Chapter 7 (with some review of 6) Utility is a measure of the satisfaction received from possessing or consuming goods and services. 2 Economists assume that: ◦ Tastes and preferences are fixed and given, and play a large role in decision making. ◦ Consumers make choices that give them the greatest utility—they maximize utility. 3 Marginal utility: the extra utility derived from consuming one more unit of a good or service. change in total utility marginal utility change in quantity 4 Principle of diminishing marginal utility: the more of a good that one obtains in a specific period of time, the less the additional utility derived from an additional unit of the good. ◦ As you consume more and more of something, the satisfaction with each unit declines. Disutility: dissatisfaction 5 Chapter 21 - Consumer Choice 6 Hours of Util of Each Hour Listening (marginal utility) Total Utility 1 200 200 2 98 298 3 50 348 4 10 358 5 0 358 6 -70 288 7 -200 88 7 Utility diminishes with increasing quantities – especially in a limited time—the shorter the time period, the more quickly marginal utility diminishes. “All You Can Eat”—restaurants with this policy assume that you will stop eating when your marginal utility falls to zero. 8 Consumers are not identical—the rate at which marginal utility diminishes depends on individual tastes and preferences, and so differs across consumers. 9 Each consumer allocates a specific budget to expenditure, and then allocates the expenditure to maximize utility. 10 When you cannot increase utility by spending more on one good and less on another within a given budget, you are said to be in a state of consumer equilibrium. The conditions for consumer equilibrium are expressed by the formula on the right MU(A) = P(A) MU(B) P(B) Units 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Pizza Utils 22 18 14 9 6 2 1 0 -4 Hot dogs Utils 15 13 10 8 6 4 2 1 0 Notes: Budget: $10 First Prices $1 each Adjust Pizza to $2 Derive 2 points on D for Pizza 12 Equimarginal principle: To maximize utility, consumers allocate their incomes among goods so as to equate the marginal utilities per dollar (MU/P) of the expenditure on the last unit of each good purchased. This is also referred to as the consumer equilibrium. MUCD MUgas MUmovie MU X PCD Pgas Pmovie PX 13 Consumers allocate their income among goods and services in order to maximize utility according to the equimarginal principle. A change in the price of any good disturbs the consumer’s equilibrium—the ratio of MU to P on the last unit of each good will no longer be equal. 14 The consumer must reallocate income across goods With income fixed, if the price of one good rises, the consumer is able to buy fewer goods and services, causing the consumer to demand less. ◦ This shows as a decrease in quantity demanded for the good whose price rose ◦ It shows as a decrease in demand for other goods 15 • An income-compensated price change is an imaginary exercise: • assume that the price of one good or service changes • Imagine that the consumer’s income is adjusted so that he or she has just enough to purchase the original combination of goods and services at the new set of prices. • Ask: What changes in purchases would the consumer make in their consumption to reflect the changing RELATIVE PRICES of the goods? • The substitution effect is the change in a consumer’s consumption of a good in response to an income-compensated price change. • Imagine the same price change as before, but with no adjustment in income. • Can the consumer make all the same purchases as before? • The changing prices = a change in purchasing power, or in effective INCOME. • What adjustments to purchases of that good whose price changed? • That change is called: The income effect of a price change is the change in consumption of a good resulting from the implicit change in income because of a price change. When the price of one good falls while everything else is constant, two things occur: 1. Other goods become relatively more expensive. So consumers buy more of the less expensive good and less of the more expensive goods. This is called the substitution effect. 2. The consumer can buy more total goods with the same income. Therefore they buy more of the now lower priced good. This is called the income effect. 19 Normal Good 20 Inferior Good 21 Indifference Curves Indifference analysis is an alternative way of explaining consumer choice that does not require an explicit discussion of utility. Indifferent: the consumer has no preference among the choices. Indifference curve: a curve showing all the combinations of two goods (or classes of goods) that the consumer is indifferent among. 22 Indifference Curve All points along the indifference curve represent combinations that are equally satisfying 23 Indifference Curves: Shape A common shape for an indifference curve is downward sloping. – For the consumer to be indifferent to the bundle of goods chosen, as less of one good is consumed, more of another must be consumed. 24 Indifference Curves: Shape (2) The indifference curves are not likely to be vertical, horizontal, or upward sloping. – – – A vertical or horizontal indifference curve holds the quantity of one of the goods constant, implying that the consumer is indifferent to getting more of one good without giving up any of the other good. An upward-sloping curve would mean that the consumer is indifferent between a combination of goods that provides less of everything and another that provides more of everything. Rational consumers usually prefer more to less. 25 Indifference Curve Shapes Improbable or impossible shapes: 26 Indifference Curves: Slope The slope or steepness of indifference curves is determined by consumer preferences. – – It reflects the amount of one good that a consumer must give up to get an additional unit of the other good while remaining equally satisfied. This relationship changes according to diminishing marginal utility—the more a consumer has of a good, the less the consumer values an additional value of that good. This is shown by an indifference curve that bows in toward the origin. 27 Marginal Rate of Substitution The slope of an indifference curve represents the rate at which a consumer would be willing to exchange one good for another – with indifference That ratio is called the Marginal Rate of Substitution 28 Indifference Curves: No Crossing Allowed! Indifference curves cannot cross. If the curves crossed, it would mean that the same bundle of goods would offer two different levels of satisfaction at the same time. If we allow that the consumer is indifferent to all points on both curves, then the consumer must not prefer more to less. There is no way to sort this out. The consumer could not do this and remain a rational consumer. 29 Indifference Curves Cannot Cross! 30 Indifference Map An indifference map is a complete set of indifference curves. It indicates the consumer’s preferences among all combinations of goods and services. The farther from the origin the indifference curve is, the more the combinations of goods along that curve are preferred. 31 Indifference Map 32 Budget Constraint The indifference map only reveals the ordering of consumer preferences among bundles of goods. It tells us what the consumer is willing to buy. It does not tell us what the consumer is able to buy. It does not tell us anything about the consumer’s buying power. The budget line shows all the combinations of goods that can be purchased with a given level of income. 33 The Budget Line 34 The Budget Line 35 Consumer Equilibrium The indifference map in combination with the budget line allows us to determine the one combination of goods and services that the consumer most wants and is able to purchase. This is the consumer equilibrium. The demand curve for a good can be derived from indifference curves and budget lines by changing the price of one of the goods (leaving everything else the same) and finding the equilibrium points. 36 Consumer Equilibrium The consumer maximizes satisfaction by purchasing the combination of goods that is on the indifference curve farthest from the origin but attainable given the consumer’s budget. 37 Deriving the Demand Curve By changing the price of one of the goods and leaving everything else the same, we can derive the demand curve. In (a), the price of a gallon of gasoline doubles, rotating the budget line from Y1 to Y2. The consumer equilibrium moves from point C to E, and the quantity demanded of gasoline falls from 3 to 2. 38 39 An individual consumer’s demand curve measures the value that the consumer places on each unit of good being considered. Consumer surplus for each unit is a measure of the difference between what a consumer is willing and able to pay for a unit of the good and the market price of a good that the consumer actually has to pay. 40 The height of the demand curve represents the value the consumer places on any given unit purchased, (as measured by willingness to pay) If a consumer buys 9 pounds of wheat… The total value to the consumer of the entire 9 units of wheat is measured by the area ABCD lying below the demand curve Suppose the consumer pays $.20 per pound for the wheat Total consumer value may then be divided into two parts: ◦ The turquoise rectangle AECD represents the amount spent. ◦ The purple triangle BCE, which is the difference between total consumer value and expenditure, is called consumer surplus Consumer surplus is the difference between what consumers actually pay and the maximum they would have been willing to pay Producer’s revenue equals price times quantity It is shown by the area AECD (both orange and green), and consists of two parts: The height of the supply curve represents the variable cost (opportunity cost) of each unit, so the area AFCD (green) represents total variable cost The difference between revenue and total variable cost (orange triangle FCE) is called producer surplus Producer surplus can be thought of in two ways As the difference between the revenue producers receive and the minimum they would have been willing to accept, at the margin, to supply each additional unit As the part of revenue that producers have available to cover fixed costs and profit The combined surplus (adjusted for fixed costs) represents the total value added or gains from trade Producer surplus is the value that producers gain compared with using the same variable resources to produce other goods consumer surplus is the value that consumers gain compared with using the same money to buy other goods Total value added may be increased in two ways ◦ By innovations that increase the product’s value to consumers and shift the demand curve ◦ By innovations that reduce the cost of production and shift the supply curve Innovations that increase value added improve economic efficiency Improvements in efficiency are shared between producers and consumers 47 Copyright © Houghton Mifflin Company. All rights reserved. 48 49