The Forest Agent-Based Landowner Economy (FABLE) Jesse Henderson Ph.D. Student North Carolina State University Two themes in the literature 1. Forest landowner decisions – (how to determine optimal time to harvest given what a landowner values) 2. Aggregate market behavior – (characteristics of those that harvest, supply elasticity, total harvests, price changes) Problem: what is the connection? Individuals ? Aggregate Literature: forest landowner decisions 1 Classical Faustmann – cut at a certain age Hartman – value on standing forest1 Reservation price – “the price is right”2 Landowner demographics/preferences3 Decisions with uncertain prices/risk4 (Hartman, 1976) 2 (McGough, Plantinga, & Provencher, 2004) 3 (Amacher, Conway, & Sullivan, 2003) (Binkley, 1981) 4 (Norstrom, 1975) (Routledge, 1980) (Koskela, 1989) (Pukkala & Kanga, 1996) (Zhang, 2001) Literature: landowner heterogeneity SURVEYS & CLUSTER ANALYSES - Timber, Multiobjective, Nontimber1 (National Woodland Owner Survey) - Thoreau, Muir, Jane Doe3 - “Multiobjective, Recreationists, Self-employed owners, Investors, and Indifferent owners”4 Representing landowner behavior by group or type (with variation) might better describe the situation. 1 (Majumdar, Teeter, & Butler, 2008) 2 (Finley & Kittredge, 2006) 3 (Favada, Karppinen, Kuuluvainen, Mikkola, & Stavness, 2009) Literature: aggregating individuals 1. “Engineering” models + 2. Econometric models1 = 3. Probit models2 4. Agent-based models 1 (Wear & Parks, 1994) 2 (Prestemon & Wear, 2000) x Literature: agent-based modeling Features of agent-based modeling (Gilbert, 2006) A computational method Heterogeneous agents Representation of an environment Agent Interactions Bounded rationality Learning Previous applications Forest Economics: W. Canada, pine beetle risk (Schwab et al., 2009) Environ. Sci.: Harvesting/ecosystem services (Satake et al 2007) Artificial Markets (Schredelseker & Hauser, 2008) Objectives - FABLE • Develop an agent-based timber market model which simulates inventory, removals and prices which emerge from heterogeneous agents. • Determine the market features that result from each of five cases. • Determine the supply response to different levels of demand and the implications for sustainability. Methods: bidding D P S Q Bid heterogeneity from: 1. Heterogenous discount rates 2. Heterogeneous stand ages Methods: outputs of the model • • • • • • • supply elasticity sustainability index price average harvest age removals demand inventory 𝑄𝑗 +1 − 𝑄𝑗 𝑃𝑗 +1 𝐸𝑠 = ∙ 𝑄𝑗 𝑃𝑗 +2 − 𝑃𝑗 +1 2310 2300 2290 2280 2270 2260 2250 2240 2230 2220 2210 2200 2190 2180 2170 2160 2150 2140 2130 2120 2110 2100 2090 2080 2070 2060 2050 2040 2030 2020 2010 Inventory (Million Green Tons) 66% Reservation Price Faustmann: inventory 6 5 4 8 3 14 2 20 1 0 Inventory for reservation price Faustmann (66%) and reservation price Hartman (34%) by demand level Remova ls (Thousa nd Green Tons) 66% Reservation Price Faustmann: removals demand 400 350 300 250 8 200 14 150 20 100 50 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060 2070 2080 2090 2100 2110 2120 2130 2140 2150 2160 2170 2180 2190 2200 2210 2220 2230 2240 2250 2260 2270 2280 2290 2300 2310 0 Removals for reservation price Faustmann (66%) and reservation price Hartman (34%) by demand level 66% Reservation Price Faustmann: price 8 210 10 Price ($ / green ton) 12 14 160 16 18 20 110 60 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060 2070 2080 2090 2100 2110 2120 2130 2140 2150 2160 2170 2180 2190 2200 2210 2220 2230 2240 2250 2260 2270 2280 2290 2300 2310 10 Price for reservation price Faustmann (66%) and reservation price Hartman (34%) by demand level 66% Reservation Price Faustmann: average harvest age 80 Average Harvest Age (years) 70 60 50 8 40 20 30 20 10 Harvest age for reservation price Faustmann (66%) and reservation price Hartman (34%) by demand level 2200 2190 2180 2170 2160 2150 2140 2130 2120 2110 2100 2090 2080 2070 2060 2050 2040 2030 2020 2010 0 Results/Conclusion: supply curves 35 30 Price ($ / green ton) 25 20 Faustmann-R Hartman-R 15 Faustmann 66% Hartman 66% 10 5 0 90000 110000 130000 150000 170000 190000 210000 230000 Quantity (green tons) Supply curves for four cases in the year 2020 Results/Conclusion: supply curves 120 Price ($ / green ton) 100 80 Faustmann-R 60 Hartman-R Faustmann 66% Hartman 66% 40 20 0 90000 100000 110000 120000 130000 140000 150000 Quantity (green tons) Supply curves for four cases in the year 2060 Results/Conclusion: supply curves 70 60 Price ($ / green ton) 50 40 Faustmann-R Hartman-R 30 Faustmann 66% Hartman 66% 20 10 0 90000 100000 110000 120000 130000 140000 150000 Quantity (green tons) Supply curves for four cases in the year 2250 2310 2300 2290 2280 2270 2260 2250 2240 2230 2220 2210 2200 2190 2180 2170 2160 2150 2140 2130 2120 2110 2100 2090 2080 2070 2060 2050 2040 2030 2020 2010 Price ($ / green ton) 200 120 50 100 40 80 30 60 20 40 20 10 0 0 Average Harvest Age (years) Results/Conclusion: Harvest age and Price Bubbles 80 20 - Price 180 70 20 - Average Harvest Age 160 60 140 2010 91+ 81 to 90 71 to 80 61 to 70 51 to 60 41 to 50 31 to 40 21 to 30 11 to 20 0 to 10 Frequency Results/Conclusion: Age Class Histograms 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 0 2020 91+ 81 to 90 71 to 80 61 to 70 51 to 60 41 to 50 31 to 40 21 to 30 11 to 20 0 to 10 Frequency Results/Conclusion: Age Class Histograms 1800 1600 1400 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 0 2040 91+ 81 to 90 71 to 80 61 to 70 51 to 60 41 to 50 31 to 40 21 to 30 11 to 20 0 to 10 Frequency Results/Conclusion: Age Class Histograms 1600 1400 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 0 THANKS Acknowledgements: Bob Abt, Jeff Prestemon, Fred Cubbage References Amacher, G. S., Conway, M. C., & Sullivan, J. (2003). Economic analyses of nonindustrial forest landowners: Is there anything left to study? Journal of Forest Economics , 137-164. Atmadja, S. S. (2008, September 17). Discount Rate Estimation and the Role of Time Preference in Rural Household Behavior: Disease Prevention in India and Forest Management in the US. Retrieved February 4, 2011, from http://www.lib.ncsu.edu/resolver/1840.16/3292 Beach, R. H., Pattanayakp, S. K., Yanga, J., Murray, B. C., & Abt, R. C. (2005). Econometric studies of non-industrial private forest management: a review and synthesis. Forest Policy and Economics , 261-281. Bengston, D. N., Butler, B. J., & Asah, S. T. (2009). Values and motivations of private forest owners in the United States: a framework based on open-ended responses in the national woodland owner survey. Proceedings of the 2008 Northeastern Recreation Research Symposium , 60-66. Binkley, C. S. (1993). Long-run Timber Supply: price elasticity, inventory elasticity, and the use of capital in timber production. Natural Resource Modeling , 163-181. Binkley, C. S. (1981). Timber Supply from Private Nonindustrial Forests. Bulletin No. 92. Yale School of Forestry and Environmental Studies , 78-81. Buchholz, T., Luzadis, V. A., & Volk, T. A. (2009). Sustainability criteria for bioenergy systems: results from an expert survey . Journal of Cleaner Production , S86-S98. Bullard, S. H., Gunter, J. E., Doolittle, M. L., & Arano, K. G. (2002). Discount Rates for Nonindustrial Private Forest Landowners in Mississippi: How High a Hurdle? Southern Journal of Applied Forestry , 26-31. Costanza, R., Fisher, B., Mulder, K., Liu, S., & Christopher, T. (2007). Biodiversity and ecosystem services: A multi-scale empirical study of the relationship between species richness and net. Ecological Economics , 478-491. Favada, I. M., Karppinen, H., Kuuluvainen, J., Mikkola, J., & Stavness, C. (2009). Effects of Timber Prices, Ownership Objectives, and Owner Characteristics on Timber Supply. Forest Science . Finley, A. O., & Kittredge, D. B. (2006). Thoreau, muir, and jane doe: different types of private forest owners need different kinds of forest management. North. J. Appl. Forestry . Forni, M., & Lippi, M. (1999). Aggregation of linear dynamic microeconomic models. Journal of Mathematical Economics , 131-158. Gilbert, N. (2006). Agent-Based Models (Quantitative Applications in the Social Sciences). 2008. Sage Publications. Sage Publications. Hartman, R. (1976). The harvesting decision when a standing forest has value. Economic Inquiry , 52-58. Koskela, E. (1989, March). Forest Taxation and Timber Supply Under Price Uncertainty: Perfect Capital Markets. Forest Science, Volume 35, Number 1 , 137-159. Majumdar, I., Teeter, L., & Butler, B. (2008). Characterizing Family Forest Owners: A Cluster Analysis Approach. Forest Science , 176-184. McGough, B., Plantinga, A. J., & Provencher, W. (2004). The Dynamic Behavior of Timber Prices. Land Economics . Mujamdar, I., L., L. T., & Butler, B. (2008). Characterizing Family Forest Owners: A Cluster Analysis Approach. Forest Science . Zhang, D. (2001). Faustmann in an uncertain policy environment. Forest. Policy Econ. , 203-210. References Nerlove, M., & Bessler, D. A. (2001). Expectation, information and dynamics. In B. L. Gardner, & G. C. Rausser, Handbook of agricultural economics: Vol. 1 (p. 160). Amsterday: Elsevier Science. Newman, D. H., Gilbert, C. B., & Hyde, W. F. (1985). The Optimal Forest Rotation with Evolving Prices. Land Economics , 347-353. Newman, D., & Wear, D. (1993). The production economics of private forestry: A comparison of industrial and non-industrial forest owners. American Journal of Agricultural Economics , 674-684. Norstrom, C. J. (1975). A stochastic model for the growth period decision in forestry. The Swedish Journal of Economics , 329-337. Pattanayak, S. K., Murray, B. C., & Abt, R. C. (2002). How Joint is Joint Forest Production? An Econometric Analysis of Timber Supply Conditional on Endogenous Amenity Values. Forest Science , 479-491. Peksa-Blanchard, M., Dolzan, P., Grassi, A., Heinimö, J., Junginger, M., Ranta, T., et al. (2007). Global Wood Pellets Markets and Industry: Policy Drivers, Market Status and Raw Material Potential. IEA Bioenergy Task 40. Prestemon, J. P., & Wear, D. N. (2000). Linking Harvest Choices to Timber Supply. Forest Science , 377-389. Pukkala, T., & Kanga, J. (1996). A Method for Integrating Risk and Attitude Toward Risk into Forest Planning. Forest Science, Volume 42, Number 2 , 198-205. Routledge, R. D. (1980). The effect of potential catastrophic mortality and other unpredictable events on optimal forest rotatino policy. Forest Science , 389-399. Satake, A., Leslie, H. M., Iwas, Y., & Levin, S. A. (2007). Coupled ecological-social dynamics in a forested landscape: Spatial interactions and information flow. Journal of Theoretical Biology . Schredelseker, K., & Hauser, F. (2008). Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems: Complexity and Artifiical Markets. Berlin: Springer-Verlag. Schwab, O., Maness, T., Bull, G., & Roberts, D. (2009). Modeling the effect of changing market conditions on mountain pine beetle salvage harvesting and structural changes in the British Columbia forest products industry. Canadian Journal of Forest Research , Volume 39, Number 10, 1806-1820(15). Tesfatsion, L. (2002). Agent-Based Computational Economics: Growing Economies From the Bottom Up. Artificial Life , 55-82. Tesfatsion, L. (2001). Introduction to the special issue on agent-based computational economics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control , 281-293. Thomson, T. A. (1992). Optimal Forest Rotation When Stumpage Prices Follow a Diffusion Process. Land Economics , 329-342. Tsvetovatyy, M., Gini, M., Mobasher, B., & Wieckowski, Z. (1997). Magma: An Agent-Based Model for Electronic Commerce. Applied Artificial Intelligence , 501-523. Wear, D. N., & Parks, P. J. (1994). The Economics of Timber Supply: An Analytical Synthesis of Modeling Approaches. Natural Resource Modeling , 199-222.