in Illinois (Munroe and Wilse-Samson, 2013), and a national analysis that controls for neighborhood and zip-code (Goodstein et al., 2013). These studies find that foreclosure is contagious and that neighbors’ behaviors influence default. 7 My study differs from these prior studies in three respects. First, my study is concerned exclusively with how the spread of the lender’s private information affects strategic default. I am able to identify this because I observe defaults and loan modifications that are private. By contrast, a foreclosure is a publicly disclosed event making it difficult to disentangle communication about the bank’s proprietary information from any learning that occurs regarding the economic trajectory of the neighborhood or foreclosure procedures (Towe and Lawley, 2013; Munro and Wilse-Samson, 2013). Second, my study focuses on the period that spans a borrower’s initial default on a loan through all renegotiations that occur until the lender sends the loan to a collection agency. Thus, my setting closely parallels the renegotiation period prior to a foreclosure. As such, I am able to investigate whether increasing loan modifications helps reduce foreclosure contagion, as suggested by Munro and Wilse-Samson (2013) yet critiqued by Posner and Zingales (2009). The paper most closely related to mine is Mayer et al. (2013), who use the Countrywide lawsuit settlement to analyze how a publicly announced mortgage modification policy affects strategic default. My approach differs from theirs because I focus on private loan renegotiations and therefore communication among customers as the channel by which learning about the lender’s policies occurs. Thus, my study more closely parallels the negotiation of a private contract, because banks and companies do not typically announce they will grant concessions to all customers who need assistance meeting their financial obligations. In doing so, I contribute new evidence showing that loan renegotiations cause strategic default contagion even when renegotiations are conducted privately with only select borrowers in default. Lastly, I examine whether the lender identifies the informational costs associated with renegotiating loans. Despite the importance of loan renegotiations as a tool to minimize bank losses, there is little work that examines whether the low incidence of renegotiations occurs because banks anticipate that loan modifications can generate information externalities. This paucity of evidence is likely due to the difficulty of finding settings where the bank’s 8 renegotiation decisions vary exogenously. I circumvent this challenge by exploiting a plausible exogenous change to the lender’s forgiveness policy that caused a surge in defaults. 3 Data I use loan data from Financiera Ayudamos (FA), a subsidiary of Grupo Financiero BBVA Bancomer, the largest commercial bank in Mexico. FA is a Sociedad Financiera de Objeto Multiple (SOFOM), a credit institution subject to less government regulation than deposit banks.3 SOFOMs primarily grant consumer credit, yet also provide financing for small and medium enterprises, distributors, and intermediaries. SOFOMs are not allowed to accept deposits; therefore, FA is fully funded by its parent company. FA began its operations in May 2007 and currently operates 54 branches concentrated in central Mexico. It mainly serves individuals with limited access to traditional credit.4 FA’s loans range from $1,500 to $50,000 MXN ($115 to $3,845 USD), have a 12 to 24 month maturity, and have the same 66% interest rate across borrowers. Loans also incur a 16% value-added tax on interest payments and a 9% origination fee or 5% renewal fee. My main sample comprises 14,649 FA loans to small business owners, granted from January 2011 through March 2014. Panel A of Table 1 reports borrower and loan characteristics at origination. On average, the loans have a principal of $6,940 MXN ($515 USD), an annual payment rate (APR) of 92%, a maturity of 18 months, and a weekly payment frequency. Borrowers are 57% female and, on average, 39 years old. Nearly two-thirds of borrowers have a credit score and, of those, the mean score is 692 of 850. According to FA’s risk management department, a credit score of 692 corresponds to a medium-risk borrower. To assess the credit-worthiness of all borrowers, FA constructs an internal credit score that aggregates borrower characteristics. Lastly, 38% of borrowers have previously obtained a loan with FA. 3 SOFOMs do not require approval from the National Banking Regulator and are exempt from capital requirements unless they have an economic relationship with a banking institution (Pena, 2008). 4 FA facilitates the borrowing process by accepting non-traditional documents as proof of income. For example, FA accepts receipts from inventory purchases as proof of income, whereas most commercial banks strictly require payroll receipts or bank statements. 9 My identification relies on borrowers living in a tight-knit neighborhood and commuting to work. Consistent with this, on average, FA’s borrowers have spent 67% of their life at their current home and travel 3.8 linear miles to work. Given the mountainous geography of Mexico, the linear distance likely understates the commute to work. For example, in Mexico City, a 3.8 linear mile can require travel of over six miles on the road, corresponding to a commute in excess of one hour. Panel B of Table 1 presents the monthly loan performance. FA monitors loan performance on a weekly basis. In a given month, an average of 16% of borrowers miss a payment and are considered to be in default. Each branch is required to pursue collection efforts, which begin with loan officers placing telephone calls and making home visits. The branch can also offer debt forgiveness should the first two methods become ineffective. Debt forgiveness is contingent on the borrower (i) paying the remainder of his deficiency such that the loan becomes fully current and (ii) committing to make the rest of his payments on time. Prior to September 2012, FA granted forgiveness to an average of 10% of defaulters, on approximately 4% of the loan principal.5 Once delinquency surpasses 60 days, FA’s centralized collection division takes over the collection process. This division is, on average, less than 15% successful at getting loans back into repayment. Lastly, once the loan is more than 90 days delinquent, it is transferred to an external collection agency that charges a percentage of any recovered portion of the loan. 5 The average forgiveness rate over the whole sample period is 20% due to the period after August 2012, as discussed in Section 5. 10 4 Borrower Communication and Strategic Default Contagion 4.1 Identification Strategy My first hypothesis is that lenders incur information externalities when they grant debt forgiveness, because borrowers communicate with other borrowers who are then more likely to default. To test this hypothesis, I must differentiate defaults that are due to information spillovers from those that are purely due to adverse economic shocks. To do so, I use a novel approach that exploits the particularities of the Mexican setting. First, I account for economic shocks to a borrower’s income that could make him unable to repay his loan. I exploit the fact that Mexicans typically commute to work, and separately analyze the default rate of a borrower’s work area and home neighborhood.6 A high default rate in a borrower’s work area indicates that local economic conditions that impact takehome pay are deteriorating. In particular, the income of small business owners, who sell food, clothes, personal care items, repair cars, repair shoes, etc., is highly dependent on common local factors such as a large store opening in the vicinity, a company closing down or downsizing, nearby protests during the week, construction in the area, etc. Next, if there are no economic shocks at the work area I consider shocks to a borrower’s home expenses that might cause default. First, I consider a rise in housing costs. According to the Mexican National Institute of Statistics and Geography (INEGI), individuals within the corresponding income deciles of my sample of borrowers only spend 3.2% of their income on rent. Consistent with this statistic, less than 1% of my sample of borrowers rent their home. Therefore, in my setting, rent increases are unlikely to contribute to a rise in the neighborhood’s default rate. Second, I consider a rise in the cost of consumption goods. INEGI reports that, on average, the two greatest expenses for individuals within the corre6 A lack of urban planning, the lack of jobs in low-income communities, and government housing in the outskirts of major cities contribute to the high number of commuters. 11 sponding income decile of my sample of borrowers are food (41%) and transportation (17%). However, my sample period had modest annual inflation rates under 4.5%. Thus, the rise in the cost of these goods is unlikely sufficient to cause an increase in neighborhood default. Lastly, if a neighborhood does not experience a widespread shock that causes expenses to increase, a borrower’s default is more likely driven by communication among neighbors regarding the lender’s forgiveness policies. In particular, the majority of individuals in Mexico live in the same neighborhood from infancy to adulthood, forming strong ties to their community of large extended families and friends (Rodriguez et al., 2007). Weekly activities within these neighborhoods also contribute to the high level of information sharing. As such, I examine whether a borrower is more likely to default after forgiveness is granted to other borrowers within his neighborhood. Considering FA’s forgiveness policy, a strategic default due to communication would occur as follows: (i) Borrower A defaults in month t, (ii) Borrower A receives forgiveness in month t + 1, and (iii) Borrower B defaults in month t + 2. Because Borrower B’s decision to default is separated from Borrower A’s default by two months, it is much less likely that Borrower B’s default is due to a pervasive economic shock that impacts the entire home neighborhood at one point in time. In sum, my identification strategy is that economic shocks that impact the borrower’s ability to repay his loan are correlated among borrowers that work in the same area, whereas defaults that are correlated among borrowers that live in the same neighborhood are primarily due to information transmission. Figure 1 illustrates the identification strategy. Borrowers A and B live in the same tightknit neighborhood and commute to their respective work areas to run small independent businesses. Borrowers C and D live in a different neighborhood and commute to their small businesses. I identify strategic default as follows: suppose Borrower A and Borrower C default in t on their small consumer loans because of an economic shock that affects the whole work area. The lender offers Borrower A debt forgiveness in t +1 as a means of getting him out of default and back into repayment. Borrower A subsequently communicates with 12 his neighbor, Borrower B, regarding the lender’s forgiveness policy. Borrower B, who has not suffered an economic shock, then chooses to strategically default in t + 2 with the objective of getting a portion of his loan forgiven. Borrower D does not default, because he neither experiences an economic shock nor has any interaction with Borrowers A or B. Moreover, suppose communication occurs among local business owners in the work area. The result would be an overstated coefficient on economic conditions and an understated coefficient on forgiveness. Therefore, it will be more difficult to detect contagion. 4.2 Empirical Analysis To implement the identification strategy I estimate the following panel regression: Def aulti,t = α0 + α1 F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 + α2 Def ault Ratework,t + (1) Controls + F ixed Ef f ects. The dependent variable, Def aulti,t , is binary and takes the value of one if a borrower’s loan i is in default at month t, but not at month t − 1, and zero otherwise. The main explanatory variable, F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 , is the forgiveness rate in borrower i’s home zip code in the prior month. Using lagged forgiveness rate overcomes the reflection problem that arises in social interaction models (Manski, 2000; Brock and Durlauf, 2001).7 To control for other determinants of default, I include measures of economic conditions, borrower characteristics, and loan characteristics. I construct a variable, Def ault Ratework,t , as a proxy for local economic conditions that impact borrowers’ ability to repay their loans.8 This variable measures the proportion of loans that are delinquent in the zip code where borrower i works (excluding borrower i). The relatively low correlation of 0.35 between 7 The reflection problem arises when determining whether group behavior affects the behavior of individuals (Manski, 1993). The issue is that group behavior is merely the aggregate of individual behaviors. 8 I construct this variable because a measure of local economic conditions is unavailable at the zip code level. INEGI’s most granular economic measures are reported at the state level. In addition, INEGI’s state data are reported quarterly and thus do not allow for a monthly analysis. 13 Def ault Ratework,t and Def ault Ratehome,t indicates that the economic conditions at the work and home zip codes are distinct from each other (Appendix Table A.2). I also include industry and time fixed effects to control for macroeconomic cycles and seasonality. I control for demographic characteristics that affect a borrower’s ex-ante likelihood of default: age, gender, education, credit score, number of years living in the current house as a fraction of age, and number of years owning the business as a fraction of age. I expect that a borrower who has owned his business for many years is more likely to generate a stable income than a borrower who recently started his business. I control for loan characteristics: payment frequency, size of the loan relative to income, and the portion of the loan that is repaid. I expect that borrowers are not likely to default immediately after obtaining a loan or when a few payments are left. I also anticipate that default is more likely to occur on loans with weekly payments, because FA grants biweekly or monthly payments only to borrowers that demonstrate a relatively stable source of income. Lastly, I cluster standard errors at the branch level to account for branches operating in distinct areas and therefore the possibility that they implement collection efforts differently. 4.3 4.3.1 Empirical Results Linear regression analysis Panel A of Table 2 presents results of the strategic default regressions using a linear probability model.9 A 1% increase in the debt forgiveness rate within a neighborhood increases the likelihood that an additional borrower will default by 0.087% (column 1). This contagion is large in terms of economic magnitude. If FA were to double the debt forgiveness rate within a neighborhood, the likelihood of a borrower defaulting in a given month increases by 1.7%, equivalent to approximately a 10.9% increase in FA’s monthly default rate. Further, the joint effect of P ct P aid and P ct P aid2 indicates that the probability of default is a concave 9 I use a linear probability model for ease of interpreting coefficients and because it allows for a larger set of fixed effects. However, in untabulated results I run logistic specifications and find similar results. 14 function that reaches its maximum when 66% of the loan is repaid. Therefore, as predicted, defaults do not typically occur at the beginning or near the maturity of the loan. In column 2, I use FA’s Internal Credit Score as a control, in lieu of borrower characteristics. The internal credit score variable aggregates borrower characteristics and can capture nonlinearities that FA has already identified and incorporated into its scoring formula. It also has the added benefit of increasing the sample size, because approximately 36% of FA’s borrowers lack a credit score. I find that the coefficient of F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 remains positive and significant. Next, I examine repeat defaulters to test whether the likelihood that a borrower defaults increases after he receives debt forgiveness on his loan. An individual repeatedly defaults for two reasons: (i) he is a bad borrower or (ii) he is taking advantage of the information that he previously learned about FA’s willingness to offer forgiveness. Accordingly, I include two additional explanatory variables (column 3). The first variable, N ot F orgiven, is binary and takes the value of one for borrowers who defaulted in the past but did not receive forgiveness. The second variable, P ast F orgiveness, is also binary and takes the value of one for borrowers who received forgiveness in the past. The coefficient of N ot F orgiven is positive, indicating that bad borrowers are more likely to default again. However, consistent with borrower learning, the coefficient of P ast F orgiveness is greater than the coefficient of N ot F orgiven. The difference in the two coefficients shows that conditional on being a bad borrower, learning about forgiveness increases the likelihood of default by 14.3%. In column 4, I include repeat borrowers. I am interested in this subset of borrowers because their past borrowing history with the lender creates less information asymmetry regarding their wealth. These borrowers are also likely interested in renewing their existing loans or obtaining new loans, which increases the cost of taking actions that negatively affect their credit score. In particular, when making renewal decisions, FA penalizes borrowers for having received forgiveness on a loan. Generally, FA does not renew a loan if the borrower has defaulted within six months or defaulted multiple times in the past. Approximately 15 5% of repeat borrowers received forgiveness on a previous loan. In line with my prediction, the coefficient of Repeat Borrower is negative and significant, indicating that repeat borrowers default less on average. The interaction coefficient of F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 × Repeat Borrower indicates that repeat borrowers do not default more when the forgiveness rate increases in their neighborhood. This is consistent with the lender being more informed about the repeat borrowers’ wealth, making it more difficult for this subset of borrowers to strategically default and obtain forgiveness. In column 4, I substitute Def ault Ratework with the interaction of work area and month fixed effects. The purpose of the work-month fixed effects is to eliminate the effect of economic shocks that are common to all businesses in a given work area each month. Lastly, I include home neighborhood fixed effects to control for time-invariant characteristics of the home neighborhood that can influence the likelihood of default (column 5). The coefficients are estimated from within-home-neighborhood variation, requiring that any potential confounding event be correlated with time-varying home neighborhood characteristics. The coefficient of F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 is positive and significant in all specifications. Next, I further investigate the communication mechanism that drives strategic default. I test whether borrowers with stronger ties to their neighborhood are more likely to strategically default after a neighbor receives forgiveness. In Panel B, I partition the main regression analysis by high and low Lif e at Home, which is determined by the median percentage of life spent in the current home. I find that the coefficients of F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 are positive and significant for borrowers in the high group. For the borrowers in the low group, the coefficients are positive, but not significant. These results demonstrate that stronger neighborhood ties lead to more pervasive communication, and ultimately higher levels of strategic default. 16 4.3.2 Instrumental variables I use instrumental variables (IV) as an alternative empirical method to strengthen the causal link between prior forgiveness and default (Table 3). The objective of the IV approach is to exploit shocks to the home neighborhoods’ forgiveness rate that are exogenous to each borrower. This is different from the regression analysis, which attempts to control for all economic conditions that affect borrowers. As such, IV allows me to circumvent potential concerns about endogeneity in FA’s decisions to grant debt forgiveness. If FA can detect different levels of communication across neighborhoods, its best response is to lower debt forgiveness in areas with high communication. From a statistical perspective, this rational behavior by FA would result in a downward bias in the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates. For each borrower i, I instrument the home neighborhood’s forgiveness rate by using the fraction of neighboring borrowers that work in a different area and became delinquent in t − 2. The first-stage regressions show that this instrument, N ew Def ault Ratework(−i),t−2 , satisfies the relevance restriction (Table 3, Panel B). The coefficient of the instrument is positive and significant and the Angrist and Pischke (2008) partial F -statistics are above the critical value for a weak instrument as defined by Stock et al. (2002). This instrument likely satisfies the exclusion restriction. First, it is constructed using the default rate of borrowers that work in a different zip code and are therefore exposed to different local economic conditions. Second, the instrument is lagged by two periods, further separating economic shocks suffered by the defaulters from shocks that could affect borrower i. Given that these borrowers have minimal or no savings, it is unlikely that they will be able to withstand economic shocks for a prolonged period of time without defaulting. As such, it is reasonable to assume that the only channel by which N ew Def ault Ratework(−i),t−2 affects borrower i’s decision to default is through the level of forgiveness that i observes in his home neighborhood. In line with my previous results, the coefficient of F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 is positive 17 and significant across all specifications. These coefficients are also larger than those of the OLS regressions, which is consistent with a downward bias in the OLS estimates. In terms of economic magnitude, a one standard deviation increase in the forgiveness rate in the home neighborhood increases the default rate by 2.6%. Overall, the results in this Section indicate that the lender’s day-to-day operations reveal proprietary information to customers who then communicate the terms of their agreement to other borrowers, causing negative externalities in the form of strategic default contagion. The lender’s private information spreads even when it is exclusively disclosed in a private contract. Considering that all types of firms engage in a multitude of private contracts this result is likely to apply to other settings where two companies transact with one another privately. For example, any firm that decides to grant better delivery terms, additional warranty, or additional services to select customers can incur costs if doing so induces additional customers to demand the same treatment. In addition, although my setting focuses on communication among individual borrowers, prior research has found evidence of information transmission among decision makers at different firms. For instance, manufacturing executives gather and transmit information about retailers’ payment policies through business associations (Doner and Schneider, 2000), investment managers communicate with other local investment managers about portfolio allocation decisions (Hong et al., 2005), and executives within the same social networks discuss and influence each other’s managerial decisions (Cohen et al., 2008; Shue, 2013). Therefore, the mechanism of communication among individual customers regarding a firm’s private information is also generalizable to communication among firms’ decision makers. Lastly, my results shed light on the information externalities associated with loan renegotiations. In particular, I provide evidence consistent with the theoretical predictions of Posner and Zingales (2009), which state that loan renegotiations, although efficient ex-post, can create future costs for the bank. This result is important from a policy perspective because renegotiations have received attention as a potential solution to reduce mortgage 18 foreclosures. For example, the Obama administration enacted the Home Affordable Modification Program in 2008 to provide incentives for lenders to increase loan renegotiations.10 Beyond demonstrating that renegotiations have a costly consequence for lenders, my results indicate that the foreclosure contagion problem cannot be solved by exclusively prescribing renegotiations. 4.4 Robustness and Alternative Explanations I perform a number of additional tests to evaluate the robustness of my main results. First, I rule out potential shocks to expenses in the home neighborhood. Then I use a placebo test to examine whether default contagion is due to online communication regarding FA’s forgiveness policy. 4.4.1 Shocks to expenses at the home I use a series of alternative specifications to test for possible alternate explanations for strategic default contagion (Table 4). First, I include the contemporaneous default rate in the home neighborhood as a control for potential correlated economic shocks in the home neighborhood that drive borrowers’ default. A drawback of including this variable, Def ault Ratehome,t , is that it is affected by the lagged forgiveness rate. As such, it will absorb a portion of the effect associated with F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 and thus, attenuate the coefficient. Although the coefficient of F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 is downwardly biased in this specification, it remains positive and significant (column 1). Therefore, increasing debt forgiveness increases strategic default contagion after controlling for economic conditions. Next, I include inflation subcomponents to control for price increases in different types of goods consumed by the borrowers. For example, according to INEGI, the average borrower in my sample spends 17% of his income on transportation. Therefore, I expect that borrowers will be more likely to default when there is a high inflation rate with respect 10 For more details on the consequences of the HAMP see Agarwal et al. (2012). 19 to transportation goods and services (column 3). Including these controls does not affect the coefficient of F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 . The coefficients of inflation in transportation, clothing, and housing are positive and significant. By contrast, the coefficient of inflation in food prices is not statistically significant, likely due to the large portion of borrowers in my sample that own food sales businesses. I also analyze natural disasters because they are economic shocks that can cause a correlation in defaults among borrowers living in the same neighborhood. I include a binary variable, N atural Disaster, that takes the value of one for loans in states that suffered a natural disaster during the year, and the interaction term F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 × N atural Disaster. The coefficients of these two variables are not statistically different from zero. In this specification, I also include a binary variable, M ultiple Accounts, that takes the value of one when a borrower has multiple credit accounts at origination, and the interaction term F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 × M ultiple Accounts. A borrower that has multiple outstanding loans is possibly learning from the actions of various lenders. By controlling for borrowers with multiple credit accounts I disentangle whether the borrower is learning from FA’s actions. I find that these borrowers are less likely to default but equally likely to learn from neighboring forgiveness and to strategically default. In column 4, I test whether the spread of a disease could explain default contagion. According to the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC), flu activity peaks between December and February. Therefore, I include a binary variable, W inter, which takes the value of one for months between November and March. I also include the interaction term F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 × W inter. The coefficient of F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 remains largely unaffected, indicating that the spread of contagious diseases such as the flu do not drive the main results. Lastly, I use a data set of 62 Walmart store openings within my sample period to test for local economic shocks to borrowers who work within 2 miles of the area. The idea is that a Walmart store opening could cause an increase in competition to local businesses. 20 Conversely, I use the store openings as a positive shock to borrowers who live within 2 miles of the area, because it could allow them to purchase goods at lower prices. I also include the interaction term of each of these two variables with F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 . The coefficients of F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 remain largely unchanged, but the coefficients of Walmart openings are not statistically significant. I attribute these results to low power in this test, because the Walmart store openings did not occur within close proximity of the majority of FA borrowers.11 4.4.2 Placebo test Under my contagion hypothesis, I expect that granting forgiveness in a home neighborhood reveals information that creates incentives for other borrowers in the same neighborhood to strategically default. A potential concern is that borrowers could learn about FA’s forgiveness policies through online communication as opposed to traditional word-of-mouth communication. To rule out this concern, I test whether randomized forgiveness rates explain future defaults. Specifically, I conduct placebo tests that assign a random home neighborhood to each borrower (column 6). I find that the average coefficient of forgiveness rate in the placebo tests is not statistically different from zero. In addition, this coefficient is positive and significant in only 3% of my simulations. 5 Communication Channel 5.1 The 2012 Event As of 2007, FA’s debt forgiveness policy required that each branch file a formal request and obtain approval from FA’s central risk management department before granting debt forgiveness to a borrower. The risk management department reviewed all formal requests to ensure each loan was at least six months old and that each borrower signed a risk awareness form 11 Less than 0.4% of my sample of loan-months fall within this category. 21 that outlined the negative credit consequences of receiving debt forgiveness.12 On average, only 10% of defaulters received debt forgiveness. Of these, few were repeat forgiveness cases as FA typically declines requests for repeat forgiveness. In August 2012, the director of the risk management department unexpectedly left FA for a position in a much larger credit institution. Consequently, the department lacked a manager with the authority to approve debt forgiveness, and within two weeks, a large backlog of requests accumulated. To alleviate the issue, the CEO/president of the company temporarily transferred the approval responsibilities to executives within the marketing department. Given the marketing department’s lack of experience in assessing risk and their focus on business growth, the executives rapidly granted most forgiveness requests as a means of getting clients to repay. The executives also eliminated the need for borrowers’ signatures on the risk awareness form. As a result, FA’s total dollar amount forgiven increased 188% from the previous month (Figure 2). In light of my prior results, I anticipate that the loan performance worsened after this event, because of a surge in strategic defaults. To examine this prediction, I compare monthly transition matrices of delinquencies in FA’s loan portfolio during the six-month period before and after September 2012. Loans that were one to 29 days delinquent increased from 29.9% to 36.8%, whereas all delinquent loans over 30 days slightly decreased from 11.2% to 10.5% (Table 5, Panels A and B). These results have two implications. First, because the delinquency rate did not increase across all groups, adverse economic conditions do not account for the high incidence of default. Second, the increase in debt forgiveness was not an effective policy to reduce the overall number of loans in default. An effective policy would have caused a larger decrease in delinquent loans over 30 days and little to no impact on the rate of loans that were one to 29 days delinquent. In addition, the likelihood that, in a given month, non-delinquent borrowers became delinquent increased by 2.24% and the likelihood 12 FA reports borrowers who received debt forgiveness to the Credit Bureau. The Credit Bureau then factors the forgiveness into the borrowers credit score, making it more difficult for him to obtain credit in the future. 22 that loans with delinquencies over 60 days re-entered repayment status increased by 0.51% (0.39%+0.12% in Panel C). In sum, the new forgiveness policy intended to help delinquent borrowers get back into repayment, yet it had the unintended consequence of incentivizing strategic default among nondelinquent borrowers. Moreover, an additional unintended consequence is a cross-subsidy between sophisticated and unsophisticated borrowers as described by Campbell (2006). Strategic defaulters are likely the higher credit quality borrowers among the group of defaulters, and will most likely absorb the majority of the forgiveness offered by FA.13 Consistent with this conjecture, the credit quality of borrowers that received forgiveness improved. The average internal credit score increased from 585 points to 597 points after the forgiveness policy change. 5.2 Neighborhood Interconnectedness To further analyze the mechanism driving my prior results, I test whether neighborhood interconnectedness explains strategic default contagion in the cross-section of branches. I expect that tight-knit neighborhoods exhibit a high level of inter-borrower communication. Therefore, branches granting loans to borrowers residing within tight-knit neighborhoods will experience a higher level of strategic default contagion as compared to branches that grant loans to less inter-connected neighborhoods. A potential concern is the endogeneity of branches’ decision to grant forgiveness, because, in equilibrium, branches that observe more communication may grant less forgiveness. To address this concern, I exploit the change to FA’s forgiveness policy in September 2012. I construct four measures of the level of neighborhood interconnectedness one month prior to the policy change, and test whether they explain the level of strategic default observed during the three months after the change. The first variable, Ref erral Ratej , captures the fraction of borrowers referred to FA by 13 Campbell (2006) explains that some financial products create a cross subsidy between sophisticated and unsophisticated households. For example, a cross subsidy arises when unsophisticated borrowers do not optimally refinance, thus allowing the sophisticated borrowers to obtain more attractive terms from the financial institution. 23 a family member or a friend. The second variable, Concentrationj , measures the geographic concentration of the loans within each branch’s portfolio through a Herfindahl measure: Concentrationj = X h2i,j , (2) i where hi.j is equal to the number of loans originated by branch j in zip code i as a fraction of the number of loans in the portfolio of branch j. The third variable, Adj. Concentrationj , adjusts the Concentrationj measure to give less weight to large zip codes: Adj. Concentrationj = X i h2i,j × 1 , log(areai ) where areai is the area of a circle with radius equal to half the distance between the center of zip code i and the center of the closest zip code. The last variable, F raction of Lif ej , is the average number of years that borrowers of branch j have spent in their current home as a fraction of their age. I use the following linear specification to analyze the relation between strategic default and neighborhood interconnectedness: Strategic Def aultj = γ0 + γ1 Ref erral Ratej,Aug12 + γ2 Concentrationj,Aug12 (3) +γ3 Adj. Concentrationj,Aug12 + γ4 F rac. of Lif ej,Aug12 . In this regression, Strategic Def aultj is equal to αd 1,j × F orgiveness Ratej , the product of the average marginal effect of the forgiveness rate and the average forgiveness rate. I estimate αd 1,j from the following specification: Def aulti,j,t = X (α1,j (Ij × F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 )) + Controls + j Ij + M onth F.E., 24 (4) where Ij is an indicator variable that takes the value of one if loan i was originated in branch j, and zero otherwise. The controls are the same as in equation 1. I use Monte Carlo simulations to adjust the standard errors to account for the presence of the generated 14 regressor αd 1,j . The coefficients of Ref erral Rate, Concentration, Adj. Concentration, and F raction of Lif e are positive; however, only Ref erral Rate is statistically significant at the 10% level (Table 6). This result suggests a positive relation between the fraction of referred customers and future contagion. The coefficient of Concentration is not statistically significant, which may be due to the variable lacking more detailed geographic and demographic data. The coefficient of Adj. Concentration is larger, but remains statistically insignificant. This finding suggests that this variable can be further improved by including more precise data about zip code population density.15 In sum, neighborhood interconnectedness helps explain the level of strategic default observed after the lender modified its forgiveness policy. This result is consistent with borrower communication as the channel by which the lender’s private information spreads. As additional borrowers communicate about the lender’s willingness to offer debt forgiveness, strategic default contagion increases. 6 Lender Learning In this Section, I examine whether the lender internalizes the costs resulting from borrowers communicating the terms of their renegotiation agreements. Specifically, I investigate whether the lender alters its operating policies as it learns about strategic default contagion. Although it is well understood that companies learn by doing (Arrow, 1962) and in particular 14 I use the coefficients α d 1,j and their joint variance-covariance matrix obtained from regression 4 to simulate 10,000 random draws of each coefficient αd 1,j,s from a multivariate normal distribution. I then estimate regression 4 using each set of simulated coefficients α d 1,j . I report the average coefficient and p-value obtained after repeating the estimation of regression 4 10,000 times. 15 The INEGI does not report information about the geographic size and total population at the zip code level, thereby limiting the set of variables available to construct more sophisticated measures. 25 by observing financial data (Pastor and Veronesi, 2009), typically, only equilibrium outcomes are observable. Therefore, identifying whether, how, and to what degree lenders learn from strategic default contagion is challenging. I overcome this obstacle by further exploiting FA’s exogenous event in 2012. I examine FA’s actions after the event and test whether branches that experienced a high level of contagion subsequently increased the strictness of their forgiveness and origination policies. 6.1 Forgiveness Policy FA’s branch managers receive a bonus as a function of delinquencies in their respective loan portfolios. As such, they have incentives to minimize the number and extent of nonperforming loans. One method to reduce defaults is to modify the forgiveness policy. Given that FA grants individual branches the autonomy to implement stricter forgiveness policies, I expect that branches that experience high strategic default will learn about the information externality and thus tighten their forgiveness policy. It is ultimately an empirical question as to how long a branch would take to identify contagion; therefore, I conduct the analysis using learning periods of three, six, and nine months (Figure 3). To test my conjecture, I first use the regression in equation 4 to estimate the coefficient of F orgiveness Rate for each branch j throughout each learning period. I then use the estimates αd 1,j as a measure of the level of information transmission among the borrowers in branch j throughout the learning period. This measure is consistent with the geographic location of the lender’s branches, because borrowers are required to originate and service their loans at the branch nearest to their home. In addition, because branches serve a distinct set of neighborhoods, they are not simultaneously impacted by strategic default. Next, I construct a measure of forgiveness policy strictness, Likelihood of F orgiveness, to analyze the extent to which each branch uses debt forgiveness. This measure captures the average number of loans in default that receive debt forgiveness at each branch. Branches that offer forgiveness to a low fraction of defaulters are considered stricter. 26 To examine the relation between the level of information transmission and the level of forgiveness policy strictness, I conduct the following cross-sectional test: Likelihood of F orgivenessj,post = γ0 + γ1 Strategic Def aultj + γ2 T otal Def aultj , (5) where Likelihood of F orgiveness is measured after the learning period, Strategic Def aultj is the product αd 1,j ×F orgiveness Ratej estimated from equation 4 using the learning period, and T otal Def aultj is the average default rate observed in branch j during the learning period. In addition, I use simulations in all specifications to correct standard errors for the presence of a generated regressor. I find no clear relation between strategic default and likelihood of forgiveness within a three-month learning period (Table 7, column 1). Thus, the branches are either unable to detect strategic default or fail to react by tightening their forgiveness policy. Consistent with the notion that learning occurs gradually, increasing the learning period to six months strengthens the relation between strategic default and forgiveness policy strictness (column 3). Although not statistically different, the coefficient is larger in absolute value and has a smaller p-value. In a nine-month period (column 5), the branches tighten their forgiveness policies in response to learning from contagion. Branches that experience higher strategic default are less likely to grant forgiveness to defaulters. In terms of economic magnitude, within a nine-month learning period, the branches reduce their use of forgiveness by 2.44%. This corresponds to approximately a 4.7% tightening of the forgiveness policy. In columns 2, 4, and 6, I include the average default rate of the branch as a control for any change in overall default, which could drive the change in forgiveness. My results are robust to including this additional control. 27 6.2 Origination Policy Next, I examine how FA branches adjusted their origination policy within the three, six, and nine months after the surge in defaults in September 2012. Branches can reduce strategic default by improving the quality of their borrowers through stricter loan origination policies. Alternatively, branches can be less strict in origination. Although the latter strategy may seem counterintuitive, it could prove effective if the lender credibly commits to not grant debt forgiveness. The idea is that borrowers would refrain from strategically defaulting once they realize that delinquent loans will not be forgiven. Relatedly, managers may choose a less strict origination policy due to their compensation incentives. FA pays an additional bonus that increases as a function of the number of loans originated. Managers can therefore substitute their loan performance bonus with the origination bonus. Specifically, when the loan performance bonus decreases due to increased default, managers can lower origination standards to increase their origination bonus. Traditionally, FA’s loan granting process takes less than 24 hours and relies on the borrower’s credit score and internal origination score. The credit and origination scores are compared to the company’s loan granting thresholds. The branches cannot grant loans to individuals who fail to meet the minimum requirements; however, they can choose to deny a loan to an individual that meets the minimum requirements. If a branch sets higher standards such that it rejects candidates that meet FA’s requirements, it is considered stricter. To examine whether the level of information transmission during the learning period affects the strictness of the origination policy for a given branch, I conduct the following test: Decision to Rejectj,post = γ0 + γ1 Strategic Def aultj + γ2 T otal Def aultj . (6) I calculate the dependent variable, Decision to Reject, as the number of qualifying loan requests that were rejected, as a fraction of all qualifying requests. This measure is based on branches’ actual decisions, as opposed to the average quality of new borrowers. Therefore, 28 the measure has the advantage of circumventing concerns regarding branches changing their strictness because of loan requests from worse candidates. For example, using a variable that measures the fraction of loans accepted or rejected could be biased if there are changes to the quality of the candidates requesting loans from the branch. In contrast, Decision to Reject captures the decision made by the loan officer. These decisions are frequently subjective and will depend on the loan officers’ incentives. The relation between level of contagion and origination strictness after a three-month learning period is not statistically significant (Table 8, column 1). Although not statistically different, the coefficients of strategic default are larger for six and nine-month learning periods (columns 3 and 5). Therefore, as the learning period increases, the lender’s branches are better able to detect strategic default and in turn tighten their origination policies. In addition, branches that suffer from higher levels of strategic default are more likely to reject loans that meet FA’s origination thresholds. After a nine-month learning period, a 1% increase in strategic default leads to a 0.8% increase in loan rejections (column 5). This is equivalent to a 10.1% increase in the likelihood that a branch rejects an acceptable loan request. In sum, I find that branches modify their operating decisions as they learn about strategic default contagion. On average, branches that experience a higher level of contagion react within nine months by granting less debt forgiveness and by rejecting more borrowers that meet FA’s loan origination thresholds. Accordingly, lenders renegotiate less often as they learn that renegotiations are suboptimal because of information externalities. 6.3 Robustness In this section I conduct two robustness tests. Specifically, in Panel A of Table 9 I perform a placebo test. I repeat the analyses in Tables 7 and 8 for a nine-month learning period assuming that the exogenous change in FA’s forgiveness policy occurred on three different placebo months: February, July, and December 2010. In these tests I find that the coefficients 29 of Strategic Def ault are not statistically significant. In some of the cases the coefficients also have the opposite sign of an outcome consistent with FA learning over time. I also test whether the learning results are due to different branches having different strictness levels for their origination and forgiveness policies before FA changed its forgiveness policy. For example, if a given branch has historically been stricter than other branches, it is not clear that learning about strategic default contagion drives the strictness level after the policy changed. In Panel B, I use changes in the level of Likelihood of F orgiveness and Decision to Reject from September 2011, one year before FA changed its forgiveness policy. The coefficients of Strategic Def ault are consistent with FA learning over time. However, in contrast to previous results, the nine-month learning period coefficient within the forgiveness regression is not significant at the 10% level (column 3). 7 Conclusion This paper exploits a unique setting to examine the negative externalities companies face when revealing private information to customers. Using a detailed data set of loans to small business owners, I find strategic default contagion among customers within the same neighborhood who communicate regarding the lender’s forgiveness policy. I also find that the lender learns from strategic default contagion and attempts to mitigate it by tightening its debt forgiveness and origination policies. A distinct feature of my setting is that negotiations occur in a private setting. Therefore, my findings shed light on the dynamic information environment of private negotiations and information transfers between firms and their customers. While theoretical models demonstrate that customers can play the role of a firm’s strategic opponent, there is a paucity of empirical evidence that quantifies the costs incurred when a firm shares private information with customers. I am able to quantify the cost by estimating the level of strategic default contagion after forgiveness is granted. 30 Customers are particularly important to study because they are a key determinant of a firm’s success. Their relationship with firms allows them to gain access to information that is not publicly available. As such, it could be especially damaging to a firm if customers freely communicate the information they obtain through negotiations. It is also valuable to understand how customers’ actions impact the firm. My results show that firms take into account the possibility of customer communication and modify their operating decisions accordingly. Furthermore, my paper contributes to the foreclosure contagion literature by demonstrating the consequences of loan modifications. The objective of loan modifications is to curtail default. However, in line with the economic predictions of Posner and Zingales (2009), I show that loan modifications do not achieve an efficient outcome. Instead, due to borrower communication, loan modifications (i) only modestly reduce the likelihood that a loan in default becomes uncollectible and (ii) cause the lender to incur expenses beyond that of granting forgiveness to financially distressed borrowers, as financially able borrowers strategically default. Lastly, I show that lenders recognize strategic default as a cost associated with loan modifications and therefore limit their renegotiation activities. This finding helps answer the question of why there was a low incidence of loan renegotiations during the financial crisis. 31 Appendix A.1 Definition of variables Variable Description Adj. Concentration Size-adjusted Herfindahl index measure of the zip code concentration of loans held by each branch on August 2012. P 1 , where hi,j is equal to Adjusted Concentrationj = i h2i,j × log(area i) the number of loans originated by branch j in zip code i as a fraction of the number of loans in the portfolio of branch; areai is the area of a circle with radius equal to half the distance between the center of zip code i and the center of the closest zip code. Age Borrower’s age in years. Ch. in Likelihood of F orgiveness Difference in the Likelihood of F orgiveness in the post-learning period and the Likelihood of F orgiveness in September 2011 (one year before the change to FA’s forgiveness policy). Ch. in Decision to Reject Difference in the rate of Decision to Reject in the post-learning period and the rate of Decision to Reject in September 2011 (one year before the change to FA’s forgiveness policy). Concentration Herfindahl index measure of the zip code concentration of loans held by P each branch on August 2012. Concentrationj = i h2i,j , where hi,j is equal to the number of loans originated by branch j in zip code i as a fraction of the number of loans in the portfolio of branch j. Credit Score Borrower’s credit score at origination, as reported by Buró de Crédito. Scores range from 400 to 850. Commuting Distance Number of miles between home and work zip codes. This distance is calculated using the spherical law of cosines using latitude and longitude coordinates from GeoData Ltd. Decision to Reject Number of loans that met the minimum origination requirements but were rejected, divided by the total number of loans that met the minimum origination requirements. During the testing period of my sample, the minimum internal score required from borrowers is 599. Def aultt One if the borrower was current on his loan in month t − 1 and had one or more missed payments at the end of month t; zero otherwise. Def ault Ratehome,t Total number of nonperforming loans in month t as a fraction of all loans in the borrower’s home zip code. 32 Variable Description Def ault Ratework,t Total number of nonperforming loans in month t as a fraction of all loans in the borrower’s work zip code. Education The highest degree of education attained by the borrower. One if primary school, 2 if secondary school, 3 if high school or technical school, 4 if undergraduate degree, 5 if graduate degree, and 0 otherwise. F orgiven in the P ast One if the borrower has previously received forgiveness on his current loan; zero otherwise. F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 Total number of loans that received forgiveness in month t − 1 as a fraction of all loans in the borrower’s home zip code. F raction of Lif e On August 2012, the average fraction of life that the borrowers in a given branch’s loan portfolio had been living in their current home. Lif e at Home Years at current home divided by age. Lif e at Occupation Years at current occupation divided by age. Gender One if the borrower is male, zero otherwise. Inf lation in Clothes Monthly inflation rate in clothing items, as reported by INEGI. Inf lation in F ood Monthly inflation rate in food, as reported by INEGI. Inf lation in Housing Monthly inflation rate in housing, as reported by INEGI. Inf lation in T ransportation Monthly inflation rate in transportation services, as reported by INEGI. Internal Credit Score FA’s internally generated borrower loan eligibility score, which incorporates demographic information and credit score. Score ranges from 0 to 680. Likelihood of F orgiveness Average number of loans in default that receive debt forgiveness at each branch. Loan Amount Principal amount of the loan at origination in thousands of Mexican pesos. M ultiple Accounts One if the borrower has multiple credit accounts at origination as reported by Buró de Crédito, zero otherwise. N atural Disaster One if the state where the borrower lives used funds from the Federal Natural Disaster Fund (FONDEN) during the year; zero otherwise. N ew Def ault Ratework(−i),t−2 Fraction of borrowers that become delinquent in t − 2 and satisfy the following two conditions: (i) they live in the same home neighborhood as borrower i, and (ii) they do not work in the same zip code as borrower i. N ot F orgiven One if the borrower has defaulted on his current loan in the past, but did not receive forgiveness; zero otherwise. 33 Variable Description P ayment F requency One if the loan requires monthly payments, two if it requires biweekly payments, and three if it requires weekly payments. P ct P aid Percentage of the loan that has been repaid at time t. P ct P aid2 Square of the percentage of the loan repaid at time t. Ref erral Rate On August 2012, the fraction of borrowers in a given branch’s loan portfolio that had been referred to FA through a family member or friend. Repeat Borrower One if the borrower has previously had a loan with FA; zero otherwise. Reported Income Borrower’s income in thousands of Mexican Pesos as reported at origination. Strategic Def ault Estimated marginal effect of forgiveness α d 1,j times average forgiveness rate. T otal Def ault Number of loans in default divided by the number of loans in the portfolio of each branch. W almart N ear Homet One if the borrower lives at a distance smaller than two miles and works at a distance greater than two miles from a Walmart store that was opened in month t. W almart N ear W orkt One if the borrower works at a distance smaller than two miles and lives at a distance greater than two miles from a Walmart store that was opened in month t. W inter One if the month is between November and March; zero otherwise. 34 A.2 Correlations table This table presents the Pearson correlations for the variables used in the strategic default regressions. Variable definitions are provided in Appendix Table A.1. 35 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) Variables Def aultt F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 Def ault Ratework,t Def ault Ratehome,t Internal Credit Score Age Gender Education Credit Score F raction of lif e at current home F raction of lif e at current occupation Loan/Income P ayment F requency Repeat Borrower (1) 1.000 0.057 0.053 0.062 -0.085 -0.068 -0.004 0.013 -0.086 0.013 -0.007 -0.041 0.034 -0.038 (2) 1.000 0.133 0.351 0.015 -0.023 0.027 0.041 -0.005 0.089 0.043 0.002 0.011 0.087 (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) 1.000 0.279 1.000 0.006 0.010 1.000 -0.010 -0.043 0.367 1.000 -0.026 0.002 0.071 0.075 1.000 -0.010 -0.005 0.015 -0.157 0.020 1.000 0.002 0.016 0.448 0.078 -0.010 -0.069 1.000 0.012 0.034 0.019 -0.254 0.022 0.176 -0.038 1.000 -0.033 -0.008 0.230 0.018 0.082 0.063 -0.013 0.203 1.000 -0.013 -0.014 0.049 0.012 -0.002 -0.010 0.131 0.031 0.007 1.000 0.031 0.018 -0.038 -0.059 -0.048 -0.108 -0.001 0.043 0.029 -0.035 -0.004 0.001 -0.009 0.095 0.039 -0.002 -0.036 0.010 0.093 0.166 (13) 1.000 -0.014 References Adelino, M., K. Gerardi, and P. S. Willen (2013). “Why don’t Lenders renegotiate more home mortgages? Redefaults, self-cures and securitization”. Journal of Monetary Economics 60, pp. 835–853. Agarwal, S., G. Amromin, I. Ben-David, S. Chomsisengphet, T. Piskorski, and A. Seru (2013). “Policy intervention in debt renegotiation: Evidence from the Home Affordable Modification Program”. NBER, Working paper. Ali, A., S. Klasa, and E. Yeung (2014). “Industry concentration and corporate disclosure policy”. Journal of Accounting and Economics, forthcoming. Angrist, J. D. and J. S. Pischke (2008). Mostly harmless econometrics: An empiricist’s companion. Princeton University Press. Arrow, K. J. (1962). “The economic implications of learning by doing”. The Review of Economic Studies 22, pp. 155–173. Brock, W. A. and S. N. Durlauf (2001). “Interactions-based models”. Handbook of Econometrics 5, pp. 3297–3380. Campbell, J. Y. (2006). “Household finance”. The Journal of Finance 61, pp. 1553–1604. Cohen, L., A. Frazzini, and C. Malloy (2008). “The small world of investing: Board connections and mutual fund returns”. Journal of Political Economy 116, pp. 951–979. Crawford, V. P. and J. Sobel (1982). “Strategic information transmission”. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 50, pp. 1431–1451. Dedman, E. and C. Lennox (2009). “Perceived competition, profitability and the withholding of information about sales and the cost of sales”. Journal of Accounting and Economics 48, pp. 210–230. Doner, R. F. and B. R. Schneider (2000). “Business associations and economic development: Why some associations contribute more than others”. Business and Politics 2, pp. 261– 288. 36 Dye, R. A. (1986). “Proprietary and nonproprietary disclosures”. Journal of Business 59, pp. 331–366. Ellis, J. A., C. E. Fee, and S. E. Thomas (2012). “Proprietary costs and the disclosure of information about customers”. Journal of Accounting Research 50, pp. 685–727. Goodstein, R., P. Hanouna, C. D. Ramirez, and C. W. Stahel (2013). “Contagion effects in strategic mortgage defaults”. George Mason University, Working paper. Guiso, L., P. Sapienza, and L. Zingales (2013). “The determinants of attitudes toward strategic default on mortgages”. The Journal of Finance 68, pp. 1473–1515. Guo, R., B. Lev, and N. Zhou (2004). “Competitive costs of disclosure by biotech IPOs”. Journal of Accounting Research 42, pp. 319–355. Hong, H., J. D. Kubik, and J. C. Stein (2005). “Thy neighbor’s portfolio: Word-of-mouth effects in the holdings and trades of money managers”. The Journal of Finance 60, pp. 2801–2824. Jones, D. A. (2007). “Voluntary disclosure in R&D-intensive industries”. Contemporary Accounting Research 24, pp. 489–522. Keefe, S.E. (1984). “Real and ideal extended familism among Mexican Americans and Anglo Americans: On the meaning of" close" family ties”. Human organization 43, pp. 65–70. Manski, C. F. (1993). “Identification of endogenous social effects: The reflection problem”. The Review of Economic Studies 60, pp. 531–542. — (2000). “Economic analysis of social interactions”. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 14, pp. 115–136. Mayer, C. J., E. Morrison, T. Piskorski, and A. Gupta (2013). “Mortgage modification and strategic behavior: evidence from a legal settlement with Countrywide”. Columbia University, Working paper. Munroe, D. J. and L. Wilse-Samson (2013). “Foreclosure contagion: Measurement and mechanisms”. Columbia University, Working paper. 37 Pastor, L. and P. Veronesi (2009). “Learning in financial markets”. Annual Review of Financial Economics 1, pp. 361–381. Pena, A. (2008). “Unregulated financial intermediation in Mexico-the new Sociedad Financiera De Objeto Multiple or SOFOM”. Law and Business Review of the Americas 14, p. 169. Piskorski, T., A. Seru, and V. Vig (2010). “Securitization and distressed loan renegotiation: Evidence from the subprime mortgage crisis”. Journal of Financial Economics 97, pp. 369–397. Posner, E. A. and L. Zingales (2009). “A loan modification approach to the housing crisis”. American Law and Economics Review 11, pp. 575–607. Rodriguez, N., C. B. Mira, N. D. Paez, and H. F. Myers (2007). “Exploring the complexities of familism and acculturation: Central constructs for people of Mexican origin”. American Journal of Community Psychology 39, pp. 61–77. Shue, K. (2013). “Executive networks and firm policies: Evidence from the random assignment of MBA peers”. Review of Financial Studies 26, pp. 1401–1442. Stock, J. H., J. H. Wright, and M. Yogo (2002). “A survey of weak instruments and weak identification in generalized method of moments”. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 20, pp. 518–529. Towe, C. and C. Lawley (2013). “The contagion effect of neighboring foreclosures”. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 5, pp. 313–335. Verrecchia, R. E. (1983). “Discretionary disclosure”. Journal of Accounting and Economics 5, pp. 179–194. Verrecchia, R. E. and J. Weber (2006). “Redacted disclosure”. Journal of Accounting Research 44, pp. 791–814. Wagenhofer, A. (1990). “Voluntary disclosure with a strategic opponent”. Journal of Accounting and Economics 12, pp. 341–363. 38 Figure 1: Identification Strategy This figure presents a graphical exposition of the identification strategy. Borrowers A and B live in the same tight-knit neighborhood. They commute to their respective working areas where they each run a small independent business. Analogously, Borrowers C and D live in another neighborhood and they also commute to the respective locations of their small businesses. I define strategic contagion in the following way: suppose Borrower A and Borrower C default on their small consumer loans, because of an economic shock that affects the whole work area. The lender offers Borrower A debt forgiveness as a means of getting him out of default and back into repayment. Borrower A subsequently communicates with his neighbor, Borrower B, regarding the lender’s forgiveness policy. Borrower B then chooses to strategically default with the objective of getting a portion of his loan forgiven. Borrower D does not default, because he neither experiences an economic shock nor has any interaction with Borrowers A or B. 39 Figure 2: Frequency and Total Amount of Debt Forgiveness over Time These figures present the frequency and total amount of debt forgiveness that FA has granted over time. Panel A plots the number of loans that received debt forgiveness during a given month. Panel B plots the total amount of debt forgiveness in thousands of Mexican pesos (MXN) in a given month. In both graphs, the vertical line is located on September 2012, the month when FA changed its debt-forgiveness policy. Panel A: Frequency of forgiveness Panel B: Total forgiveness amount 40 Figure 3: Branch Learning This figure presents the time structure of the learning analysis conducted in section 6. Each of the three learning periods begins on September 2012, the date that FA changed its debt-forgiveness policy. Learning period 1 consists of three months after the policy change and the corresponding testing period begins thereafter. Learning period 2 consists of six months after the policy change and the corresponding testing period begins thereafter. Learning period 3 consists of nine months after the policy change and the corresponding testing period begins thereafter. 41 Table 1: Descriptive Statistics This table presents the summary statistics for the loan sample. The loans in the sample were originated in 54 branches from January 2011 through March 2014. Panel A reports the borrower and loan characteristics at origination for 14,649 loans. Panel B reports the performance of the loans in 110,649 loan months. Panel C reports summary statistics at the branch level. Variable definitions are provided in Appendix Table A.1. Panel A: Borrower and loan characteristics Variable N Mean Age 14,649 39.22 Gender 14,649 0.43 Education 14,649 2.69 Credit Score 9,412 691.87 Internal Credit Score 14,649 601.20 Lif e at Home 14,649 0.67 Lif e at Occupation 14,649 0.29 Loan/Income 14,649 0.85 P ayment f requency 14,649 2.92 Repeat borrower 14,649 0.38 Commuting distance 14,649 3.80 Std. Dev. Q1 Median 12.24 29.00 38.00 0.50 0.00 0.00 0.75 2.00 3.00 33.62 671.00 696.00 20.02 587.00 604.00 0.31 0.39 0.69 0.16 0.17 0.27 0.37 0.62 0.80 0.31 3.00 3.00 0.48 0.00 0.00 4.38 1.25 2.38 Panel B: Loan-performance Variable Def ault Def ault Ratework,t Def ault Ratehome,t F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 Mean 0.16 0.29 0.29 0.20 Std. Dev. 0.36 0.11 0.12 0.12 Q1 0.00 0.23 0.23 0.13 Median 0.00 0.29 0.30 0.20 Q3 0.00 0.36 0.36 0.28 Mean 0.26 0.06 0.19 0.67 0.54 0.10 Std. Dev. 0.10 0.05 0.13 0.11 0.19 0.05 Q1 0.18 0.03 0.12 0.59 0.42 0.05 Median 0.25 0.04 0.14 0.67 0.51 0.09 Q3 0.33 0.07 0.21 0.75 0.62 0.13 statistics N 110,649 110,649 110,649 110,617 Panel C: Branch-level statistics Variable N Ref erral Rate 54 Concentration 54 Adj. Concentration 54 F raction of Lif e 54 Likelihood of F orgiveness 54 Decision to Reject 54 42 Q3 48.00 1.00 3.00 715.00 615.00 1.00 0.40 1.08 3.00 1.00 4.86 Table 2: Effect of Debt Forgiveness on Defaults This table reports the estimation results from regressions of the following form: Def aulti,t =α0 +α1 F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 +Controls + T ime F.E. In this model, the dependent variable is binary and takes the value of one if a loan i is in default at month t, but not at month t − 1, and zero otherwise. The main explanatory variable is the forgiveness rate at month t − 1 in the zip code where borrower i lives. Panel A reports a linear regression analysis. Panel B partitions the analysis at the median of Fraction of Life at Current Home. Variable definitions are provided in Appendix Table A.1. Standard errors are clustered at the branch level and are reported below the coefficient estimates. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the two-tailed 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Panel A: Linear Regression Analysis Variables F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 Predicted Sign + Def ault Ratework,t + Internal Credit Score - Age ? Gender ? Education - Credit Score - Lif e at Home ? Lif e at Occupation - Loan/Income + P ct P aid ? P ct P aid2 ? P ayment F requency + F orgiven in the P ast + N ot F orgiven + Repeat Borrower - F orgiveness Rate × Repeat Borrower ? Month fixed effects Industry fixed effects Work zip code - month fixed effects Home zip code fixed effects Prior forgiveness Repeat borrowers Adj. R2 Observations 43 (1) 0.087∗∗∗ (0.023) 0.129∗∗∗ (0.031) (2) 0.074∗∗∗ (0.019) 0.129∗∗∗ (0.021) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) (3) 0.053∗∗∗ (0.019) 0.122∗∗∗ (0.019) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) -0.002∗∗∗ (0.000) -0.008 (0.006) -0.002 (0.004) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) -0.018∗ (0.010) -0.014 (0.015) 0.037∗∗∗ (0.008) 0.446∗∗∗ (0.034) -0.337∗∗∗ (0.053) 0.035∗∗∗ (0.008) 0.051∗∗∗ (0.009) 0.458∗∗∗ (0.025) -0.371∗∗∗ (0.035) 0.037∗∗∗ (0.007) 0.051∗∗∗ (0.008) 0.264∗∗∗ (0.024) -0.305∗∗∗ (0.032) 0.029∗∗∗ (0.005) 0.317∗∗∗ (0.016) 0.174∗∗∗ (0.008) Yes Yes No No No No 0.035 32,415 Yes Yes No No No No 0.026 64,222 Yes Yes No No Yes No 0.068 66,339 (4) 0.095∗∗∗ (0.027) (5) 0.086∗∗ (0.028) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) 0.036∗∗∗ (0.007) 0.227∗∗∗ (0.028) -0.256∗∗∗ (0.037) 0.025∗∗∗ (0.006) 0.281∗∗∗ (0.014) 0.167∗∗∗ (0.007) -0.043∗∗∗ (0.008) -0.018 (0.036) No Yes Yes No Yes Yes 0.170 107,687 0.055∗∗∗ (0.008) 0.316∗∗∗ (0.027) -0.293∗∗∗ (0.035) 0.026∗∗∗ (0.008) 0.241∗∗∗ (0.013) 0.134∗∗∗ (0.007) -0.038∗∗∗ (0.011) -0.013 (0.042) No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 0.179 107,687 Panel B: Linear regression analysis partitioned at the median of Lif e at Home Lif e at Home Variables F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 Predicted Sign + Def ault Ratework,t + Internal Credit Score - Loan/Income + P ct P aid ? P ct P aid2 ? P ayment F requency + F orgiven in the P ast + N ot F orgiven + Repeat Borrower - F orgiveness Rate × Repeat Borrower ? Month fixed effects Industry fixed effects Work zip code - month fixed effects Home zip code fixed effects Prior forgiveness Repeat borrowers Adj.R2 Observations (1) 0.052∗ (0.029) 0.134∗∗∗ (0.031) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) 0.043∗∗∗ (0.009) 0.453∗∗∗ (0.029) -0.387∗∗∗ (0.037) 0.033∗∗∗ (0.008) Yes Yes No No No No 0.027 28,157 44 Low (2) 0.036 (0.028) 0.127∗∗∗ (0.028) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) 0.045∗∗∗ (0.009) 0.321∗∗∗ (0.028) -0.348∗∗∗ (0.036) 0.028∗∗∗ (0.007) 0.304∗∗∗ (0.019) 0.128∗∗∗ (0.007) Yes Yes No No Yes No 0.057 29,056 (3) 0.065 (0.057) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) 0.048∗∗∗ (0.013) 0.391∗∗∗ (0.044) -0.335∗∗∗ (0.058) 0.024∗ (0.013) 0.209∗∗∗ (0.025) 0.081∗∗∗ (0.010) -0.031∗∗ (0.014) -0.035 (0.053) No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 0.096 46,497 (1) 0.090∗∗∗ (0.026) 0.148∗∗∗ (0.022) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) 0.069∗∗∗ (0.010) 0.466∗∗∗ (0.030) -0.351∗∗∗ (0.044) 0.037∗∗∗ (0.009) Yes Yes No No No No 0.028 28,157 High (2) 0.079∗∗∗ (0.023) 0.141∗∗∗ (0.021) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) 0.066∗∗∗ (0.009) 0.296∗∗∗ (0.025) -0.285∗∗∗ (0.037) 0.033∗∗∗ (0.007) 0.281∗∗∗ (0.015) 0.137∗∗∗ (0.007) Yes Yes No No Yes No 0.057 29,056 (3) 0.105∗ (0.060) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) 0.093∗∗∗ (0.013) 0.428∗∗∗ (0.047) -0.355∗∗∗ (0.062) 0.051∗∗∗ (0.016) 0.187∗∗∗ (0.023) 0.074∗∗∗ (0.014) -0.042∗ (0.022) 0.008 (0.099) No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 0.081 46,498 Table 3: Instrumental Variables Regressions This table reports the coefficients from the instrumental variables regressions. Panel A reports the estimation results of the second-stage regression of the following form: Def aulti,t = α0 + d Ratehome,t−1 )+Controls. In this model, the dependent variable is binary and takes α1 (F orgiveness the value of one if loan i is in default at month t, but not at montht − 1, and zero otherwise. The main explanatory variable is estimated from the following first-stage regression: F orgivenessRatehome,t−1 = γ0 + γ1 N ew Def ault Ratework(−i),t−2 + Controls, reported in Panel B. The instrument, N ew Def ault Ratework(−i),t−2 , is defined as the fraction of borrowers that become delinquent in t − 2 and satisfy the following two conditions: (i) they live in the same home neighborhood as borrower i, and (ii) they do not work in the same area as borrower i. Robust standard errors are reported below the coefficient estimates. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the two-tailed 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Panel A: Second-stage regressions Variables F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 Predicted Sign + Def ault Ratework,t + Internal Credit Score - Loan/Income + P ct P aid ? P ct P aid2 ? P ayment F requency + Repeat Borrower - F orgiveness Rate × Repeat Borrower ? F orgiven in the P ast + N ot F orgiven + F orgiveness Rate × F orgiven in the P ast - Month fixed effects Industry fixed effects Adj.R2 Observations Panel B: First stage regressions Instrument N ew Def ault Ratework(−i),t−2 Predicted Sign + Second stage regressors Angrist-Pischke partial R2 Angrist-PischkeF -stat 45 (1) 2SLS 0.214∗∗ (0.108) 0.130∗∗∗ (0.017) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) 0.063∗∗∗ (0.006) 0.289∗∗∗ (0.024) -0.181∗∗∗ (0.033) 0.040∗∗∗ (0.006) (2) 2SLS 0.264∗∗∗ (0.100) 0.116∗∗∗ (0.013) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) 0.039∗∗∗ (0.004) 0.306∗∗∗ (0.017) -0.152∗∗∗ (0.024) 0.031∗∗∗ (0.004) -0.078∗∗∗ (0.030) 0.095 (0.138) (3) 2SLS 0.248∗∗∗ (0.080) 0.124∗∗∗ (0.012) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) 0.021∗∗∗ (0.004) 0.141∗∗∗ (0.018) -0.175∗∗∗ (0.026) 0.027∗∗∗ (0.003) Yes Yes 0.015 50,817 Yes Yes 0.026 91,462 0.349∗∗ (0.144) 0.174∗∗∗ (0.004) -0.222 (0.557) Yes Yes 0.062 91,462 (1) 0.198∗∗∗ (0.008) Yes 0.023 545.03 (2) 0.199∗∗∗ (0.008) Yes 0.023 888.44 (3) 0.193∗∗∗ (0.006) Yes 0.022 883.34 (4) 2SLS 0.182∗ (0.099) 0.110∗∗∗ (0.012) -0.001∗∗∗ (0.000) 0.039∗∗∗ (0.004) 0.106∗∗∗ (0.018) -0.135∗∗∗ (0.027) 0.022∗∗∗ (0.003) -0.088∗∗∗ (0.029) 0.143 (0.136) 0.358∗∗ (0.144) 0.173∗∗∗ (0.004) -0.248 (0.558) Yes Yes 0.067 91,462 (4) 0.198∗∗∗ (0.008) Yes 0.022 884.60 Table 4: Robustness Analysis and Alternative Hypotheses This table reports the estimation results from regressions of the following form: Def aulti,t = α0 + α1 F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 + Controls + T ime F.E. In this model, the dependent variable is binary and takes the value of one if loan i is in default at month t, but not at month t − 1, and zero otherwise. The main explanatory variable is the forgiveness rate at month t − 1 in the zip code where borrower i lives. Columns 1-6 vary in the controls included in the regression. Variable definitions are provided in Appendix Table A.1. Standard errors are clustered at the branch level and are reported below the coefficient estimates. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the two-tailed 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 Predicted Sign + Def ault Ratework,t + Def ault Ratehome,t + Inf lation in F ood P rices + Inf lation in T ransportation + Inf lation in Clothes + Inf lation in Housing + N atural Disaster + F orgiveness Rate × N at. Disaster ? M ultiple Accounts - F orgiveness Rate × M ultiple Acc. ? W inter + F orgiveness Rate × W inter + W almart N ear W ork + F orgiveness Rate × W almart W ork - W almart N ear Home - F orgiveness Rate × W almart Home ? Borrower and loan characteristics Month fixed effects Industry fixed effects Work zip code - month fixed effects Adj.R2 Observations (1) 0.049∗∗ (0.019) 0.126∗∗∗ (0.015) 0.095∗∗∗ (0.014) (2) 0.098∗∗∗ (0.031) (3) 0.084∗∗∗ (0.024) 0.143∗∗∗ (0.016) (4) 0.077∗∗∗ (0.018) 0.145∗∗∗ (0.015) (5) 0.078∗∗∗ (0.019) 0.146∗∗∗ (0.015) Placebo (6) -0.004 (0.016) 0.140∗∗∗ (0.003) 0.053 (0.053) -0.089 (0.239) 0.026 (0.051) -0.077 (0.233) Yes Yes Yes No 0.024 89,943 Yes Yes Yes No 0.025 89,943 0.021 (0.023) 0.019 (0.015) 0.072∗∗∗ (0.013) 0.149∗∗∗ (0.032) 0.074∗∗∗ (0.016) 0.001 (0.007) -0.009 (0.026) -0.031∗∗∗ (0.005) -0.004 (0.024) -0.051∗∗∗ (0.013) 0.002 (0.025) Yes Yes Yes No 0.025 89,943 46 Yes No Yes Yes 0.045 89,943 Yes Yes Yes No 0.026 89,943 Yes Yes Yes No 0.024 89,943 Table 5: Loan-Performance Transition Matrices, pre and post September 2012 This table presents loan-performance transition matrices. In all panels, the rows indicate the delinquency status of the loan at month t, ranging from non-delinquent to over 90 days delinquent. The columns indicate the status of the loan at month t + 1, ranging from non-delinquent to over 90 days delinquent. In Panel A, the transition probabilities are calculated for the six-month period before the change in forgiveness policy. In Panel B, the transition probabilities are calculated for the six-month period as of the change in forgiveness policy. Panel C reports the difference between Panel B and Panel A, with *, **, and *** indicating significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Panel A: March 2012 to August 2012 Fraction of loans Status at month t Non-delinquent 1-29 days 30-59 days 60-89 days 90+ days 58.9% 29.9% 3.7% 3.0% 4.5% Status at month t + 1 Non-delinquent 1-29 days 79.9% 18.7% 1.9% 0.3% 0.0% 20.1% 69.0% 8.8% 0.8% 0.1% 30-59 days 60-89 days 90+ days 0.0% 12.3% 3.8% 0.3% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 85.5% 1.6% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 97.1% 99.8% 30-59 days 60-89 days 90+ days 0.0% 11.6% 2.2% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 81.1% 1.9% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 96.6% 99.7% 30-59 days 60-89 days 90+ days 0.00% -0.68%∗∗∗ -1.64%∗∗∗ -0.17%∗∗ -0.02% 0.00% 0.00% -4.45%∗∗∗ 0.33% -0.03% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% -0.47% -0.13% Panel B: September 2012 to February 2013 Fraction of loans Status at month t Non-delinquent 1-29 days 30-59 days 60-89 days 90+ days 52.7% 36.8% 4.4% 3.3% 2.9% Status at month t + 1 Non-delinquent 1-29 days 77.6% 18.4% 5.0% 0.7% 0.2% 22.4% 70.0% 11.8% 0.7% 0.2% Panel C: Changes in delinquency after September 2012 (Panel B − Panel A) Fraction of loans Status at month t Non-delinquent 1-29 days 30-59 days 60-89 days 90+ days ∗∗∗ -6.19% 6.86%∗∗∗ 0.65% 0.29% -1.62%∗∗ Status at month t + 1 Non-delinquent 1-29 days ∗∗∗ -2.24% -0.35% 3.13%∗∗∗ 0.39%∗∗∗ 0.12%∗∗ 47 ∗∗∗ 2.24% 1.03%∗∗∗ 2.96%∗∗∗ -0.08% 0.06% Table 6: Ex-ante Measures of Contagion This table reports the estimation results from the following regression: Strategic Def aultj = β0 + β1 Ref erral RateAug0 12,j + β2 ConcentrationAug0 12,j + β3 Adjusted ConcentrationAug0 12,l + β4 F raction of Lif eAug0 12,j . In this model, the dependent variable is computed as α d 1,j × F orgiveness Ratej during the three-month period after the change in forgiveness policy. α d 1,j is estimated by running the strategic default regression, Def aultj,t = α0 + α1 F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 + Controls + T ime F.E., for branch j. Variable definitions are provided in Appendix Table A.1. Simulations are used to correct the standard errors for the presence of a generated regressor. P-values are reported below the coefficient estimates. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the two-tailed 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Variable Predicted Sign Constant Ref erral Rate + Concentration + Adjusted Concentration + F raction of Lif e + (1) (2) -0.073∗ 0.009∗ * (0.061) (0.029) 0.316∗ (0.079) 0.044 (0.457) (3) 0.030 54 48 0.002 54 (5) 0.0021 -0.110 -0.154∗ (0.163) (0.213) (0.086) 0.180∗ (0.091) 0.078 (0.189) Adj. R2 Observations (4) 0.008 54 0.052 (0.327) 0.192 0.172 (0.161) (0.216) 0.005 54 0.038 54 Table 7: Bank’s Adjustments to the Forgiveness Policy This table reports the estimation results from the following regression: Likelihood of F orgivenessj = γ0 + γ1 Strategic Def aultj + γ2 T otal Def aultj . In this model, the dependent variable is computed as the average likelihood that a defaulter in branch j receives forgiveness. In columns 1 and 2, the analysis is performed over a three-month learning period, in columns 3 and 4, a six-month learning period, and in columns 5 and 6, a nine-month learning period. In all Columns, the main explanatory variable is the level of strategic default among borrowers serviced by branch j. Strategic default is measured as α d 1,j × F orgiveness Ratej , estimated from: Def aultj,t = α0 + α1 F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 + Controls + T ime F.E., columns 2, 4, and 6 include the level of total defaults in each branch as an additional control. Simulations are used to correct the standard errors for the presence of a generated regressor. P-values are reported below the coefficient estimates. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the two-tailed 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Learning period: Prediction with learning: Constant Strategic Def ault 3 months 9 months (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (-) 0.538∗∗∗ (<.001) -0.165 (0.577) (-) 1.287∗∗∗ (<.001) -0.191 (0.612) -7.475∗∗ (0.010) (-) 0.509∗∗∗ (<.001) -1.036 (0.103) (-) 1.038∗∗∗ (<.001) -0.891 (0.136) -5.388∗∗ (0.034) (-) 0.519∗∗∗ (<.001) -1.397∗ (0.069) (-) 1.011∗∗∗ (<.001) -1.212∗ (0.086) -5.191∗∗ (0.018) 1.08% 54 9.82% 54 2.15% 54 10.69% 54 2.43% 54 12.91% 54 -0.871 (0.903) -0.700 (0.709) -0.361 (0.305) -0.321 (0.281) T otal Def ault R2 Observations: 6 months Three-month difference: t-test 49 Table 8: Bank’s Adjustments to the Origination Policy This table reports the estimation results from the following regression: Decision to Rejectj = γ0 + γ1 Strategic Def aultj + γ2 T otal Def aultj . In this model, the dependent variable is computed as the number of loans rejected by branch j as a fraction of the number of loans that met FA origination requirements. In columns 1 and 2, the analysis is performed over a three-month learning period, in columns 3 and 4, a six-month learning period, and in columns 5 and 6, a nine-month learning period. In all columns, the main explanatory variable is the level of strategic default among borrowers serviced by branch j. Strategic default is measured as α d 1,j × F orgiveness Ratej , estimated from: Def aultj,t = α0 + α1 F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 + Controls + T ime F.E., columns 2, 4, and 6 include the level of total defaults in each branch as an additional control. Simulations are used to correct the standard errors for the presence of a generated regressor. P-values are reported below the coefficient estimates. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the two-tailed 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Learning period: 3 months (1) Prediction with learning: Constant Strategic Def ault T otal Def ault R2 Observations: 6 months (2) (+) (+) ∗ 0.096 0.153∗ (0.070) (0.070) 0.278 0.260 (0.357) (0.386) -0.571 (0.492) 3.30% 54 3.93% 54 Three-month difference: t-test 50 9 months (3) (4) (5) (6) (+) 0.086∗∗∗ (<.001) 0.505 (0.227) (+) 0.179∗∗ (0.013) 0.544 (0.188) -0.945 (0.185) (+) 0.076∗∗∗ (<.001) 0.799∗ (0.095) (+) 0.150∗∗∗ (<.001) 0.843∗ (0.098) -0.783 (0.175) 5.11% 54 8.56% 54 9.71% 54 13.28% 54 0.227 (0.268) 0.284 (0.336) 0.294 (0.310) 0.299 (0.311) Table 9: Robustness Analysis of FA’s Learning Panel A of this table reports the estimation results from the following regressions: Likelihood of F orgivenessj = γ0 +γ1 Strategic Def aultj +γ2 T otal Def aultj and Decision to Rejectj = γ0 + γ1 Strategic Def aultj + γ2 T otal Def aultj .The analysis is performed over a nine-month learning period that starts on three placebo dates: February 2010, July 2010, and December 2010. Panel B reports the estimation results from the following regressions: Ch. in Likelihood of F orgivenessj = γ0 + γ1 Strategic Def aultj + γ2 T otal Def aultj and Ch. in Decision to Rejectj = γ0 + γ1 Strategic Def aultj + γ2 T otal Def aultj . In all Columns, the main explanatory variable is the level of strategic default among borrowers serviced by branch j. Strategic default is measured as α d 1,j × F orgiveness Ratej , estimated from: Def aultj,t = α0 + α1 F orgiveness Ratehome,t−1 + Controls + T ime F.E. Simulations are used to correct the standard errors for the presence of a generated regressor. P-values are reported below the coefficient estimates. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the two-tailed 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Panel A: Placebo changes to FA’s Forgiveness Policy Dependent variable: Likelihood of F orgiveness Month of placebo change: February 2010 (1) Prediction with learning: Constant (-) 1.044∗∗∗ (<.001) -0.119 (0.284) -6.361∗∗∗ (0.003) (-) 1.246∗∗∗ (<.001) 1.052 (0.131) -7.900∗∗∗ (<.001) (-) 1.400∗∗∗ <.001) 0.822 (0.161) -8.789∗∗∗ (0.002) (+) 0.130 (0.229) 0.124 (0.531) 0.121 (0.336) (+) 0.126 (0.246) 0.627 (0.257) 0.030 (0.900) (+) 0.135 (0.148) 0.353 (0.280) -0.279 (0.757) 16.31% 54 21.7% 54 18.45% 54 1.51% 54 4.61% 54 3.57% 54 Strategic Def ault T otal Def ault R2 Observations: July 2010 December 2010 (2) (3) Decision to Reject February 2010 (4) July 2010 December 2010 (5) (6) Panel B: Changes in likelihood of forgiveness and decision to reject Dependent variable: Learning period: Prediction with learning: Constant Strategic Def ault T otal Def ault R2 Observations: Three-month difference: t-test Ch. in Likelihood of F orgiveness Ch. in Decision to Reject 3 months (1) 6 months (2) 9 months (3) 3 months (4) 6 months (5) 9 months (6) (-) 1.278∗∗∗ (<.001) -1.242 (0.114) -8.079∗∗ (0.019) 13.47% 54 (-) 0.976∗∗∗ (0.002) -0.800 (0.252) -5.491∗ (0.083) 7.70% 54 (-) 0.974∗∗∗ (<.001) -1.640 (0.102) -5.553∗ (0.057) 9.88% 54 (+) -0.219∗∗∗ (<.001) 0.140 (0.339) 1.013∗∗∗ (<.001) 1.24% 54 (+) -0.178∗∗∗ (<.001) 0.464 (0.169) 0.508∗∗∗ (<.001) 1.21% 54 (+) -0.246∗∗∗ (<.001) 0.792∗ (0.074) 0.526∗∗∗ (0.001) 2.25% 54 0.442 (0.363) -0.840 (0.644) 0.324 (0.466) 0.328 (0.371) 51