Susan A. Channick, J.D., M.P.H.
February 16, 2011
Currently, access and affordability are sacrificed to ensure excellent care but only for those who can afford
Ration by denying access because of inability to pay or inadequate portals to access (unemployed, health status)
Hence, 50M people in the U.S. lack health insurance and more lack adequate health insurance
Under Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (PPACA), the primary goal is universal access to adequate, affordable HI
ACA creates access for an addit’l 32M people with individual mandate as linchpin
Skewed health care costs (most expensive 5% population = 50% of costs; least expensive 50% = 3% of costs) mitigated by large numbers
ACA prohibits insurers’ behavior to avoid risk pool fragmentation
Exhibit 5. Source of Insurance Coverage Under Current Law and
House and Senate Bills, 2019
16 M (6%)
Other
4 M (1%)
Exchange
17 M (6%)
Exchange
(Private Plans)
(Public Plan)*
18 M (6%)
Uninsured
16 M (6%)
Other
9 M (3%)
Nongroup
168 M
(60%)
ESI
50 M
(18%)
Medicaid
15 M (5%)
Nongroup
35 M
(12%)
Medicaid
54 M
(19%)
Uninsured
162 M
(57%)
ESI
Current Law
16 M (6%)
Other
10 M (4%)
Nongroup
24 M (9%)
Exchanges
(Private Plans)
23 M (8%)
Uninsured
50 M
(18%)
Medicaid
158 M
(56%)
ESI
House Senate
Among 282 million people under age 65
*CBO estimates 20% of people enrolled in exchange will choose the public plan under the House bill. Employees whose employers provide coverage through the exchange are shown as covered by their employers (9 million in the House bill and 5 million in the Senate bill). Note: ESI is
Employer-Sponsored Insurance.
Source: Revised Estimate of the Affordable Health Care for America Act, Congressional Budget Office Letter to the Honorable John Dingell,
November 20, 2009, http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=10741 . The Congressional Budget Office Analysis of the Patient Protection and
Affordable Care Act, Incorporating the Manager’s Amendment, Dec. 19, 2009, http://cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=10868 .
Individual mandate; penalty for noncompliance
Employer mandate: Pay-or-play choice; Employers >50 employees who do not play, i.e., offer HI pay a tax to subsidize insurance for employees who purchase from exchanges
Creation of state HI exchanges with federal default
Federal subsidies available for individuals and small businesses
(premium tax credit)
Income at 133-400% FLP (family of four: $29,327 - $44,100)
Expanded Medicaid to include all under-65 individuals eligible for Medicaid
Income eligibility 133% FLP
Children, pregnant women, elderly, disabled, adults
All citizens and legal residents must purchase HI
Exemptions: Medicare, Medicaid, CHIP, employment, religious objections, the incarcerated, American Indians, defined financial hardship
HI no longer voluntary
Penalty=greater of $695 per year up to a maximum of
$2085 per family; or 2.5% household income
Penalty like penalty for failure to pay income taxes; collected by
IRS; the question is whether the penalty is itself a tax
Goals:
To achieve (almost) universal coverage
To reduce adverse selection
But fear is that the relatively negligible penalty will not force compliance, i.e. will not achieve mandate
Healthy people often choose not to purchase insurance until they become sick and need care
This phenomenon justifies behavior by insurers such as individual rating, denials for pre-existing conditions, & rescissions when insureds become ill
The ACA regulates such conduct by insurers that is tolerable when HI is voluntary but intolerable when insurers are required to accept everyone regardless of health status
If people could get HI regardless of health status, they would opt out of insurance until they became sick and needed health care
When people who can afford health insurance but choose not to be insured become sick and cannot get insurance, unaffordable costs of care are often shifted to the rest of society
Allowing healthy people to opt out of the insurance pools dilutes the pools with a disproportionate number of unhealthy and raises the cost of premiums
Social Security, an income-replacement and welfare system, is funded by a mandatory payroll tax
If tax were not mandatory, high-income earners would opt out and contribute to individual retirement accounts which are purely incomereplacement
Contributions to Social Security are regressive (12.4% tax on first
$106,800 in earnings in 2011)
Distributions are partly income replacement (progressive) and partly redistributive (cross-subsidization)
The contributions from high-wage participants are partly redistributed to lower wage earners in order to ensure an income safety net
Without redistribution from the wealthy, the floor of the income safety net would be substantially lower and standard of living among the elderly would fall
Is the individual mandate different from Social Security?
A rational decision for young, healthy is to forego health insurance
Preference for spending money on something else;
Less risk averse than older and sicker for whom the risk of ill health is much greater and for whom it is rational to purchase health insurance
Insurance pools become highly segmented by health status
As members of the pool become sicker and more costly, insurers
Raise premiums and more people drop out because of unaffordability;
Refuse to sell or renew or cancel the policies of those who are ill.
The number of uninsured rises
Conclusion: It is difficult to achieve affordable universal access unless there is very high participation of the populace in the insurance pools which, in a free-market, competitive system, can be achieved only by mandated participation.
2/5 of 22M eligible but unenrolled in Medicaid & CHIP
¼ undocumented immigrants
Decrease from 18.6% to 14.9% due entirely to expanded
Medicaid (additional 12 – 16M Americans)
Commerce Clause
Necessary and Proper Clause
General Welfare Clause
General Welfare Clause
Commandeering
Prior to the formation of the United States, there were thirteen separate and sovereign states
The design of authority of the United States is a dual sovereignty regime that delegates certain powers to the Congress; powers not delegated nor prohibited by the Constitution to the states are reserved to them
The federal government is permitted only narrow authority to regulate in the states (preemption; conditional spending such as Medicaid &
EMTALA; Commerce Clause) because it lacks a plenary power to regulate for the general welfare
The individual mandate is a compulsory directive to the states to require their residents to purchase health insurance
No language of preemption
No conditional spending
The question is whether the mandate impermissibly intrudes on the states’ plenary power to regulate for the public’s well-being
The constitutionality of the individual mandate and penalty depends on the USSC’s interpretation of the Commerce Clause which permits
Congress to narrowly regulate commerce among the several states under limited conditions:
The use of channels of interstate commerce;
The instrumentalities of interstate commerce; and
Intrastate activities having a substantial economic effect on interstate commerce
Necessary and Proper Clause has been used to implement the power of
Congress over interstate commerce, i.e. where the activity has a substantial economic effect on interstate commerce
The Commerce Clause has historically applied to acts which directly burden or obstruct interstate commerce
Starting in the 1940s (Jones v. Laughlin Steel, Darby, and Wickard) until the mid-
1990s, the USSC broadened its reach to activities, even intrastate activities, that have a “substantial effect” on interstate commerce
In 1995, the Rehnquist Court struck down the federal Gun Free School Zones Act which criminalized the possession of a firearm in a school zone holding it exceeded Congress’s authority under the Commerce Clause because gun possession within 1,000 feet of a school a noneconomic activity (U.S. v. Lopez)
In 2000, the Court reaffirmed the economic/non-economic distinction of Lopez striking down the civil remedy provision of the federal Violence Against Women
Act of 1994 which criminalized certain activity against women calling the regulated activity non-economic (U.S. v. Morrison). On behalf of the legislation, the government argued that violence against women deterred women from engaging in interstate commerce thus reducing the productivity of women
In Lopez, the Court determined that the Gun Free School
Zone Act regulated a noneconomic class of activity, possession of a gun within 1000 feet of a school
In Morrison, the Court upheld the Lopez economic/noneconomic scheme finding the federal civil remedy for victims of gender-motivated crimes against women (VAWA) unconstitutional because its noneconomic, criminal nature did not impact interstate commerce
In 2005, the Court again broadened the reach of the Commerce
Clause to prohibit, via the federal Controlled Substances Act (to regulate drug trafficking), the local, purely intrastate individual cultivation and use of marijuana permissible under California’s
Compassionate Use Act (1996) (Gonzales v. Raich)
The CSA regulates the production, distribution, and consumption of commodities for which there is an established and lucrative interstate market
The Compassionate Use Act creates an exemption from criminal prosecution for physicians as well as patients and primary caregivers who possess or cultivate marijuana for medicinal purposes with the approval of a physician
The 9 th Circuit Court of Appeals, relying on Lopez and Morrison, held that purely local cultivation and possession for medicinal purposes was beyond the reach of federal power
The USSC decision relied on the holding of a 1942 case, Wickard v.
Filburn, in which the Court upheld a provision of the Agricultural
Adjustment Act limiting the quantity of wheat that an individual farmer could grow for his own consumption because of the (aggregate) effect that might have on interstate commerce, i.e. decreasing the demand for wheat in the interstate market
Notwithstanding what seemed to be the purely intrastate nature of the activity, the Court held that Congress can regulate purely intrastate activity if “failure to regulate would undercut regulation of the interstate market in that commodity.” In the case of marijuana, the diversion of homegrown marijuana into the interstate market would frustrate the federal interest in eliminating such commercial transactions, i.e. drug trafficking
The justification for Raich has been attributed to the comprehensiveness of the federal statutory framework for regulating controlled substances
Where intrastate economic activity has a substantial effect on interstate commerce, Congress can regulate
In Wickard, the fear was that wheat grown locally could have been drawn into the interstate market thereby lowering the price of interstate wheat and disrupting the statute’s intent to stabilize that market.
In Raich, the fear was that growing marijuana locally could have an adverse effect on even illegal interstate commerce by increasing the supply of marijuana available in that market and frustrating the intent of the Controlled Substances Act
Thomas More Law Center v. Obama, 720 F. Supp. 2d 882 (E.D. Mich 2010) and Liberty Univ., Inc., v. Geithner, WL 4860299 (W.D. Va. 2010), both of which were brought by individual plaintiffs, in which the federal district court judges upheld the individual mandate as constitutional;
Virginia v. Sebelius, 728 F. Supp. 2d 768 ( E.D. Va. 2010), brought by the
Commonwealth of Virginia, in which federal district court judge Henry
Hudson found the individual mandate unconstitutional, and Florida v. HHS,
Case No.: 3:10-cv-91-RV/EMT (N.D. Fla 2011), brought by the State of
Florida and 25 other states, in which federal district court judge Roger
Vinson found the individual mandate unconstitutional and unseverable from the entire health care reform act.
Other cases have been filed, some dismissed procedurally and others still awaiting disposition
State standing:
States passed laws declaring that pending health care reform infringes on state powers
Existence of even declaratory law is sufficient to trigger duty of the AG to defend the law and the sovereign power to enact it
Merits
Plaintiffs (states’ AGs/Governors) argue that the Commerce Clause can only reach individuals engaged in an “activity” and that failure to purchase health insurance is “inactivity”
Defendant (federal government) argues that:
Activity is not required for Commerce Clause power;
Not having health insurance constitutes activity;
This mandate has a substantial effect on interstate commerce
Individual mandate falls within the Necessary and Proper Clause;
Most recently, mandate penalty is a tax
Thomas More (upholding mandate)
An individual’s economic decision to self-insure (with public money as a backstop) rather than purchase HI is activity which can be regulated because of its tendency to have a substantial effect on interstate commerce, i.e. an individual’s decision not to purchase insurance could undercut the broader regulatory scheme of the Affordable Care
Act.
State of Florida (striking down mandate)
Commerce Clause jurisprudence requires economic activity in order for Congress to have the authority to regulate. The failure to purchase health insurance is inactivity that does not have a significant effect on interstate commerce and is therefore beyond the scope of Congress’s authority to regulate under the
Commerce Clause.
All prior Commerce Clause jurisprudence has dealt with regulating an economic activity
Economic decision to forego health insurance equals activity
Making an economic decision to forego now and pay for out of pocket later coupled with access to uncompensated care at taxpayer’s expense
Thomas More and Liberty Univ., Inc.
One fear of upholding the ACA is the possibility of precedent
Uniqueness of the health insurance market – the limiting principle
All human beings are susceptible to illness and injury so no-one can opt out of the health care market
Hospitals required by law to provide care regardless of ability to pay
Cost-shifting to third parties; $43B in uncompensated care costs in 2008
But what about the similarities of the food market – can Congress require people to get food insurance?
The outcome is difficult to predict for three reasons:
The individual mandate paradigm is so unusual; Congress has never required individuals to purchase a product from private industry. If Congress can mandate insurance coverage, can it mandate buying and consuming broccoli? Purchasing a GM car should GM become financially unstable? Joining a health club?
Commerce Clause jurisprudence is not compelling either broadly or narrowly (Lopez/Morrison versus Wicker/Raich)
Lack of economic activity has become a new threshold question for courts in determining the constitutionality of the Affordable
Care Act
Is not having health insurance coverage (1) an activity versus a nonactivity?; (2) one that affects interstate commerce?
Necessary and Proper Clause
To make all Laws which shall be necessary and proper for carrying into execution the [specifically granted] foregoing Powers
Is the Clause independent or dependent? Can it be used as an independent ground for upholding individual mandate?
Or, alternatively, will it vitiate the enumerated powers doctrine?
ACA Regulatory Reform
insurers now must take all comers regardless of health status and with little differential in rating
These reforms incentivize delay in purchase of HI
If healthy young people stay out of the pools, less opportunity to crosssubsidize care of the ill
Government makes the argument that the penalty for failure to comply with the mandate is a tax justified under the General Welfare Clause (gov’t may tax and spend for the general welfare)
Taxes are defined by the USSC as having a revenue raising purpose which the penalty does not have.
In addition, the penalty is not a tax because
Not identified as a revenue raising measure for purposes of scoring the costs of legislation
Failure to pay does not subject the individual to criminal prosecution or penalty
Federal government not given the usual remedies such as liens and levies against the non-compliant tax-payer
Compare with the Act’s employer pay-or-play provision
Pay-or-play requires certain large employers to either provide health insurance for eligible employees or pay a tax to subsidize the cost of purchasing health insurance from the exchanges
The pay-or-play provision is cited by Congress as authorized by its taxing power while the levy on the uninsured is described as a penalty
Thomas More: The penalty is not a tax subject to the General Welfare
Clause but a penalty imposed incidentally under the Commerce Clause and therefore subject to Commerce Clause jurisprudence
Virginia v. Sebelius: The text of Section 1501 (the minimum essential coverage provision) states that the penalty is a product of the Commerce
Clause and not the General Welfare Clause; the revenue generated by the provision is incidental to its regulatory purpose; and that the government is trying to smuggle in an unconstitutional exercise of the Commerce Clause in the guise of a tax
This penalty has a revenue raising purpose, i.e. to defray the increased costs of health insurance from adverse selection
How is the mandate penalty different from a tax on cigarettes or alcohol?
The intention is both to raise revenue and regulate conduct that Congress believes is socially undesirable
Medicaid is a conditional spending program; federal assistance depends on states’ voluntary opt in and compliance
Currently FMAP is from 50% - 75% of costs
One way the ACA expands coverage is to expand Medicaid eligibility to all adults whose income does not exceed 133% of FLP ($14,404)
Presently, deserving poor (pregnant women, children until 19, aged, disabled, adults with dependent children at varying levels of income)
Individuals above 133% FLP and 400% of FLP entitled to federal HI premium subsidies
Expands Medicaid by 16M
Federal government to pick up approximately 95% of the cost of additional
Medicaid beneficiaries from 2014 - 2019 with states picking up the balance
Congress projects that over time Medicaid expansion will save the states money such as uncompensated care costs and costs of coverage of beneficiaries who will shift to HI exchanges and premium subsidies
In Florida vs. HHS, the state plaintiffs claim that the Act violates the
Spending Clause of the Constitution by expanding and altering the
Medicaid program to such an extent they cannot afford the newly-imposed costs and burdens
They allege that Medicaid expansion violates the Spending Clause because it is coercive and effectively commandeers the states
The states argue that because they have no choice but to participate in the
Medicaid program, the lack of choice transforms the spending provision from pressure into compulsion
The Hobson’s Choice the states are put to is (1) to accept the new costs and obligations of the Medicaid expansion; or (2) exit the Medicaid program altogether and lose FMAP
Judge Vinson, in Florida vs. HHS, ruled in favor of the government that the states’ claim of commandeering did not survive a motion for summary judgment
The individual mandate penalizes individuals who do not purchase a product from a private company
The requirement of the purchase of health insurance is necessary because Congress chose to solve the universal health insurance problem by preserving the private insurance market instead of adopting a single-payer solution like “Medicare For All”
If Congress can force individuals to purchase HI, can it make you buy broccoli? Can it make you buy a GM car if GM is again on the verge of insolvency?
The irony of the challenges to the mandate is that preservation of the private insurance market was a conservative shield against the single-payer option, and is now being used, after the fact, as a sword against the constitutionality of the ACA.
Constitutionality issue arises because Congress insisted and the administration acquiesced on preserving private insurance market
Individual mandate necessary to stabilize private insurance market in light of regulatory reforms
Reforms make it possible for individuals to opt out
If the healthy opt out, adverse selection spiral causes prices to rise forcing out more and . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
The federal district court cases to date have fallen out along party lines, i.e. depending on the political affinity of the judges
Is this because conservative judges simply don’t like health care reform
(or Barack Obama) or because they believe that Congress has really overstepped the scope of its Commerce Clause power?
Eventually, the USSC will no doubt opine on whether the
PPACA will survive constitutional muster but, on the way, a number of circuit courts of appeal will opine as well
The federal bench is populated with judges who believe there is too much government regulation of economic affairs
Can this be true after the cataclysmic financial meltdown?
Once it gets to the USSC, the question is whether the Court will divide on political lines (Roberts, Scalia, Thomas and
Alito vs. Ginsburg, Breyer, Sotomayor, and Kagan with
Kennedy havingf the swing vote)
Larry Tribe’s February 7 op-ed piece in the NYTimes