The State of the By Richard B. Hoey, Chief Economist of The Dreyfus Corporation ebate First Quarter 2003 Reflation or Deflation There is a major debate between the bulls and the bears on the U.S. economy and the U.S. markets. This is a status report on the debate between the optimists and the pessimists about the U.S. economy and the U.S. markets. The optimists expect reflation in the U.S. economy and the pessimists expect a destructive deflation. Reflation or Deflation? The Roots of Deflation Risk The most crucial debate in the markets today is whether the prospects for the economy over the next several years will be characterized by deflation or reflation. This is a critical investment issue, because of the implications for different asset classes. Stocks and higher-risk bonds tend to be relative beneficiaries of both anticipated reflation and actual reflation, while the highest-grade long-term bonds tend to be relative beneficiaries of both anticipated deflation and actual deflation, all other things being equal. Uncertainty may persist over the next few months, but in this debate we are on the side of those who expect reflation to prevail in the end. The roots of today’s deflation risk lie in the 1970s. The rise from minimal inflation to double-digit inflation in that period created an anti-inflationary mindset among a generation of central bankers. That mindset led to policies which brought inflation down from a double-digit pace two decades ago to low levels today in many countries. In addition, the global free-trade system has fostered persistent price competition from emerging country exports. Strong domestic demand in the U.S. has not been matched by strong domestic demand abroad. Weakness in foreign domestic demand remains a major source of deflationary risk in the world economy. We would define pervasive deflation as a broad-scale and sustained decline in consumer prices which is widely expected to persist. The capital misallocation which occurred during the boom of the late 1990s contributed to excess capacity and fears of deflation. Excessively cheap risk capital generated a rapid expansion of capacity in a number of new economy industries in the years prior to the onset of recession. In the current context, we would define reflation as a multiyear reacceleration in economic growth strong enough to reduce excess capacity in the goods and labor markets. We expect clear evidence of reflation to emerge by midyear 2003. A full-scale reflation would be expected to generate a rise in corporate profits driven by an acceleration of corporate revenue growth and rising capacity utilization. There tends to be a cycle in the fear of deflation risks. They are most intense when expectations for economic activity have already dropped, stock prices have already declined and Treasury bond prices have already risen (1998, 2002). Once the consensus shifts away from a fear of deflation, there is often an increased potential for a reversal of these market moves, due in large part to the anticipated effect of anti-deflationary policies. Our most likely case over the next several years is economic reflation in a low inflation environment. A year from today, we expect a substantially lower fear of destructive deflation. Issue 6 d The Varieties of Deflation Deflation is a word with many meanings. We believe that a major deflation is one which is both sustained and broad-based. The word deflation has also been applied to temporary or narrow price declines, but these are usually normal attributes of the cyclical ebb and flow. We would not tend to label as a full-scale deflation either (1) a temporary cyclical drop in producer, commodity or goods prices or (2) a drop in prices in a particular sector of the economy following a sectoral boom. We would refer to these as cyclical deflation or sectoral deflation. The most dangerous deflation is collateral deflation or debt deflation where the value of the collateral underlying the financial system plunges and destroys Currency and Deflation The Financial System and Deflation 2 the net worth of the banking system. This occurred in the 1930s worldwide and in Japan a decade ago. Deflation tends to become deeply entrenched if it destroys the net worth of the banking system. In nearly all deflationary periods, numerous defaults occur among high-risk and medium-risk borrowers, as deflation raises the real burden of debt and weakens both sales and profits. There is a distinction between benign deflation and destructive deflation. Destructive deflation usually involves a balance sheet meltdown, which is much deeper and more prolonged than the usual cyclical stresses. Mild deflation can be benign if the pace of deflation is moderate and balance sheet stress is limited. However, since even benign deflation is accompanied by the risk of deterioration into more severe forms of deflation, policymakers should attempt to reduce deflation risk even if deflation is mild and benign. Central Banks and Deflation Central bank policy has a dominant role in the trend of inflation or deflation. Inflationary or deflationary expectations can sharply shift the demand for liquidity in the private sector. The shifting inflation or deflation expectations of the public help determine whether a given pace of money supply growth is appropriate, excessive or deficient relative to the demand for liquid financial assets. As a result, interpreting the basic stance of monetary policy is not simple. In many deflations, central banks underestimated the true severity of their policy restraint until it was much too late. Persistent deflation is generally the result of a monetary policy mistake. By word and deed, the Federal Reserve has recently shown that it has adopted a proactive anti-deflationary policy. Many Federal Reserve policymakers have stated that deflation will not be permitted to occur. Alan Greenspan and other Fed officials have indicated that they would be willing to adopt unconventional measures to prevent deflation. We assume that this could include actions designed to overcome extreme risk aversion. We are convinced that the Fed has both the power and the willingness to prevent deflation. One key concept is “asymmetrical risk.” Since deflation is hard to stop once it begins, it is better to take the risks of too easy a monetary policy than of too tight a monetary policy when deflation is a risk. A central bank can always find an interest rate high enough to be restrictive. However, a zero interest rate may be too high to be stimulative in a deflation. Real interest rates (interest rates minus inflation) can be high during a deflation even if interest rates are zero. That has occurred in Japan in recent years and has depressed demand in its economy. We believe that the Fed has learned from the mistakes of the Bank of The State of the Debate Japan over the last decade and of many central banks in the 1930s. Central banks generally do have the power to prevent deflation, but have sometimes failed to do so, often because they misunderstood the actual effect of their policy. The Financial System and Deflation We believe that the U.S. banking system is currently sound. There have been the usual cyclical loan losses, but nearly all major financial institutions are profitable and have a strong net worth position. Much of the credit risk in the financially vulnerable industries was taken on outside the banking industry during the boom. As a result, the losses were widely dispersed among investors rather than concentrated in the core financial institutions, where it would have had a more leveraged impact. We believe that since the U.S. banking system is sound, deflation is avoidable as long as policymakers are committed to preventing it. Currency and Deflation The distribution of inflation risk or deflation risk among countries is influenced by currency values. Countries can export their deflation problem to some degree when they have a weak currency which stimulates their exports. In the 1930s, this practice was referred to as “exchange dumping.” In recent years, many Asian countries have intervened by buying dollars that their private sector chose not to buy. This fostered undervalued exchange rates for these countries despite strong exports and persistent trade surpluses. The depressed level of the euro until recently had the same effect, although it was more the result of lack of confidence in European policy and economic prospects than of intentional government policy toward the currency. While the level of a country’s currency influences its trade balance and its inflation/deflation pressures, the directional trend influences international financial flows. We believe that the dollar needs to adjust to a lower level but do so in a gradual way so that financial flows do not become disruptive. In the meantime, the elevated level of the dollar is causing the U.S. to import deflationary pressures from foreign countries with weak domestic demand. We believe that the high level of the dollar has permitted foreign countries to depend on growing exports to the U.S. and postpone the adoption of growth-stimulating domestic economic policies. The best solution to the worldwide risk of deflation would be the adoption of policies overseas which would strengthen domestic demand abroad. The State of the Debate 3 Throughout the history of the world, war has been associated with inflation due to increased demand for goods, increased demand for labor and rising government deficits, usually financed by money creation. While a major broad-scale war or military buildup would tend to have an anti-deflationary effect, that effect would be much more muted in the event of a relatively brief military action. In the current context, however, worry about war may intensify short-term deflation fears because uncertainties about future military action encourage companies and consumers to delay some spending decisions until after war uncertainties are reduced. The degree of leverage is not the sole key to the outcome of a risk crunch in a deflation-prone period. A crucial factor is the flexibility of the economic system to quickly recognize and respond to impaired value and to redirect resources to businesses with sound business plans, including those exiting Chapter 11. This flexibility was missing in Japan, but is an important characteristic of the U.S. economic system. The more flexible the economic system, the more likely it is that the disorderly phase of deleveraging can be a brief cyclical episode and that the deflationary risks will prove temporary. Risk Cycle and Relative Performance Deflation: Near Miss or Crash Landing? Deflation tends to be accompanied by a rise in defaults. With corporate revenues and earnings weak, high-risk borrowers have difficulty earning enough to meet their debt obligations. That’s why the spread of corporate bond yields relative to Treasury bond yields can be regarded as a fever chart of anticipated deflation risk. We believe that the recent peaking of corporate bond spreads is an encouraging signal of a transition from disorderly deleveraging to orderly deleveraging. A period of deflation risk can end either with a near miss or a crash landing into destructive deflation. What determines which path the economic system will follow? A risk cycle is a normal part of the business cycle, but there is a difference between inflation-prone and deflationprone periods. In inflation-prone periods, rising inflation raises fear of a future monetary policy tightening which will depress future profits. In deflation-prone periods, the fear is that current monetary policy is already so restrictive that revenues and profits are likely to remain weak. The relationship between stocks and bonds tends to be different in deflation-risk periods than in inflation-risk periods. In inflation-risk periods, rising inflation pushes up long-term interest rates and raises fear that aggressive monetary tightening will lower future profits and therefore depress stock prices. Thus, in inflation-risk periods Treasury bond prices and stock prices tend to move in the same downward direction as inflation risks rise. In deflation-risk periods, Treasury bond prices and stock prices usually go in opposite directions when the risks of deflation and weak corporate profits intensify. When deflation intensifies, the risk of defaults and disappointing profits is intensified. Treasury bond prices tend to rise while stock prices decline in response to a worsening profit outlook. We believe the U.S. has just passed the point of maximum deflation risk. If we are correct, the trend of a calming of deflation-risk fears is likely to be sustained. We believe that the four keys to avoiding a crash landing into deflation are (1) a central bank which is both willing and able to adopt a successful anti-deflationary policy, (2) a banking system which is sound at the core, so financial stresses can be temporary rather than persistent, (3) flexible and appropriate mechanisms for reallocating both capital and economic resources and (4) public expectations that the economy is not trapped in deflation and is likely to expand in the future. We believe these four factors align to make a crash landing into full-scale deflation in the U.S. quite unlikely. Channels of Monetary Policy Impact The Federal Reserve has eased the federal funds rate twelve times over the last two years, from 6.50% to 1.25%. The traditional channels by which the lowering of the federal funds rate tends to stimulate faster growth in real GDP and current dollar GDP are: (1) housing, (2) consumer durables, including autos, (3) dollar weakness, (4) lower debt cost of capital, and (5) higher stock prices, which both lowers the equity cost of capital and bolsters consumer confidence through the wealth effect. Over the last year, only the housing and consumer durable channels have been operating fully, and much, if not all, of their potential demand strength has already been realized. The dollar has declined modestly from its multiyear highs, but is still high enough that U.S. domestic demand is being drained by foreign countries with weak domestic demand. Channels of Monetary Policy Impact Leverage War and Deflation War and Deflation The State of the Debate 4 World Reflation World Reflation The stock market and debt cost of capital channels for transmission of monetary ease were largely blocked until the fourth quarter of 2002. The confidence crisis in the honesty of financial reporting postponed the cyclical improvement in the cost of risk capital. As of early October, stock prices were at multiyear lows and the spreads of high-risk and medium-risk bond yields above Treasury yields were at multiyear wide levels even though yields had dropped for the highest-grade bonds. The cost of risk capital (both debt and equity) was at crisis levels relative to corporate sales growth. Since then, conditions in the financial market channels have begun to improve, as the stock market has risen and corporate bond spreads have begun to narrow. The Fed eased aggressively enough to generate an uptrend in stock prices and a narrowing of credit spreads. The case for eventual reflation rather than a drop into full-scale deflation has improved as conditions in these two key financial channels have begun to improve. U.S. Reflation U.S. Reflation We believe that the most likely outlook for the U.S. economy over the next several years is reflation, especially once war-related uncertainties are reduced. The main reason for this is that U.S. monetary and fiscal policymakers have been flexible and proactive in adopting stimulative anti-deflationary policies. Measured by real GDP, the recent recession was mild because neither the housing sector nor the automobile sector experienced their usual cyclical decline. Measured by corporate profits, however, the recent recession was severe. Facing the aftermath of the capacity and cost buildup in the boom, plus weak corporate revenues in a deflation-risk environment, corporations have so far concentrated on improving their cash flow rather than increasing their capital spending. The U.S. economic recovery resembles a relay race in which there is a need for a handoff from the housing and consumer sectors to the corporate sector as the recovery unfolds. As long as macroeconomic policy is stimulative enough to create a downtrend in the debt cost of capital and the equity cost of capital, this handoff from consumer and housing demand to capital spending demand is likely to occur. The odds favor worldwide reflation. However, there are currently greater problems with foreign macroeconomic policies than with U.S. macroeconomic policies. Many foreign countries have been reluctant to reform rigidities which currently restrain domestic demand. Instead, they have adopted policies which favored exports over imports. We are confident that reflation will soon dominate deflation in the U.S., but it is likely to do so more slowly in Japan and Europe (especially in Germany). Japan has been struggling to reform its deflationary policy mix but has not yet succeeded in this effort. European regulatory, fiscal and monetary policies have not yet shifted to a pro-growth stance. Germany is especially vulnerable to deflationary pressures because it entered the euro at an overvalued exchange rate and has been reluctant to deregulate its economic system. There are encouraging signs that European policymakers are beginning to rethink the macroeconomic policies which have generated such disappointing growth. China is growing rapidly, but its main engine of growth has been a dramatic growth in exports. Overall, we believe that U.S. macroeconomic policy is stimulative but that the pace of domestic demand growth overseas may be a problem until policies overseas shift to a pro-growth stance. Inflation Risk in Three Years Three years from today, in 2005, the main concern may be inflation rather than deflation. U.S. monetary and fiscal policymakers are pulling out all the stops to stimulate the U.S. economy, so a strong preelection expansion in the 18 months prior to November 2004 is quite likely. Fear of a negative impact on the housing sector might cause the Fed to tighten rather hesitantly rather than aggressively over the next two years. By 2005, both the labor and goods markets are likely to be much tighter, especially if foreign governments finally move toward the stimulation of domestic demand in the meantime. Given the large current account deficit, an eventual weakness in the U.S. dollar is likely. Deflation is today’s risk, but will not necessarily be the crucial problem several years from now. Once a problem is fully recognized, it is usually well on its way to solution. d This report represents the general economic overviews of Mr. Richard Hoey, Chief Economist of The Dreyfus Corporation, and does not constitute investment advice, nor should it be considered predictive of any future market performance. ©2003 Dreyfus Service Corporation, Distributor DRY-SOD-0103