Notes 4, More on demand and supply Markets Market: a meeting of a buyer and a seller to arrange price and quantity and make a trade. Markets are a really big deal in economics. “Market economics” is the name given to the way of thinking that the best way to organize economic activity, that is, producing and consuming goods and services, is to assign property rights to all resources to private individuals (as opposed to the government) and let those self-interested individuals work out on their own, or in free cooperation with other people (i.e., business firms) how to put those resources to the best use. Market economics requires that the people who own these resources be able to communicate their wants to each other and to get together to exchange their resources with each other. That’s what markets do. What does a market look like? It’s pretty variable. Say you travel to Mexico and go to an open-air market in the middle of town, with vendors hawking their wares from little tented kiosks, and you stop at a stall where some guy is selling wool scarves. He tells you how wonderful his scarves are, blah, blah, blah, and that the price is $50. You offer him $10. He pretends to be offended. You walk away. He comes after you. You eventually end up paying $20 for a scarf. Is this a market? Yes. A buyer and a seller meet, arrange a price and a quantity, and make a trade. Now, as I’m writing this I’ve just gone to eBay and bought two bottles of dog tapeworm remover pills for my dear little Lucy. A few mouse clicks and the pills are on their way. Is this a market? Yes. The buyer (me) contacted the seller (some guy in Harwinton, Connecticut, wherever that is) via eBay. (“meeting of a buyer and a seller “) I looked at his Buy-It-Now price, thought it was ok (less than half the pet store price), clicked the button, and entered 2 in the quantity box. (“arrange price and quantity”) He’ll send me the stuff, I’m pretty sure, since he has all positive ratings, and I’ve sent him the money via PayPal. (“make a trade”) (Note: the pills, as described, arrived in four days.) I want to emphasize the importance of property rights in all this. The tapeworm pill seller was willing to buy the pills from wherever he got them because he was confident that he would be able to keep them or sell them as he wished, and that they would not be taken away from him in the meantime. He was willing to sell them to me because of his confidence that PayPal would deliver the money to him. And I’m willing to pay for them, confident that when I get them, I can use them as I see fit. In a nation without strong property rights, say, Cuba, the seller would have to worry that the government might confiscate his inventory arbitrarily. If so, he might be better off not buying the pills in the first place, and the trade would never take place. Markets can’t work unless participants are secure in their rights of ownership of the goods and services they trade. That’s why foreign corporations are leery of investing in places like Cuba. (Most of the ones that do, are doing so in the expectation -remember that expectations are important--of better times after Castro finally kicks the bucket, and they want to have the core of their business operation in place when the day comes.) Demand The consumer, or buyer, side of the market is called the demand side. Demand: the willingness and ability of buyers to pay for different quantities of goods at different prices during a given time period. Law of demand The law of demand holds that an increase in the price of a good leads to a decrease in the quantity demanded, or the amount consumers actually buy, ceteris paribus, or all other things constant. In symbols, for a good which we'll call x, P represents the price of the good, Qd the quantity demanded, i.e., the amount that buyers are willing to buy at that price. The "c.p." stands for ceteris paribus, which translates approximately from the Latin as “all other things equal.” It also holds true in reverse, i.e., a decrease in price leads to an increase in quantity demanded. The law of demand is pretty universal; few if any goods are immune to its effects. This leads to a demand curve that is downward sloping. As you can see in Figure 1, representing the market for music CDs, the quantity demanded falls when the price rises—just like the law of demand says. At a price of $10, buyers in the market are willing to purchase 50 units of the good. But when the price rises to $15, some of the buyers are not willing to pay that higher price, and drop out of the market. The quantity demanded falls to 30 units. Why? The substitution effect The primary--although not the only--reason why demand curves slope downward is the substitution effect, which states that consumers will substitute cheaper goods for dearer (more expensive) ones. As the price of CDs rises, potential buyers will buy few of them, and instead buy substitutes. This could mean they download more music in MP3 format. Or it could mean that they buy some other form of entertainment altogether, like green fees for putt-putt golf. Or more beer; it all depends on the buyers’ preferences. The point is, to some extent they’ll switch away from CDs, which give them utility at a high price, to something else that gives them utility at a lower price. Demand curves as willingness-to-pay curves Look again at Figure 1 again. How much is the 50th CD worth to the buyer? Or, what is the same thing, how much is he just willing to th pay for it, at a maximum, rather than go without it? Apparently, $10. Why? Because at a price of $10, the buyer will buy the 50 CD, but won’t buy the 51st. If the price rises to something over $10, the buyer chooses not to buy the 50th CD, i.e., Qd < 50. So the buyer th must value the 50 CD at $10. The point is that, as Alfred Marshall pointed out, demand curves are willingness-to-pay curves. They show the maximum amount a consumer is willing to pay for a certain unit of a good. We'll keep this in mind as we proceed. Responsiveness of buyers to price changes differs among goods Consider three everyday goods: Yellow delicious apples, movie tickets, and gasoline. Now imagine that, tomorrow, each of them rises in price by 10%. The law of demand implies that you will buy fewer of each (presuming you buy some now). But for which of the three will you reduce your consumption the most? Probably not gasoline, I imagine! Why? While the law of demand holds for almost all goods, consumers respond more strongly to price changes for some goods than others. This subject--known as price elasticity--will be taken up in more detail in Economics II. For now, let's note that the primary reason for the differences we see is the existence and closeness of substitute goods. Consumers respond fairly strongly to changes in the price of movie tickets largely because there are many substitutes for a night at the movies--renting a video, going to a ballgame, etc. There are no really close substitutes for gasoline, and so an increase in its price leads to a relatively small change in consumer behavior. In the short run, anyway. Over a period of years, substitutes for gasoline--direct and indirect-- become feasible. Say that, 2 years after a "permanent" rise in the price of gasoline, you decide to trade in your old car. You will likely trade it for a car which consumes less fuel. As old cars are sent to the scrap heap, they are replaced by higher-MPG cars, and so gasoline consumption falls. Also, over time, people can rearrange where they live, where they work and play. High gasoline prices encourage people to reduce the number of miles they have to travel, and the amount of gasoline they consumer per mile of travel, and so reduce gasoline consumption. It takes time, but people do respond. Wants and needs--a myth exploded Need: a matter in which there is no choice. There are no needs. You do not need anything. You probably don’t believe me. Suit yourself. But consider this. If you say that you need water to live, and you have a bottle of water in front of you, and I take that water and drink it myself, then you’ll die, right? Well, no, of course not. You might need water in some general sense, but you don’t need that particular bottle of water. If I drink it up, you’ll just go and find some substitute source of water. And if I grab that one away from you, too, you’ll run away from me and find yourself some other substitute source. The point is, we don’t consume goods in an abstract, general sense. We consume only unique, discrete, identifiable units of goods. And there are always substitutes for any individual unit of water or anything else. The existence of substitutes means that choices are available. And if there are always choices are available . . . well, refer to the definition of need above. More fundamentally, think of the basic premise of economics: We live in a world of scarcity, a condition of unlimited human wants but limited resources. This forces us to make choices. You might say you need something, but even if you do obtain what you “needed,” you had to choose to give up something else to get it. Choice is everywhere. And where there is choice . . . there are no needs. Look at Figure 2a. Here we have a vertical demand curve, say for heroin for Benny, a hard-core heroin addict. At a street price of $100 per fix, he will buy one fix per day. At a price of $200, he will steal twice as many car stereos and buy the same quantity. Aha, you say, here is an example of a need. Not really. Say that the street price of his fix skyrockets to $1000. Unless he is a really good thief, he won’t be able to steal that much per day, and so he can’t afford his fix, and his quantity demanded falls to zero. Figure 2b gives a truer picture of his demand curve. For prices below, say, $500, he can steal enough goods to raise the money for his fix. At prices above that, he can’t. So his Qd = 1 for any price of $500 or less, and equals zero for all prices above that. His demand curve really consists of two discontinuous vertical sections, with the gap at a price of $500. In Figure 2c, I’ve linearized this relationship. Choose two prices, $1000 and $100. Mark a point above the corresponding quantities for each. Now draw a straight line between the two points. What do you have? A downward sloping demand curve. The point is this: The law of demand always holds. Sometimes it’s a gradual thing, with a small increase in P leading to a small decrease in Qd. Sometimes it’s all or nothing . . . like with heroin. Supply Supply: the willingness and ability of sellers to offer for sale different quantities of goods at different prices during a given time period. With the exception of the highlighted words, this is the same as the definition of demand. Law of supply Just as there is a law of demand which explains buyers' behavior there is a law of supply for producers. According to this principle, increases in the price of a good lead producers to offer more of it for sale, i.e., the quantity supplied (Qs) increases. In symbols, Here we have a direct relationship, which gives us an upward-sloping curve in Figure 3. Why? Higher prices mean more production becomes profitable Say that you are managing a plant that manufactures CDs, and that your plant is currently producing close to its capacity. Then a music distributor manufacturer places a rush order for 50,000 copies of a CD by a new group that is unexpectedly popular. In order to fill the order, you will have to speed up production lines and work employees overtime. What will happen to your production costs as a result? Higher production volumes will probably lead to more waste and defective discs that will have to be scrapped, and overtime work will cost you more per hour (indeed, even more than you might think, because worker productivity will fall when workers stay for extra shifts). Will you be willing to take the order? It depends. If the music distributor will pay you a price high enough to cover your increased costs, yes. Categories of goods that do not "obey" the law of supply If the price offered for land in downtown Huntsville rises, how does the quantity of land supplied respond? Not at all, of course! Some goods--those which are not produced by human action--are impervious to the law of supply. An increase in the price of a good promises higher profits and encourages production; the higher price acts as an incentive. But if people do not produce the good in the first place, no incentive can bring forth more of it. There are two broad categories of these goods: 1. "Land," by which we mean all natural resources. This includes land, minerals, and—remember—human talent. Note that an increase in the price of crude oil will bring forth more oil "production," but what this really means is that more oil will be pumped from the ground during a given time period. It does not mean that more oil will come into existence under the earth’s surface. 2. Irreproducible goods, such as works of art, rare coins and stamps, etc. No matter how high the price offered for an original Van Gogh painting, there will be only one authentic painting. Goods such as these have a vertical supply curve, as shown in Figure 4 . A change in price has no effect on quantity supplied. Market equilibrium A market is in equilibrium if the quantity demanded equals the quantity supplied. That way, we have neither sellers with unsold goods, nor buyers with unsatisfied demand. That’s why we often say that the market “clears.” We’ll see that this will happen only at one price among all possible prices that could be charged in the market. First, let's clarify our terms. The equilibrium price (Pe) is the hypothetical price that "matches" demand and supply exactly. The market price (Pmkt)is the actual observed price that happens to prevail in the market at a particular time. The two do not have to be the same, that is, the market does not have to be in equilibrium. But it has a strong tendency to do that, and if it is not exactly in equilibrium, it will tend to move toward it. Now our two cases.