Economies of Scope and the Learning Curve Outline 1. What are economies of scope? 2. Measuring economies of scope 3. Real world examples 4. The learning curve 5. Source of learning 6. Cost and profit maximization 7. The shut down rule Economies of Scope If a single firm can jointly produce goods X and Y more cheaply that any combination of firms could produce them separately, then the production of X and Y is characterized by economies of scope This is an extension of the concept of economies of scale to the multi product case Economies of scope can be measured by as follows: C (Q1 ) C (Q2 ) C (Q1 , Q2 ) SC C (Q1 ) C (Q2 ) Where C(Q1,Q2) is the cost of jointly producing goods 1 and 2 in the respective quantities; C(Q1) is is the cost of producing good 1 alone, and similarly for C(Q2). Example: Let C(Q1) = $12 million; C(Q2) = $8 million; and C(Q1,Q2) = $17 million. Thus: $12 $8 $17 $3 SC .15 $12 $8 $20 Thus joint production of goods 1 and 2 would result in a 15 percent reduction in total costs Economies of scope arise from “complementarities” in the production or distribution of distinct goods or services Real world examples Economies of scope between cable TV and high speed internet service. Production of timber and particle board. Corn and ethanol production Production of beef and hides. Power generation and distribution Joint cargo and passenger transportation in airlines reduces excess capacity. Global wholesale distribution of cheese, salad dressing, and cigarettes (example: Phillip-Morris-Kraft). Computer aided design of (CAD) of aircraft components. The Learning Curve The learning curve embodies the (inverse) relationship between average production cost and cumulative output. Over 1,000,000,000,000,000 sold We should have this figured out by now Sources of learning •The experience of the workforce tends to increase with cumulative output—thus workers are more familiar with the production process and have their movements/activities become routinized or a matter of habit. •There are usually several ways to do a task, and it takes time and experimentation to find the best way. •Quality control for inputs and outputs needs time to identify potential problem areas. •Input suppliers have their owning learning process Figure 7.6a Average Cost Example: Texas Instruments pushed calculator prices from about $1,000 to around $10 in the 1970s. Learning curve Cumulative Output Average cost is a decreasing function of cumulative output Figure 7.6b Average Cost Learning is manifested by a downward shift of the LAC function LAC (year 1) Increasing returns Learning LAC (year 2) 1,000 1,500 Rate of Output (per Month) Figure7.7 Costs and Profit-Maximization: The single product case Dollars per Unit of Output Demand ' AC MR' P¡ P* AC MC Demand MR Q¡ Q* Qmin Q' Output Green-shaded area is economic profit Figure 7.8 Loss Minimization Means producing Some Output Dollars per Unit of Output MC P* AC AVC Marginal revenue Q* Demand Output Summary If the firm shuts down production, then losses will be equal to fixed cost, or: Losses = If the firm supplies Q* units at the price P*, then: Losses = P* Moral of the story: So long as price (average revenue) exceeds average variable cost, the loss minimizing strategy will entail producing some output.