Yield Curve As A Predictor of Recessions: Evidence From Panel Data Huseyin Ozturk Luis Felipe V. N. Pereira Abstract In this study we test empirically whether the slope of the yield curve - yield spread - is a good predictor of recessions. We follow Estrella and Trubin (2006) although instead of time series, we adopt an unbalanced panel data framework for 32 OECD countries from 1990 to 2011. This modification allows one to apply this model for countries with short time series. Furthermore, we include four quarter lagged GDP in the model to assure that yield spread is a good predictor of recessions, even when controlling for GDP changes. Our models are estimated using panel Probit, Logit and MLE. The results show that with a Type I error of 25%, the models deliver a power of roughly 63% and can be used as an effective instrument to predict recessions one year ahead. Keywords: term structure, panel probit, panel logit, recession Resumo Este estudo testa a capacidade da inclinação da curva de rendimentos – “spread” de juros – para prever recessões. A metodologia segue o proposto por Estrella e Trubin (2006), mas substitui as séries de tempo por dados em painel não balanceado, incluindo 32 países da OCDE de 1990 a 2011. Essa modificação permite aplicar o modelo proposto a países com séries de tempo curtas. Ainda, incluímos defasagens do PIB para garantir que o “spread” de juros é útil na previsão de recessões, mesmo quando se controla para os efeitos de mudanças no PIB. Os modelos são estimados utilizando painel Probit, Logit e MLE. Os resultados indicam que com um nível de erros Tipo-1 de 25%, os modelos possuem poder de aproximadamente 63% e confirmam que esta metodologia pode ser utilizada como um instrumento efetivo para prever recessões com um ano de antecedência. Palavras-chave: estrutura a termo, painel probit, painel logit, recessão JEL Classification: C23, C24, C25 Área 7 – Microeconomia, Métodos Quantitativos e Finanças Undersecretariat of Treasury of the Republic of Turkey and Hacettepe University. Email: huseyin.ozturk@hazine.gov.tr Brazil National Treasury Secretariat and Catholic University of Brasilia. Email: luis.fpereira@catolica.edu.br. The views and opinions expressed in this work are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Brazil National Treasury or the Undersecretariat of Treasury of the Republic of Turkey. 1. Introduction It has been widely discussed in recent literature that expectations about short-term interest rates, which determine a substantial part of the movement of long-term interest rates, depend upon macroeconomic variables. Therefore, one would expect macroeconomic variables and modeling exercises to be quite informative in explaining and forecasting the yield-curve movements. Likewise, yield curve movements would be informative in explaining and forecasting future economic performance. A strong rationality supports the relationship between the slope of the yield curve and real economic activity. There are at least three main reasons that explain the relationship and thus explain why the yield curve might contain information about future recessions. In general, this relationship is positive and, essentially, reflects the expectations of financial market participants regarding future economic growth. A positive spread between longterm and short-term interest rates, i.e. a steepening yield curve, is associated with an expectation of an increase in real economy activity, while a negative spread, i.e. a flattening or inverted yield curve, is associated with an expectation of a decline in real activity. The first reason stems from the expectations hypothesis of the term structure of interest rates. This hypothesis states that long-term interest rates reflect the expected path of future short-term interest rates. Thus, long-term rates can be considered a weighted average of expected future short-term rates. In particular, it claims that, for any choice of holding period, investors do not expect to get different returns from holding bonds of different maturity dates (Anderson et. al. 1996). An anticipation of a recession implies the expectation of a decline of future interest rates that is reflected in a decrease of long-term interest rates. These expected reductions in interest rates might be induced from countercyclical monetary policy designed to stimulate the economy. Yet, the monetary policy and yield curve dynamics is out of the scope of this study. Another reason that explains the aforementioned relationship is related to the effects of monetary policy on yield curve. For example, when monetary policy is tightened, shortterm interest rates rise; long-term rates also typically rise but usually by less than the current short rate, leading to a downward-sloping term structure. The monetary contraction can eventually reduce spending in sensitive sectors of the economy, causing economic growth to slow and, thus, the probability of a recession to increase. Estrella and Mishkin (1998) show that the monetary policy is an important determinant of term structure spread in this sense. The third reason is given by Harvey (1988) and Hu (1993) and is based on the maximization of the inter-temporal consumer choices. The central assumption behind their model is that consumers prefer a stable level of income rather than very high income during expansion and very low income during slowdowns. Therefore, if the consumers expect a reduction of their income, in case of a recession, they prefer to save and buy long-term bonds in order to get payoffs in the slowdown. By doing that they increase the demand for long-term bonds and that leads to a decrease of the corresponding yield. Further, to finance the purchase of the long-term bonds, a consumer may sell short-term bonds whose yields 2 will increase. As a result, when a recession is expected, the yield curve flattens or gets inverted. Indeed, yield spread between long – term and short – term interest rates may contain significant information about future economic activity, in particular, recessions. Based on this background, this paper focuses on the study of the information content of the yield curve in order to predict recessions in OECD. Based on the vast literature, our study revisits the issue and extends the validity of the methodology to these countries that have short time series data. As per the stylized fact suggests, we test for the information content of the yield curves. The problem faced is that some countries have short time series. Econometrics analysis traditionally makes use of long time series. We overcome this problem by employing panel data. By doing so, we will be able to investigate this relationship for the countries who have short time series as well. As for the best of our knowledge, this study is the first to employ panel data to investigate this issue. First, by using panel data we adopt standard probit, logit and MLE methods to predict recessions. Second, we include in our a model the GDP lagged four quarters, Our results show that both models in all three methods deliver roughly the same level of power. Regarding the the logit and probit methods, both are expected to have same estimation results1. The MLE estimates are also roughly the same. Lastly, we compare predicted recessions with actual recessions by defining Type I and Type II errors and evaluating the power of each model. The paper is organized as follows: the next section will have a brief literature survey. Section 3 explains the data and methodology and focus on methodological procedures to make accurate estimations. Section 4 will present our econometric results for probit, logit and MLE. The robustness of the results is also tested in this section. This section will discuss the results for the estimation result for those countries that have short time series. Section 5 has some concluding remarks. 2. Literature Several economics and finance papers have explored the macroeconomic determinants of the unobservable factors of the yield curve identified by empirical finance studies. Wu (2001) examines the relationship between the Federal Reserve's monetary policy "surprises" and the movement of the "slope" factor of the yield curve in the U.S. after 1982. His study identifies monetary policy "surprises" in several ways to make the analysis more robust; the results indicate a strong correlation between such monetary policy "surprises" and the movement of the "slope" factor over time. Ang and Piazzesi (2001) examine the influences of inflation and real economic activity on the yield curve in an asset-pricing framework. In their model, bond yields are determined 1 Logit and probit models produce comparable results. In both estimation methodologies, error terms are distributed logistically and normally. These distributions have very much common except for their tails being one of them is fatter. Our sample is not so large to catch the differentiation in tails. Therefore, logit and probit model estimation produce similar results. 3 not only by the three unobservable factors—level, slope, and curvature—but also by an inflation measure and a real activity measure. They find that incorporating inflation and real activity into the model is useful in forecasting the yield curve's movement. However, such effects are quite limited. Inflation and real activity help explain the movements of shortterm bond yields and medium-term bond yields (up to a maturity of one year), but most movements of long-term bond yields are still accounted for by the unobservable factors. Therefore, they conclude that macroeconomic variables cannot substantially shift the level of the yield curve. Evans and Marshall (2001) analyze the same problem using a different approach. They formulate several models with rich macroeconomic dynamics and look at how the "level", "slope," and "curvature" factors are affected by the structural shocks identified in those models. Their conclusion confirms Ang and Piazzesi's (2001) result that a substantial portion of short- and medium-term bond yields is driven by macroeconomic variables. However, they also find that in the long run macroeconomic variables do indeed explain much of the movement of the long-term bond yields, and the "level" factor responds strongly to macroeconomic variables. For instance, their identification results indicate that the changes in households' consumption preferences induce large, persistent, and significant shifts in the level of the yield curve. Ahrens (2002), analyzes the concept with another question. He studies the informational content of the term structure as a predictor of recessions in eight OECD countries. The results of the study suggest that for all countries in the analysis the term spread turns out to be a successful predictor for recession. Karunaratne (2002) also studies the relationship between recession and yield curve. After testing for the unit root, stationary variables reveals out that the yield curve gives the best forecast on economic activity. Non-nested tests of other financial indicators, that are nominees to be used for predicting recession, demonstrate that yield curve is the outperformer in predicting recession. In his analysis four quarter time horizon gives the best results in predicting recession for Australia. Afonso and Martins (2010) study fiscal behavior and the sovereign yield curve in the U.S. and Germany during the period 1981:I-2009:IV. The latent factors, level, slope and curvature, obtained with the Kalman filter approach, are used in a VAR with macro and fiscal variables, controlling for financial stress conditions. Last but not the least, De Pace (2012) describes of the leading properties of the term structure for output growth relationship using use time-varying-parameter models and realtime data to shed light on the dynamic characteristics of the yield curve. He investigates five European economies and USA over the last decades and until the third quarter of 2010. Interestingly, the main argument of the paper is that the predictive content of the term spread is not a reliable predictor of output growth over time and across the country set. He also contend that the yield spread significantly contributes to the forecast performance of simple growth regressions in Europe but not in the USA in recent years and the variance of the random shocks to the term spreads tends to fall in all countries. 4 The increasing interest to predict recession from the term structure is evident. Since Estrella and Mishkin (1998), many studies have been conducted that investigate power of long – term and short – term yield spread as a recession predictor. Estrella and Trubin (2006) have also argued that the slope of the yield curve – in a bold definition, the spread between long and short – term interest rates – is a good predictor of future economic activity. The focus of their study was the slope of the curve could be a good forecasting tool in real time, although it was instrumental in predicting past recessions. We follow Estrella and Mishkin (1998) and Estrella and Trubin (2006) in modeling recession. By employing panel data, information content of yield curve as a recession predictor has been tested for these countries, even if they have short time series data. We employ binary response models and MLE in estimation process. 3. Data and Methodology Empirically, we build a model that converts the steepness of the yield curve at the present time into a likelihood of a recession four quarter ahead. The reason why we make predictions four quarter ahead is that Estrella and Mishkin (1998) makes forecasts one, two, four and six quarters ahead. The basic finding they arrived is that the performance of the yield curve spread improves considerably as the forecast horizon lengthens to two and four quarters. By the same token, Estrella and Trubin (2006), predicts recessions four quarter ahead. All in all, our analysis is composed of four items: a measure of steepness of the yield curve, a definition of recession, two models that combine both of them and reliable econometric techniques for estimation. 3.1. A measure of steepness For the sake of simplicity we define the steepness of the yield curve as the difference between long – term and short – term interest rate (Estrella and Trubin 2006, Estrella and Mishkin 1998). Although the very recent methods to estimate the term structure of the yield curve give thorough approximation of the slope, we follow the literature on predicting recession over the yield curve which defines the steepness of the yield curve as the difference between long – term and short – term interest rate. Then, long – term and short – term interest rate need to be identified. We utilize OECD methodology in identifying long – term and short – term interest rate. According to OECD definition, the short term interest rate are usually either the three month interbank offer rate attaching to loans given and taken amongst banks for any excess or shortage of liquidity over several months or the rate associated with Treasury bills, Certificates of Deposit or comparable instruments, each of three month maturity. For Euro Area countries the 3month "European Interbank Offered Rate" is used from the date the country joined the euro. Whereas, long term (in most cases 10 year) government bonds are the instruments whose field is used as the representative ‘interest rate’ for this area. Generally the yield is calculated at the pre-tax level and before deductions for brokerage costs and commissions 5 and is derived from the relationship between the present market value of the bond and that at maturity, taking into account also interest payments paid through to maturity. 3.2. Definition of recession There have been many attempts to define recession, yet, there is no official or generally agreed definition of recession. Although NBER’s archive represents recessions in US thoroughly, such a statistics does not exist for the other countries subject to our analysis 2. There is a piece of literature dealing with recession definition from business cycles. In this literature, the beginning and the end of a recession are turning points in the business cycle, i.e. the beginning represents a peak in the cycle while the end represents a trough. Artis et al., (1997) proposes an algorithm detecting turning points in industrial production series of G7 and the European countries. Ross and Ubide (2001) also apply the same methodology to the Euro area. This methodology utilizes binary response model and estimate recession. We opt for more a literal definition of recession. There is not a clear cut definition of recession, yet, we define recession as follows: Definition: A recession has occurred if a country reports two consecutive quarters of negative GDP growth. For estimation purposes, our binary variables will represent two different approaches in terms of measuring the duration of such recession. In Model 1, we consider that a recession actually happened and binary variable takes the value “1” starting only on the second quarter of negative GDP growth. Alternatively, Model 2 considers a recession actually happened in both first and second quarters of negative GDP growth, as long as both quarters are consecutive. 3.3. Data For the econometric modeling we use data from 32 OECD. To obtain evidences on the usefulness of the slope of the yield curve for predicting recessions in the countries of interest, we should make use of long time series. The problem here is that some of the countries in our analysis have very short time series. Moreover to the best of our knowledge, no attempt has been made to estimate recession in these countries due to this lack of long time series. To deal with this problem we construct a database composed of the long – term and short term rates of countries from OECD official website and adopt a panel data framework. We retrieved quarterly data starting from 1990Q1 to 2011Q13. The data is not homogenous in terms of their starting data. One of the main foci of this study is to predict recession in countries that have short time series. In our country set, there are countries having relatively shorter time series and are subject to repercussions of Euro zone debt crisis. Recession fears and yield curve dynamics in Euro-zone countries that have short time series will be interesting to analyse. Therefore, we pay special attention to the data for Portugal, Iceland, Ireland, Greece and Spain. The data for these countries are also 2 3 Please visit: http://www.nber.org/cycles.html Details on time series for each country are available in Appendix Table 1. 6 shorter. Investigating the relationship between slope of yield curve and recession with panel data will enable us to have an insight also for these countries. 3.4. Methodology We estimate an unbalanced panel model of 32 countries from 1990Q1 to 2011Q1 in order to ensure robustness of the results, we compare the three most common methodologies for estimation, namely: Probit Model, Logit Model and MLE. Equation (1) below is the basic model we estimate. We also estimate a modified model, i.e. equation (2), which includes the autoregressive series of the state of the economy (the indicator of recession or expansion currently). A measure of accuracy of the forecast was calculated and compared among different specifications of the models. Re cessioni ,t , m 0,i 1,i slopei ,t 4 i ,t (1) Re cessioni ,t , m 0,i 1,i slopei ,t 4 2,i GDPi ,t 4 i ,t (2) where m 1,2 are the models, that differ in terms of the definition of recession. i 1,...,32 are the cross section units, represented by the OECD countries and t 1990Q1,...,2011Q1 represents the time dimension of quarterly data. In our analysis we define recession as follows: 1, recession occur Re cessioni ,t ,m 0, recession does not occur Regarding the probit and logit model we employed, the main rationale behind including the lagged GDP into the basic model is as follows: one of the main assumptions of the binary response models is that the random shocks are i.i.d. normal random variables with zero mean. In this kind of model the errors are generally auto-correlated. In traditional time series approach this kind of problem is removed by using an autoregressive moving average (ARMA) filter. Here, since the shocks to 𝑢 are unobservable this technique is not available. Therefore, we adopt the solution proposed by Dueker (1997) to remove the serial correlation in 𝑢 by adding a lag of GDP. Adding a lag of GDP will also help to deal with auto–correlation in MLE, although ARMA type of filters is preferred. Yet, we follow a single procedure to remove auto–correlation, since ARMA filters are not available for binary response models. 3.4. Econometric Procedures The econometrics of binary outcome models concern is to give the correct treatment to the discreteness of the dependent variable, and in our case to constrain predicted probabilities between zero and one. Traditional MLE estimator ignores these concerns. The likelihood function is the joint density, which given independent observations are the product Π𝑖 𝑓(𝑦𝑖 |𝑥𝑖 , 𝛽) of the individual densities. The log likelihood function is then the log of a product, which equals the sum of logs. The estimator 𝛽̂ maximizes: 7 𝑁 1 ∑ ln 𝑓(𝑦𝑖 |𝑥𝑖 , 𝛽) 𝑁 𝑖=1 To properly deal with binary variables, literature applies both logit a probit models. The commonly used models take the form of conditional probability given by: 𝑄𝑁 (𝛽) = pi Pr yi 1 x F ( xi' ) where yi stands for the dependent variable and xi' stands for a matrix of independent variables. In the Logit model, function F (.) takes the form of: ex ' p F x ' i 1 e x And for the Probit model the analogous probability is: ' p xi' ( z )dz xi' where (.) is the standard normal cumulative distribution function with derivative z2 1 , which is the standard normal density function. exp 2 2 The choice between the econometric models has theoretical and empirical considerations. Theoretically speaking, the appropriate model depends on the data generation process, which is unknown. Also theoretically, the MLE model would not be chosen, since it violates the probability boundaries. However, empirically, there is little or no difference between predicted probabilities. ( z) 4. Results The goodness of fit for binary outcome models is usually evaluated by a comparison of fitted and actual values, although there are alternative diagnostics detailed in Amemiya (1981) and Maddala (1983). Consider yi as the dependent variable, and ŷi a prediction, the criterion yi yˆi 2 gives i the number of wrong predictions. The most intuitive prediction rule is to set yˆ 1 pˆ F ( x' ) 0.5 . However, if most of the sample has yˆ 1 , then often when y yˆ n(1 y ) , 2 i i i since it is likely that pˆ 0.5 , and hence yˆ 1 for all observation. To overcome this problem, typically a cutoff value is considered, letting yˆ 1 if pˆ c . We follow the traditional Type I and Type II error definition, commonly used to forecast business failure. Typically, a Type I error refers to failed firms that are classified by the models as non-failed ones, while type II error refers to non-failed firms that are classified as failed (see Zopounidis and Doumpos (1999) and Boritz and Kennedy (1995)). Our approach for defining Type I and Type II error, follows the same rationale, although it is adapted to better fit our framework. 8 Boritz and Kennedy (1995) argue that there is no generally accepted basis for trading off Type I and Type II errors. There may have different perceptions of the relative costs of Type I and Type II errors. In our analysis we prefer to minimize Type II error and tolerate Type I error. Therefore, we define the power of estimation as (1 – Type II error). The following table describes the resulting Type I and Type II errors in our study. Actually Recession Actually Non-Recession Predicted Recession Correct Type II error Predicted Non-Recession Type I error Correct Our results are based on an unbalanced panel data set. This issue is important especially when one is not able to assure that data was randomly missing (see Baltagi (2005)). To avoid any critics regarding this issue, we compare the results of our unbalanced panel with a balanced panel, where we excluded countries that have missing data. As results are almost the same in terms of statistical significance, fitting and power, we will present only results for unbalanced data4. Table I shows the estimation results for Model 1. The model is estimated through probit, logit and MLE. The parameter estimates for slope and GDP data are both significant at 5%. Table II presents the cut-off value, Type I, Type II and the power of each estimation. We fix exogenously level of Type I errors as close as possible to 25%. This means that the power we present in Table II is compatible with a model that gives one “false alarm” for each four recession predictions. The results are interesting in a sense that the powers are roughly the same at 63%. This means that a recession is correctly predicted 63% of the time, even for countries with short time series. Furthermore, one should note that Log Likelihood, AIC, BIC and Pseudo R2 are very close in Logit and Probit estimates, and they slightly improve with the inclusion of lagged GDP. Results for MLE should be used only for comparison purposes, since they do not represent properly our binary framework. By combining Tables I and II, one can confirm the goodness of fit and robustness of our panel data models and its reliability to predict future recessions. 4 Results for balanced panel data are available upon request. 9 Table I – Estimation Results for Model 1 Slope (t-4) GDP (t-4) Constant Observations No. of countries Log Likelihood AIC BIC Pseudo R2 Probit -0.107** -0.113** (0.017) (0.018)** -0.086 (0.037) -1.397** -1.317** (0.061) (0.065) 2086 1959 32 32 -562,339 -541,564 1130,678 1091,128 1147,607 1113,449 0,36389 0,38739 Logit -0.230** -0.262** (0.042) (0.046) -0.152** (0.069) -2.433** -2.291** (0.124) (0.135) 2086 1959 32 32 -563,378 -541,753 1132,756 1091,507 1146,685 1113,827 0,362848 0,387305 MLE -0.020** -0.022** (0.003) (0.003) -0.013** (0.006) 0.095** 0.110** (0.008) (0.010) 2086 1959 32 32 -219,218 -243,773 446,4365 497,5462 469,0085 525,4472 -0,236 -0,37444 Note: * and ** indicate 90% and 95% of statistical significance level, respectively. In parenthesis are the standard deviations. AIC and BIC stand for Akaike and Bayesian information criteria, respectively. Table II – Power of Model 2 Cut-off Type I Error Type II Error Power Probit Without GDP With GDP 0,07 0,07 25,0% 25,3% 36,5% 36,3% 63,5% 63,7% Logit Without GDP With GDP 0,07 0,07 25,0% 25,3% 36,6% 36,2% 63,4% 63,8% MLE Without With GDP GDP 0,08 0,08 25,0% 25,3% 36,0% 36,2% 64,0% 63,8% Table III shows estimation results for Model II. All coefficients have proper signs and are statistically significant. Pseudo-R2 values in Table II also increase with the inclusion of lagged GDP, which can be understood as better fit of the model. According to Pseudo-R2, AIC and BIC one would prefer to rely on the model with lagged GDP. Results in Table IV show that the Power of the models decrease with the second definition of recession, to the range 56.9-58.4%. Therefore, the models are sensitive to the definition of recession. However, robustness of the models are again reaffirmed, since the Power is roughly the same for Logit, Probit and MLE. 10 Table III - Estimation results for Model 2 Slope (t-4) GDP (t-4) Constant Observations No. of countries Log Likelihood AIC BIC Pseudo R2 Probit -0.105** -0.113** (0.017) (0.017) -0.061* (0.034) -1.211** -1.139** (0.068) (0.072) 2086 1959 32 32 -712,16 -685,327 1430,32 1378,655 1447,249 1400,975 0,370526 0,394243 Logit -0.218** -0.253** (0.038) (0.052) -0.101* (0.061) -2.069** -1.938** (0.130) (0.139) 2086 1959 32 32 -713,012 -685,041 1432,042 1378,082 1448,971 1400,403 0,369962 0,394678 MLE -0.023** 0.026** (0.004) (0.004) -0.012* (0.006) 0.130** 0.147** (0.012) (0.131) 2086 1959 32 32 -540,678 -542,588 1089,355 1095,177 1111,927 1123,078 0,279072 0,276525 Note: * and ** indicate 90% and 95% of statistical significance level, respectively. In parenthesis are the standard deviations. AIC and BIC stand for Akaike and Bayesian information criteria, respectively. Table IV– Power of Model 2 Probit Cut-off Type I Error Type II Error Power Without GDP 0,10 25,1% 43,1% 56,9% With GDP 0,10 25,0% 41,6% 58,4% Logit Without GDP With GDP 0,10 0,10 25,1% 25,0% 43,1% 43,1% 56,9% 56,9% MLE Without With GDP GDP 0,11 0,12 25,1% 25,0% 43,1% 40,3% 56,9% 59,7% Figure 1 below plots the probability of a recession in the blue line, against vertical bars representing actual recessions. The red dashed line represents our cutoff value. It is interesting to note that the model we employed is successful in predicting recession one year ahead in countries where there exist long time series. Especially, it is striking that the recessions both in US and UK have been predicted successfully. In both country cases, there are some quarters when there was not an actual recession, and a recession is falsely estimated, i.e. false alarms, though. Mexico is another very good case where 8 recession period has been predicted very successfully. The latest recession period has been predicted on the edge, where the estimated value is roughly the cut-off value. The model is also very successful in the remainder of country cases. 11 0 Recession Recession Recession Slope Slope Slope Cutoff 1 Cutoff 0 0,02 Australia Austria 1 Belgium Canada 0 0 0,18 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 1 0,14 1 Cutoff 0 1 Cutoff 0,02 0 0 Finland 0,25 0 0 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 0,16 Q1-1991 Slope Q1-1990 1 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 0 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Recession Cutoff Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Slope 0,2 0,18 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 Q1-1991 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 1 Q1-1990 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Recession Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 0 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Figure 1. Recessions for Countries with Long Time Series (in-sample) UK 1 US 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 Recession Slope Germany Recession Slope Recession Recession Recession Slope Slope Slope Cutoff 0,04 0 1 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,06 0,04 Cutoff 0 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 Cutoff 1 0,2 0,15 0,05 Cutoff 0,02 0 France 0,25 0,2 0,08 0,15 0,1 Cutoff 0,05 0 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 0,18 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 Denmark 0,3 0,25 0,1 0,2 0,15 0,1 0,05 0 12 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 0 Recession Recession 0 Slope Slope Q1-2011 Q1-2010 Q1-2009 Q1-2008 Q1-2007 Q1-2006 Q1-2005 0 1 New Zealand Netherlands Cutoff 1 Norway Portugal Cutoff 1 0 0 0,18 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 1 0,25 1 0 0,12 0 Recession Slope 0,05 Spain Cutoff 0 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 0,2 Q1-1998 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 0 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Cutoff Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Slope Q1-2004 Q1-2003 Q1-2002 Q1-2001 Slope Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Recession Q1-2000 Q1-1999 Q1-1998 Q1-1997 Q1-1996 Q1-1995 Q1-1994 Q1-1993 Q1-1992 Q1-1991 Q1-1990 Recession Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 0 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 1,2 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 1 Mexico 1 Italy 1 0,8 0,6 0,4 Recession 1 Cutoff Slope Recession Slope Recession Slope Recession Slope Cutoff Cutoff 0 0,2 0,15 0,1 0 Cutoff 1 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 Cutoff 0,18 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 Sweden 0,18 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 Switzerland 0,18 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 Note: The figures above plot the probability of a recession against vertical lines representing actual recessions. Grey vertical lines are actual recessions where blue lines are estimated values. Red dash line is the cut – off value. If the blue line exceeds the cut – off value a year ahead of actual recession, then the model predicts recession successfully. Otherwise, if the blue line exceeds the cut – off value but there has not occurred an actual recession a year after, or vice versa, the model is unsuccessful. In the same way, Figure 2 below plots the probability of a recession in the blue line, against vertical bars representing actual recessions. The red dashed line represents our cutoff value. 13 Countries in Figure 2 are those with relatively short time series. Recessions in those countries are also predicted quite well. The model predictions for Portugal, Ireland, Iceland, Greece and Spain are quite satisfactory. For instance, the very recessions after 2009Q1 are very well predicted. Yet the remainder has not been so. The reason for this may come from the market sentiment toward the afore-mentioned countries, especially for Greece. As rumors during and after 2010, lead to heightened default risk. Short after the increased anxiety, the top level policy makers commented on the rumors about a possible Greek default and calmed down the markets. Furthermore, all Euro-zone officials gave implicit guarantees not to let Greece to default. Although the financial markets were calmed down thanks to officials’ announcement, the economic activity in Greece continued to slow down and recession occurred. We deem the slope of the yield curve in Greece has not been successful for this reason. Yet, recessions in Portugal, Ireland, Iceland and Spain is well predicted. Another interesting case is Chile. Chile has a quarterly data starting from 2005. Such a short time series would not allow predicting recession in the country if the analysis were carried out with times series. Yet, thanks to the panel data framework, recessions during 2008 – 2009 have been predicted quite well. There recession period have been successfully predicted. This holds also for Japan, Hungary, Ireland and the others whose data starts after 2000. Yield curve have been very successful in predicting recession. For instance, Hungary has five quarters of recession before and after 2009. Five quarters of recession have been successfully predicted. For Japan, the estimated values are below but one year ahead estimated values rises very near to cut – off values although not successful enough to predict recessions. The remaining country cases are also interesting but the comments are left to the readers due to lack of space. 14 0 Recession Recession Slope Recession Slope Slope Slope Cutoff 1 0 Cutoff 1 Cutoff 1 0 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 0,12 0 0,12 0 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Recession Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 1 Japan Hungary Chile Czech Republic 0 0 0,18 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 1 0,25 1 0,05 Cutoff Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 0 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Figure 2. Recessions for Countries with Short Time Series (in-sample) Greece 1 Iceland 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 Recession Spain Recession Slope Recession Slope Recession Slope Slope Cutoff 1 0,02 Cutoff 0 0,2 0,15 0,1 0 Cutoff 0,5 0,45 0,4 0,35 0,3 0,25 0,2 0,15 0,1 0,05 0 Portugal 0,1 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,08 0,06 0,06 0,04 0,04 0,02 0 0,25 0,2 0,15 0,1 Cutoff 0,05 0 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 15 0 Recession Slope Q1-2010 Q1-2009 Q1-2008 1 Cutoff 1 Cutoff 0 1 Cutoff Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Cutoff Slovak Republic Slovenia 0 0 0,18 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 1 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Slope Q1-2007 Slope Q1-2006 Slope Q1-2005 Q1-2004 Recession Q1-2003 Recession Q1-2002 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Recession Q1-2001 Q1-2000 Q1-1999 Q1-1998 Q1-1997 0 Q1-1996 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 0 Q1-1995 Q1-1994 Q1-1993 Q1-1992 Q1-1991 Q1-1990 0,16 0,02 0 0,35 0,05 0 0,35 0,05 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 Q1-1990 Q1-1991 Q1-1992 Q1-1993 Q1-1994 Q1-1995 Q1-1996 Q1-1997 Q1-1998 Q1-1999 Q1-2000 Q1-2001 Q1-2002 Q1-2003 Q1-2004 Q1-2005 Q1-2006 Q1-2007 Q1-2008 Q1-2009 Q1-2010 Q1-2011 1 Ireland 1 Korea 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0 Recession Slope Luksembourg Recession Slope Poland Recession Recession Cutoff Slope Slope 0,2 0,18 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 1 Israel 0,3 0,25 0,2 0,15 0,1 0 Cutoff 0,45 0,4 0,35 0,3 0,25 0,2 0,15 0,1 0,05 0 Korea 0,3 1 0,25 0,2 0,15 0,1 Cutoff Cutoff 0 0,2 0,18 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 0,16 0,14 0,12 0,1 0,08 0,06 0,04 0,02 0 Note: The figures above plot the probability of a recession against vertical lines representing actual recessions. Grey vertical lines are actual recessions where blue lines are estimated values. Red dash line is the cut – off value. If the blue line exceeds the cut – off value a year ahead of actual recession, then the model predicts recession successfully. Otherwise, if the blue line exceeds the cut – off value but there has not occurred an actual recession a year after, or vice versa, the model is unsuccessful. 16 5. Concluding Remarks In this paper the importance of the use of the term spread as predictor of recessions is confirmed for OECD countries. The results of this paper show that yield spread appears to contain useful information for predicting recessions. To arrive at this conclusion we define recession as two consecutive quarters of negative GDP growth. Models differentiate in terms of the usage of the definition of recession. Both two consecutive quarters adopted as recession in Model II and only the second quarter as recession in Model I. Variables are lagged by four quarters, to allow one to predict recessions one year ahead. In order to control for current dynamics of the economy we also controlled for the GDP growth, i.e. four quarter lagged GDP growth is added, in a separate estimation. We employed probit, logit and MLE with panel setting in estimation process. Model specification used our analysis is proposed by Estrella and Mishkin (1998). We found that the use of a lagged GDP growth variable helps to forecast historically recessions in the countries. We have taken into consideration of the accuracy of forecast specifically. We carried out an exercise of out-of-sample forecasting to investigate the outof-sample performance of the models especially for those countries who have shorter time series. The results present that the model proposed by Estrella and Mishkin (1998) have robust predictive power not only for the countries who have long time series but also the ones who have shorter time series. Panel data estimation also suggests great goodness of fit. The model estimations deliver power close to 65% with type I error of 25% with good statistical properties. As a suggestion for future research, we believe that this model can be applied to several other countries, even those with short time series. Furthermore, literature still lacks some results about how other yield curve factors can be applied in these binary models to predict recession. References Artis, M. J., Z.G. Kontolemis, and D. R. Osborn, 1997. "Business Cycles for G7 and European Countries" The Journal of Business, University of Chicago Press, Vol. 70, No: 2, 249-79. Afonso, A. and M. M. F. Martins, 2010. “Level, Slope, Curvature of the Sovereign Yield Curve, and Fiscal Behaviour” . ECB Working Paper No. 1276. Ahrens, R., 2002. “Predicting Recessions with Interest Rate Spreads: A Multicountry Regime-Switch Analysis.” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 21, No: 4, 519-37. Amemiya, T., 1981. “Qualitative Response Models: A Survey”. Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 19, 1483-1536. Anderson, N., F. Breedon, M. Deacon, A. Derry and G. Murphy, 1996. “Estimating And Interpreting The Yield Curve” Wiley, Chichester. Ang, A., and M. Piazzesi. 2001. "A No-Arbitrage Vector Autoregression of Term Structure Dynamics with Macroeconomic and Latent Variables." Working Paper. Columbia University. Forthcoming, Journal of Monetary Economics. 17 Artis, M. J., Z. G. Kontolemis, and D. R. Osborn, 1997. “Business Cycles for G7 and European Countries" Journal of Business, vol. 70, no. 2 Boritz, J. Efrim and Duane B. Kennedy, 1995. “Effectiveness of Neural Network Types for Prediction of Business Failure”. Expert Systems with Applications, Vol. 9, No: 4, 503-512. Arturo Estrella & Frederic S. Mishkin, 1998. "Predicting U.S. Recessions: Financial Variables As Leading Indicators," The Review of Economics and Statistics, MIT Press, vol. 80(1), 45-61. Baltagi, B. H., 2005. “Econometric Analysis of Panel Data”. John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, England. Dueker, M. J., 1997. “Strengthening the case for the yield curve as predictor of U.S. recessions", Federal Reserve Bank St. Louis Review, Vol. 79. pp. 41-51. Constantin Zopounidis and Michael Doumpos, 1999. “Business failure prediction using the UTADIS multicriteria analysis method”. The Journal of the Operational Research Society, vol. 50(11), 1138-1148. Estrella, A., and M. Trubin, 2006. “The Yield Curve as a Leading Indicator: Some Practical Issues” Federal Reserve Bank Of New York, Vol. 12, No:5. Evans, C., and D. Marshall. 2001. "Economic Determinants of the Nominal Treasury Yield Curve." FRB ChicagoWorking Paper 01-16. Harvey, C.R., 1988. "The Real term Structure and Consumption Growth " Journal of Financial Economics , Vol. 22, No. 2. 305-335. Hu, Z., 1993. “The yield curve and real activity," IMF Staff Paper, No.40, pp. 781-806, December. Karunaratne, N. D., 2002. “Predicting Australian Growth and Recession via the Yield curve” Economic Analysis & Policy. Vol. 32, No:2, 233-250. Maddala, G. S. “Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Economics”, Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press, 1983. Pace, P. D., 2012. “Gross Domestic Product Growth Predictions Through The Yield Spread: Time-Variation And Structural Breaks” International Journal of Finance and Economics (article first published online: 29 Feb 2012) Ross, K., and A. Ubide, 2001. “Mind the gap: What is the best measure of slack in the euro area? ", IMF Working Paper, December. Wu, T., 2001. "Monetary Policy and the Slope Factor in Empirical Term Structure Estimations." FRB San Francisco Working Paper 2002-07. 18 Appendix Table 1. List of Countries and Initial Data Dates GDP Country Australia Austria Belgium Canada Chile Czech Republic Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Iceland Ireland Israel Italy Japan Korea Luxembourg Mexico Netherlands New Zealand Norway Poland Portugal Slovak Republic Slovenia Spain Sweden Switzerland United Kingdom United States Start 1990Q1 1990Q1 1995Q2 1990Q1 1996Q1 1996Q2 1991Q2 1990Q1 1990Q1 1991Q2 2000Q2 1995Q2 1997Q2 2000Q2 1995Q2 1990Q1 1990Q1 1990Q1 1995Q2 1993Q2 1990Q1 1990Q1 1990Q1 1995Q2 1995Q2 1997Q2 1996Q1 1995Q2 1993Q2 1990Q1 1990Q1 1990Q1 End 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 Slope Start 1990Q1 1990Q1 1990Q1 1990Q1 2004Q3 2000Q2 1990Q1 1990Q1 1990Q1 1990Q1 2001Q1 1999Q2 1994Q1 1990Q1 1997Q1 1991Q2 2002Q2 2000Q4 1999Q1 1997Q1 1990Q1 1990Q1 1990Q1 2001Q1 1993Q3 2000Q4 2002Q2 1990Q1 1990Q1 1990Q1 1990Q1 1990Q1 End 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 2011Q1 19