Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Preface The idea is not new. In fact, it is rather old. Probably because it makes perfect sense: to really understand the mental processes underlying economic behavior both psychologists and economists are needed. What is relatively special, however, is that at Tilburg University, psychologists and economists had the wisdom to actually do something with this idea and make it an academic reality. Tilburg University has always been a place where psychologists and economists are in close contact with each other and where they actually collaborate on empirical research projects. Recently, this collaboration has been formalized in a multidisciplinary research institute. ‘Tiber’ has become the name of both a meandering river in Italy and the Tilburg Institute for Behavioral Economics Research in the Netherlands. Tiber brings together economists, psychologists, and marketing researchers to cooperate intensively in furthering our understanding of the psychology of economic behavior. Tiber aims to contribute to the development of new insights into the psychological determinants of economic behavior by combining the best practices from economics and social psychology. Economists have formulated strong and mathematically precise models for describing, explaining, and predicting economic behavior. However, the psychological basis of these models is not always wellresearched. Insights from psychological theory may help to improve these models and to better understand how individuals will behave when they make economic choices and decisions. Thus, Tiber hopes not only to contribute to the building of new theories of human economic behavior, but also to contribute to the development of new methodologies to study this behavior. This issue of Tilburg Research hopefully gives an idea of how we, Tiberians, do this. Please enjoy. Diederik A. Stapel Director of Tiber 4 16 23 26 FEATURES 10 Tilburg Research Tilburg Research is a newsletter for special-interest groups about research at Tilburg University, located in the southern Netherlands. Tilburg University specialises in the Social Sciences and the Humanities. (page 26), Gerard Til/Hollandse Hoogte (page 31), Tim Dirven (page 36). Tiber members inside: Ton Toemen, Ben Bergmans. Translation Paul Jones (The Word Co.) Layout and graphic design Beelenkamp Ontwerpers, Tilburg Printer Drukkerij Groels, Tilburg 23 ‘The economic assumption of the selfish individual has become second best’ Interview with Ernst Fehr 26 How does the mind work? The value of basic psychology by Jean Vroomen 30 ‘Reason is not much different from postponed emotions’ Interview with Nico Frijda Colophon Publisher Office of Public and External Affairs, Tilburg University Authors Marion de Boo, Irene Herbers, Rik Oerlemans, Jan Potters, Corine Schouten, Marga van Zundert Editor Irene Herbers, Diederik Stapel Photographs Tim Smith (cover), Xavier Cervera (page 4), ANP/EPA (page 11), Ilja Vreman (page 12), George Georgiou (page 16), Qilai Shen (page 23), Tom Haller (page 25), Jez Coulson ‘Psychologists can influence society only by influencing economists’ Interview with Daniel Kahneman 36 Big shiny things What brands should be like - according to Giep Franzen Columns 9 21 39 Barry Schwartz on choice distress Alain de Botton on status anxiety Fred van Raaij on ‘Fire and Water’ ON TIBER 4 16 19 20 Understanding the psychology of economic behavior Can consumers handle more choice? A fruitful cooperation Juggling with our rational and emotional self Tiber researchers Throughout this issue Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Tiber director Diederik Stapel: Understanding the psychology of economic behavior Why are more computers bought on a sunny day? How do we prevent young women wanting to become as slim as those portrayed in advertisements? What are the psychological motives underlying the buying behavior of consumers? And why don’t people grasp an opportunity if they’ve previously missed out on a bigger one? These are the sorts of questions addressed by research carried out at the Tilburg Institute for Behavioral Economics Research (Tiber). Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Tiber was established in 2000 to a PhD student, Stapel investigates merge the fields of economics, marthe concept of cognitive consistency keting, and psychology. The research- as a motive for human behavior. ers investigate the psychological “Why do people do what they do? processes that underlie individual Not simply to make themselves feel choices and economic decisions. good, but also because of a need for “Preferably via relevant, carefully con- structure and predictability. This ducted, and moreover, provocative, need for consistency appears to be exciting research”, says the research a very important motive. People director, Professor Diederik Stapel. don’t like to be surprised. In fact, “Those are the criteria on which we our experiments have shown that evaluate all of our projects. An internice things are not always initially disciplinary approach offers, furappreciated if they were not expected. thermore, much added value.” Tiber For instance, consumers prefer to has three strands: Marketing (e.g., buy herbal tea in the knowledge that market research, consumer behavit’s made using a ‘traditional recipe’ ior, advertising); Economics (e.g., and are less taken by claims that the solidarity, social preferences, social product is ‘totally new’. Consumers dilemmas); and Social Psychology are certainly open for improved and (e.g., decision-making). Each element innovative products but not if they has its own co-director who is also hadn’t expected them. This is an a professor. Diederik Stapel himself important conclusion for marketers. studied psychology and communication science. In each case, he was The Tilburg tradition awarded ‘cum laude’, which is the Tiber is rooted in the Tilburg tradimost prestigious graduate accolade. tion. “Our university originates from Stapel is now a professor in consumer an economics school as is evidenced science at Tilburg University and by the fact that the economics works as an editor for various top department resides in the highest journals in his area of expertise. He’s building on the campus”, says Stapel full of enthusiasm. “We’re a virtual somewhat tongue-in-cheek. Other institution but our specialisms really disciplines like law, social and behavinteract and we work on research ioral sciences are also very imporprojects together. We’re open to each tant for economic problems and other’s ideas. Besides our full-time issues. Tilburg was one of the first staff, PhD students and post-docuniversities in the world where you toral researchers (who are paid by could study economical psychology. Tiber), other top researchers seek The group of Economic Psychology fellowships within the Tiber network at Tilburg remains unique in because they are interested in the The Netherlands. Stapel: “In the past, economists were not always work we do and in the informal and cooperative atmosphere of our group. enthusiastic about the possibility of psychology entering their domain. Together with Marret Noordewier, They were satisfied with their own models of the market to explain homo economicus. Economists like to portray people straightforwardly as beings for whom rationality is central and where maximizing utility is a key concern. We pick up every penny that’s thrown on the floor. Everything revolves around money or better, utility. Maximizing utility is our core motive according to classic economists. But philosophers and psychologists continue to argue that the economic view on human behavior is somewhat incomplete. People want to maximize utility in the most efficient way, yes, but that is not only or always what drives their behavior. People, for example, have emotions. We are often irrational and do not always process all the available information concerning supply and demand. But as psychologists continue to penetrate the domain of economics and improve their understanding of the jargon that goes with it, then slowly psychology’s insights may be absorbed.” Nowadays, for example, both psychologists and economists, point to the importance of understanding issues like solidarity, social preferences and social dilemmas, the urge to do something good and meaningful for society, and the benefits and advantages of doubt (sometimes people prefer uncertainty and ignorance over certainty and perfect knowledge). These are just a few illustrations of factors that could be added to the well-understood selfinterest expressed by economical motives. One important milestone Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 in the bridging of economics and psychology, was the Nobel Prize of economics awarded in 2002 to the cognitive psychologist Daniel Kahneman from the Princeton University concerning his research on and modeling of the role of context effects and psychological processes, such as emotions, in economic decision-making. “The role of contexts and emotions in decision-making is now an important research area and that is reflected in economic models”, says Stapel. “This reappraisal of economics also permeated into the field of psychology. Economists have taught psychologists that they need to be both more ‘ambitious,’ analytical, precise, and formal on their theorizing for their research to have a real impact on society.” Compelling models A big difference between psychology and economics concerns the degree to which formal models are used to describe and predict a large array of phenomena. According to Stapel, economists like to develop one large, theoretical and incisive model with a clear, somewhat normative portrayal of human behavior. Psychologists, on the other hand, work with many small mini-theories, each of which only apply to a very specific subdivision of reality. “Psychologists focus more on exceptions than on rules. And according to many economists, psychologists testing arrangements and computer tasks in which people have to react to artificial stimuli or imagine certain scenarios are of little practical, real-life relevance. ‘Economists are sometimes over-optimistic. Psychologists, on the other hand, are often too careful.’ Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 so little influence on policy issues and the social debate. “At a ministry level, for instance, hardly any psychologists are employed – we simply work in the background in our laboratories. But policy makers certainly need sound advice from us. Consider the pension debate. You could address this by applying economic/ mathematical models, but the policy makers don’t think they need such advice. They also want insight into human motives: How long do people want to remain working?; Under what conditions do they want to enter retirement?; What perceptions of risk are involved? and How can you predict future behavior?” In the next few years, Tiber wants to conduct more field research. Such a project has recently been launched on the topic of “green marketing”. In this project, researchers compare consumer behavior in branches of a supermarket chain which has either been refurbished or not with new, barely noticeable (but certainly influential) ‘green cues’. Participants in psychology experiments are typically required to press buttons in the laboratory under controlled conditions in order to see, for instance, how they choose between red and blue balls. In contrast, marketing researchers, for example, want to know when people choose between a jar of peanut butter with either a red or a blue lid. And economists seek general rules and are consequently sometimes overoptimistic about the universality of human behavior. Psychologists, on the other hand, are often too careful in their approach; they always see exceptions everywhere and seldom come to a decisive and succinct conclusions. It is too often: under some circumstances, for some of the people, some time… Tiber offers a Different cultures fantastic opportunity to arrive at more Stapel emphasizes that, in pracprecise, decisive, and relevant contice, working with researchers clusions since economics offers us a from different disciplines is not as robust model and a strong theoretical straightforward as you may think. perspective of human behavior and “The remaining specialists, with psychology offers us rich and precise their own idiosyncrasies and their methodologies to study the workings own cultures, are easy to detect. of the human mind. Economists like to have definitive rules. If I, as a psychologist, think Social debate deeply about the question of how Stapel finds it unfortunate that psymood influences consumer behavior, chologists - as opposed to economists I first want to know what’s going on and sociologists, for example - have in your head, what memory process- Jan Potters (Economics), Diederik Stapel (Director of Tiber), Rik Pieters (Marketing) and Marcel Zeelenberg (Social Psychology). es are being activated, and how such moods materialize. What exactly is a mood actually, and what does it do precisely when it comes to the way we look at reality? Economists are much more practical. For instance, they examine the effect of sunny/ rainy weather on product purchases which leads to a good, testable, and usable, model.” These different approaches make the collaboration really interesting. “You become compelled to look at your own academic discipline in a different way”, says Stapel. “In Tiber, we do research, for example, that investigates the relationship between religion and creativity that has produced some very surprising conclusions.” Independence, reputation, and excellence Tiber is an institution financed chiefly by University and other government funds. Tiber receives few funding from elsewhere. Fundamental research is our primary concern. To date, commercial companies or institutions do not contribute financially. “Independence, reputation, and excellence are very important for Tiber. We hope to add a reputation of excellence to the university”, says Stapel. “We’re not in it to get as many commercial assignments as possible. We like to do research for companies such as Super de Boer, Philips, or Shell as long as we can allocate a considerable part of the budget to basic research. This provides us with scientific ‘added value’ and delivers fundamental knowledge about the psychology of economic behavior.” The results are preferably published in top journals like Psychological Science, Psychological Review, Journal of Marketing Research, American Economic Review and the Quarterly Journal of Economics. Stapel: “Everyone who’s interested in laying bare the universal laws of human decision making and social, economic behavior is welcome. We’re not going to solve a specific or temporary problem for company X or company Y if that doesn’t augment our fundamental understanding. Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Column Too much choice, too little satisfaction By Barry Schwartz I had an epiphany while buying jeans a few years ago. Jeans buying for me had always been ‘waist size, inseam, and out the door in two minutes.’ But when I went into the store, I encountered more than a dozen different varieties of style and fit. There were no ‘regular’ jeans any more. Suddenly, a two-minute operation had turned into an hour-long project. What’s more, though I ended up with a pair of jeans that fit me better than any I had ever worn before, I felt worse about them. What happened to me is that all the options I was given raised my expectations about just how well jeans were supposed to fit. My new jeans fit very well, but they weren’t perfect, and I now expected perfect. The result was disappointment. All this choice enabled me to do better, but feel worse. “Everyone who’s interested in laying bare the universal laws of human decision making and social, economic behavior is welcome at Tiber”, says research director Diederik Stapel. Tiber was not set up to answer practical questions from the likes of Unilevers of this world, but rather, what we do is sound research in cooperation with external partners.” A sample of motives Tiber has good contacts with various government institutions including ministries, local and regional authorities and semi-commercial parties (e.g., pension fund organizations, advertising agencies, and marketing research companies). The idea that Tiber research should not only be rigid, precise, and provocative, but also ‘relevant’ and ‘practical’ is evidenced by the many newspaper and radio interviews, and TV appearances that are given by Tiber researchers. In next few years, Tiber wants to address the question of the extent to which economic models should be supplemented with additional factors in order to better predict human behavior. Up until now roughly, each researcher from the institute has their own pet theory. Consider, for instance, the role of emotions in decision-making, the role of social preferences, the importance of eye movements in evaluating advertisements, or the effect of financial versus social sanctions. “But what are the ten most important determinants?”, says Stapel. “How can we develop theories that go beyond researchers’ individual preferences or perspectives? “What is it all about, really? This is what we want to find out.” I began to look around for evidence that it wasn’t just me. And there was plenty to be found, most of which is brought together in my book, The Paradox of Choice: Why More Is Less. Here are two examples: As options increase among varieties of gourmet jam or chocolate, shoppers are less likely to buy any of them. Twenty-five options attract more attention – but less buying – than five. As employers increase the number of investment options provided to employees in retirement plans, the employees become less likely to participate in any of them, even though this often means passing up an employer match of several thousand dollars per year. In addition, several colleagues and I have found that the problem of choice overload is especially acute for people whose aim is to get the ‘best’ (we call them ‘maximizers’) rather than ‘good enough’ (we call them ‘satisficers’). The only way to find the best is to examine all the possibilities, which in the cornucopia of modern, affluent societies is just impossible. Maximizers, we find, when faced with extraordinary consumer choice, are less likely to buy, and are less satisfied and more regretful when they do buy, than satisficers. Maximizers have extremely high expectations about the results of their decisions, and they are often disappointed. More importantly, maximizers are in general less happy, less optimistic, less satisfied with their lives, and more depressed than satisficers. The orthodoxies of rational choice theory and of economics tell us that there can never be too much choice. Those who don’t care can ignore options, while those who do care can find just what they’re looking for. These same orthodoxies tell us that the development of ever higher standards for satisfaction are signs of material progress. The results I have just described provide a strong indication that whereas these orthodoxies may be logically true, they are psychologically false. There can be too much of a good thing: too many options and too high standards, with the result that people feel worse even when they do better. Barry Schwartz is the Dorwin Cartwright Professor of Social Theory and Social Action in the Psychology Department at Swarthmore College, Swarthmore, Pennsylvania, where he has taught for more than thirty years. The arguments in this article are detailed in The Paradox of Choice: Why More Is Less. Schwartz is also the author of The Battle for Human Nature, and The Costs of Living, along with several other books and many articles in professional journals and periodicals. 10 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Nobel Prize laureate Daniel Kahneman: the then editor and he remembered that he took it because he ‘liked the math’. I was really disappointed. I thought that was absolute nonsense; there were some very important ideas in the article but he just liked the math.” ‘Psychologists can influence society only by influencing economists’ That taps into the many difficulties in the discourse between economists and psychologists. Kahneman: “The fact that Amos was trained in decision theory and mathematics was extremely important because we could write in a way that economists could respect. It’s like knowing the language. But ultimately, that was not the reason for the impact of our theory on economics. The reason was that the economist Richard Thaler could come and work for us on a grant from the Sloan Foundation to promote psychology in economics. In a very serious way, Thaler, Tversky and I working together was the beginning of behavioral economics. After Prospect Theory, it had become respectable for economists to look at the work of psychologists – that also helped a lot.” A penthouse in Manhattan, New York. Marcel Zeelenberg, Professor of Social and Economic psychology at TIBER, meets psychologist and Nobel prize laureate Daniel Kahneman, one of the founders of behavioral economics. They talk about the past, present and future of the psychology of economics. Zeelenberg: Could you tell us how you entered the field of behavioral decision research? Kahneman: “I’d thought a lot about my own judgment of other people and was also very interested in intuitions about statistics, which I had been teaching. Then there was that wonderful accident when I invited Amos Tversky to speak in my graduate seminar on the applications of psychology to real-world problems in 1969. He spoke about the research of his former mentor, Ward Edwards, on people’s judgments about probabilities involving gambles and red and white poker chips, and I really didn’t like it. We had a good argument in front of the class which brought together our different approaches. He was trained as a decision theorist and I was mainly into perception. It turned out to be the key to our collaboration. At lunch, we exchanged personal accounts of our own recurrent errors of judgment, and decided to study the statistical intuition of experts. After that, we were just very lucky that we complemented each other. For 12, 13 years we just had a wonderful time working together very closely.” Do you consider this to be your best work? Kahneman: “Yes, clearly. It was my best work; it was Amos’s best work. It was a bit wilder than the work that Amos did by himself and it was a lot crisper and more definitive and authoritative than the work I do by myself. We had a better mind jointly than each of us separately. The reason that our collaboration started to wind down in the 1980’s was primarily geographic. But we remained friends and never stopped interacting. I know you put a lot of effort into getting Prospect Theory right. Why were you so precise? Kahneman: “On our Science paper on heuristics and biases in human judgment, we worked for almost a year. It’s 5,000 words and we did nothing else. We argued about everything. Prospect Theory took several years. We’re both perfectionists and we liked each other’s company, so that meant we had infinite patience. Amos used to say: ‘let’s get it right’. Of course, we were also ambitious. But we did not aim to influence economics. Econometrica happened to be the best journal for this theory. So we went for it. But they accepted the article for the wrong reason, which I think is funny. A few years ago, I met 11 “We create stories. That is what Amos and I did”, says Daniel Kahneman. “They’re stories that make you think. What hasn’t happened yet, but is about to happen, is the development of a joint language.” What do you think is important in the field of behavioral economics at the moment? Kahneman: “The work of John List at the University of Chicago. He has shown that the endowment effort changes with the amount of experience in training. Actually, I think behavioral economics is the only hope for having psychology gain influence on policy. It is perhaps different in Europe, but in the United States, the gatekeepers who con- 12 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 trol academic input into policy are economists and lawyers. You can’t do anything except through economists and lawyers. The only way we can influence society is by influencing economists.” And how do you see the future of behavioral economics? Is it neuroeconomics? Kahneman: “I’m a big fan of neuroeconomics – ignorant, but a big fan. Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Actually, I think that the economists who are doing neuro-economics have become psychologists. They have to be because they are studying the working of the brains. But I think psychologists will continue to provide economists with ideas. We create stories. That is what Amos and I did. They’re stories that make you think. What hasn’t happened yet, but is about to happen, is the development of a joint language.” About Daniel Kahneman Daniel Kahneman (1934, Tel Aviv) is an Israeli-American Psychologist and Nobel laureate, notable for his work on behavioral economics and hedonic psychology. One of his childhood experiences encouraged him to become a psychologist: “It must have been late 1941 or early 1942. Jews were required to wear the Star of David and to obey a 6 p.m. curfew. I had gone to play with a Christian friend and had stayed too late. I turned my brown sweater inside out to walk the few blocks home. As I was walking down an empty street, I saw a German soldier approaching. He was wearing the black uniform that I had been told to fear more than others – the one worn by specially recruited SS soldiers. As I came closer to him, trying to walk fast, I noticed that he was looking at me intently. Then he beckoned me over, picked me up, and hugged me. I was terrified that he would notice the star inside my sweater. He was speaking to me with great emotion, in German. When he put me down, he opened his wallet, showed me a picture of a boy, and gave me some money. I went home more certain than ever that my mother was right: people were endlessly complicated and interesting.” (Kahneman, 2003) Kahneman’s early work focused on visual perception and attention. With Amos Tversky, he published articles in the field of judgment and decision-making, one of which was Judgment under uncertainty (Science, 1974). It turned out to be an empirical psychological article that economists could take seriously. Kahneman and Tversky’s collaboration culminated in the publication of their Prospect Theory in 1979 in Econometrica. After 1983, when the two no longer worked at the same university, the intensive collaboration began to wind down. Kahneman was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics in 2002 for his work on Prospect Theory. It is generally believed that Tversky would have as well, had he been alive. He died in 1996. Kahneman claims that he never took a single course in economics: what he knows of the subject was (like Tversky) learnt from collaborators Richard Thaler and Jack Knetsch. Kahneman is currently a senior scholar and an emeritus faculty member at Princeton University’s Woodrow Wilson School. He is also a fellow at Hebrew University. In 2007, he was presented with the American Psychological Association’s Award for Outstanding Lifetime Contributions to Psychology. What are the goals for your remaining academic career? Kahneman: “I’ll be doing things that interest me as long as I can. I won't be giving talks after this year, because I’ve spoken enough. But what gets me excited is the new priming work, like the work by John Bargh. I think it’s revolutionary and it blows my mind. And the Dutch work on priming is really beautiful. Just to be a consumer of that is enormously exciting. I also have access to very interesting quantitative and qualitative data on well-being. I was looking at them this morning: when people are poor, you can predict their well-being from the circumstances; but when people are rich, you cannot because money is a buffer, it protects you. So when you’re in trouble, it’s good to be rich. Another very exciting progress is the structure of happiness in different countries. For instance, in which countries is it important to be rich? In Holland, I think it is not.” Marcel Zeelenberg is Professor of Economic and Social Psychology at Tilburg University. He co-founded Tiber and is its co-director. His research focuses on the role of emotions in decision making. What fascinates Zeelenberg most of all is how people can make reasonably good decisions with only a minimum amount of information. Zeelenberg: “Every day, we make hundreds, if not thousands, of decisions. Yet, many of these involve a lot of uncertainty. What will the economy do? Do I really know what I want to do this afternoon? If I take a holiday in Asia, would I still be able to enjoy a holiday in my home country? The decisions made on 13 the basis of this kind of information actually shape our lives.” According to Zeelenberg, Kahne-man and his collegues have succeeded in providing invaluable insight into how people form judgements and make choices. They have created the field of psychological decision making and behavioural economics as well as the opportunity for psychologists to talk with economists and business administration experts. “Kahneman's work is simple”, says Zeelenberg, “yet very elegant, precise and robust. That is probably why his work has been so influential. The phenomena Kahneman described turned out to be relevant to many everyday decisions.” What is Prospect Theory? Prospect Theory is about choice under uncertainty. It was proposed by Kahneman and Tversky in 1979 as an alternative to the more traditional expected utility theory (EUT). Prospect Theory distinguishes two phases in the decision-making process: the editing phase, a preliminary analysis of the offered prospects, and an evaluation phase. In the evaluation phase, the outcomes of the prospects are transformed by a value function and the probabilities are transformed by a weighting function. The value of each outcome is multiplied by a decision weight. Next, the prospect with the highest value is chosen. In the value function, changes in wealth (gains and losses with respect to a reference point) are the carriers of value instead of final wealth. The value function is concave for gains, convex for losses, and is steeper for losses than for gains (reflecting loss aversion). In 1992, Tversky and Kahneman published an updated version, named Cumulative Prospect Theory. The theory incorporates some new developments concerning how people weigh probabilities. 14 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 2 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 2 15 THE researchers of TIBER Product decisions: the benefits of distraction Copycatting and consumer behavior: Even a subtle copy can endanger a premium brand Name: Femke van Horen (PhD student) Education: Social Psychology, Marketing, University of Amsterdam, Tilburg University Tiber research: Copycatting “ Supermarket shelves display many private labels which deliberately look like premium products. My research focuses on the effectiveness of this ‘lookalike’ strategy, also known as ‘copycatting’, and explores the factors affecting how the consumer evaluates and buys copycats (consumer evaluation and choice rate of copycats). Current literature states that copycats with a high degree of similarity can jeopardize the premium product because the copycat free-rides on the premium product’s positive associations. The rationale being that visual similarity raises the value placed on the look-a-like making it more likely to be purchased. However, my research shows that this is not necessarily the case. The extent to which similarity is perceived by consumers is critically dependent on characteristics of the shopping situation. In the laboratory, I investigated how the presence or absence of a premium brand influences the consumers evaluation of a copycat. My research suggests that the evaluation of the highly similar, blatant copycat is more likely to be rejected when the premium product is present. In fact, contrary to common belief, moderately similar copycats fair more favorably than highly similar copycats when in the presence of the premium brand. This is because the presence of the premium brand instigates direct comparison between the copycat and the premium brand and that tends to prompt a negative evaluation of the more blatant copycat. The greater the similarity, the stronger the invitation to compare and the more the differences between the two brands are noticed. Consequently, blatant copycats are rejected, whereas subtle copycats still seem able to benefit from the positive associations attached to the premium brand. Another important factor in the evaluation of copycats versus premium brands appears to be the role which consumers adopt. When people act purely as consumers, they consider whether or not to buy the copycat product. However, when people adopt the role of a judge, they critically evaluate the copycat in terms of its acceptability. Therefore, when making judgments, people are more likely to compare the copycat with the premium product, resulting in a negative evaluation when the copycat is highly similar. However, when people consider whether or not the copycat is worth buying, no direct comparisons are made and so the highly similar copycat is evaluated positively. My research into copycatting speaks to the legal and the copycatting literature by showing that subtle imitations can be as damaging, or perhaps even more damaging, than blatant imitations. Furthermore, it demonstrates that in addition to the degree of similarity, other characteristics of the shopping situation, such as the physical arrangements in the supermarket and the consumers’ frame of mind, also influence the effectiveness of a look-a-like strategy. ” Name: Davy Lerouge (Assistant Professor) Education: Applied Economics, University of Leuven Tiber Research: The effect of distraction on product evaluations “ Suppose you are choosing among several houses for sale. Such a choice typically involves large amounts of information with each alternative having its specific pros and cons on various dimensions. For instance, you could have difficulties deciding between the following: (a) a centrally located, modern, but small house without a garden; and (b) a larger, but older house with a nice garden in a less attractive location. Advice that consumers often receive from others when making such complex decisions is “let the information rest for a while” or “sleep on it”. But, is such common advice really helpful? The idea that temporary distraction might be beneficial when making product decisions is intriguing given that decision theory typically advises us to think hard about complex product decisions. For instance, many consumers conscientiously write down the various pros and cons of each product alternative in order to find the best option. Yet, recent evidence suggests that thinking deliberatively about complex product decisions does not necessarily result in the best choice. Instead, it is argued that distracting attention away from the product information is a better decision for complex decisions. Although this advice may seem provocative at first, many people are familiar with the experience that sometimes the solution to a decision pops up all of a sudden when we are not consciously thinking about it any more (e.g., when taking a shower, cycling etc.). My research demonstrates that it is the manner in which consumers process the available product information that determines whether distraction will be beneficial or not. More specifically, I argue that distraction will only help consumers who tend to perceive products as coherent entities, whereas it will not help consumers who typically focus on the specific features of products. Participants in my studies were exposed to attribute information of four product alternatives. One alternative was made rather attractive and another one rather unattractive. After product information was presented, some participants were distracted for a short period whereas others were not. Together, the results show that for consumers with a (situational or chronic) motivation to perceive products as coherent entities, the mental representations of the attractive alternative become more dominated by positive aspects; in contrast, the representations of the unattractive alternative become more negative after distraction. Importantly, distraction did not result in better differentiation between attractive and unattractive product alternatives for consumers who tend to focus on individual (negative and positive) product features. This research is a good example of Tiber research because it applies and extends basic psychological knowledge about how people (unconsciously) process information in order to get insights into how and when distraction is beneficial for making consumer decisions. ” 16 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Can consumers handle more choice? More choice and more liberal markets. Many economists believe that this is the best way to make consumers better off. More choice enables consumers to find the goods and services that best fit their preferences; competition renders them affordable. The benefits of this policy depend critically, however, on the ability of consumers to make good decisions. According to Tiber professors Jan Potters (Economics) and Rik Pieters (Marketing), this may well be the Achilles' Heel. Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 In several domains, consumers behave in a way that seems rather myopic. This does not mean that they are stupid. Certain choices are just very complex. For example, what is the best saving, investment or insurance product when planning for retirement? This is a decision that involves many uncertainties. What will the interest rate do? How will the stock market evolve? How will my income change? Will I be healthy? Will I have grandchildren? Few people have the knowledge and the ability to make such decisions optimally. Asking a financial adviser might be an alternative, but as recent scandals indicate, there is little guarantee that these experts put the consumer's interest first. Moreover, choosing an expert, or picking the best advice, is almost as difficult a problem. Research indicates that the more complex the decision, the more likely it is that people resort to relatively simple decision rules. They take the cheapest option, chose the same one as their neighbor, or take the advice of the best looking expert. Others may avoid making a decision at all. They stick to the status quo or the default option and spend their time on more enjoyable consumer activities, like buying a new iPod. There is evidence for this with respect to financial products (e.g., mortgages, pensions, and health insurance), but also for choices which are difficult for other reasons, such as choosing to be an organ donor or not. Will-power and self-control It is not only when decisions are ‘A policy of liberalization does not always bring as many benefits to consumers as one might hope.’ complicated that consumers seem to have trouble making the right choice. Every smoker knows that it would be better to quit. Office workers realize that it would be wise to visit the fitness club more often. Students know that it is better to start studying well before an exam. Still, many find it hard to follow up on the good advice of their inner self. Willpower and self-control come in limited supply. As a result, we drink too much, eat too much fatty food, watch too much television, and exercise too little. Some people are rather naïve about this. They are convinced that they will improve their lives tomorrow (but just not today). Others realize that they will fall prey to the same temptations over and over again, and they try to take precautionary measures. They purchase expensive running shoes, buy cigarettes in small quantities, set deadlines for themselves, and leave their credit card at home when visiting the casino (or the shopping mall). Even with the aid of such commitment devices, however, consumers often make choices which are not in their best interest. Labels and frames There are several other reasons why people sometimes exhibit behavior that is hard to reconcile with the 17 economists' image of the rational consumer. One of them is the effect of labels and frames. For example, consumers spend income differently depending on whether it is labeled as ‘child benefit’ or ‘vacation allowance’. Even though such labels would seem irrelevant, they seem to matter for consumers. Also emotions, like anxiety and regret, may interfere with a purely rational deliberation. For instance, consumers are more likely to play the postal code lottery than the state lottery. Not because the chances of winning are better, but because they anticipate the regret of not participating if it transpires that they could have won. In such cases, it is of little help if consumers are provided with more information or more choice. One could even argue that choice and information overload cause some of the problems in the first place. This is why a policy of liberalization does not always bring as many benefits to consumers as one might hope. Towards a better understanding Tiber is committed to the study of consumer behavior in all its aspects. What are the main drivers of consumer choice for different types of goods and services? When are consumers more or less likely to make good decisions? How do firms respond to the potential weaknesses of consumers? Is there a role for the government, and if so, what are the best policies? In addressing these issues, Tiber researchers employ a range of empirical methods including experiments, field studies, 18 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 surveys, and process methods (e.g., eye-tracking and brain imaging). What makes Tiber unique is that it combines the insights, the models, and the methods from econom- Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 ics, marketing, and psychology. Its researchers are dedicated to step outside the comfort zone of their own discipline. Whereas economists take consumer rationality very seriously, psychologists pay attention to market forces. This unification of the social sciences will lead to a better understanding of consumer behavior and to more effective advice. Myopic consumer behavior Four fictive cases: Jan Potters and Rik Pieters describe the general behavioral patterns they exemplify. 64 times, at an average cost of 15 Euro per visit. It would have saved him 448 Euro had he decided to pay per visit. Case 1 Annie saves 5% of her monthly income and she is considering how to invest this. At 65 she wants to have a decent supplement to her pension. She knows that investing in stocks offers a much better average rate of return than she can get on saving deposits. She has noticed, though, that stock prices vary a lot over time and there are some years in which the return is even negative. Annie hates the possibility that her investments might actually decrease in value! Therefore, she decides to invest all her money in a saving deposit. General insight: Consumers tend to overestimate their willingness to do costly or unpleasant activities in the future, while underestimating their willingness to do gainful or pleasurable acts. General insight: People tend to be influenced more by short term fluctuations than by long term outcomes. When planning for their long term future (e.g., retirement or mortgage), people are deterred by short run price fluctuations of stocks; instead, they prefer safer investments, despite the long term benefits of investing in stock. Case 2 Bjorn wants to start exercising in a fitness club and decides to buy a membership card with free access (60 Euro per month) instead of paying per visit (8 Euro). He expects that he will go at least two times a week so the monthly pass is surely cheaper. After a month, he has only visited five times, but realizes it takes time to adjust to a new routine. Bjorn decides not to cancel his membership, which is then automatically renewed. In the second and third month, he exercises twelve times in total, but he is sure this will increase over the coming months as he will be less busy at work. After 16 months, Bjorn decides to cancel his membership. He has visited the gym a total of Case 3 scenario 1. Chris makes a hotel booking for a conference meeting and is asked whether he wants a 40 Euro access pass to the gym and sauna. The pass is valid for a week. Since, he is only staying for two nights, he decides not to purchase the pass. scenario 2 . Colin makes a hotel booking for a conference meeting and is asked whether he wants a 40 Euro access pass to the gym and sauna. The pass is valid for two days. Since he is staying for two nights, he is happy to purchase the pass. General insight: Consumers want to avoid the idea that they are wasting money. This can override an evaluation based on net value or utility. The same holds for costs and expenses that have incurred in the past. Consumers find it difficult to let bygones be bygones. Case 4 Dana is asked how much she is willing to pay for insurance that covers all medical expenses. Her answer: 800 Euro. Diane is asked how much she is willing to pay for insurance that covers all medical expenses in case of an accident. Her answer: 900 Euro. General insight: Occasions and events that come to mind easily and vividly tend to be overrated. 19 A fruitful cooperation Jan Potters is Professor of Economics at Tilburg University and Co-Director of Tiber, as well as Academic Director of the CentERLab for experimental economics. Potters talks about the cooperation between economists and psychologists at Tiber. “I am an econometrician by training, but I have always had a real interest in political processes. It was while studying for my PhD that I came into contact with experimental economics which investigates actual human behavior under controlled conditions, just as in psychology. In one of our first experiments, we tested how people lobby. Participants sent messages, which the recipient either believed or did not, and from which they might or might not gain some benefit. That exposed all kinds of psychological mechanisms that are now being taken more and more seriously in economics. One of our main research interests is social dilemmas. The classic example is pollution. If we all blindly follow our self-interest, the aggregate result is worse for everyone. But there are also some interesting social dilemmas associated with market forces. Companies want to outwit the competition with keen prices and a clever marketing strategy. But if everyone does that, as in a supermarket price war, then prices fall across the board and the only winner is the consumer. Because of that, every market is characterized by a permanent tension between competition and cooperation. Perhaps CEO’s are making secret deals on the golf course. Most economists have too much faith in the power of the free market. Tiber is studying the strategies companies pursue to avoid the competitive pressure in a free market. Another example. To enter many markets, firms first have to invest heavily. New telecommunications businesses have to buy an expensive license. In Tilburg, fairground operators pay the local authority E 50,000 for a site. A gas-station owner has to purchase selling rights. Economists find it difficult to accept the idea that such entry fees push up prices in such markets. But our economic experiments show that this effect is very strong. We found an explanation for that in the theory advanced by the psychologists Kahneman and Tversky. Economists love simple theories that are widely applicable and can be demonstrated using simple, formal models. Thus, psychological insights are much more likely to make headway in the realm of economics if they can be modeled effectively. Economists can barely communicate with most psychologists, but Tilburg is an exception. The scientific outlook of our psychologists is much closer to that of economics. They are quite precise in the way they form their theories, and their perceptions are broad in scope. Moreover, there is a strong group of social psychologists here. That makes our cooperation in Tiber particularly fruitful.” ‘Economists can barely communicate with most psychologists, but Tilburg is an exception.’ 20 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Juggling with our rational and emotional self 21 Column Status Anxiety By Alain de Botton Rik Pieters studied Economic Psychology at Tilburg before obtaining his PhD from Leiden for research into environmental awareness. He is now Professor of Marketing at Tilburg University, and Co-Director of Tiber. Pieters talks about the complex effects of advertising. “Advertising has fascinated me for years. I probably was about fourteen when I started to read The Psychology of Advertising in bed every night. One common misconception is that advertising is mainly intended to sell bad products by telling a good story. But what do manufacturers gain from that? If your cheese tastes horrible, you won’t sell it a second time. Advertising is about telling people things to make them enthusiastic about products the seller actually believes in. What exactly consumers do with that information, and the way it influences their decisions, is a complicated story. For a long time, scientists regarded consumers as a sort of rational computers that had a complete understanding of the market and who optimized their choices accordingly. But that image turned out to be faulted. For a while after that, consumers were seen as very fickle and impulsive. But that’s not really the case either. One intriguing question is why people often have trouble achieving their short and long-term objectives. For example, we don’t want to put on too much weight. So the trend towards smaller portions – single servings of ice cream, individually packaged cookies – would seem to be good news. But nothing could be further from the truth. With one of those family packs full of small bags of potato chips in the cupboard, there is actually less to stop you opening one. After a week, the pack is empty, and you’ve put on a kilo. One of our students used an elegant experiment to test this hypothesis about snacking behavior. To begin with, she found an excuse to persuade half of her participants to weigh themselves in front of a mirror, and measure their waistlines. Then, everyone was told that they would be assessing a series of six TV commercials. To make the experiment as realistic as possible, the researcher said that the ads would be shown during an episode of the series Friends. And, to make it totally realistic, they could eat potato chips while they were watching. They were given either a bowl of potato chips or a supply of small bags. Surprisingly enough, those who had not been reminded of their weight beforehand hardly touched the potato chips, either loose or in bags. Those who had weighed themselves and were given a bowl (the contents of which were carefully weighed before and after the experiment) ate much more, but those who had been reminded of their weight and were then given the ‘sensible’ mini-bags ended up eating the most.” ‘Why do people have trouble achieving their short and long-term objectives? That’s an intriguing question.’ Status anxiety is a worry about our standing in the world – whether we’re going up or down, whether we’re winners or losers. We care about our status for a simple reason: because most people tend to be nice to us according to the amount of it we have. If they hear we’ve been promoted, there’ll be a little more energy in their smile. If we’re sacked, they’ll pretend not to have seen us. Ultimately, we worry about having no status because we’re not good at remaining confident about ourselves if other people don’t seem to like or respect us very much. Our ‘ego’ or selfconception could be pictured as a leaking balloon, forever requiring external love to remain inflated and vulnerable to the smallest pinpricks of neglect. We rely on signs of respect from the world to feel acceptable to ourselves. While it would be unusual to be status-anxious in a famine, history shows that as soon as societies go any way beyond basic subsistence, status anxieties quickly kick in. In the modern world, status anxiety starts when we compare our achievements with those of other people we consider to be our equals. We might worry about our status when we come across an enthusiastic newspaper profile of an acquaintance (it can destroy the morning), when a close friend reveals a piece of what they naively – or plain sadistically – call ‘good’ news (they have been promoted, they are getting married, they have reached the bestseller list) or when we are asked what we ‘do’ at a party by someone with a firm handshake who has recently floated their own start-up company. Status anxiety is certainly worse than ever, because the possibilities for achievement (sexual, financial, professional) seem to be greater than ever. There are so many more things we expect if we’re not to judge ourselves ‘losers’. We are constantly surrounded by stories of people who have made it. For most of history, an opposite assumption held sway: low expectations were viewed as both normal and wise. Only a very few ever aspired to wealth and fulfillment. The majority knew well enough that they were condemned to exploitation and resignation. Of course, it remains highly unlikely that we will today ever reach the pinnacle of society. It is perhaps as unlikely now that we could rival the success of Bill Gates as that, in the seventeenth century, we could have become as powerful as Louis XIV. Unfortunately, though, it no longer feels unlikely – depending on the magazines one reads, it can in fact seem absurd that one hasn’t already managed to have it all. Could Bill Gates suffer from status anxiety? Of course he does – because he compares himself to his own peer group. We all do this, and that’s why we end up feeling we lack things even though we’re so much better off than people ever were in the past. It’s not that we’re especially ungrateful, it’s just that we don’t judge ourselves in relation to people far away. We cannot be cheered for long by how prosperous we are in historical or geographical terms. We will only take ourselves to be fortunate when we have as much as, or more than, the people we grow up with, work alongside, have as friends, and identify with in the public realm. That’s why the best way to feel successful is to choose friends who are just that little bit less successful than you… Are there solutions? Think about death. It’s the best way to stop worrying so much about what others make of you. To discover whose friendship you should really care about, ask yourself who – among your acquaintances – would make it to your hospital bedside. If need be, look at a skeleton: what others think about you will soon start to lose its intimidating power. But most of all, and perhaps most seriously, the solution to such issues lies in thought 22 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 – and here economic thinking may be as powerful as the philosophical. Economics in the classical mode left behind questions of feeling and happiness, a situation which is now changing. The great hope is that we will in the coming years see the development of a more emotionally focused hedonistic philosophy. Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Alain de Botton (1967) is a writer and television producer who lives in London. In 1997, he made his international breakthrough with the book ‘How Proust can change your life’. With this book and other bestsellers on literature, love, travel, status and architecture, he succeeded in making difficult philosophical themes accessible to a wider public. See also: www.alaindebotton.com Experimental economist Ernst Fehr: Fokke and Sukke are the stars of a famous Dutch comic strip, created by Jean-Marc van Tol, John Reid, and Bastiaan Geleijnse. The one-panel comic usually features humor of a politically incorrect nature but always comments on aspects of social life in a near-brilliant manner. While the creators have pointed out that “Fokke” and “Sukke” are ordinary West-Frisian language names, the names of the comic strip’s protagonists, a duck wearing a small sailor’s cap and a small bird wearing a backward baseball cap, are often misunderstood. ‘The economic assumption of the selfish individual has become second best’ Ernst Fehr, a renowned Austrian experimental economist, was one of the first to introduce non-selfish motives into economic models. In the early 1990s, he pulverized the rational, selfish “Homo economicus” by showing that people are willing to punish shirking coworkers, even at personal cost to themselves. “Economists accused me of opening Pandora's Box.” 23 24 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 People do not act and decide solely on rational grounds, or on the basis of self-interest. This may be an obvious fact in daily life, but the standard model in economics assumes 100 percent rationality in human beings. Using a variety of games, experimental economist Ernst Fehr has provided hard data showing that fairness, altruism, and reciprocity really do exist – and that these so called “social preferences” really matter to fundamental economic issues like unemployment or contract efficiency. His research met with a lot of skepticism in the early 1990s, but today, he is a renowned professor and director of the Institute for Empirical Economics at the University of Zurich, Switzerland. Fehr’s work is not only followed closely by economists, but also by psychologists, and even by evolutionary biologists, who see it as providing building blocks for the evolution of human cooperation and sociality. Tiber postdoc Rob Nelissen talks with him. How did an economist become so interested in psychology? “In the late 1980s, I was studying unemployment, a topic at the very heart of market economics. The prevailing theory stated that, by inventing different types of contracts, it is always possible to eliminate joblessness. Involuntary unemployment, for example, could be overcome by charging people an upfront fee for a job. The idea of asking unemployed people to pay for work immediately struck me as completely absurd. Everybody knows that that would make them angry. So I introduced a fairness motive to the theory. Now, one could no longer invent a clever contract that solved involuntary unemployment. I wrote a theoretical paper about it, but nobody wanted to publish it at the time.” You repeatedly stress the importance of non-selfish motives in understanding how financial incentives work. What can be learned from your work? “The most important lesson is that non-selfish motives play a tremendous role in the effectiveness of financial incentives. I'll give an example. Economists usually consider reputation incentives as pecuniary. And, indeed, they do have a pecuniary component. If I work very diligently today, I establish a good reputation, I will be promoted soon, and this may increase my future salary. However, I don't think that this is the whole story. We care about our reputation per se. The power of reputation as a driver of efforts is much stronger because of the existence of social preferences such as fairness or pride. “Moreover – and this may sound complex – nonselfish motives can constitute incentives in themselves. We witness this in finitely repeated games; that is, games that are only played for a few rounds. In all but the final period, participants cooperate with the game leader, the principal. But some players defect completely in that last period because this will maximize their gain. They are the selfish types. Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 But, in the earlier rounds, everybody – fair or selfish – behaves in a similar way. The fair types because they are fair guys, the others because they want to look fair. Here, the existence of fair types creates the opportunity for reputation as an effort-enhancing tool. If everybody were selfish, and everybody knew this, no one would acquire a reputation for providing the greatest effort.” ‘I am not convinced that preferences change quickly’ What are the practical implications of this? “We can use it to explain labor market segmentation, for example. Very recently, we ran economic experiments – games – in which participants can acquire a reputation. The principal could observe the behavior of all participants in previous periods, even if they were not working for that particular principal then. What we observed is quite interesting. Some workers are very keen to acquire a good reputation, but there are also people that don't care. Those with a good reputation were paid high wages by the principals, and were rarely controlled. Their principal trusted them. But those participants who didn't care and didn’t work hard received low wages and were highly controlled. And that is exactly what labor market segregation is.” “When I’m designing an experiment, I always keep my most skeptical colleagues in mind”, says experimental economist Ernst Fehr. Can we use this knowledge of incentives to change work ethos? “That would be norm internalization: changing preferences. Economists don't like changes of preferences, since every economic model is based on an assumption that they remain stable. It becomes far more complicated if you believe that changes in behavior can also be caused by changes in preferences. Even though I'm open to the possibility, I am not convinced that preferences change quickly. For economists, the concept would open a Pandora's Box. Actually, we were accused of the same thing when we introduced non-selfish motives. But it wasn't true: we had the tools to measure preferences properly. And with that, the whole economic assumption of the selfish individual became second best. When you can measure something precisely, you do not have to, and should not, rely on assumptions.” Why do many economists still hang on to the standard model? “There is a good reason. Rationality and self-interest keep economic models simple at the individual level. Complexity at that level makes it difficult to model interactions at the institutional level. Mathematically, we face a trade-off between efficiency and complexity. I hope we can manage to change that habit by showing that neglecting social motives has serious effects. Ultimately, it’s really important to convince the unconvinced. Whenever I'm designing an experiment, I always keep my most skeptical colleagues in mind.” 25 Can psychologists also learn from experimental economists? To put it provocatively, psychologists realized decades ago that people are not selfish. “Psychologists have also long known about the ‘bad apple’ effect: the notion that one bad apple spoils the bunch. In more scientific terms, a minority of selfish types can make a majority of altruistic types defect from cooperation. But it took economists to provide the theoretical structure behind this phenomenon by using the public goods game. They mathematically demonstrated and described the equilibrium behind the bad apple effect. Economists provide a much more precise characterization of social preferences and are able to work out the implications for social interactions at both a theoretical and an empirical level. So I do think that psychologists can learn a lot from economists, but they tend to have a natural reticence towards formal models.” What do you think about Tiber, the new institute for behavioral economics in Tilburg? “It is a very good idea to let economists and psychologists interact on a daily basis because they have non-overlapping knowledge. It will lead to crossfertilization, to learning new things. And isn’t that just what we scientists like? So it isn’t just a good idea in terms of scientific output – you could also call it a pleasure machine.” 26 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 How does the mind work? The value of basic psychology These days, economists carry out brain scans to investigate how people make decisions. To do so, they rely on paradigms that were first developed within the field of cognitive psychology as a means to discover how the brain works. “Psychological knowledge increasingly permeates into the applied sciences”, says Jean Vroomen, professor of Experimental Psychology at Tilburg University. “You only have to look around to see that people are not rational decisionmakers”, argues Jean Vroomen. “A Skoda offers a lot of value for a low price, but I don’t see many people driving them. And all salespeople know that they must take advantage of gut feelings to sell their products. The Bounty advert is the classic example.” Is the psychologist from Tilburg a little frustrated that economists have only recently started to take an interest in psychology? Vroomen: “A well-established finding from the cognitive psychology literature is that people are unable to think about more than three or four factors at a time. But many choices are much more complicated. However badly economists would like it to be true, the brain cannot make decisions on a purely rational basis. But economists only began to examine the role of emotions after the Nobel prize for economics was awarded to a psychologist in 2002. Still, I genuinely applaud this interest. And, with our current technology, there remains much more to be discovered that will further help the field of economics.” The role of the brain scan One technique from neuropsychology that economists have enthusiastically embraced is called functional MRI. MRI stands for Magnetic Resonance Imaging although it is better known as simply a ‘brain scan’. With an MRI, a researcher can take a photo of the brain in a few seconds and see which parts are active when people carry out tasks, view certain images, or think about something. What does such a photo reveal exactly? Vroomen: “In fact, it only means that an area of one cubic millimetre uses more oxygen – and is therefore active. But even though we don’t exactly know what’s happening in the ten thousand brain cells in this area, cognitive psychologists have, nevertheless, precisely identified where ‘attention’, ‘memory’, ‘hearing’ and ‘motion’ are located, thanks to MRI. Economists are now using that knowledge to gain further insight into thinking processes”. For example, neuroeconomists offered people in the scanner 500 or 50,000 euro for their car. So, what happens is that with a bad offer, the same area of the brain is activated as is the case with pain impulses. A good offer, on the contrary, shows activity in a cell cluster that is associated with happiness. Vroomen: “A scan is an actual reflection of what happens in the brain. In this way, you can discover links. Which areas are activated and in what order? Does the same thing happen in children? And what about apes, shop-a-holics, and people with brain damage? Each result yields another research question. Gut feeling and ratio Functional MRI also demonstrates that emotions play an important role in decision-making. If you show someone in a scanner an interesting product, then one can measure activity in the amygdala. The amygdala are two almond shaped areas deep in the brain that have been proven to be associated with our emotions. Vroomen: “The amygdala are linked with what we call ‘gut-feeling’, a quick/automatic instinctive judgement. You either like something or not; you either endorse an idea or not”. The ratio seems to be located mainly in the front of the brain (i.e., the part of the brain behind the forehead). If someone is offered the choice of receiving ‘Study the brain if you want to learn how people make choices. This is where it happens – not in your big toe’ 1000 euro now or 2000 euro in two years, then after a few seconds there is much activity in this frontal area of the brain. Vroomen: “This area plays an important role in conscious decision-making in the long run as it does with complex emotions such as honesty and guilt. In other words, situations where you re-think certain aspects of the situation. In humans, this frontal cortex has much more evolved than in animals. ‘Knock-out’ without damage The frontal cortex, though, remains the least understood area in the brain and additional experimentation is needed to increase our insights into how it functions and what it does. Transcranial Magnetic Stimulation (TMS), another technique from neuropsychology, is a timely method that can help in this respect. During a brain scan, a certain area of the brain can be effectively ‘shut down’ using a directed magnetic pulse. Vroomen: “The magnetic pulse causes an electrical current resulting in a cluster of brain cells that are temporarily disabled (i.e., ‘knockout’) – of course, without permanent damage to the person. In this way, you can examine what happens, or what the differences are, if a specific part of the brain does not work. Does someone choose differently, for example, when you disengage the 27 anxiety centre of the brain, or does one become a shop-aholic if frontal cortex is shut down? Practical benefits of collaboration Another example of the ‘infiltration’ of fundamental psychology research into economic research is eye movement registration. In the 1970s, cognitive psychologists wanted to know how we read words and developed a device that precisely registers how the eyes move over a page. Nowadays, this technique is used by companies to analyze the effectiveness of advertisements. Are the ads in the right place? What do people read first? Does the logo stand out? Vroomen: “As a psychologist, I often get questions about the practical value of my work. But astronomers investigating the ‘Big bang’, or History of art students, are rarely bothered by such questions. Psychology must be useful. But, we can’t always expect that to be the case. Much of my research is concerned with the question of how the brain combines sounds and images. Is that of any practical value? Perhaps. Or better to say ‘possibly’. But when and how..?” Economic models are based on the idea that humans behave rational. For example, a car should be sold more quickly if it’s relatively cheap. But in practice, it appears that this is not necessarily the case. People may, for example, distrust the offer. Psychology can help us to explain such behaviour. And, if you want to understand how people make choices, then it is important to study the brain, because this is where it happens – not in your big toe.” 28 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 29 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 THE researchers of TIBER “ Tales of the unexpected: People love consistency Status: Its determinants and consequences Name: Marret Noordewier (PhD student) Education: Social Psychology, University of Groningen Tiber research: Consistency and expectancies Name: Rob Nelissen (Tiber postdoc) Education: Biology, Social Psychology, Utrecht University, Maastricht University Tiber research: The causes and consequences of status-oriented behavior Personality, taste, price, performance, appearance... People have a lot of expectancies about all kinds of future circumstances or events. But what happens when reality is different to that expected? My research is about how people respond to the unexpected: how do people feel and how do they judge things that they didn’t anticipate? We all have a strong need to understand, structure, and predict reality. Expectancies are an important tool to achieve this goal. Because people dislike inconsistencies, it is unpleasant when reality does not match our expectations. On the other hand, people like positive outcomes: they like friendly people, success, sunny weather, and pleasant tastes. But how would one feel when reality turns out to be both inconsistent with our predictions (i.e., unpleasant), but positive (i.e., pleasant)? Thus, the question is, how you feel when you expect someone to be unkind (negative) who then turns out to be really nice (unex-pected but positive)? My research shows that the way people respond to the unexpected depends on their focus. People may either focus on consistency or on outcomes. We demonstrated that people love consistency and that the need for consistency is basic and primary. Thus, people first focus on the consistency and later on the outcome of events. In particular, they first like consistent outcomes more than inconsistent ones (even when these consistent outcomes are negative), and only later focus on the positivity of those outcomes. Not until people are able and willing to do so, can they abandon the safe comfort of their expectancies and focus on reality as it really is. Then, they can say, “Okay, although this is not what I expected, I like it.” An important question is, therefore, when are people able and willing to abandon their focus on their expectancies? The first answer is that some people value consistency more than others. Some people are organized and plan ahead, whereas others are more chaotic. The second answer is that some situations are more consistency-inviting than others. For example, people who work under time pressure or cognitive load are more likely to stick with their first impressions, their expectancies, and their stereotypes compared to when they are not under such stressful conditions. Our intention is that my research will be able to be applied to all situations where people have expectancies. So far, I have focused mainly on person-perception, product price, visual stimuli, and performance. Recently, we also started to focus on innovation and change and we also examine whether our ideas can be generalized to general surprise effects. What we typically do in is create an expectancy and subsequently present a reality that either confirms this expectancy or not. In addition, we measure or manipulate the value people assign to consistency; for example, we measure individual differences or use different situations to induce a high/ low need for consistency. Subsequently, we ask questions about how people feel, how they judge the outcome and – in the case of products – what they would choose. ” “ What do the person who spends a lot of money on brand clothes and the one who spends it on donations to charity have in common? They may both be driven by concerns about status. Simply put, status is one’s position relative to others on a trait that is held desirable by most, like wealth or physical attractiveness. Luxury expenditures and charity donations improve one’s status because they signal desirable traits, such as wealth and good character (respectively). General perspectives on human behavior (e.g., economic theory) have trouble accounting for the type of behavior described above because they assume that people only act in their self-interest. Spending money on useless products or on other people is wasteful from this point of view. It is therefore necessary to abandon these perspectives to explain the causes and consequences of status, which is what my research is about. Behavior may improve status precisely because it is wasteful and incurs costs in terms of time, energy, money, or even physical risk. The cost associated with the act guarantees its reliability as a signal of some unobservable, yet desirable trait. The more time and effort I spend on doing things for others, the more likely it is that I am actually a nice and caring person. Do people indeed seek to improve their reputation when they help others? In order to find out, I also study the psychological mechanisms that motivate people to strive for more status. Feelings of pride play an important role in this. Still, I have found that in order to feel proud about the things we do, we require information about how well we have done compared to others, and about the social relevance of our accomplishment. This links pride firmly to striving for status. It is not only important to study the causes of status-oriented behavior, but also to identify the consequences of status differences in social life. Why is having status so important to people? Possessing high status has all sorts of benefits. Being known as friendly makes me attractive as a friend, colleague, or partner. Other signs of status have other benefits. Wearing designer clothes enhances status, too, which has implications in negotiations inasmuch as people who dress in this way achieve better results. They get more money even though they are already perceived as wealthier! Striving for status is an ineradicable element of human nature, and one we share with most animals. The recent financial crisis in the US was caused by the irresponsible investment of borrowed money, which may well have been brought about by a desire to keep up with neighbors, friends, and colleagues. It has been argued that concern with status has incited a ‘luxury fever’ that has grasped Western society. At the same time, it appears that even people in impoverished countries prefer to spend their money on luxury goods, rather than on food and shelter. My research on the determinants and consequences of status is at the heart of the Tiber philosophy, because it combines insights from evolutionary theory, economics, and psychology to arrive at a better understanding of seemingly erratic acts. ” 30 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 31 ‘Reason is not much different from postponed emotions’ “I count myself lucky that for all of my life, I’ve earned my money doing what I like doing”, says Nico Frijda. The Dutch psychologist, after more than sixty years of studying emotions, is still fascinated by them. Although he retired in 1992, his work still keeps him busy everyday. Pure hobby. Frijda has published widely, particularly in the area of facial expressions, social interaction, and emotions. The Emotions (1986), arguably his most important piece of work, has been regarded worldwide as a major contribution to the field. At the end of 2007, the distinguished professor received the highest accolade of his work by being awarded an honorary doctorate from the University of Padua. Five questions to a passionate expert. How did you become so fascinated by emotions? The rumour goes that having fallen in love was the reason for your interest. Is that correct? “When I was 19- years old, I fell in love. The girl – besides my being very much in love with her – surprised me because she used to tremble with emotion all the time. I found it strange that I could see that from the outside since emotions are things you feel from the inside. The continually changing facial expressions and emotions of my first girlfriend inspired my PhD research which was entitled ‘Understanding Facial Expressions’. Love was one reason, but there were more. Emotions give people a lot of trouble. They influence our lives in a way that sometimes requires us to control them. I really wanted to know how that worked. Moreover – and this was undoubtedly part of my secret agenda – I thought that you might be able to make them harmless with this knowledge. Everything you understand allows you more control. At least, that’s what I had hoped. Emotions: what are your main contributions to this topic? “There are three. The first is the concept of appraisal. That is, the idea that emotions do not primarily emerge from certain events as such, but rather through the interpretation of these events. I was, however, not the first or the only one with this insight. At the end of the 70s/beginning of the 80s, two American researchers and I – independently of each other – came up with this idea. Later, we helped one another in working things out. The second insight is my theory concerning ‘action readiness’. Around 1980, the dominant view was that emotions were no more than states of physiological arousal. Thus, physiological mechanisms were assumed to cause emotional feelings. I thought that was ridiculous because when I’m in love, I don’t only feel stomach cramps. I further reasoned that emotions are, in fact, passions. And that means you’re not only subject to them, but that they also initiate action, or for that matter, inaction. For that reason, I introduced the graceless term ‘action readiness’. What is anger, for example? It is the experience of the urge to hit someone, to insult them, to somehow hurt him or her or otherwise cause discomfort, in order to – and that is the core of the thought – make him or her stop doing what they are doing. ‘I thought that was ridiculous because when I’m in love, I don’t only feel stomach cramps’. Sadness, on the other hand, renders one passive: nothing can be done to undo the loss. Emotions are therefore about tendencies to act and about inclinations to change something in the immediate environment, or by contrast, to keep them as they are. Which action corresponds to which emotion differs from one individual to the other, and depends on the circumstances. And finally, contribution number three refers to the notion of ‘control precedence’. A strong emotion controls or dictates one’s desires, behaviors, and thoughts. 32 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Nico Frijda One has, at that moment, absolutely no idea what damage this might inflict on ourselves or others. These are, in my view, meaningful and insightful thoughts. I consider them to be my most important contributions to emotion theory. Frijda thinks that, thereafter, no real spectacular insights in emotions have appeared. And it is unfortunate that his insights are still not used enough, as is the fact that they never became a central topic of study. Why is that? Particularly, I think, because of the cognitive orientation in psychology. Within the more contemporary areas of cognitive psychology, researchers prefer to use representations as the core concept in explaining perception and behavior, rather than dynamic elements such as: motivation, striving, and persisting in a given behavior (even if it does not yield desired outcomes). That is, ‘control precedence’. Anyone who wants to understand love, greed or addiction must consider these processes. Anyway, psychology as a whole has difficulties in understanding what drives people and animals, or what puts them into motion when we go beyond satisfying our basic needs (e.g., such as hunger, thirst, or loneliness). Why are people sometimes so intensely curious? And how does something like sexual desire or craving work? Or religious or political fanaticism? How can something be so strong as to put everything else aside? How do intense emotions – again control precedence – engage all our psychological functions, such as attention, thinking, imagination, fantasy, perception, memory, prediction? All this is central to understanding emotions, but it is often neglected in research. That is unfortunate, since emotions arise through events that are perceived to imply promise or threat to one's concerns, the things that move us, such as needs and desires. What is the relationship between emotions and economics? Describe this relationship. When I once asked an economist what precisely causes a crash on the stock market, he said: “That’s for you psychologists to say.” And, of course, he was right. A market crash revolves around uncertainty, fear, and loss of confidence. The psychology of emotions is very relevant to economics. Indeed, emotional factors are frequently involved in economic decisions. Think, for example, of novelty, the role of brand names, product confidence and preferences, including product confi- Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 dence and preference shown by other people. Emotional factors like these imply that economic behavior sharply deviates from the classic decision-making models that many economic theories endorse. People are not always rational beings striving to maximize their economic gain. They usually stop the choice process as soon as they come across an alternative that best satisfies them (satisficing model, Herbert Simon). But the role of psychology in economics goes much further. Indeed, a core element of my perspective is that emotions emanate from events that are relevant to one’s concerns: they either help or hinder those concerns. Economics is largely defined by supply and demand, but demand derives from someone’s concerns, and notably from his or her needs and desires. Economic demand results from emotions that people expect after the demand has been satisfied. Why do people buy a car? For the convenience and the fact that it saves time? But why is saving time so important? Because of convenience (again) and economic gains. And why do people always seek gains? So the cycle continues. The rationality of economic decisions stems from its correspondence with anticipated emotions. Reason is not much different from anticipated or postponed emotion. It is not much different, in particular, from emotions that are due to satisfying concerns that one strongly shares. If other people have emotions due to concerns that one does not strongly share, there is nothing rational in their emotions. But that is not everything. Every event has different consequences for different concerns. A marriage satisfies the desire for intimacy and sex, but conflicts with the need for independence. The net emotion, therefore, depends on what people think about, and thus on their appraisal. And that raises problems for economic considerations: how far do people pursue their appraisal? That can vary, and can make huge differences in the estimated economic outcome – whether it appears good or bad. Time gain and economic profit are worth pursuing on account of other concerns that result from other emotions. That is one. But the car also produces carbon dioxide that is relevant to our concerns for our health and that of our children. That may (or may not) enter our calculations of net profit and, thus, net emotions. Take another example. Take the telephone computer voice that says: “There are still 40 people before you.” That indeed does save a firm the cost of 39 telephone operators, but also entails a loss of what has been called "social capital", such as interpersonal trust and loyalty. What is considered net profit thus depends on one's own concerns. And this leads on to something important. Reason is postponed emotion, and is therefore liable to the laws of emotions. One of them is George Ainslie’s time-discounting principle: future emotional states are perceived as considerably less intense compared to those being experienced in the present. In popular parlance: ‘I’ll cross that bridge when I come to it’. This thought must have crossed the American mortgage lenders' minds in the last few years…” Apart from his key works, ‘The Emotions (1986)’ and ‘The Laws of Emotion (2006)’, Frijda also wrote a book in Dutch entitled ‘Psychology makes sense’. How does the emotion psychologist look at the current world? With the pessimism that it deserves. Psychologists have invested much energy, for example, in understanding and preventing human violence, but that hasn’t made a difference. Psychologists, and other scientists interested in human thought processes, have, in various ways, tried to reduce prejudice and unrealistic thoughts. That has only strengthened fundamentalism rather than 33 weakened it. I could go on. All this psychology doesn’t make any difference because the power of the psychology of violence is negligible compared to the power of violence itself … Despite that, you wrote a book about the usefulness of psychology, didn’t you? “I don’t think that psychology can do much to change the world. But it does contribute to individual happiness and well being. Psychology seeks to give an account of who we are. That, by the way, brings me back to your very first question. That is why I find the psychology of emotions so nice, and I do remain fascinated by the subject. Because it seeks to elucidate who we are and who I am. Psychology makes sense. A little bit. ‘Why are people sometimes so intensely curious? And how does something like sexual desire or craving work? Or religious or political fanaticism? How do intense emotions engage all our psychological functions? All this is central to understanding emotions, but it is often neglected in research.’ 34 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 35 THE researchers of TIBER “ Market Bubbles and Crashes The Dutch are oversensitive to economic losses Name: Charles Noussair (Professor) Education: Economics, Psychology, Social Sciences, University of Pennsylvania, California Institute of Technology Tiber research: Experimental study of asset market bubbles and crashes Name: Gijs van de Kuilen (Tiber postdoc) Education: Economics, University of Amsterdam, University of Otago Tiber research: Individual decision-making under risk and uncertainty Asset markets at times experience spectacular price fluctuations. One pattern that seems to occur repeatedly is a bubble, a sustained period of apparently unreasonably high and increasing prices, followed by a market crash, in which prices rapidly decrease by a large amount. For example, the Shanghai stock exchange, after posting a gain of 467% between May 2005 and October 2007, lost half of the amount gained by April 2008. More generally, in markets for stocks, real estate, and other assets, bubble and crash price patterns occur and appear to indicate mispricing relative to fundamental values, and thus raise doubts about whether markets are efficient. However, with data from “real world” markets such as these, researchers cannot distinguish between two explanations of these price patterns. The first possibility is that market prices are tracking fundamentals, which are in turn exhibiting increases and rapid falls. The second possibility is that markets are becoming decoupled from fundamental values when they form bubbles and subsequently crash. We use English methods such that prices can be compared to fundamental values, which can be made observable and controlled. The basic approach is the following. Each member of a group of traders is endowed with units of a dividend-bearing asset and some money to make trades, as well as the ability to participate in a market in which the asset can be traded. The asset is designed in a manner so that it has an unambiguous fundamental value, which can be compared to the prices at which the asset trades. Experimental research shows that when traders are inexperienced, prices in such markets exhibit a tendency to depart from fundamental values. Indeed, the typical price pattern observed is a bubble and crash, reminiscent of those observed in real world markets. As traders gain more experience in similar markets, bubbles become smaller and crashes less common. Eventually, prices come to track fundamental values. Thus, the overall pattern suggests that bubbles and crashes are consequences of the presence of a large number of inexperienced participants, and depend on individual trading behavior that diminishes with experience. The research I have recently conducted, building on the structure described above, has yielded a number of results about the behavior of experimental asset markets, as well as insights about real world financial markets. Allowing individuals to make short sales results in lower prices, and introducing futures contracting on the asset induces pricing at close to fundamental values, and thus improves market efficiency. These benefits provide an explanation for why these types of contracts tend to co-exist with trading of financial assets. My experiments show that asset markets track fundamentals better at times when the fundamentals are peaking than when they are experiencing a low point, and adjust better to inflation than to deflation, providing a possible explanation for why some studies find that real world stock prices track fundamentals while others find the opposite. ” “ Every day, consumers take numerous decisions with an uncertain outcome. I am trying to understand the psychological factors behind that process. To attain this understanding, I do experiments. Only rarely do people know in advance what the consequences of their choice will be. Of course, that matters more for some decisions than for others: some decisions are complex, others are relatively easy. The decision-making model that is often used in economics is called ‘expected utility theory’, and it assumes that people derive a certain amount of utility from the different outcomes of choice alternatives. Someone who has to choose between two options with uncertain outcomes will simply select the option that yields the highest expected utility. This purely rational consideration is thought to explain someone’s attitude towards risk. In practice, however, we see that individuals do not always make choices on purely rational grounds. Take the way people behave at a casino, for instance. Gamblers are not averse to risk. Quite the opposite, in fact: they are risk seeking. The classic decision-making model, based on the maximization of expected utility, is unable to explain this kind of behavior – all the more so because many of those who flirt with risk at the casino often carefully avoid risk when taking out an insurance policy. In response to this kind of irrational behavior, many alternative decision-making models have been developed, often based on findings from psychology. Some of these models assume that individual choice behavior deviates from the predictions of the classical expected utility model because people are overly sensitive to tiny possibilities and certainties. Take a lottery, for instance, where the probability of winning a cash prize is minute; despite this, huge numbers of people still buy a ticket every month. Or the many unnecessary insurance policies taken out by consumers. They indicate an oversensitivity to certainty. These two examples illustrate that people often fail to discriminate sufficiently between different levels of likelihood. Another aspect of my research is response to losses. Consumers appear to evaluate the outcomes of their choices relative to a reference point, and are overly sensitive to outcomes below this reference point i.e., they are overly sensitive to losses. My research has shown that the average Dutch person weights a particular loss about one-and-a-half times as heavy as a commensurable gain. Hence, the average Dutch person is indeed oversensitive to economic losses. To sum up, then, I am looking at human decision-making under conditions of uncertainty. What are the underlying psychological factors? With that knowledge, we hope to be better able to predict how economic choices are made in the future. ” 36 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 If there is any trade where economics, psychology, and marketing come together, it is the advertising business. The skill of persuading people to buy your stuff, and to trust in your promise – time and again – is one of the most important driving forces of the world economy. And it is a costly one, too. That is why it is so staggering to watch brands that fail to succeed, and at the same time so fascinating to observe others that remain successful for decades. What is the reason behind this? Are we able to pinpoint why things went right, and why other things went wrong? Is there a scientific brand theory that reveals the secret? Well, yes. And no. Big shiny things What brands should be like – according to Giep Franzen If you have the good fortune to spend time in a less polluted part of the world, the starry sky on a moonless night can be a fascinating treat. There they are: your friends the stars. The big, shiny, solid heavenly bodies seem close, even if they are billions of kilometres away. Their presence is serene, never changing and comforting. That is what great brands look like, according to professor Giep Franzen. In front of the impressive stage of the nocturnal firmament, satellites, shooting stars, planes, and other objects flash by like disturbing mosquitoes. That is what minor brands look like. Quite a difference, if you think about it. Franzen explains why branding has everything to do with astronomy – and nothing to do with astrology. The consistency rule With a career lasting 54 years, and counting, Giep Franzen is a true veteran in advertising. His knowledge of the trade is not only wide and profound, it is also very up to date. “I keep collecting things,” he says. “That is only obvious for a very young science like commercial communication. I have a continuing curiosity about brands. Their successes and failures are amazing research material. One thing is very clear to me: there is a certain lack of consistency in both the companies and the mentality of today. First of all, people stop reading after they have completed their studies. Their careers come to prevail over the freshness of their knowledge. At SWOCC [the Foundation for Fundamental Research on Commercial Communications at the University of Amsterdam], we publish piles of brochures on new and very important topics. Thin but interesting booklets. We have a hard time distributing them though, because people think they are hard to comprehend. Would you consult a surgeon who had stopped reading in 1990 because his specialist literature was too complex? Secondly, the careers of marketing people are inconsistent, too. If the team that carries the values of a company changes entirely every three years, how can you possibly expect that firm to operate a consistent branding policy?” Overly self-conscious In this climate of inconsistency, companies have a tendency to become somewhat overly self-conscious. Six years ago, Volkswagen, the unpretentious brand of the people, introduced its Phaeton, a top-end luxury limousine capable of competing with the BMW 740 and the Mercedes C-Class. The car’s development cost Volkswagen 900 million euros. But nobody bought it. “It’s obvious why,” says Franzen. “Who wants to spend 100,000 to 185,000 euros on a supercar with a Volkswagen logo on the grille? Second-hand Phaetons with very low mileages are for sale today in Germany for less than 14,000 euros. US sales stalled in 2005. This failure is an exception for a brand like Volkswagen. They are well known for their consistent branding policy and low advertising cost per car sold. But nonetheless, it remains a failure, a big one.” 37 A brand belongs to the public Today, large companies seem to have their own religion, which urges the people involved to become believers in the success of the next project – whatever projects that may be. Their vision is inward-looking and they seem to underestimate the complexity of their assignments. “The science is pretty basic,” Franzen comments. “For example, the introduction of a new product under an existing brand name has an 80-90 percent chance of failure. That is a fact proven by SWOCC. Big businesses such as Unilever, Sara Lee, and Procter & Gamble probably account for the 10 percent that do it by the book. The rest should keep their money in their pockets. But somehow, they don’t seem aware of the fundamental principles of branding.” One of those fundamental principles is that you should keep your hands off a brand as much as possible, even if it is your own. A brand belongs Tiber Co-Director Rik Pieters about Giep Franzen: “He is the David Ogilvy of the science of advertising. He is a born advertiser, gifted entrepreneur, strategic thinker, self-made academic, and true gentleman. He is the only one who can weld theory and practice into a solid union. Incessantly striving to discover new truths about the effectiveness of commercial communication.” 38 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 Tilburg Research - 2008, volume 5, number 3 39 Column to the public. At least, that is how the consumer sees it. And that is only logical: if we are confronted with hundreds of brand messages every day, they become part of our daily routine and identity. We want them to remain untouched, because human beings are conservative animals. So anything you do should be done with great care and consideration for your customers. Brands that add something – whatever that something is – to people’s identity are particularly prone to damage. Companies like Nike, Apple and – again – car manufacturers should be vary careful, because the slightest deviation can turn strong believers into disappointed deserters. Determination and consistency Franzen calls BMW the most admired car brand in the world. “Literally everything they do is based on the same strong yet basic assumption: sheer driving pleasure. Building engines has always been the strongest quality of the Bayerische Motoren Werke. Mind you, it was only in 1960 that BMW started to produce cars and positioned itself alongside Mercedes with this very strong psychological assumption: If a businessman has made something of his life in Germany and has to show his neighbour he is something, he can only drive a Mercedes. If, however, he has made something of his life, but feels not the slightest need to show off, then he can buy himself a BMW. Over the years, this way of positioning the brand, and its drive for perfection in technology, has established BMW as one of the best carmakers around the globe. Both determination and consistency can turn your brand into an icon.” The success of the BMW brand is described in the book 'Driven', by David Kiley; compulsory reading, according to Giep Franzen. Past, present and future Marketing and advertising have nothing to do with predicting the future. “The objective reality of things is a fact,” says Franzen. “You must be willing to find out what that means. If you are working on new projects, you need experience to rely on; just trying and praying won’t do. Lately, I have been slightly worried about the position of marketing people; they are being thrown off companies’ management boards because they cannot account for their contribution to the financial results. Their work is not visible in the profit or the loss of a company. Corporate brands that appear in the stock exchange suffer the most: every three months they have to report to the stockholders. If you let the present rule your decisions, you won’t be able to pursue a consistent policy. A good branding policy is always based on the past, the present and the future.” Branding is just hard work David Ogilvy, who has often been called ‘The Father of Advertising’, was never driven by his ego or his dreams, he was just incredibly curious. “All the time,” says Franzen, “he was busy collecting the facts about his profession. His book, On Advertising, can be seen as the first branding theory. Now there are hundreds of them. So there is no lack of research material. I urge anyone with ambitions in the business to study it thoroughly. After all, branding is hard work. Visionary talent is rare. Freddy Heineken was a special and amusing exception to that rule: I sat next to him at a lot of presentations by people from FHV BBDO, Heineken’s publicity agency. During every session, those poor boys and girls stuttered and acted clumsily with the overhead sheets. But Freddy totally ignored them; he just sat there smiling and cracking dirty jokes at me. Heineken’s decisions were rarely influenced by anyone but Heineken himself. He was a natural. But everyone else must learn.” Fire and Water By Fred van Raaij Economics as a science developed in a period when psychology was still in its infancy and was not yet recognized as an independent empirical discipline. Early micro-economists could thus not yet use the input of empirical psychology and therefore developed their own behavioral foundation. Hedonic Utility Theory, developed by Jeremy Bentham (1789), was their inspiration. In this theory, pleasure and pain are the central concepts. People seek pleasure and avoid pain. Their preference for alternatives and their behavior are assumed to be explained by a ‘pleasure-pain calculus’, a kind of pleasurepain trade-off. The psychologist William James criticized this in 1890 as being a too simple explanation and predictive basis of behavior. However, he could not prevent (micro) economics disengaging itself from psychology and thus from a psychological behavioral foundation. The foundation of (micro) economics centers on a system of utility maximization which assumes that people have complete information about alternative options and are aware of their stable preferences. This means that economics is essentially a normative, rather than a descriptive, science. Descriptive science starts from a portrayal of how economic actors (e.g., consumers, investors, and entrepreneurs) behave and make economic decisions in real and/or experimental situations. The Nobel laureate, psychologist Herbert Simon (1978), introduced the concept of ‘satisficing’ and showed that, in many cases, people cannot maximize their utility as economic theory assumes. People are typically satisfied with a choice outcome that meets most (if not all) of their criteria. But with regard to ‘satisficing’ economists could, nevertheless, still argue that people are not rational; and, that economic theory offers the solution and the correction for the irrationality. But our understanding of psychology has since developed and is now better equipped to provide a behavioral foundation for micro-economics. Economic psychologists and behavioral economists use experimental and survey techniques (based on psychological and sociological models and theories) to investigate the behavior of consumers, investors, entrepreneurs, and tax payers. However, economists still seem to learn more from psychologists than psychologists learn from economists. The transfer of knowledge in the latter case still has to gather momentum. The Nobel laureate Daniel Kahneman (2002) and Amos Tversky (both psychologists) developed Prospect Theory and showed that human deviations from economic theory are systematic. Such departures should, therefore, no longer be considered as purely human shortcomings. People react to gains and losses from a reference point. And people take more risk to avoid a loss than to reach a gain. This instigated the acceptance of behavioral economics to economics more generally. However, many economics textbooks still are lacking a behavioral introduction. Tiber will thus be functioning within a changed economics environment. Tiber will be a part of micro-economic science using psychological findings and experiments. Tiber will be a part of macroeconomics where the confidence and expectations of consumers, investors and entrepreneurs became a critical factor for success. And Tiber will be a part of behavioral accounting, behavioral finance, and other new developments in economics. Economics and psychology are no longer “fire and water” (as the late Amos Tversky once lamented), but rather provide mutual support and learning. Fred van Raaij is Professor of Economic Psychology at Tilburg University.