Chapter 3 Market Structure and Market Power 1 Introduction • Industries have very different structures – numbers and size distributions of firms • ready-to-eat breakfast cereals: high concentration Top 4 firms account for about 80% of sales • Games and toys (not including video games): The largest 4 firms accounts for 35% to 45% • How best to measure market structure – summary measure (Figure 3-1) – concentration curve is possible – preference is for a single number – concentration ratio or – Herfindahl-Hirschman index (HHI)= the sum of the squares of the market shares of all of the firms in the2 industry. Measure of concentration • Compare two different measures of concentration: Firm Rank Market Share (%) Squared Market Share 1 25 625 2 25 625 3 25 625 4 5 25 5 5 25 6 5 25 7 5 25 8 5 25 Concentration Index CR4 = 80 HHI = 2,000 3 • Concentration index is affected by, e.g. merger Firm Rank Market Share (%) 1 Assume that firms 2 4 and 5 decide to merge 3 25 4 5 5 6 7 } 25 625 Market shares 625 change 25 625 5 The Concentration Index changes 8 Concentration Index Squared Market Share } 10 25 25 5 25 5 25 5 25 CR4 = 80 85 } HHI = 2,000 100 2,050 4 3.1.1 What is a market? • No clear consensus:To use CR4 or HHI as an overall measure of a market’s structure, we need to be able to identify a well-defined market first. Example 1, the market for automobiles • should we include light trucks; pick-ups SUVs? Example 2, the market for soft drinks • what are the competitors for Coca Cola and Pepsi? – With whom do McDonalds and Burger King compete? • Presumably define a market by closeness in substitutability of the commodities involved – how close is close? 5 Market definition (cont.) – how homogeneous do commodities have to be? • Does wood compete with plastic? Rayon with wool? • Definition is important – without consistency concept of a market is meaningless – need indication of competitiveness of a market: affected by definition – public policy: decisions on mergers can turn on market definition • Staples/Office Depot merger rejected on market definition • Coca Cola expansion turned on market definition • Standard approach has some consistency – based upon industrial data – substitutability is production not consumption (ease of data 6 collection) Market definition (cont.) • Government statistical sources Census Bureau: Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) • The measure of concentration varies across countries • Use of production-based statistics has limitations: – can put in different industries products that are in the same market • The international dimension is important – Boeing/McDonnell-Douglas merger – relevant market for automobiles, oil, hairdressing 7 Market definition (cont.) • Geography is important – barrier to entry if the product is expensive to transport – but customers can move • what is the relevant market for a beach resort or ski-slope? • Vertical relations between firms are important – most firms make intermediate rather than final goods – firm has to make a series of make-or-buy choices – upstream and downstream production – measures of concentration may assign firms at different stages to the same industry • do vertical relations affect underlying structure? 8 Market definition (cont.) – Firms at different stages may also be assigned to different industries • bottlers of soft drinks: low concentration • suppliers of sift drinks: high concentration • the bottling sector is probably not competitive. • In sum: market definition poses real problems – existing methods represent a reasonable compromise 9 • Measuring Market Power • The Lerner Index (LI) is one way to measure how well a market performs from an efficiency point of view. The LI measures how far the outcome is from the competitive ideal in the following way: • LI= (P-MC)/P • Because LI directly reflects the discrepancy between price and marginal cost it captures much of what we are interested in when it comes to the exercise of market power. • For a competitive firm, LI is zero since such a firm prices at marginal cost. • For a pure monopolist, on the other hand, the LI can be shown to be the inverse of the elasticity of demand-the less elastic the demand the greater is the price-marginal cost distortion. To see this, a monopolist’s MR = P+(dp/dQ)*Q 10 • For profit maximization: MR=MC • So, P + (dP/dQ)*Q = MC. • Rearranging and dividing by price P, we obtain (P-MC)/P = - (dP/dQ)*(Q/P) = 1/ elasticity of the demand. • Note that the LI can never exceed 1 and that it can only achieve this maximum value if MC=0. • With more than one but not “many” firms, the Lerner Index is more complicated: need to average. – suppose the goods are homogeneous so all firms sell at the same price LI = P-SsiMCi P 11 Assume two identical firms each with costs AC1 $/unit MC MCA AC1 MC´A If they are to produce a given output at lowest cost, they must operate at the same marginal cost Why? Assume firm A is operating at MCA and firm B is operating at MCB Transferring one unit of output from A to B lowers total cost MC´B MCB QB QA Quantity If the two firms operate at the same marginal cost they must produce identical outputs Suppose not: firm A has output QA and firm B has output QB Transferring one unit of output from A to B lowers total cost 12 It follows that AC2 represents the lowest possible average cost if output is produced by two firms: AC2 is obtained by adding AC1 to itself horizontally AC1 is average cost if output is produced by Now assume that one firm. output is produced by If total output is 2Q1 then two firms. $/unit we know that each firm has This market is a to produce Q1 and average natural cost is AC1 If total output is 2Q2 then monopoly up to AC1 we know that each AC firm has 2 output QM even to produce Q2 and average AC1 though this is cost is AC2 greater than If total output is 2Q* then AC2 MES Q*: it is we know that each firm has AC* less costly for to produce Q* and average output to be cost is AC* produced by one rather than Q1 2Q1 Q* QM 2Q* Quantity two firms: Q2 2Q 2 subadditivity 13 Chapter 4 Technology and Cost 14 The Single-Product Firm • Profit-maximizing firm must solve a related problem – minimize the cost of producing a given level of output – combines two features of the firm • production function: how inputs are transformed into output Assume that there are n inputs at levels x1 for the first, x2 for the second,…, xn for the nth. The production function, assuming a single output, is written: Q = F(x1, x2, x3,…,xn) • cost function: relationship between output choice and production costs. Derived by finding input combination that minimizes cost n Minimize S wixi subject to F(x1, x2, x3,…,xn) = Q1 i=1 15 Now assume that input 1 becomes cheaper • Review input choice: one This makes the isocost output and two inputs lines less steep The production function Cost of producing can be illustrated as a set of output Q1 is minimized isoquants, one for x2 by finding the point each level of output The input choice where an isocost line is x11 of input 1 is tangent to the The cost-minimizing input and x12 of Q1 isoquant combination changes input 2 x12 More of input 1 is used and less of input 2 x2 The new costminimizing point 2 x11 x21 Production cost can be Q2 illustrated as a set of isocost lines, with slope Q1 w1/w2. The lower the Q0 isocost line, the lower the cost. x1 16 • This analysis has interesting implications – different input mix across • time: as capital becomes relatively cheaper • space: difference in factor costs across countries • Analysis gives formal definition of the cost function – denoted C(Q): total cost of producing output Q – average cost = AC(Q) = C(Q)/Q – marginal cost: • additional cost of producing one more unit of output. • Slope of the total cost function • formally: MC(Q) = dC(Q)/d(Q) 17 Cost curves: an illustration Typical average and marginal cost curves $/unit Relationship between AC and MC MC If MC < AC then AC is falling AC If MC > AC then AC is rising MC = AC at the minimum of the AC curve Quantity 18 Economies of scale • Definition: average costs fall with an increase in output • Represented by the scale economy index AC(Q) S= MC(Q) • S > 1: economies of scale • S < 1: diseconomies of scale • S is the inverse of the elasticity of cost with respect to outputdC(Q) dQ dC(Q) C(Q) MC(Q) 1 hC = C(Q) Q = dQ Q = AC(Q) = S 19 An example Average cost is taken as the mean of 145 and 136 • Take a simple example Output 5 6 11 12 Total Cost Average Cost Marginal Cost Scale Economy ($) ($) ($) Index 725 145 140.5 91 140.5/91 = 1.54 816 136 1331 121 122.5 157 122.5/157 = 0.78 1488 124 } } Percentage increase in cost of increasing output from 5 to 6 Percentage increase in output Check the relationship to the elasticity of the cost curve 816 - 725 = 11.8% (816+725)/2 6-5 = 18.2% (6+5)/2 hC = 11.8/18.2 = 0.65 and 1/ hC = 1/0.65 = 1.54 20 • Minimum efficient scale: – output at which economies of scale are first exhausted $/unit AC1 AC2 MES1 MES2 With average cost curve AC1 minimum efficient scale is MES1 With average cost curve AC2 minimum efficient scale is MES2 Quantity 21 Natural monopoly • If the extent of the market is less than MES then the market is a natural monopoly: S > 1 in such a market. • But a natural monopoly can exist even if S < 1. Economies of scale • Sources of economies of scale – “the 60% rule”: capacity related to volume while cost is related to surface area – product specialization and the division of labor – “economies of mass reserves”: economize on inventory, maintenance, repair 22 – indivisibilities Indivisibilities • Some inputs can be employed only in indivisible units VC $ – transport routes – major items of capital equipment • Three implications: – cost is “lumpy” or fixed at F1 – maximum rated capacity Q1 – average fixed cost F1/Q falls with output up to rated capacity • Other inputs vary with output: variable costs • Average total costs exhibit economies of scale over some range F1 FC Quantity Q1 $ ATC AVC AFC Quantity Q1 23 • If projected output is greater than current capacity install higher-rated capacity equipment or add additional capacity • It may be cheaper to have spare capacity than operate up to capacity $/unit If projected output is greater AC1 AC2 than Q* it is cheaper to install higher capacity even though there is spare capacity Consistent with evidence on excess capacity: see Federal Statistics Q* Q1 Q2 Quantity 24 Fixed costs, indivisibilities and sunk costs • Indivisibilities make scale of entry an important strategic decision: – enter large with large-scale indivisibilities: heavy overhead – enter small with smaller-scale cheaper equipment: low overhead • Some indivisible inputs can be redeployed – aircraft • Other indivisibilities are highly specialized with little value in other uses – market research expenditures – rail track between two destinations • The latter are sunk costs: nonrecoverable if production stops • Fixed costs and sunk costs affect market structure by 25 affecting entry Multi-Product Firms • Many firms make multiple products – Ford, General Motors, 3M etc. • What do we mean by costs and output in these cases? • How do we define average costs for these firms? – – – – total cost for a two-product firm is C(Q1, Q2) marginal cost for product 1 is MC1 = C(Q1,Q2)/Q1 but average cost cannot be defined fully generally need a more restricted definition: ray average cost 26 Ray average cost • Assume that a firm makes two products, 1 and 2 with the quantities Q1 and Q2 produced in a constant ratio of 2:1. • Then total output Q can be defined implicitly from the equations Q1 = 2Q/3 and Q2 = Q/3 • More generally: assume that the two products are produced in the ratio 1/2 (with 1 + 2 = 1). • Then total output is defined implicitly from the equations Q1 = 1Q and Q2 = 2Q • Ray average cost is then defined as: RAC(Q) = C(1Q, 2Q) Q 27 An example of ray average costs • Assume that the cost function is: C(Q1, Q2) = 10 + 25Q1 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2 • Marginal costs for each product are: MC1 = MC2 = C(Q1,Q2) Q1 C(Q1,Q2) Q2 = 25 - = 30 - 3Q2 2 3Q1 2 28 • Ray average costs: assume 1 = 2 = 0.5 C(Q1, Q2) = 10 + 25Q1 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2 Q1 = 0.5Q; Q2 = 0.5Q RAC(Q) = = C(0.5Q, 0.5Q) Q 10 + 25Q/2+ 30Q/2 - 3Q2/8 Q Now assume 1 = 0.75; 2 = 0.25 C(0.75Q, 0.25Q) RAC(Q) = Q 10 + 75Q/4+ 30Q/4 - 9Q2/32 = Q 10 55 + = Q 2 3Q 8 10 105 + = Q 4 9Q 32 29 Economies of scale and multiple products • Definition of economies of scale with a single product C(Q) AC(Q) S= MC(Q) = Q.MC(Q) • Definition of economies of scale with multiple products C(Q1,Q2,…,Qn) S= MC1Q1 + MC2Q2 + … + MCnQn • This is by analogy to the single product case – relies on the implicit assumption that output proportions are fixed – so we are looking at ray average costs in using this 30 definition The example once again C(Q1, Q2) = 10 + 25Q1 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2 MC1 = 25 - 3Q2/2 ; MC2 = 30 - 3Q1/2 Substitute into the definition of S: C(Q1,Q2,…,Qn) S= MC1Q1 + MC2Q2 + … + MCnQn = 10 + 25Q1 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2 25Q1 - 3Q1Q2/2 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2 It should be obvious in this case that S > 1 This cost function exhibits global economies of scale 31 Economies of Scope • Formal definition SC = C(Q1, 0) + C(0 ,Q2) - C(Q1, Q2) C(Q1, Q2) • The critical value in this case is SC = 0 – SC < 0 : no economies of scope; SC > 0 : economies of scope. • Take the example: 10 + 25Q1 + 10 + 30Q2 - (10 + 25Q1 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2) SC = >0 10 + 25Q1 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2 32 Economies of Scope (cont.) • Sources of economies of scope • shared inputs – same equipment for various products – shared advertising creating a brand name – marketing and R&D expenditures that are generic • cost complementarities – – – – – producing one good reduces the cost of producing another oil and natural gas oil and benzene computer software and computer support retailing and product promotion 33 Flexible Manufacturing • Extreme version of economies of scope • Changing the face of manufacturing • “Production units capable of producing a range of discrete products with a minimum of manual intervention” – – – – Benetton Custom Shoe Levi’s Mitsubishi • Production units can be switched easily with little if any cost penalty – requires close contact between design and manufacturing 34 Flexible Manufacturing (cont.) • Take a simple model based on a spatial analogue. – There is some characteristic that distinguishes different varieties of a product • sweetness or sugar content • color • texture – This can be measured and represented as a line – Individual products can be located on this line in terms of the quantity of the characteristic that they possess – One product is chosen by the firm as its base product – All other products are variants on the base product 35 Flexible Manufacturing (cont.) • An illustration: soft drinks that vary in sugar content (Diet) 0 Low (LX) (Super) 0.5 1 High Each product is located on the line in terms of the amount of the characteristic it has This is the characteristics line 36 The example (cont.) (Diet) 0 Low (LX) (Super) 0.5 1 High • Assume that the process is centered on LX as base product. A switching cost s is incurred in changing the process to either of the other products. There are additional marginal costs of making Diet or Super - from adding or removing sugar. These are r per unit of “distance” between LX and the other product. There are shared costs F: design, packaging, equipment. 37 The example (cont.) • In the absence of shared costs there would be specialized firms. • Shared costs introduce economies of scope. m Total costs are: C(zj, qj) = F + (m - 1)s + S [(c + rzj - z1)qj] j=1 If production is 100 units of each product: one product per firm with three firms C3 = 3F + 300c one firm with all three products C1 = F + 2s + 300c + 100r C1 < C3 if 2s + 100r < 2F F > 50r + s This implies a constraint on set-up costs, switching costs and marginal costs for multi-product production to be preferred. 38 Economies of scale and scope • Economies of scale and scope affect market structure but cannot be looked at in isolation. • They must be considered relative to market size. • Should see concentration decline as market size increases • For example, entry to the medical profession is going to be more extensive in Chicago than in Oxford, Miss 39 Network Externalities • Market structure is also affected by the presence of network externalities – willingness to pay by a consumer increases as the number of current consumers increase • telephones, fax, Internet, Windows software • utility from consumption increases when there are more current consumers • These markets are likely to contain a small number of firms – even if there are limited economies of scale and scope 40 The Role of Policy • Government can directly affect market structure – by limiting entry • taxi medallions in Boston and New York • airline regulation – through the patent system – by protecting competition e.g. through the Robinson-Patman Act 41