Lecture # 08 The Theory of Demand (conclusion) Lecturer: Martin Paredes 1. Individual Demand Curves 2. Income and Substitution Effects and the Slope of Demand 3. Applications: the Work-Leisure Trade-off 4. Consumer Surplus 5. Constructing Aggregate Demand 2 Definition: The income-consumption curve of good X is the set of optimal baskets for every possible income level. Assumes all other variables remain constant. 3 Y (units) I=40 U1 0 10 X (units) 4 Y (units) I=68 I=40 U1 0 10 18 U2 X (units) 5 Y (units) I=92 I=68 U3 I=40 U1 0 10 18 U2 24 X (units) 6 Y (units) I=92 Income consumption curve I=68 U3 I=40 U1 0 10 18 U2 24 X (units) 7 Note: The points on the income-consumption curve can be graphed as points on a shifting demand curve. 8 Y (units) I=40 0 Income consumption curve U1 10 X (units) PX $2 I=40 10 X (units) 9 Y (units) I=68 I=40 0 Income consumption curve U2 U1 10 18 X (units) PX $2 I=68 I=40 10 18 X (units) 10 Y (units) I=92 I=68 I=40 0 U3 Income consumption curve U2 U1 10 18 X (units) 24 PX $2 I=68 I=40 10 18 24 I=92 X (units) 11 The income-consumption curve for good X can also be written as the quantity consumed of good X for any income level. This is the individual’s Engel curve for good X. 12 I (€) 40 0 10 X (units) 13 I (€) 68 40 0 10 18 X (units) 14 I (€) 92 68 40 0 10 18 24 X (units) 15 I (€) Engel Curve 92 68 40 0 10 18 24 X (units) 16 Note: When the slope of the income-consumption curve is positive, then the slope of the Engel curve is also positive. 17 Normal Good: If the income consumption curve shows that the consumer purchases more of good X as her income rises, good X is a normal good. Equivalently, if the slope of the Engel curve is positive, the good is a normal good. 18 Inferior Good: If the income consumption curve shows that the consumer purchases less of good X as her income rises, good X is a inferior good. Equivalently, if the slope of the Engel curve is negative, the good is a normal good. Note: A good can be normal over some ranges of income, and inferior over others. 19 Y (units) Example: Backward Bending Engel Curve I=200 0 U1 • 13 X (units) I (€) 200 • 13 X (units) 20 Y (units) Example: Backward Bending Engel Curve I=300 I=200 0 U1 U2 • • 13 18 X (units) I (€) 300 200 • 13 • 18 X (units) 21 Y (units) U3 I=300 I=200 0 Example: Backward Bending Engel Curve I=400 U1 • • • U2 13 16 18 X (units) I (€) • 400 300 200 • • 13 16 18 X (units) 22 Y (units) U3 I=300 I=200 0 Example: Backward Bending Engel Curve I=400 U1 • • • Income consumption curve U2 13 16 18 X (units) I (€) • 400 300 200 • • Engel Curve 13 16 18 X (units) 23 There are two effects: 1. Income Effect 2. Substitution Effect 24 Definition: When the price of good X falls, purchasing power rises. This is called the income effect of a change in price. It assumes all else remain constant The income effect may be: 1. Positive (normal good) 2. Negative (inferior good). 25 Definition: When the price of good X falls, good X becomes cheaper relative to good Y. This change in relative prices alone causes the consumer to adjust his consumption basket. This effect is called the substitution effect. It assumes all else remain constant The substitution effect is always negative 26 Usually, a move along a demand curve will be composed of both effects. Let’s analyze both effects for the cases of: Normal good Inferior good 27 Y Example: Normal Good: Income and Substitution Effects BL1 has slope -PX1/PY A • U1 0 XA X 28 Y Example: Normal Good: Income and Substitution Effects BL2 has slope -PX2/PY A • C • U2 U1 0 XA XC X 29 Y Example: Normal Good: Income and Substitution Effects A • C • B 0 XA XB • U2 BLd has slope -PX2/PY U1 XC X 30 Y Example: Normal Good: Income and Substitution Effects Substitution Effect: XB-XA A • C • B 0 XA XB • U2 U1 XC X 31 Y Example: Normal Good: Income and Substitution Effects Substitution Effect: XB-XA Income Effect: XC-XB A • C • B 0 XA XB • U2 U1 XC X 32 Y Example: Normal Good: Income and Substitution Effects Substitution Effect: XB-XA Income Effect: XC-XB Overall Effect: XC-XA A • C • B 0 XA XB • U2 U1 XC X 33 Y Example: Inferior Good: Income and Substitution Effects BL1 has slope -PX1/PY A • U1 0 XA X 34 Y Example: Inferior Good: Income and Substitution Effects • C A • U2 BL2 has slope -PX2/PY U1 0 XA XC X 35 Y Example: Inferior Good: Income and Substitution Effects • C A • • B 0 XA XC XB U2 BLd has slope -PX2/PY U1 X 36 Y Example: Inferior Good: Income and Substitution Effects Substitution Effect: XB-XA • C A • • B 0 XA XC XB U2 U1 X 37 Y Example: Inferior Good: Income and Substitution Effects Substitution Effect: XB-XA Income Effect: XC-XB • C A • • B 0 XA XC XB U2 U1 X 38 Y Example: Inferior Good: Income and Substitution Effects Substitution Effect: XB-XA Income Effect: XC-XB Overall Effect: XC-XA • C A • • B 0 XA XC XB U2 U1 X 39 Theoretically, it is possible that, for an inferior good, the income effect dominates the substitution effect A Giffen good is a good that is so inferior, that the net effect of a decrease in the price of that good, all else constant, is a decrease in consumption of that good. 40 Y Example: Giffen Good: Income and Substitution Effects BL1 has slope -PX1/PY A • U1 0 XA X 41 Y Example: Giffen Good: Income and Substitution Effects • C U2 BL2 has slope -PX2/PY A • U1 0 XC XA X 42 Y Example: Giffen Good: Income and Substitution Effects • C U2 A • • BLd has slope -PX2/PY B 0 XC XA XB U1 X 43 Y Example: Giffen Good: Income and Substitution Effects • C Substitution Effect: XB-XA Income Effect: XC-XB Overall Effect: XC-XA U2 A • • B 0 XC XA XB U1 X 44 Notes: For Giffen goods, demand does not slope down. For the income effect to be large enough to offset the substitution effect, the good would have to represent a very large proportion of the budget. 45 Example: Finding Income and Substitution Effects Suppose a Quasilinear Utility: U(X,Y) = 2X0.5 + Y => MUX = 1/X0.5 PY = € 1 I = € 10 MUY = 1 46 1. Suppose PX = € 0.50 • Tangency condition: MUX = PX _1_ = 0.5 XA = 4 MUY PY X0.5 • Budget constraint: PX . X + PY . Y = I YA = 8 • Utility level: U* = 2 (4)0.5 + 8 = 12 47 2. Suppose PX = € 0.20 • Tangency condition: MUX = PX _1_ = 0.2 XC = 25 MUY PY X0.5 • Budget constraint: PX . X + PY . Y = I YC = 5 • Utility level: U* = 2 (25)0.5 + 5 = 15 48 3. What are the substitution and income effects that result from the decline in PX? • Find the basket B that gives a utility level of U = 12 at prices PX = € 0.20 and PY = € 1 49 Y Substitution Effect: XB-XA Income Effect: XC-XB Overall Effect: XC-XA A • C • B 0 XA=4 XB • U2=15 U1=12 XC=25 X 50 • Tangency condition: MUX = PX _1_ = 0.2 XB = 25 MUY PY X0.5 • Utility constraint: U* = 2 (25)0.5 + Y = 12 YB = 2 • Then: • Substitution Effect: • Income Effect: XB - XA = 25 - 4 = 21 XC - XB = 25 - 25 = 0 51 The individual’s demand curve can be interpreted as the maximum amount such individual is willing to pay for a good In turn, the market price determines the amount the individual actually pays for all the units consumed. 52 Definition: The consumer surplus is the net economic benefit to the consumer due to a purchase of a good It is measured by the difference between the maximum amount the consumer is willing to pay and the actual amount he pays for it. The area under the ordinary demand curve and above the market price provides a measure of consumer surplus. 53 Example: Consumer Surplus • Consider a Demand function: • Suppose PX = € 3 Q = 40 - 4PX • What is the consumer surplus? • First, at price PX = € 3 => Q = 28 54 PX Example: Consumer Surplus 10 X = 40 - 4PX ... Demand 40 X 55 PX Example: Consumer Surplus 10 3 28 40 X 56 Example: Consumer Surplus PX 10 Area = (0.5) (10-3) (28) = 98 G 3 28 40 X 57 PX 10 Example: Consumer Surplus What if PX = € 2? Area = (0.5) (10-2) (32) = 128 3 2 28 32 40 X 58 Definition: The market demand function is the horizontal sum of the demands of the individual consumers. In other words, the market demand is obtained by adding the quantities demanded by the individuals at each price and plotting this total quantity for all possible prices. 59 Example: Suppose we have two consumers, as shown below: P 10 P Q = 10 - p P Q = 20 - 5p 4 Consumer 1 Q Consumer 2 Q Q Market demand 60 1. Individual ordinary (uncompensated) demands are derived from the utility maximization problem of the consumer. 2. The optimal consumption basket for a utility maximizing consumer changes as prices change due to both income and substitution effects. 61 3. If income effects are strong enough, a price rise may result in increased consumption for an optimizing consumer. 4. Consumer surplus measures the net economic benefit of a purchase. 5. Market demand is the horizontal sum of the individual consumer demands for a particular good. 62