CHAPTER 14 Aggregate Demand and Fiscal Policy Prepared by: Jamal Husein © 2006 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin Learning Objectives Why do governments cut taxes to increase economic output? Why is the U.S. economy more stable than it was prior to World war II? If consumers become more confident about the future of the economy, can that confidence lead to faster economic growth? If a government increases spending by $10 billion, could total GDP increases by more than $10 billion? © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 2 Behind the AD Curve: A short Run Analysis The demand for goods and services determines output, or the level of GDP, at least in the short run. The short run is a period of time during which prices do not change, or change very little. In the short run, producers supply all of the output that is demanded. In the short run, the economy rapidly adjusts to reach the equilibrium level of output, where total demand equals production, i.e., AD equals AS. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 3 Shifts in Aggregate Demand Price, P A shift in AD curve from AD0 to AD1 increases output from y0 to y1. SRAS AD1 AD0 y0 © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e y1 O’Sullivan & Sheffrin Output, y 4 Shifts in Aggregate Demand An increase of government spending of $10 billion will initially shift original AD by $10 billion (from A to B). Total AD will increase by more than $10 billion after a period of time due to the multiplier effect. Price, P A B C Final AD Initial shift Original AD y0 © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing y1 Survey of Economics, 2/e y2 O’Sullivan & Sheffrin Output, y 5 The Consumption Function & the Multiplier The relationship between consumer spending and income is called the consumption function: C = Ca + by Ca= autonomous consumption spending, or the amount of consumption spending that does not depend on the level of income. by = induced consumption, or the amount of consumption induced by higher income. b= marginal propensity to consume (MPC). y= level of income in the economy. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 6 Consumption Function The consumption function is a line that intersects the vertical axis at Ca. the value of autonomous consumption spending. When income equals zero, the value of total consumption (C) equals Ca. It corresponds to the amount of consumption that does not depend on the level of income. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 7 The MPC & the MPS The slope of the consumption function is the marginal propensity to consume (MPC), or the value of b in the linear equation. For each additional dollar of income received, a consumer will spend part of it and save the rest. The fraction that the consumer spends is given by his or her MPC or the slope of the consumption function b. The MPC is always less than one © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e 0 b<1 O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 8 The MPC & the MPS The fraction that the consumer saves is determined by his or her marginal propensity to save (MPS). For example, if b (MPC) = 0.6, then 60 cents of each additional dollar are consumed and 40 cents (MPS = .4) are saved. The sum of the MPC and the MPS is always equal to one MPC + MPS = 1 © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 9 Changes in the Consumption Function The consumption function can change for two reasons: A change in autonomous consumption A change in the marginal propensity to consume Factors that cause autonomous consumption to change are: Consumer wealth, or the value of stocks, bonds, and consumer durables held by the public (Franco Modigliani). Consumer confidence. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 10 Changes in the Consumption Function Factors that cause the marginal propensity to consume to change are: Consumers’ perceptions of changes in income. Studies show that consumers tend to save a higher proportion of a temporary increase in income, and spend a higher proportion of income if the increase in income is perceived to be permanent. Changes in taxes, as we will see later in this chapter. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 11 Changes in the Consumption Function Impact of a change in autonomous consumption © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e Impact of a change in the marginal propensity to consume O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 12 Determining Aggregate Demand In an economy without government or the international sector, AD will be determined by consumption (C) and investment spending (I). We stack up the amount of investment on top of consumption function. At any level of output (income), total demand for goods and services can be read of the C + I line. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 13 Equilibrium output, where y = C+I, is found where the 450 line intersects the demand line (C+I). The y* level of output means that firms are producing precisely the level of output necessary to meet the consumption and investment demands by households and firms. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Demand Determining Aggregate Demand 450 E C Ca + I Survey of Economics, 2/e C+I Ca y* Output, y O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 14 The Multiplier The model of AD can be used to explain what happens to equilibrium output (employment) if there is a change in investment spending (an autonomous expenditure); An increase in investment, i.e., from I0 to I1 (called ∆I) will shift the initial C+I0 curve upward by ∆I to C+I1; The intersection of C+I1 curve with the 45 degree line shifts equilibrium from E0 to E1; As a result AD increases from Y0 to Y1; © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 15 The Multiplier The change in AD (∆y) is greater than the increase in I, which is the general result that the increase in output always exceeds the increase in investment; This explains the multiplier or why the final shift in AD is greater than the initial shift in AD; The Multiplier is a number that shows by how much equilibrium output will change as a result of a change in the value of autonomous expenditures. For example, if b = 0.75, then the multiplier equals 4. A one-dollar increase in autonomous consumption or in investment, will increase equilibrium income by 4 dollars. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 16 The Multiplier E1 Demand y1 ∆I 450 C+I1 C+I0 y0 E0 C I1 I0 CA ∆y y0 © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin y1 Output, y 17 The Multiplier in Action (millions $) Round of Spending Increase in Demand 1 $10 Increase in GDP and Income $10 2 8 8 6.4 3 6.4 6.4 5.12 4 5.12 5.12 4.096 5 4.096 4.096 3.277 … … … … Total 50 million 50 million 40 million Multiplier © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing = Survey of Economics, 2/e Increase in Consumption $8 1 (1 – MPC) O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 18 Government Spending and Taxation Both the level of government spending and the level of taxation, through their influence on the demand for goods and services, affect the level of GDP in the short run. Using taxes and spending to influence the level of GDP (shift the AD curve) in the short run is known as Fiscal Policy. Government purchases of goods and services are a component of total spending; Total Spending including government = C + I + G © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 19 Government Spending Increases (decreases) in government spending shifts the C+I+G curve upward (downward), just as changes in investment; 450 450 C+I+G1 C+I+G0 C+I+G0 y0 © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Demand Demand y1 Output, y Survey of Economics, 2/e C+I+G1 y1 O’Sullivan & Sheffrin y0 Output, y 20 The Impact of Taxes After taxes and transfers are taken into account, national income becomes personal disposable income: Yd = y - T The consumption function becomes: C = Ca + by d or C = Ca + b(y T) For example, if taxes increase by $1, aftertax income will decline by $1. Since the MPC is b, this means that consumption (C) will fall by b×$1 and the C+I+G curve will shift downward by b×$1 ; © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 21 The Impact of Taxes Increases (decreases) in taxes shifts the C+I+G curve downward (upward) and impact total demand and equilibrium output. 450 450 C+I+G C+I+G y0 © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Demand Demand C+I+G y1 Output, y Survey of Economics, 2/e C+I+G y1 O’Sullivan & Sheffrin y0 Output, y 22 The Impact of Taxes The multiplier for taxes is less than that for government spending; Decreasing government spending (G) by $1, will shift the C+I+G curve downward by $1; However, increasing taxes by $1, consumers will cut back their consumption by a fraction of $1 (b×$1), thus the C+I+G curve will shift downward by less than $1, or exactly by b×$1; © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 23 Government Spending and Taxation We use a special terminology to describe fiscal policy; Government policies directed towards increasing AD and GDP are called expansionary policies such as tax cuts and increases in government spending; Government policies directed towards decreasing AD and GDP are called contractionary policies such as tax increases and government spending cuts © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 24 Government Spending and Taxation Budget deficit, the difference between government spending and its revenue, will be impacted by government policies; An increase in government spending or a reduction in taxes (expansionary policies) will increase the government's budget deficit; A decrease in government spending or an increase in taxes (contractionary policies) will decrease the government's budget deficit © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 25 Fiscal Policy in Action According to Keynesian economics, expansionary fiscal policy—tax cuts and increased government spending—could pull the economy out of a recession or depression. During the 1930s, however, politicians did not believe in Keynesian fiscal policy, largely because they feared the consequences of budget deficits. Although government spending increased during the 1930s, so did taxes, resulting in no net fiscal expansion. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 26 Fiscal Policy in Action It was not until the early 1960s, during the Kennedy administration, that modern fiscal policy came to be accepted. Tax cuts were used to try to reduce unemployment. Estimating the actual effects the tax cuts had is difficult, but from 1963 to 1966, both real GDP and consumption grew at rapid rates. This rapid growth suggests that the tax cuts had the effect, predicted by Keynesian theory, of stimulating economic growth. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 27 Fiscal Policy in Action From 1966 to 1969, the unemployment rate fell below 4%, and fiscal policy was used in economic policy again. A temporary surcharge tax, enacted in 1968, raised the taxes of households by 10%. But since the tax was temporary, it did not have a major effect on permanent income, and the decrease in demand was smaller than economists had anticipated. Households simply saved less during that period. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 28 Fiscal Policy in Action During the 1970s there was no net change in fiscal policy. Mild changes in taxes were enacted in 1975, after the economy went into a recession in 1973. Significant tax cuts were enacted in 1981, but these tax cuts were justified on the basis of their impact on supply, not demand. A major tax increase was passed under President Clinton that successfully brought the budget into balance. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 29 Fiscal Policy in Action By year 2000, the federal budget began to show surpluses that set the stage for tax cuts that were passed by President George W. Bush. Post September 11, 2001, the president and the Congress became less concerned with balancing the budget and authorized new spending programs to provide relief to victims and to stimulate the economy © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 30 Automatic Stabilizers Certain taxes and transfers act as automatic stabilizers for the economy. When income is high, the government collects more taxes and pays out less transfer payments, thereby reducing spending. When output is low, the government collects less taxes and pays out more in transfer payments, putting more funds into the hands of consumers. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 31 Automatic Stabilizers As such automatic stabilizers prevent consumption from falling as much in bad times and from rising as much in good times. Other factors contributing to the stability of the economy is that consumers base their spending decisions on permanent income and not just their current level of income. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 32 Growth Rate of U.S. GDP, 1871-2000 © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 33 Exports and Imports Exports (X) and imports (M) affect AD through their influence on how foreigners demand goods and services produced in the U.S. An increase in exports means an increase in demand for U.S. goods and services, while an increase in imports means an increase in demand for foreign goods and services by U.S. residents. © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 34 Exports and Imports To recognize the impacts of exports and imports on AD and GDP, we take two steps and ignore government spending and taxes for the moment: Add exports, X, which we assume to be autonomous because they depend on foreign income, to other sources of spending; and subtract imports, M, which depends on the level of domestic income, from total spending by U.S. residents y = C + I + (X – M) © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 35 Exports and Imports Consumers will buy more foreign goods and services (M) as income rises; imports = M = my Additional spending on U.S. goods and services out of additional income can be obtained by subtracting m or the (marginal propensity to import) from b or the MPC. MPC for domestic spending = b – m © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 36 Exports and Imports For example, if b = 0.8 and m = 0.2, then Demand MPC for domestic spending = b – m = 0.8 – 0.2 = 0.6 450 Demand In an open economy, the level of equilibrium income is determined by the intersection of total demand for U.S. goods and services with the 45 degree line. Ca+I+X y* © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e Output, y O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 37 Exports and Imports Demand 450 Demand An increase in exports Will increase the level of Aggregate Demand. An increase in marginal propensity to import will decrease the level of AD. 450 ∆X Ca+I+X Ca+I+X y1 y0 Output, y © 2005 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Survey of Economics, 2/e y0 y1 Output, y O’Sullivan & Sheffrin 38