The Efficiency Role of Government • When a well-functioning, perfectly competitive market is permitted to reach its equilibrium, the outcome is efficient – No opportunities for mutual gain remain unexploited – Any government intervention that changes the market quantity (say, a price ceiling or a price floor) will create inefficiency—a welfare loss • But government can—and does—contribute to the economic efficiency of markets – Provides infrastructure that permits markets to function • Physical infrastructure—bridges, airports, waterways, and buildings • Institutional infrastructure—laws, courts, and regulatory agencies – Stepping in when markets are not working properly • When they leave Pareto improvements unexploited and therefore fail to achieve economic efficiency 1 The Institutional Infrastructure of a Market Economy • Americans take their institutional infrastructure almost completely for granted • In some countries – Police are more likely to steal from citizens than to protect them from thievery – People have no effective rights to their own property – If a person is injured by a drunk driver, there may be no system for compensating her or punishing the drive • In nations with highly developed and stable legal infrastructures, such incidents are the exception • When countries are divided into three groups, according to the quality of their institutional infrastructure – There is a strong relation between infrastructure and output per worker 2 Average Output per Worker Figure 8: Government Infrastructure and Output per Worker $18,000 14,000 10,000 6,000 2,000 Low Medium High Quality of Infrastructure 3 The Legal System: Criminal Law • The backbone of a market economy’s institutional infrastructure is the legal system • Criminal law – While criminal law has important moral and ethical dimensions • Central economic function is to limit exchanges to voluntary ones – By making most involuntary exchanges illegal, criminal law helps to channel our energies into exchanges and productive activities that benefit all parties involved— Pareto improvements • In this way, criminal law contributes to economic efficiency 4 Property Law • Property law gives people precisely defined, enforceable rights over things they own • When property rights are poorly defined – Much time and energy are wasted in disputes about ownership • People spend time trying to capture resources from others – Time that could have been spent producing valuable goods and services • Property law contributes to economic efficiency by increasing total production – Raising total benefits that markets can provide by reducing disputes about property – Channeling resources into production 5 Contract Law • In countries in which contract law is less well defined or less strictly enforced, investors would worry that they would not be able to collect their share • A contract is a mutual promise – Often one party does something first and the other party promises to do something later • Contracts play a special role in a market economy – Without them, only Pareto improvements involving simultaneous exchange could take place • You get a bag of apples from a farmer and simultaneously hand over some money 6 Contract Law • Contracts enable us to make exchanges that take place over time and in which one person must act first – In this way, contracts help society enjoy the full benefits of specialization and exchange • Legal enforcement of contacts is not the only force that makes people keep promises – Parents, religious organizations, and schools teach people that keeping promises is a moral obligation – A reputation for failing to keep promises would be harmful to a business or a person • While socialization and concern over reputation are important, contracts and the infrastructure for enforcing them play vital role in making economy more efficient • Because of contract law, people are more willing to take a chance with a new business – Since they know that they have a law behind them if new business reneges on a deal 7 Tort Law • Deals with interactions among strangers or people not linked by contracts • Specifically, a tort is a wrongful act—such as manufacturing an unsafe product—that causes harm to someone, and for which the injured person can seek remedy in court – Tort law defines types of harm for which someone can seek legal remedy • And what sorts of compensation the injured person can expect • When people and business are held responsible for injuries they cause, they act more carefully • Also protects against fraud – In which a seller of something—a product, a business, shares of stock—lies to the buyer in order to make the sale 8 Antitrust Law • Designed to prevent business from making agreements or engaging in other behavior that limits competition and harms consumers – Operates in three areas • Agreements among competitors – U.S. antitrust law—expressed in Section 1 of Sherman Act—prohibits “contracts, combinations, or conspiracies” among competing firms that would harm consumers by raising prices • Monopolization – Section 2 of Sherman Act Makes it illegal to monopolize or attempt to monopolize a market • Mergers – In a merger, two firms combine to form one new firm » The result is to increase the danger of higher prices from oligopoly or monopoly » Mergers of this type are often blocked by U.S. government based on Section 7 of Clayton Act 9 Regulation • Important part of the institutional infrastructure that supports a market economy – Under regulation, a government agency—such as the Food and Drug Administration (FDA), the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), or a state public utilities commission—has power to direct business to take specific actions • In addition to protecting public safety and health – Regulation is also used to help markets function more efficiently • Regulation differs from use of legal procedures in a fundamental way – Regulators reach deep into the operations of business to tell them what to do • While legal procedures typically result in fines or other penalties if businesses do something wrong 10 Law and Regulation in Perspective • Invisible hand of market system cannot operate on its own – Legal system, along with regulatory agencies, creates an environment in which invisible hand can do its job – Almost every Pareto improvement that we can think of relies on legal and regulatory infrastructure • But what about cases where law and regulation don’t seem to be working perfectly? – Does this mean that our institutional infrastructure is failing us? 11 Law and Regulation in Perspective • Yes…and no – While instances like these are never welcome, society has chosen not to eliminate them entirely – Must balance benefits—safer products, reduced crime—against costs • A legal and regulatory system that ensured the complete elimination of crime, unsafe products, and other unwelcome activities would be less efficient than a system that tolerated some amount of these activities – An efficient infrastructure must consider the costs, as well as the benefits, of achieving our legal and regulatory goals 12 Market Failures • Another vitally important role for government – To intervene in situations of market failure • When a market equilibrium—even with the proper institutional support—is economically inefficient • General types of market failures to which economists have devoted a lot of attention – Monopoly power – Externalities – Public goods • While economists and policy-makers agree in theory on what causes a market failure – Dealing with real-world market failures remains one of the most controversial aspects of government policy 13 Monopoly and Monopoly Power • A firm has monopoly power when it can influence the price that it charges for its product – A market with just one seller, or a few oligopolists who cooperate and behave as a monopoly, is a more serious market failure • Monopoly and imperfectly competitive markets— in which firms charge a single price greater than marginal cost—are generally inefficient – Price is too high, and output is too low, to maximize net benefits in market • What can government do to make this monopoly market more efficient? 14 Figure 9: The Welfare Loss from Monopoly 1. A monopoly charges a higher price than a competitive market . . . MC Dollars 3. The result is a welfare loss . . . $22 $19 2. and produces a lower quantity. E 4. from not producing the efficient quantity, at point E. MR 2,500 D Number of Lessons per Week 4,000 15 Anti-trust Law as a Remedy • In the case of the guitar-lesson monopoly, there may be a solution – Since this market would function very well under competitive conditions, the government could use anti-trust law to break the monopoly into several competing firms • But breaking up a monopoly would not make sense when the market would perform even worse with more competition • Monopolies that arise from patents and copyrights, provide an incentive for artistic creations and scientific discovery • Monopoly power that arises from network externalities offers benefits that would be hard to achieve under more competitive conditions • When a monopoly arises as a natural monopoly – Using anti-trust law to break it up or even to prevent its formation in the first place is a poor remedy 16 The Special Case of Natural Monopoly • A natural monopoly exists when, due to economies of scale, one firm can produce for the entire market at a lower cost per unit than can two or more firms – If government steps aside, such a market will naturally evolve toward monopoly • If breaking up a natural monopoly is not advisable, what can government do to bring us closer to economic efficiency? – One option is public ownership and operation • Public takeover of private business is rare, except when certain conditions are present – That leaves one other option • Regulation 17 Figure 10: Regulating A Natural Monopoly Dollars Unregulated monopoly $60 A Efficient production (requires subsidy) C $29 $15 "Fair rate of return" production F MR 50,000 B LRATC MC D 100,000 85,000 Number of Households Served 18 Regulation of Natural Monopoly • Under regulation, a government agency digs deep into the operations of a business and takes some of the firm’s decisions under its own control – In the case of a natural monopoly, regulators are interested in achieving economic efficiency, which they do by telling the firm what price it can charge • At first glance, you might think that natural monopoly regulators have an easy job • Unfortunately, it’s not that easy – There is the matter of information • Regulators must be able to trace out firm’s MC curve as well as market demand curve 19 Regulation of Natural Monopoly • Even with perfect information about monopolist’s cost and demand curves, regulators have a serious problem – Look again at Figure 7—notice that MC curve lies everywhere below LRATC curve – Problem for regulators • If they set the efficient price of $15 so that buyers demand efficient quantity of 100,000, firm’s cost per unit is greater than $15 – Firm will suffer a loss – In long-run, it will go out of business 20 Regulation of Natural Monopoly • Leaves regulatory agency with two alternatives – Set prices to MC and subsidize the monopoly from the general budget, to make up for the loss • In practice, however, regulators in market economies around the world have usually chosen a different solution – Regulators determine a price that gives owners a “fair rate of return” for funds they’ve put into the monopoly – Should give monopoly what economists call normal profit • Profit just high enough to cover all of the owners’ opportunity costs, including the foregone interest of their own funds • What price will accomplish this? – A fair rate of return is already built into LRATC curve – This strategy—called average cost pricing—is the most common solution chosen by regulators of natural monopolies 21 Regulation of Natural Monopoly • With average cost pricing, regulators strive to set price equal to cost per unit where LRATC curve crosses demand curve – At this price, the natural monopoly makes zero economic profit • Which provides its owners with a fair rate of return, and keeps the monopoly in business • Average cost pricing is not a perfect solution – Does not quite make the market efficient – Provides little or no incentive for the natural monopoly to economize on capital • Tendency of regulated natural monopolies to overinvest in capital is known as the Averch-Johnson effect, after the two economists who first explained it • Averch-Johnson effect is a specific example of a more general idea – When a firm is not striving to maximize profit (in this case, because the government is guaranteeing a specific rate of return) » Firm need not economize on costs 22