19731 COMMENTS such a system are attributable to a weakness in its basic structure, it is contended that no system works properly unless it is adequately monitored and enforced. A rise in the crime rate due to a lack of police enforcement of our criminal laws, for example, does not necessarily indicate a fatal substantive deficiency in that system. V. CONCLUSION Disregard of laws and agreements providing public safeguards is often popular with those groups who are thereby restrained. In this perspective, it may be seen that the direction of unauthorized practice must not be determined by the singular objective of convenience; convenience provides us with an amblyopic perspective, and not a talismanic formula for reform. The recasting of roles must be planned with reference to the total needs of the homeowner. The complexion of these laws has frequently changed for convenience sake; and although convenience is often the motivation for change it is not always the precursor of progressive reform. KENNETH G. LORE Minimum Fee Schedules as Price Fixing: A Per Se Violation of The Sherman Act Every contract, combination in the form of a trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several states or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal.! It must be accepted that fee schedules are designed to increase a lawyer's income and that they are 2a means of price fixing and eliminating or reducing price competition. Professional services have traditionally enjoyed a judicially implied exemption from antitrust actions as not constituting trade or commerce within the meaning of the Sherman Act. The Supreme Court has sought to constrict the sweep of this exemption by seeking increased regulation of the commercial aspects of professional organizations under section I. Sherman Antitrust Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1 (1970). 2. Arnould & Corley, Fee Schedules Should Be Abolished, 57 A.B.A.J. 655, 656 (1971). 440 THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 22 one of the Sherman Act, leaving unresolved the question of whether the professional relationship existing between practitioner and client may also be reached by this statute. This comment proposes that the implied exemption which has long been tacitly applicable to the legal profession is no longer valid. Further, it proposes that a careful examination of the practice of state bar associations in formulating and implementing minimum fee schedules will result in the determination that the scope of section one of the Sherman Act includes the commercial aspects of legal practice, that the establishment and dissemination of minimum fee schedules is a form of pricefixing, and that as such, it constitutes a per 3 se restraint of trade. I. MINIMUM FEE SCHEDULES With few exceptions, it is the practice of state bar associations to promulgate minimum fee schedules,4 or suggested minimum fee sched- ules, as they are sometimes called. These listings consist of the lowest fee, or range of fees, that the bar association has determined should be charged by attorneys for specific categories of legal services.5 Supporters of minimum fee schedules contend that they do not interfere with the judgment of the individual attorney in setting his fee.' This position is based upon the American Bar Association pronouncement that minimum fee schedules are intended to be flexible and not obliga- tory, and upon similar pronouncements of state bars. The substance of this position is that since many other factors 7 in addition to the mini3. Prices charged for legal services are undergoing examination in the British as well as American systems. One British commission characterized minimum fees as a "collective obligation not to compete in price" and found them to be "one of the most efTective restraints on competition." THE MONOPOLIES COMMISSION, REPORT OF PROFESSIONAL SERVICES, CMND. No. 4463 (pt. I, I 115,319 (1970). See also Harris, Restrictive Practices in the Professions, 120 NEw L.J. 1021 (1970). 4. Statistics indicate that thirty-four states and the District of Columbia have statewide fee schedules; eleven states have schedules adopted by local bars. Five state bar associations did not respond. Arnould & Corley, supra note 2, at 656-57. 5. Real estate services are a specialty of legal practice frequently subject to minimum fees established by bar associations. At present, every state bar association minimum fee schedule contains fees for various real estate transactions. Emphasis on this area of legal practice is not to suggest that any justification exists for distinguishing among legal specialties. This comment proposes that minimum fee schedules are not valid, regardless of the type of professional service involved. 6. See note 7 infra. ABA COMM. ON PROFESSIONAL ETHICS, OPINIONS No. 302 (1961); id., at No. 323 (1970). See AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION, LEGAL ECONOMICS (1970). 7. These. factors are said to include 1)results obtained, 2) amount of time expended, PUBLICATION, MINIMUM FEE SCHEDULES-DEVELOPMENT AND UTILIZATION 1973] COMMENTS mum fee schedule theoretically contribute to the determination of a fee, the schedule itself is only a minor consideration interposed between client and attorney. The effectiveness of this disclaimer is diluted by the American Bar Association Code of Professional Responsibility, which states that consistent disregard for minimum fee schedules may be a basis for discipli- nary action by the bar association.' The language of some state bars is even stronger. The pertinent Virginia State Bar Opinion' reaffirms an earlier opinion to the effect that the habitual failure to follow minimum fee schedules is grounds for disciplinary action. 0 Clearly, the intent of the bar associations is to insure that fees charged for professional services do not fall below a certain stated level." That the coercive measures used to implement the minimum fees are veiled or couched in discretion- ary language does not erase their impact.' 2 The intrusion of the bar association and its minimum fee schedul6 into an attorney's determina- tion of the monetary value of his professional services unquestionably interferes with the freedom of the practitioner to set his fees. He is 3) customary charges of the bar for similar services, 4) complexity of the matter, 5) importance of the matter to the client, 6) total amount involved, 7) whether the client is regular or casual, 8) whether acceptance of the case adversely affects the attorney, 9) general nature of the employment, 10) whether the employment yields prestige to the firm. Buchanan, Jr., TheArt ofBillingthe Client, LEGAL ECONoMics NEWS, Jan., 1971, at I. 8. ABA CODE OF PROFESSIONAL RESPONSIBILITY, ETHICAL CONSIDERATION 2-18 (1970). 9. VIRGINIA STATE BAR, OPINION, No. 170 (1971). 10. Id., No. 98 (1960). II. See Brown, Some Observations on Legal Fees, 24 Sw. L.J. 565 (1970). See also Association of N. Cal. Plymouth Dealers v. United States, 279 F.2d 126 (9th Cir. 1960) wherein the court stated: The competition between Plymouth dealers and the fact that the dealers used the fixed uniform list price in most instances as a starting point, is of no consequence. It was an agreed starting point; it had been agreed upon between competitors; it was in some instances in the record respected and followed; it had to do with, and had its effect upon, price. Id. at 132. 12. The fact that prosecutions of attorneys for consistently charging fees below the minimum rates are rare does not negate the intent of the bar associations in establishing schedules. The coercive apparatus is present; that its formal sanctions are not often applied is reflective only of an ineffective administrative mechanism, not of the intent of bar associations in adopting schedules. The threat of sanction continues to exist and the threat itself is coerceive. For an examination of a marketing agreement deemed to be coercive, see Simpson v. Union Oil Co. of Cal., 377 U.S. 13 (1964); United States v. Parke, Davis & Co., 362 U.S. 29 (1960). 442 THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 22 forced to add an extra factor to his determination, one anchored in peer group pressure, which militates toward higher fees for the client and which tends to relieve the practitioner of the responsibility of setting his own fee. The American Bar Association admits the intended influence of the fee schedule 3 in stating that "the schedules have been established by members of the bar who have, after due deliberation and study of the economic factors, determined that a given fee is the lowest charge a reasonably competent attorney could make, considering the factors of skill, time and overhead expense and still earn himself a reasonable return."' 4 II. THE PER SE CONCEPT When applying the Sherman Act, the courts have sought to distinguish between classes of restraints on trade. A practice which constitutes a restraint is not automatically violative of section one of the Act unless 5 it is within the category of a per se violation. Price fixing has been found to constitute such a violation. 6 The reason for declaring price 13. The intended use of minimum fee schedules is often foiled. One examination has found that eighty-seven percent of the attorneys questioned made some use of the schedules in fee determination, but the 40.3 percent who made greatest use of fee schedules were among lower income attorneys (less than $20,000 per annum). Obviously many attorneys exceed the fee schedules, but few set fees below the minimums. Arnould & Corley, supra note 2, at 660. The fact that such statistical evidence supports the position that minimum fee schedules are not effective in increasing attorneys' incomes is irrelevant to the determination that the schedules are an instance of price fixing. See text accompanying notes 33-35 infra. 14. Minimum Fee Schedules-Neither Fish Nor Fowl, LEGAL ECONOMICS NEws, May, 1971, at 5. 15. In Northern Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1(1958), the Court describes its view of the per se concept: [T]here are certain agreements or practices which because of their pernicious effect on competition and lack of any redeeming virtue are conclusively presumed to be unreasonable and therefore illegal without elaborate inquiry as to the precise harm they have caused or the business excuse for their use. This principle of per se unreasonableness not only makes the type of restraints which are proscribed by the Sherman Act more certain to the benefit of everyone concerned, but it also avoids the necessity for an incredibly complicated and prolonged economic investigation into the entire history of the industry involved, as well as related industries, in an effort to determine at large whether a particular restraint has been unreasonable-an inquiry so often wholly fruitless when undertaken. Among the practices which the courts have heretofore deemed to be unlawful in and of themselves . . .[is] price fixing. . .. Id. at 5, citing United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 210 (1940) (emphasis in original). 16. Id. 1973l COMMENTS fixing to be within the per se category is grounded in the public policy of antitrust. 7 This rationale is powerful enough to support the conclusive presumption that price fixing is an unreasonable restraint of trade.18 On the evils of this practice, the Court has said in United States v. Trenton Potteries Co.:19 The aim and result of every price fixing agreement, if effective, is the elimination of one form of competition. The power to fix prices, whether reasonably exercised or not, involves power to control the market and to fix arbitrary and unreasonable prices ....20 In United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co.,21 Justice Douglas, speaking for the Court, broadly defined the type of practice which constitutes price fixing: "under the Sherman Act a combination formed for the purpose and with the effect of raising, depressing, fixing, pegging, or stabilizing the price of a commodity- in interstate or foreign commerce is illegal per se. ' 22 This expansive definition of pricefixing has 23 received repeated approval since Socony. 17. An examination of the legislative history of the Sherman Act, leading cases, and scholarly commentary reveals several general goals of antitrust policy. These include the protection and preservation of competition, avoidance of the necessity for government intervention in and control of industry to correct and maintain reasonable market conditions, and the promotion of a marketplace operating at or approaching full efficiency. These specific policy considerations are viewed as methods of achieving the more general goals of consumer protection and maintenance of an economic system reasonably approximating free enterprise. For the legislative history of the Sherman Act, see I. TOULMIN, A TREATISE ON THE ANTITRUST LAWS OF THE UNITED STATES chs. 1, 4 (1949); Pogue, The Rationale of Exemptions from Antitrust, 19 A.B.A. ANTITRUST LAW PROCEEDINGS 313 (1961); Comment, The Anatomy of JudicialExemptions from Antitrust: A Study in Gap-Filling, 15 WAYNE L. REV. 813 (1969); C. KAYSEN & P. (1959); Bork, Legislative Intent and the Policy of the Sherman Act, 9 J. LAW & ECON. 7 (1966). 18. In regard to the per se concept and price fixing, see Note, Price Fixing and the TURNER, ANTITRUST POLICY Illegal PerSe Concept, 5 U. RICH. L. REV. 422 (1971); Bork, The Rule of Reason and the Per Se Concept: Price Fixing and Market Division (pt. 1), 74 YALE L.J. 775 (1965); Bork, The Rule of Reason and the Per Se Concept: Price Fixing and Market Division (pt. 2), 75 Yale L.J. 373 (1966); Smposium on Price Competition and Antitrust Policy, 57 Nw. U.L. REV. 137 (1962); Comment, The Per Se Illegality of Price Fixing-Sans Power, Purpose, or Effect, 19 U. CHI. L. REV. 837 (1952). 19. 273 U.S. 392 (1927). 20. Id. at 396-97. 21. 310 U.S. 150 (1940). 22. Id. at 223. 23. United States v. Container Corp. of America, 393 U.S. 333 (1969); Plymouth Dealers Associates of N. Cal. v. United States, 279 F.2d 128 (1960); United States v. McKesson & Robbins, Inc., 351 U.S. 305 (1956); Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distil- 444 THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 22 The tendency of the Court in dealing with the earlier cases in which the existence of price fixing was an issue has been to examine the suspect practice from a practical standpoint. Does the practice tend to produce price uniformity?24 To some degree the test is misleading if it is taken to mean "do the prices charged tend to be the same or similar." When dealing with minimum fee schedules the test should be rephrased: "[d]o the fees charged tend to be in compliance with the minimum fee schedule?"'25 This is the type of test used in Socony. The language of "raising, depressing, fixing, pegging, or stabilizing"2 is general enough to easily encompass minimum fee schedules which are intended to artificially raise prices, occasional examples of sub-minimum prices notwithstanding.27 The Sherman Act requirement of a "combination or conspiracy" in finding a restraint of trade presents no difficulty in the case of state bar associations' promulgation of minimum fee schedules. The Court has consistently construed the requirement broadly. The bar association, which adopts and distributes a minimum fee schedule with the intent to promote price uniformity, has satisfied the combination or conspiracy lers Corp., 341 U.S. 384 (1951); Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, Inc., 340 U.S. 211, 213 (1951); United States v. Univis Lens Co., 316 U.S. 241, 244-45 (1942). 24. Sugar Inst. v. United States, 297 U.S. 553 (1936); Appalachian Coals, Inc. v. United States, 288 U.S. 344 (1933); Maple Flooring Mfrs. Ass'n v. United States, 268 U.S. 563 (1925); Board of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231 (1918). The difference between price leadership, an acceptable occurrence wherein the initiative of the individual entrepreneur is not completely usurped when he decides to conform his price to that of the market, and the strictly prohibited price fixing, has become a more difficult distinction to draw since United States v. Container Corp. of America, 393 U.S. 333 (1969); see text accompanying notes 27-28 infra. The same can be said for price information exchange and price fixing. See note 28 infra. 25. See note II supra. 26. 310 U.S. 150, 223 (1940). 27. A clear line of cases, not expressly overruled by Socony and its progeny, has not held certain practices, which had a discernible effect on competition, to be restraints on trade. There are grounds for distinguishing these cases from the broad sweep of the Socony-Container Corp. line. See, e.g., Sugar Inst., Inc. v. United States, 297 U.S. 553 (1936) (trade association announcing prices prior to sale); Appalachian Coals, Inc. v. United States, 288 U.S. 344 (1933) (producers in co-operative selling agreement); Maple Flooring Mfrs. Ass'n v. United States, 268 U.S. 563 (1925) (anonymous publication of trade information). In the above line of cases, the determination of price was not made by a group or association and then distributed to individual purveyors. The decisionmaking process remained at the individual level, while the concerted action focused primarily on dissemination. Admittedly, this dissemination may have had some effect on future prices, but the essential point is that the free exercise of judgment remained 1973] COMMENTS language. No specific agreement, oral or written, is necessary." "[A] combination may be inferred from an agreement, either express or im- plied, or by the use of any means to secure adherence to a minimum price fixing scheme that goes beyond a unilateral vertical announcement by a seller and a mere refusal to sell."2 " Illustrative of this position is the holding of United States v. Container Corporation of America,0 wherein the mere informal exchange of current price information, without adoption of a minimum price schedule designed to affect price, was said to have affected prices quoted by defendant and chilled competition to the degree which constituted price fixing."' The requisite intent to promote price uniformity needed to satisfy the "combination or conspiracy" language of the Act is often inferred from the practice itself. 3 The reason for the need to infer is obvious-most action which may constitute price fixing is not undertaken with the express declaration that it is intended to h.ffect price. Occasionally there is a stated intent to affect price, on the theory that the practice is exempt from the sweep of the Sherman Act by virtue of a statutory or judicially with the individual. In the Socony-Container Corp. line, that exercise of judgment is more clearly denied to the individual unit of the marketing apparatus. The minimum fee set or suggested by the bar association is an example of the imposed-from-above model of Socony-Container Corp., rather than any hybrid contained in early cases. 28. The combination or conspiracy essential to find a violation of the Sherman Act may be found in a course of dealing or other circumstances, as well as in an exchange of words. United States v. Schrader's Son, Inc., 252 U.S. 85 (1920). See also United States v. Parke, Davis & Co., 362 U.S. 29 (1960); American Tobacco Co. v. United States, 328 U.S. 781 (1946); United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150 (1940). 29. Comment, Maximum Price Fixing: A PerSe Violation of the Sherman Act, 1969 LAW & SOCIAL ORDER 476, 477 n.6. 30. 393 U.S. 333 (1969). 31. A forerunner to United States v. Container Corp. of America, 393 U.S. 333 (1969), was American Column & Lumber Co. v. United States, 257 U.S. 377 (1921), where an extensive "open competition" plan, including the exchange of certain price information, was held violative of the Sherman Act. Regarding the range of permissible trade association activity, see Monroe, PracticalAntitrust Considerationsfor Trade Association, 1969 UTAH L. REv. 622 (1969); Note, Guidelinesfor Data Dissemination Through Trade Associations, 10 WASHBURN L.J. 93 (1970); Note, Antitrust Implications of the Exchange of Price InformationAmong Competitors, 68 MICH. L. REv. 720 (1970). Since ContainerCorporation,the line between information exchange and price fixing has grown appreciably dimmer. 32. Simpson v. Union Oil Co., 377 U.S. 13 (1964); Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distillers Corp., 341 U.S. 384 (1951); American Column & Lumber Co. v. United States, 257 U.S. 377 (1921); United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300 (1919); United States v. Trenton Potteries, 273 U.S. 392 (1927). THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 22 declared exemption. 33 This is the case with minimum fee schedules. Bar associations apparently view not merely its noncommercial aspects, but the entire practice of law as exempt. Consequently, they feel free to state that two of the justifications for schedules are a desire to eliminate price competition by uniform or nearly uniform minimum fees, and a desire to raise attorneys' incomes by means of establishing minimum fees. 4 A court need go no further in searching for intent. Other bar 33. The exemptions from antitrust form a disorderly patchwork on the statutes. It is estimated that twenty percent of the national income originates in exempt sectors. Pogue, supra note 17. See generally Comment, supra note 17; Coleman, Jr., Antitrust Exemptions, Exempt Areas: LearnedProfessions, 33 ABA ANTITRUST L.J. 48 (1967); Comment, PersonalServices and the Antitrust Laws, I WAYNE L. REv. 124 (1955); Comment, Governmental Action and Antitrust Immunity, 119 U. PA. L. REV. 521 (1971); Comment, Immunity From Prosecution Under the Sherman Act, 4 GONZAGA L. REV. 304 (1969); Costilo, Antitrust's Newest Quagmire: The Noerr-Pennington Defense, 66 MICH. L. REV. 333 (1967). Judicially declared exemptions from the sweep of the antitrust statutes include state action. George R. Whitten, Jr., Inc. v. Paddock Pool Builders, Inc., 424 F.2d 25 (1st Cir. 1970); Hecht v. Pro-Football, Inc., 312 F. Supp. 472 (D.D.C. 1970); E.W. Wiggins Airways, Inc. v. Massachusetts Port Authority, 362 F.2d 52 (Ist Cir. 1966), cert. denied, 385 U.S. 947 (1966); Stroud v. Benson, 254 F.2d 448 (4th Cir. 1958), cert. denied, 358 U.S. 817 (1958); Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. 341 (1943); cf Note, The Anthracite Coal Protection Plan, 102 U. PA. L. REv. 368 (1964). Other such exemptions include action by the federal government. Alabama Power Co. v. Alabama Elec. Co-op, Inc., 394 F.2d 672 (5th Cir.), cert. denied, 393 U.S. 1000 (1968); Larson v. Domestic & Foreign Commerce Corp., 337 U.S. 683 (1949). A third exemption is the exercise of constitutionally protected rights to attempt to influence the course of government. George R. Whitten, Jr., Inc. V.Paddock Pool Builders, Inc., 424 F.2d 25, 3 1-34 (1st Cir. 1970); United Mine Workers of America v. Pennington, 381 U.S. 657 (1965); Eastern R.R. Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U.S. 127 (1961). 34. The double-pronged argument of exemption based on the "learned profession" rationale [see text accompanying notes 53-72 infra] and the "state action justification" is raised by the Virginia State Bar Association in current litigation. Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, Civil No. 75-72A (E.D. Va., filed Feb. 22, 1972). Plaintiffs charge that the minimum fee schedules of state and local bar associations are a restraint of trade. Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. 341 (1943), exempts state-created restraints of trade where the state has attained an active degree of participation in the subject activity and the public interest is protected by means other than the antitrust statutes. The position of the integrated state bar association (one which all attorneys are required by law to join before being allowed to practice in the state) of which the Virginia Bar Association is an example, theoretically is secure if the alternative means of protection for the public are present; however, the standard is a rigorous one. Two local bar associations, those of Alexandria, and Arlington, have agreed to abolish their fee schedules and have been severed as defendants. The opinion in Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, rendered on January 5, 1973, distinguishes between the remaining local bars, whose fee schedules were adjudged a per se violation, and the State Bar, whose fee schedule was validated. 1973] COMMENTS association justifications for minimum fee schedules, often said to be noncommercial in nature, 35 are irrelevant when dealing with a per se violation. The breadth of the per se rule is further revealed by the court in Plymouth Dealers Association of Northern California v. United States.3 1 Speaking to the question of whether the agreement, once found to exist, must also be found to affect the price actually charged, the court said: "[tihe test is not what the actual effect is on prices, but whether such agreements interfere with the freedom of traders and thereby restrain their ability to sell in accordance with their own judg37 ment." In a number of recent cases, the Supreme Court has held various activities of professional associations to be price fixing. In UnitedStates v. NationalAssociation of Real Estate Boards,38 the Court enunciated a number of factors relevant in characteiizing the commission schedule promulgated by the broker's association as price fixing. Neither the fact that the rates were not mandatory nor the absence of official sanctions was said to eliminate the existence of an agreement designed to affect price. The Court deemed the use of the prescribed rates in a majority of cases and the tendency of the Board's Code of Ethics to promote adherence as important indicia of the agreement to fix prices. The distinction between the two appears to be a dubious one and appeal is likely. See Leary & Donty, Minimum Fee Schedules and the Antitrust Laws: A Preliminary Analysis (American Bar Foundation Research Memorandum, Series No. 12, 1958). 35. Bar associations contend that there are multiple purposes for establishing minimum fees and that the most important of these are not commercial. See note 7 supra. The argument that the avoidance of price competition protects the public because it allows an attorney to focus his attention on professional skills, not competition for fees, is a position given nominal support by United States v. Oregon Medical Soc'y, 343 U.S. 326 (1952). Reaffirming the Court's position in Semler v. Oregon State Bd. of Dental Examiners, 294 U.S. 608 (1935), Justice Jackson stated: "[t]his court has recognized that forms of competition usual in the business world may be demoralizing to the ethical standards of a profession." 343 U.S. at 336. Reliance on Oregon State MedicalSociety and Semler to support the position that the public needs protection from shoddy legal services caused by price competition is misplaced. In point of fact, no positive correlation has been shown between the quality of legal work and the fee charged, at least with regard to a downward variance. See Coons, Non-Commercial Purpose as a Sherman Act Defense, 56 Nw. U.L. REv. 705 (1962). 36. 279 F.2d 128 (9th Cir. 1960). 37. Id. at 132, quoting Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, 340 U.S. 211, 213 (1951). The issue in Seagram was whether an agreement among competitors to fix maximum prices violated the Sherman Act. The Court declared that it did, reaffirming United States v. Socony Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150 (1940). 38. 339 U.S. 485 (1950). THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW 448 [Vol. 22 Northern California PharmaceuticalAssociation v. United States39 approached the price schedule distributed by the Association in a manner similar to that of NationalAssociation of Real Estate Boards. The suggested prices of the schedule for pre-compounded prescription drugs reflected the existence of an agreement, and the absence of sanctions to enforce the agreement did not render its existence nugatory. Further, the Court held that the very existence of the agreement could be implied from the operation of the pricing schedule among the members. In United States v. Utah PharmaceuticalAssociation," the district court was not at all hesitant in finding the price schedule for prescription drugs distributed to Association members to be price fixing. Again, the factors important to the determination included the membership in the Association of a majority of pharmacists in the state and the consequent widespread use of the schedule. The absence of sanctions for non-use was not dispositive. The parallels between the practices of the associations of the pharmaceutical and brokerage professions and those of state bar associations are striking. In instances where most practitioners are association members, where the fee schedules are said to be suggested but nevertheless receive wide use, and where there are no formal or effective enforcement mechanisms, the courts have found fee schedules to be price fixing. The criteria appear to apply equally to bar associations as well as other professional associations. III. THE PRACTICE OF LAW As INTERSTATE COMMERCE Before a practice may be regulated by the federal statute, the threshold jurisdictional requirements that the activity be both interstate and consist of trade or commerce must be satisfied.4t Only after these determinations are made is the particular practice examined to ascertain whether it is a restraint of trade or commerce. In dealing with professional associations, the Supreme Court has consistently applied a relatively stringent test to determine whether the association is engaged in interstate commerce.42 This variance from the 39. 306 F.2d 379 (9th Cir.), cert. denied, 371 U.S. 862 (1962). 40. 201 F. Supp. 29 (D. Utah), aff'd per curiam, 371 U.S. 24 (1962). 41. U.S. CONST. art. 1, § 8, cl. 3. 42. The defense that the subject activity is not interstate commerce has, on occasion, prevailed. See United States v. Oregon State Medical Soc'y, 343 U.S. 326 (1952); Spears Free Clinic & Hospital for Poor Children v. Cleere, 197 F.2d 125 (10th Cir. 1952). The most notable aberration in antitrust commerce clause interpretation concerns professional baseball. Recent rejection of the view that the sport is interstate 1973] COMMENTS modern trend of commerce clause expansion in the commercial field43 reflects an effort by the Court to protect the professional-client relationship. The test of interstate commerce enunciated in Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader" focuses on factors having a substantial and direct effect on interstate commerce. The interstate contacts demonstrated in United States v. Oregon State Medical Society"s were characterized as "few, sporadic and incidental."4 This type of connection is insufficient to bring the professional society within the scope of the commerce clause. A similar finding was made in Elizabeth Hospital, Inc. v. Richardson,4 7 where the treatment of out of state patients and the purchase of out of state equipment by the hospital was not found to constitute the direct and substantial effect on interstate commerce needed to satisfy the commerce clause." Of primary importance in treating these professional association cases is the fact that the alleged offenders were found not to be subject to the antitrust statutes on the basis that they did not satisfy the requirement of interstate commerce. They do not stand for the proposition that professional associations are exempt merely because they consist of practitioners of a profession. The viability of the position that fortycommerce within the meaning of the Sherman Act appears in Flood v. Kuhn, 407 U.S. 258 (1972). The Court there indicates that baseball is an isolated exception. Attempts to extend it to other professional sports have been unsuccessful. Radovich v. National Football League, 352 U.S. 445 (1957); United States v. International Boxing Club of N.Y., Inc., 348 U.S. 236 (1955). 43. In purely commercial areas, [t]he power of Congress over interstate commerce is not confined to the regulation of commerce among the states. It extends to those activities intrastate which so effect interstate commerce or exercise of the power of Congress over it as to make regulation of them appropriate means to the attainment of a legitimate end, the exercise of the granted power of Congress to regulate interstate commerce. United States v. Darby, 312 U.S. 100, 118 (1941). Any practice or activity which is burdensome or has substantial economic effect on interstate commerce is reachable by the federal government via the commerce clause. Wickard v. Filburn, 317 U.S. 11I, 12425 (1942). 44. 310 U.S. 469 (1940). 45. 343 U.S. 326 (1952). 46. Id. at 339. 47. 269 F.2d 167 (8th Cir.), cert. denied, 361 U.S. 884 (1959). 48. Accord, Riggall v. Washington County Medical Soc'y, 249 F.2d 266 (1957); Speers Free Clinic & Hosp. for Poor Children v. Cleere, 197 F.2d 125 (10th Cir. 1952). Interstate contacts which are not substantial, and no more than incidental, will not, in the instance of professional associations, satisfy the jurisdictional requirement of interstate commerce. 450 THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 22 nine" state bar association minimum fee schedules do not affect interstate commerce is dubious. Fee schedules affect virtually all legal clients whose cumulative private and corporate affairs constitute the sum and substance of interstate commerce. 0 To state that the purchase of legal advice and services does not affect interstate commerce is to deny potor bar associaence to the concept." The fact that one client, attorney, 12 dispositive not is state single a in located is tion IV. THE PRACTICE OF LAW As "TRADE" WITHIN THE SHERMAN ACT The threshold requirement that the bar association activity consisting of setting minimum fees is trade within the meaning of the Sherman Act presents a more difficult issue. The Supreme Court has never ruled directly on the question of whether the practice of law is trade or commerce, but by analogy to rulings regarding the commercial practices of other professions and services, it is clear that at least the nonprofessionalaspects of legal practice are within the ambit of "trade or commerce." It has been the practice of the Court to broadly construe the jurisdictional "trade" requirement. 53 Moreover, the Court has repeatedly stated that statutory and judicial exemptions from antitrust are to be narrowly construed.54 In United States v. NationalAssociation of Real 49. See note 34 supra. 50. United States v. Darby, 312 U.S. 100, 118 (1941); Wickard v. Fillburn, 317 U.S. I II, 125 (1942). See note 1 supra. 51. The degree of effect on interstate commerce is immaterial. Modern interpretation of the commerce power focuses on the existence of the effect, not on its magnitude. United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150 (1940); Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader, 310 U.S. 469 (1940). 52. It is settled law that Congress can, by virtue of its power over interstate commerce, regulate local or interstate matters which burden that commerce. United States v. South-Eastern Underwriters Ass'n, 322 U.S. 533, 539 (1944); Local 167 Int'l Bhd. of Teamsters v. United States, 291 U.S. 293 (1934); NLRB v. Jones & Laughlin Steel Corp., 301 U.S. 1 (1937). Mandeville Island Farms, Inc. v. American Crystal Sugar Co., 334 U.S. 219 (1948). 53. The scope of Sherman Act trade has been said to include "every person engaged in business whose activities might restrain or monopolize commercial intercourse among the States." United States v. Southern-Eastern Underwriters Ass'n, 322 U.S. 533, 553 (1944). "It is in [the]. . . broad sense that 'trade' is used in the Sherman Act." United States v. National Ass'n of Real Estate Bds., 339 U.S. 485, 491 (1950). 54. See George R. Whitten, Jr., Inc. v. Paddock Pool Builders, Inc., 424 F.2d 25, 30 (Ist Cir. 1970); United States v. First City Nat'l Bank, 386 U.S. 361, 368 (1967); Carnation Co. v. Pacific Westbound Conference, 383 U.S. 213, 217-18 (1966); United States v. Philadelphia Nat'l Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 350-51 (1963); California v. FPC, 369 U.S. 482 (1962). 19731 COMMENTS Estate Boards,5 the Court implied that "trade," as used in the Sherman Act, encompasses all activity without statutory or judicially construed exemption. The practice of law has no statutory exemption. 6 The most that can be argued is an implied judicial exemption from application of 7 the Sherman Act.1 There is some superficial support for the position that the entire profession should be exempt. The basis for this contention is that the public interest in maintaining high levels of professional competence outweighs the adverse affects of potential restraints on trade.5" Thus, in Federal Trade Commission v. Raladam,59 the Supreme Court indicated in dicta that the practice of medicine was not a "trade." Of course, medical practitioners, by some of whom the danger of using the remedy without competent advice was exposed, are not in competition with respondent. They follow a profession and not a trade, and are not engaged in the business of making or vending remedies but in prescribing them.60 1 the More recently, in United States v. Oregon State Medical Society," Court declined to rule specifically on whether the practice of medicine is a trade. The issue was whether the Society, through its nonprofit corporation, restrained trade in the business of prepaid health care. No refusal to deal with private health organizations could be proved. Again in dicta the Court commented on the special factors involved in a profession which support at least partial exemption. We might observe in passing, however, that there are ethical considerations where the historic and direct relationship between patient and physician is involved which are quite different than the usual consideration prevailing in ordinary commercial matters." 55. 339 U.S. 485 (1950). 56. See, e.g., Federal Aviation Act, 49 U.S.C. § 1384 (1970). 57. On the possible existence of an implied exemption for the legal profession see, Comment PersonalServices And The Antitrust Laws, 1 WAYNE L. REV. 124 (1955); Coleman, supra note 30. 58. Regarding fee schedules in general, and for analysis of the various justifications propounded, see Pietz & Nolden, The Wisconsin Minimum Fee Schedule: A Problem of Antitrust, 1968 Wis. L. REV. 1237; Arnould & Corley, supra note 2; Miller & Weil, Let's Improve, Not Kill, Fee Schedules, 58 A.B.A.J. 31 (1972); Note, CriticalAnalysis of Bar Association Minimum Fee Schedules, 85 HARV. L. REV. 971 (1972); AMERICAN -BAR AssoCIATION, supra note 6. 59. 283 U.S. 643 (1931). 60. Id. at 653. 61. 343 U.S. 326 (1952). 62. Id. at 336. THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 22 But the argument to the effect that because the contact between the professional and the client is qualitatively different from that of a more commercial endeavor, the entire professional practice should be exempt from the Sherman Act as not a "trade," is simplistic and overprotective. It is also in direct opposition with the judicial trend in dealing with the defense of alleged non-trade status in professional antitrust cases." There is good reason to continue extending the distinction between commercial and noncommercial aspects of a profession, with only the latter being exempt. The Court has reached this position by implication in Oregon State Medical Society, wherein a prepaid medical care plan, rather than the individual medical service rendered was emphasized. The distinction was more sharply drawn in a recent lower court decision, Marjorie Webster Junior College, Inc. v. Middle States Association of Colleges and Secondary Schools, Inc.64 The court held that the nature of the act of accreditation by the Association was not of the commercial character contemplated by the Sherman Act. [T]he proscriptions of the Sherman Act were "tailored. . . for the business world," not for the noncommercial aspects of the liberal arts and learned professions. In these contexts, an incidental restraint of trade, absent an intent or purpose to affect the commercial aspects of the professions, is not sufficient to warrant application of the antitrust laws." 63. Those more recent cases which have not found professions and professional associations subject to the antitrust laws have been predicated on the fact that the activity in question was not a trade. The reasoning of FTC v. Raladan, 283 U.S. 643 (1931) originating in The [Schooner] Nymph, 18 F. Cas. 506 (No. 10,388) (C.C.D. Me. 1834), seems to stand alone in a legal backwater. Justice Story defined "trade" broadly, then implied exceptions to the application of the term. [Tihe word "trade" is often, and indeed generally used in a broader sense, as equivalent to occupation, employment, or business, . . . [wherever such] is car- ried on for the purpose of profit, or gain, or a livelihood, not in the liberal arts or in the learned professions. ... Id. at 507. The judicial trend is toward viewing even professional services as trade for the purposes of antitrust. See note 66 infra for incidents of services as trade under the Sherman Act. AMA v. United States, 317 U.S. 519 (1945), approached the distinction between commercial and noncommercial aspects of the medical profession, but declined to draw the line. The American Medical Association was found to have restrained the operation of Group Health Association, Inc., a service providing prepaid health care. Rather than ruling the practice of medicine a trade, the Court found the occupation of defendants immaterial where their activity operated to restrain others in commercial endeavors. Id. at 528. 64. 432 F.2d 650 (D.C. Cir. 1970), wherein plaintiff alleged that refusal by the Association to accredit the college amounted to a restraint of trade. 65. Id. at 654. (emphasis added) (footnotes omitted). 1973] COMMENTS Services, including those rendered by the professions, have been increasingly subjected to the antitrust laws. 6 Each expansion of Sherman Act "trade" has been predicated upon the awareness that the determining factor in categorizing a course of conduct as within the Act is the degree of commercialism involved.6 7 In holding that the fixing of brokers' fees by the National Association of Real Estate Boards 8 constituted a per se violation of the Sherman Act, Justice Douglas emphasized the commercial nature of the activity. We do not intimate an opinion on the correctness of the application of the term [trade] to the professions. We have said enough to indicate we would be contracting the scope of the concept of "trade," in a precedentbreaking manner if we carved out an exemption for real estate brokers. Their activity is commercial and carried on for profit.69 Although the Supreme Court has not ruled directly on the issue of 66. Fixing prices as well as other unreasonable restraints on trade perpetrated by those providing personal services have been struck down by the courts. Northern Cal. Pharmaceutical Ass'n v. United States, 306 F.2d 379 (9th Cir.), cert. denied, 371 U.S. 862 (1962); United States v. Utah Pharmaceutical Ass'n, 201 F. Supp. 29 (D. Utah), aff'd per curiam, 371 U.S. 24 (1962) (sale of pharmaceutical products); Radovich v. National Football League, 352 U.S. 445 (1957) (professional football); United States v. National Ass'n of Real Estate Bds., 339 U.S. 485 (1950) (real estate brokerage); United States v. Paramount Pictures, 334 U.S. 131 (1948); Schine Shain Theatres v. United States, 334 U.S. 110 (1948) (production, exhibition and distribution of motion pictures); Associated Press v. United States, 326 U.S. 1 (1945) (obtaining news); AMA v. United States, 317 U.S. 519 (1943) (providing medical services); Atlantic Cleaners & Dyers, Inc. v. United States, 286 U.S. 427 (1932) (cleaning and dyeing of clothing); United States v. Shubert, 348 U.S. 222 (1955); Hart v. B.F. Keith Vandeville Exch., 262 U.S. 271 (1923) (production of theatrical attractions). 67. Two lower court cases make the distinction between commercial and noncommercial aspects of the pharmaceutical profession. In United States v. Utah Pharmaceutical Ass'n, 201 F. Supp. 29 (D. Utah), aff'd per curiam, 371 U.S. 24 (1962), the court found that although professional services, i.e., the noncommercial elements, were included in a drug pricing schedule disseminated to association members, the principle element in price determination was not professional, but was in fact, commercial. Thus, where the balance was found to tip toward the commercial aspects of the profession, the fee schedule was struck down as an instance of price fixing. Northern Cal. Pharmaceutical Ass'n v. United States, 306 F.2d 379 (9th Cir.), cert. denied, 371 U.S. 862 (1962), presented much the same problem. The prescription drug price schedule of the association was so grounded in the "entrepreneurial" aspects of the profession that no professional exemption could be said to exist. In both of these cases the court examined the dual scope of the price schedules, determined that the commercial aspects of each predominated over the professional, and applied traditional antitrust law, i.e., the concept that price fixing is a per se violation. 68. United States v. National Ass'n of Real Estate Bds., 339 U.S. 485 (1950). 69. Id. at 491-92. 454 THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 22 the practice of law as trade within the Sherman Act, the Oregon State Medical Society and Marjorie Webster Junior College cases lay a firm foundation for the Court to distinguish and exempt only the noncommercial aspects of legal practice. They have done so with the medical profession, 7 with pharmacists, 71 and with real estate brokers where the activity in question was primarily commercial. There is no reason to anticipate a future constriction of Sherman Act "trade," especially where the relationship to be preserved, here attorney-client, will be protected without such constriction. The direction of the law is toward declaring that commercial aspects of legal practice are "trade" within the meaning of the Act, while validating a judicial exemption for noncommercial aspects. Once the distinction between commercial and noncommercial aspects of the professions is made, the application of the Sherman Act to nonexempt portions becomes possible in a manner consistent with the body of case law applicable to wholly commercial enterprises. V. CONCLUSION The foregoing analysis reveals the legal hurdles to be negotiated in eliminating the minimum fee schedules established by bar associations by means of section one of the Sherman Act. The questions of whether the practice of law is interstate commerce, and whether the practice of setting and disseminating minimum fees is price fixing, are not delicate, innovative, or even particularly difficult legal issues. The suggestion that minimum fee schedules violate the Sherman Act is not new, although the schedules have not been treated as per se violations. Statute and case law abound to aid the courts in deciding the questions. It is the position of this comment that those issues will be decided in the affirmative. The core issue is, however, not interstate commerce or price fixing. Most important is the status of the professions vis-a-vis the antitrust laws. The present inquiry deals with attorneys and bar associations, but the resolution of the question has direct consequences for doctors, accountants, architects, and their professional associations, as well as for any group viewing itself as representing those engaged in a learned profession. The schedules violate both the antitrust statutes and the ethical stan70. Levin v. Joint Comm'n on Accreditation of Hosps., 354 F.2d 515 (D.C. Cir. 1965); Elizabeth Hosp., Inc. v. Richardson, 269 F.2d 167 (8th Cir.), cert. denied, 361 U.S. 884 (1959); AMA v. United States, 317 U.S. 519 (1943). 71. See note 67 supra. 72. United States v. National Ass'n of Real Estate Bds., 339 U.S. 485 (1950).