Energy consumption and income: An inverted-U at the household level? Vivien Foster, Jean-Philippe Tre, and Quentin Wodon1 World Bank September 2000 Abstract Substantial empirical work has been done at the international level data in order to test for an inverted-U relationship between income per capita and energy consumption and/or environmental pollution using multi-country data. But there is a lack of similar work at the household level within a given country. In this note, we find an inverted-U using data for Guatemala. The finding has implication for social and environmental policy. 1 The authors are with the Poverty group of the Latin America region at The World Bank. This paper was funded jointly by the Office of the Chief Economist for Latin America (Guillermo Perry) and by the ESMAP program (Dominique Lallement). The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank. 1. Introduction A stylized fact in the energy literature is the existence of a transition process whereby households gradually ascend an energy ladder. The ladder begins with biomass fuels (firewood and charcoal), moves to modern commercial fuels (kerosene and LPG), and culminates with electricity (e.g., Albouy and Nadifi, 1999). The reality is of course more complex than suggested by this stylized energy ladder, and the empirical work suggests that at any given point in time, households rely on a range of fuels that encompasses at least two steps of the energy ladder (e.g., Barnes and Qian, 1992; Hosier and Kipondya, 1993; ESMAP, 1994; Eberhard and van Horen, 1995)2. Still, the ascent of the ladder is associated with rising income, and the fuels which are higher up in the ladder tend to be more efficient (for lighting for example, electricity is more than one hundred times more efficient than candles or kerosene lamps). As a result, if we define net energy consumption as the product of gross energy consumption times an efficiency factor taking into account the efficiency of the energy sources used by households, we may observe an inverted-U relationship between gross energy consumption and income, even though net energy consumption may be monotonically increasing in income3. This note finds evidence of such an inverted-U using data for Guatemala. The finding has implication for social and environmental policy. 2 Methodology To motivate the empirical work, we first present a model which, while extremely simple, does suggest a rationale for a household-level inverted-U. The model will also help in defining the key variables in the empirical work. Consider a household’s whose utility depends on net energy consumption NE, with NE=GE*EF, where GE is the household’s gross energy consumption and EF is the efficiency factor which depends on the energy sources used by the household. The household’s utility also depends on the efficiency factor, because more efficient energy sources such as electricity are easier and cleaner to use (the efficiency factor is a proxy for the comfort level associated with the pattern of energy use in the household). The utility function is W=W(NE, EF), with ∂W/∂NE>0, ∂W/∂EF>0, ∂2W/∂NE2<0 and ∂2W/∂EF2<0. The partial derivative of W with respect to gross energy consumption is: ∂W ∂W ∂W NE = EF − ∂GE ∂NE ∂EF GE 2 (1) 2 In Guatemala, according to the 1998/99 ENIGFAM (Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y Gastos Familiares) survey used in this note, each household uses on average 2.6 different types of fuels. 3 While substantial work has been devoted to testing for environmental inverted-U relationships at the international level between income per capita and various types of environmental pollution (e.g., Selden and Song, 1994; HoltzEakin and Selden, 1995; List and Gallet, 1999; Heil and Selden, 2000; see also the special issue of Environment and Development Economics of October 1997), there is no similar work at the household level to our knowledge. At high levels of net energy consumption, increasing gross energy consumption may be associated with a decrease in utility. In other words, households who can afford to do so will reduce their gross consumption by switching to more efficient energy sources, and this may result in an inverted-U. To test for the inverted-U relationship, we use the ENIGFAM (Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y Gastos Familiares) income and expenditure survey for Guatemala. The survey covers the period April 1998 to March 1999. The survey includes monthly household expenditures for various fuels (batteries, candles, electricity, fuelwood, kerosene and propane gas). In the case of fuelwood, for the households who gather their own wood, the survey provides an estimate provided by the household as to the cost of purchasing an equivalent amount of fuelwood in the market place. In order to convert the expenditures data into physical units of consumption, data on energy prices are required. Because the ENIGFAM did not incorporate a price survey, regional unit prices were taken directly from the Guatemalan Consumer Price Index. Dividing expenditures by unit prices yields estimates of the physical consumption for each energy source. Next, since each fuel is measured in different units, it is necessary to convert them all into a common unit of kilowatt hours for aggregation. This is done by applying standard conversion factors (United Nations, 1987). The standardized measures of physical energy use are summed together to obtain an estimate at the household level of total gross energy consumption GE in kilowatt-hours. To move from gross to net household energy consumption, we must take into account the efficiency of various fuels. Cooking fuels vary in terms of the efficiency with which they generate heat from one kilowatt-hour of fuel input. Similarly, lighting fuels vary in terms of their luminous efficacy, which is the amount of light they provide from one kilowatt-hour of fuel input. Furthermore, any particular fuel may exhibit a greater or lesser degree of efficiency (or luminous efficacy) depending on the capital good with which it is used. For example, kerosene produces eight times more luminosity when burnt in a hurricane lamp than in a primitive wick lamp (Van der Plas and De Graaff, 1988). In this note, gross energy consumption figures were adjusted to reflect the efficiency of each fuel relative to the efficiency of electricity in the same use using the parameters provided in table 1. The efficiency factors show that for cooking, one kilowatt-hour of energy obtained by burning propane gas provides only 77 percent of the heat given by one kilowatt-hour of electricity, whereas wood is only 15 percent as efficient as electricity. For lighting, the divergence is far greater. Kerosene wick lamps produce only 2 percent of the luminosity of electricity per kilowatt-hour of energy used, whereas for candles the corresponding value is a mere 1percent. Finally, batteries are believed to be about 90 percent as efficient as main power. Multiplying gross energy consumption by the efficiency factors EF in table 1 yields an estimate of net energy consumption in kilowatt-hours. Since the efficiency factors have been normalized against electricity, the net energy amount NE can be interpreted as the total amount of electricity that the household would have to consume to obtain its current level of energy consumption exclusively from electricity. Net energy consumption is better than gross energy consumption to assess how households meet their energy needs. Additionally, as mentioned earlier, households may place some value in the efficiency factor itself, since it is associated with easier to use and cleaner (more healthy) energy sources. In the empirical section, we provide measures of gross and net energy consumption by income decile in Guatemala that suggest an inverted-U relationship. To test whether this relationship remains when controls are included for factors other than income which may affect energy consumption, we also use regression analysis. Let L represent a vector of geographic location dummies, H a vector of nonincome characteristics of the residents in the household (demographics, education and employment essentially), E a vector of dummies indicating access to various energy sources including electricity, and Y a vector of dummies for the position of the household in the distribution of per capita income by quintile. We estimate: log( NE i ) = β 0 + β 1 Li + β 2 H i + β 3 E i + β 4 Yi + ε i log(GE i ) = λ 0 + λ1 Li + λ 2 H i + λ 3 E i + λ 4 Yi + υ i (2) log( EFi ) = γ 0 + γ 1 Li + γ 2 H i + γ 3 E i + γ 4 Yi + κ i Given that NEi = GEi*EFi, we have for all parameter estimates βj = λjγj. The coefficient vector λ4 is the parameter of interest for the inverted-U hypothesis. Under the inverted-U hypothesis, we would expect the parameters in λ4 to be lower for the lowest and highest income quintiles than for the middle groups. By contrast, we would expect the parameters in the vectors β4 and γ4 to be increasing in income. 3. Empirical results Table 2 and Figure 1 give the mean energy expenditure, gross and net energy consumption, and efficiency factors by income decile. On average, households in Guatemala spend US$247 for energy goods per year, yielding gross and net consumption of respectively 13,090 and 3,236 kilowatt-hours. The mean efficiency factor is 0.25. Household expenditures for energy rise steadily with income, with the tenth decile spending 3.61 times as much as the first. There is an inverted-U since gross energy consumption peaks at around the fifth decile, and is lower in the tenth decile than in the first decile. By contrast, net consumption is monotonically increasing in income, as is the efficiency factor (both are normal goods). The top decile consumes more than three times as much net energy as the bottom decile, and the efficiency factor rises from 0.16 in the first decile to 0.59 in the tenth decile as households switch towards more efficient forms of energy such as propane gas and electricity. These findings are confirmed in the regression analysis which is conducted with quintiles to ensure enough observations in each income bracket. The results are provided in table 3. The coefficient estimates in λ4 suggest again an inverted-U, with the largest coefficient estimate obtained for the third quintile (the coefficient estimate for the fifth quintile is zero since this is the excluded dummy in the regression). By contrast, the βs and γs are increasing in income. The same results (available upon request) are obtained when the equations in (2) are estimated for urban and rural areas separately. 4. Policy implications This paper has documented the existence of an inverted-U relationship at the household level between energy consumption and per capita income in Guatemala. The finding provides a microfoundation for similar relationships observed at the international level using multi-country data. The finding may also be used to suggest policy initiatives. Although this has not been discussed above, one of the factors at the root of the inverted-U in Guatemala is the fact that butane gas is used for cooking only by the highest income deciles, with the middle group still relying on wood. Part of the reason why butane gas is not used more has to do with limited distribution networks, especially in rural areas. Butane is also more expensive to use than wood when the cost of the equipment needed to use butane is taken into account. More specifically, butane gas requires an investment of about US$ 200 in a butane stove, whereas wood can be burned at zero capital cost using a primitive three stone stove. Furthermore, it may be more difficult for poor households to budget for the purchase of butane cylinders. This is because butane is sold in relatively large quantities 35lb cylinders costing around US$ 9 while wood can be gathered in the amount required often without monetary outlay. Switching from wood to butane would probably generate welfare gains for the poor. It would also probably generate health gains through reduced indoor air pollution. Programs promoting the use of butane gas in countries such as Guatemala could be financed using funds for carbon emissions reductions. While more work would be needed to conduct a cost-benefit analysis of such an initiative, our results do suggest that it could be promising. Table 1: Relative efficiency factors used to adjust from gross to net energy consumption Cooking Appliances Relative Fuel Relative luminous efficiency efficacy Electricity 1.00 Electricity 1.00 Electricity 1.00 Propane 0.77 Kerosene 0.01 Batteries 0.90 Fuelwood 0.15 Candles 0.02 Car batteries 0.90 Sources: Leach and Gowen (1987); Van der Plas and De Graaff (1988). Electricity provides the baseline against which the efficiency and luminous efficacy of other fuels are expressed. Hence, the factor for electricity is one. Fuel Lighting Relative efficiency Fuel Table 2: Comparison of energy expenditures with gross and net consumption across deciles Energy expenditures (US$ per capita) GE Gross consumption (kWh pa) Per capita income decile 1 120 2 161 3 194 4 190 5 229 6 219 7 254 8 279 9 301 10 434 Overall mean 238 Ratio deciles 10: 1 3.61 Source: Authors’ estimation using ENIGFAM 1998/99 10,060 13,320 15,506 13,799 16,216 14,160 13,627 13,387 11,448 9,399 13,090 0.93 NE Net consumption (kWh pa) EF Efficiency factor (Net/Gross kWh) 1,658 2,217 2,692 2,607 3,173 3,055 3,516 3,798 4,078 5,539 3,236 3.34 0.16 0.17 0.17 0.19 0.20 0.22 0.26 0.28 0.36 0.59 0.25 3.58 Table 3: Determinants of energy consumption and energy efficiency, Guatemala 1998/99 Log(GE) St. Err. 95% Conf. Int. Coef. Coef. Demographics Babies 0.117 0.031 0.057 0.177 0.123 Children 0.170 0.025 0.121 0.219 0.179 Adults 0.320 0.030 0.262 0.378 0.359 Babies squared -0.006 0.009 -0.024 0.013 -0.008 Children squared -0.013 0.006 -0.025 -0.001 -0.018 Adults squared -0.022 0.004 -0.029 -0.015 -0.027 Female head 0.257 0.050 0.159 0.356 0.285 Age of head 0.005 0.001 0.003 0.007 0.002 Education Head 6-8 years -0.121 0.038 -0.195 -0.047 -0.014 Head > 9 years -0.067 0.030 -0.126 -0.008 0.035 Spouse 0 years 0.354 0.057 0.243 0.465 0.327 Spouse 6-8 years 0.262 0.060 0.144 0.380 0.308 Spouse > 9 years 0.360 0.053 0.256 0.463 0.375 Employment Head industry 0.102 0.030 0.043 0.160 0.057 Head family wk. 0.130 0.126 -0.118 0.377 0.109 Head public wk. -0.004 0.046 -0.094 0.085 -0.015 Head employed -0.064 0.044 -0.149 0.022 -0.094 Head searching -0.251 0.123 -0.492 -0.010 -0.230 Spouse industry 0.290 0.053 0.185 0.395 0.183 Sp. Family wk. 0.218 0.079 0.062 0.373 0.187 Sp. Public wk. 0.093 0.075 -0.055 0.240 0.085 Sp. Employed -0.241 0.050 -0.339 -0.143 -0.167 Sp. Searching -0.025 0.205 -0.427 0.378 0.085 Location Norte -0.032 0.076 -0.181 0.117 -0.076 Nor-oriente -0.060 0.074 -0.204 0.084 -0.033 Sur-oriente -0.049 0.057 -0.160 0.062 -0.121 Central -0.053 0.062 -0.174 0.069 0.000 Sur-occidente -0.225 0.070 -0.363 -0.087 -0.221 Nor-occidente 0.432 0.110 0.216 0.648 0.054 Peten 0.388 0.112 0.168 0.608 0.068 Income p.c. 1st quintile -0.177 0.061 -0.297 -0.058 -0.923 2nd quintile 0.120 0.051 0.021 0.219 -0.593 3rd quintile 0.205 0.041 0.125 0.286 -0.416 th 4 quintile 0.127 0.034 0.060 0.194 -0.302 Access Public electricity 0.019 0.102 -0.182 0.219 0.662 Private elect. -0.092 0.040 -0.170 -0.014 0.553 Butane -0.121 0.054 -0.226 -0.016 -0.185 Urban household -0.379 0.035 -0.448 -0.311 -0.032 Constant 7.803 0.102 7.603 8.004 6.575 Source: Authors’ estimation using ENIGFAM 1998/99. Log(NE) St. Err. 95% Conf. Int. Coef. Log(1/EF) St. Err. 95% Conf. Int. 0.025 0.020 0.024 0.008 0.005 0.003 0.040 0.001 0.075 0.140 0.313 -0.022 -0.027 -0.032 0.206 0.000 0.171 0.218 0.406 0.007 -0.008 -0.021 0.364 0.003 -0.006 -0.009 -0.040 0.002 0.004 0.005 -0.027 0.004 0.016 0.013 0.016 0.005 0.003 0.002 0.027 0.001 -0.038 -0.035 -0.070 -0.008 -0.002 0.001 -0.080 0.003 0.026 0.017 -0.009 0.011 0.011 0.008 0.025 0.005 0.030 0.024 0.045 0.048 0.042 -0.073 -0.013 0.238 0.213 0.292 0.045 0.082 0.416 0.402 0.458 -0.107 -0.101 0.027 -0.046 -0.016 0.020 0.016 0.030 0.032 0.028 -0.146 -0.133 -0.032 -0.108 -0.070 -0.068 -0.070 0.085 0.017 0.039 0.024 0.101 0.037 0.035 0.098 0.043 0.063 0.060 0.040 0.164 0.010 0.104 0.045 -0.089 0.307 0.020 -0.087 0.056 0.011 -0.162 -0.026 0.030 -0.422 -0.037 -0.021 0.099 0.267 0.107 0.063 0.312 0.031 -0.033 0.203 0.008 -0.245 -0.088 -0.074 -0.238 0.407 -0.109 0.016 0.067 0.024 0.023 0.065 0.028 0.042 0.040 0.026 0.108 0.014 0.076 -0.110 0.151 -0.036 0.058 -0.015 0.076 -0.148 0.106 0.051 0.162 -0.052 0.113 -0.070 0.086 -0.126 -0.023 -0.322 0.103 0.061 0.059 0.045 0.050 0.056 0.088 0.090 -0.195 -0.149 -0.210 -0.097 -0.332 -0.119 -0.109 0.044 0.082 -0.032 0.097 -0.111 0.227 0.244 0.043 -0.027 0.072 -0.053 -0.004 0.379 0.321 0.040 0.039 0.030 0.033 0.037 0.058 0.059 -0.035 -0.103 0.013 -0.117 -0.077 0.264 0.204 0.122 0.049 0.131 0.011 0.069 0.493 0.437 0.049 0.040 0.033 0.027 -1.019 -0.673 -0.481 -0.356 -0.827 -0.514 -0.352 -0.248 0.745 0.714 0.622 0.429 0.032 0.027 0.022 0.018 0.682 0.661 0.579 0.393 0.809 0.766 0.664 0.464 0.082 0.032 0.043 0.028 0.082 0.501 0.491 -0.269 -0.087 6.414 0.823 0.615 -0.100 0.023 6.735 -0.643 -0.645 0.064 -0.347 1.229 0.054 0.021 0.028 0.018 0.054 -0.749 -0.686 0.008 -0.383 1.123 -0.537 -0.604 0.119 -0.311 1.334 Figure 1: Gross and net energy consumption and efficiency factor by per capita income decile 4.00 Efficiency factor 3.50 3.00 2.50 Net energy consumption 2.00 1.50 1.00 Gross energy consumption 0.50 0.00 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Decile Source: Authors’ estimation using ENIGFAM 1998/99 10