PLEASE NOTE The Australian Government is undertaking further design work on a possible national Energy Savings Initiative (ESI). Reports, such as the one which is provided below, have been prepared by consultants to assist with this work. However: • no decision has been made about whether a national ESI will be introduced; • the report should not be interpreted as reflecting Government thinking on the design of a possible national ESI (for example, comments by consultants about the eligibility of activities for creating certificates should not be interpreted as a proposed list of eligible activities under a possible national scheme); and • the report should not be interpreted as a commitment by Government to a policy or course of action. Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options A Report for the Energy Savings Initiative Secretariat 22 March 2012 Australian Government Disclaimer This report was prepared by NERA Economic Consulting and Oakley Greenwood for the Commonwealth of Australia as represented by the Department of Resources, Energy and Tourism, as part of the Australian Government’s efforts to investigate the cost and benefits of a possible national Energy Savings Initiative. The report includes the views and opinions of third parties and does not necessarily reflect the views of the Commonwealth of Australia or any Australian State or Territory Government, or indicate a commitment to a particular policy or course of action. This report includes the opinions of, and analysis by, NERA Economic Consulting and Oakley Greenwood. It is provided on the understanding that the Commonwealth of Australia is not providing professional advice and such information is not intended to be, nor should it be, relied upon as a substitute for legal, financial or other professional advice. Before relying on the material contained in this report, users should seek independent professional advice relevant to their particular circumstances. While reasonable efforts have been made to ensure that the report is accurate, correct and reliable, the Commonwealth of Australia accepts no liability, including liability for negligence, for any loss, damage, injury, expense or cost incurred by any person as a result of accessing, using or relying upon any of the information or data set out in this report to the maximum extent permitted by law. Copyright This work is copyright, the copyright being owned by the Commonwealth of Australia. With the exception of the Commonwealth Coat of Arms, the logo of the Department of Resources, Energy and Tourism and other third party material which is protected by intellectual property law, this copyright work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 Australia Licence. Under this licence, you are free to copy, communicate and adapt the work, so long as you attribute the work to ‘NERA Economic Consulting and Oakley Greenwood for the Commonwealth of Australia (Department of Resources, Energy and Tourism)’ and abide by the other licence terms. This work should be attributed in the following way: © Commonwealth of Australia (Department of Resources, Energy and Tourism) 2012 To view a copy of this license, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/au/. For terms of use of Coat of Arms visit It’s an Honour at http://www.itsanhonour.gov.au/coatarms/index.cfm. Requests and inquiries concerning reproduction and rights should be addressed to Manager, Energy Efficiency Opportunities Program, Department of Resources, Energy and Tourism, GPO Box 1564 Canberra ACT 2601 Email: ret@ret.gov.au Project Team NERA Economic Consulting Adrian Kemp Martin Chow Oakley Greenwood Lance Hoch NERA Economic Consulting Darling Park Tower 3 201 Sussex Street Sydney NSW 2000 Tel: +61 2 8864 6500 Fax: +61 2 8864 6549 www.nera.com Oakley Greenwood GPO Box 4345 Melbourne VIC 3001 Tel: +61 3 9486 8097 Fax: +61 3 8080 0760 www.oakleygreenwood.com.au Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Contents Contents Executive Summary i Potential benefits of a peak demand scheme Evaluation of peak scheme design options Modelling the benefits of peak savings i iii iv 1. Introduction 1 2. The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme 3 2.1. 2.2. 2.3. 2.4. 2.5. Concepts relevant to a peak energy savings scheme What is load factor? Context and rationale Potential benefits from a peak savings scheme Objective for a peak savings scheme 3. Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options 3.1. 3.2. 3.3. 3.4. Status Quo Arrangements Option 1: Peak Energy Saving Incentives Option 2: A Stand-Alone Peak Energy Saving Scheme Option 3: A Single Buyer of Peak Energy Savings 4. Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings 4.1. 4.2. 4.3. Modelling generation benefits Modelling network benefits Summary 5. Evaluating Scheme Design Options 5.1. 5.2. 5.3. 5.4. 5.5. Criteria for assessment Scheme design and implementation Scheme benefits Other considerations Summary 6. Further Considerations for the Design of a National ESI Appendix A. Peak Technical Group and Network Modelling Group Members NERA Economic Consulting 3 5 8 11 13 14 14 17 23 28 32 32 36 42 44 44 44 45 45 46 48 52 i Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options List of Tables Table 4.1 Data Requirements of the Static and Dynamic Approaches to Estimate Wholesale Market Benefits Table 4.2 Principal Advantages and Disadvantages of the Deferral and Area-Wide Approaches to Assessing the Network Benefits of Peak Savings Table A.1: Organisations that Participated in the Peak Technical Group and Network Modelling Group 34 38 52 List of Figures Figure 2.1 Stylised Example of an Activity that Improves Load Factor: Direct Load Control for Air Conditioners Figure 2.2 Stylised Example of an Activity that Worsens Load Factor: High Efficiency Street Lighting Figure 2.3 Maximum Demand by National Regions, 1996-07 to 2010-11 Figure 3.1 Incentives for Peak Demand Reductions under Current Arrangements Figure 3.2 Option 1: Peak Energy Savings Incentive Scheme Figure 3.3 Option 2: Stand-Alone Peak Energy Savings Target Scheme Figure 3.4 Option 3: Single Peak Savings Buyer Scheme Figure 4.1 Illustrative Alignment of Peak Savings Measure with Network Peaks (Impact of High Efficient Street Lighting) NERA Economic Consulting 6 7 8 17 20 25 29 41 i Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Executive Summary Concerns about rising electricity prices have led to a renewed focus on the drivers of costs in the electricity supply chain. One often cited contributing factor for electricity price rises is the cost of expanding both network and generation capacity to satisfy continuing growth in peak electricity demand. Indeed, electricity use during peak periods has been growing at around 1.7 times the rate of total electricity use over the past ten years. If this continues, then the unit cost of supplying electricity will also continue to grow as there is a need for: increased use of peaking generators, which have a higher cost per unit of electricity produced; and greater network capacity that is used for a small fraction of the year, and remains idle for the remainder. The Australian Government is currently considering options for implementing a possible national Energy Savings Initiative (ESI) to replace the existing state based schemes.1 As part of its consideration of design options for a national ESI, NERA Economic Consulting and Oakley Greenwood have been asked to investigate design options for an incentive or scheme to explicitly promote peak electricity savings. This report presents the outcomes of this investigation. Potential benefits of a peak demand scheme Central to a consideration of the potential benefits of a peak demand scheme is an appreciation that the demand for – and the cost to supply – electricity varies depending on customers’ aggregate needs throughout the day. A ‘peak’ in demand is therefore a normal phenomenon of this variation in demand and is not in and of itself a sign of a problem. It is therefore important to consider the rationale for introducing a peak demand scheme within the existing electricity system and market framework. It is commonly understood in economics that in a market with many buyers and sellers where prices represent the cost of supplying the next unit of production, consumers purchase a good or service up to the point where the value to them is equal to the price. This means that if electricity prices paid by consumers represented the cost of supplying each unit of electricity, and if a consumer’s use of electricity did not affect the price paid by any other consumer, then the use of electricity would be efficient (ie, it would equate the value to the consumer with the cost). However, because the cost of supply varies considerably depending on the time and location of use, the actual price faced by consumers rarely equates with the cost of supply and so either: more electricity is demanded, particularly during peak times, than is warranted given the underlying true cost of supply and benefits received from its use; or 1 Subject to economic modelling and a regulatory impact analysis, the Government will make a final decision on whether to adopt a national energy savings initiative. A national energy savings initiative would be conditional on the agreement of the Council of Australian Governments and the abolition of existing and planned state schemes. NERA Economic Consulting i Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options less electricity is demanded, particularly during off-peak times than is warranted given the underlying true cost of supply and benefits received from its use. The challenge for the framework applying to the electricity system is to ensure that consumers face appropriate incentives for peak demand reductions in the absence of price signals of the true cost of supply at each point in time and location. Addressing this challenge is not straightforward because: the benefits of reducing peak demand are split along the supply chain, and so no single entity along the supply chain will have an incentive to invest appropriately in demand reductions; the generation benefits arise from avoiding the cost of new generation investments, and over time changes to the generation plant mix, which is an avoided cost where the benefit of which is captured by consumers; there remains uncertainty as to the reliability of non-network alternatives to network investments, which creates an additional hurdle to realising the benefits those alternatives could provide; and there is a lack of depth in the market for provision of demand management and energy efficiency services, which means that these services have been unable to achieve sufficient economies of scale to be cost effective. The current National Electricity Rules address the split benefit problem by requiring transmission businesses to explicitly consider non-network alternatives to proposed network augmentations, and in doing so to consider the entire supply chain benefits and costs. This means that a non-network alternative that delivers greater net benefits across the entire supply chain when compared to a network augmentation must be undertaken even if its direct costs exceed the cost of a proposed network augmentation. This has the effect of transferring part of the benefit received by consumers from such an option to the network to assist with funding the proposed non-network investment. While these rule requirements currently apply only to transmission network investments, similar requirements are being proposed to be applied to distribution network investments. We believe that the rules provide an incentive to network operators to consider non-network solutions to network investments, and should in principle promote efficient investment in peak demand reducing activities. That said there remain potential benefits from a peak savings scheme that provides a direct incentive on reductions to wholesale market peaks, where the cost of reducing peak demand is less than the forward looking cost of satisfying the peak demand from generation investments. The wholesale market benefits of peak savings include: direct generation fuel cost savings from lower electricity use; new peak generation investment cost savings from investment deferral; and a reduction in unserved energy. NERA Economic Consulting ii Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options These wholesale market benefits arise despite the wholesale market reflecting the cost of wholesale supply in each five minute interval because: a customer typically does not face the wholesale market price as retailers manage wholesale price fluctuations on behalf of end-use customers; a customer has an incentive to reduce demand during peak periods where the cost (either direct costs and/or the cost from not using electricity) does not exceed the price paid for electricity during the peak period; and the value of a reduction in peak demand, which alters the system load profile and is sufficient to significantly defer future need for new peak generation capacity, is greater than the current wholesale price (which only reflects the cost of supplying the current and expected system load profile). This combination of factors means that a customer will underinvest in peak demand savings as compared to the value this investment would reflect for the market as a whole from the associated peak demand saving. Evaluation of peak scheme design options We have considered and evaluated three broad peak energy savings scheme designs, namely: schemes that provide incentives to promote peak demand reductions as part of a national Energy Savings Initiative (ESI) – ie, a peak savings incentive within an ESI; schemes that create a separate obligation on a party to achieve specified reductions in peak demand – ie, a stand-alone peak savings scheme; and schemes that directly purchase peak demand reductions within a specified budget – ie, a peak savings buyer scheme. Placing a peak savings incentive within an ESI scheme could be achieved through either: deeming activities that result in peak demand savings as having higher value (ie, receiving a greater number of certificates); or requiring obligated parties (ie, retailers) to obtain a portion of the scheme target from peak savings. A stand-alone peak savings scheme would stand apart from a national ESI and therefore creates flexibility to place the target obligation on network businesses as compared with retailers. By having a peak savings certificate, a direct value would be created for peak savings as compared to energy savings achieved under a national ESI. A peak savings buyer scheme is a non-market approach to achieving peak savings outcomes. It involves the creation of a new role within the electricity system, responsible for achieving peak savings targets. The buyer could fulfil its role by: standing in the market to purchase all peak savings at a predetermined price; conducting auctions to purchase peak savings outcomes in the future; working closely with network businesses and/or demand management operators to fund identified peak demand activities and achieve voluntary targets; or NERA Economic Consulting iii Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options contracting for callable or dispatchable peak demand activities and operating directly in the wholesale market to reduce wholesale market peaks. All the peak savings design options are expected to achieve generation sector benefits and incremental network benefits over the medium to long term. The main differences between the design options are the incentives and penalties that would be placed on network and retailer businesses and the likely timeframes for the achievement of benefits. The advantage of including an incentive for peak savings within an ESI scheme is its ease of administration and implementation. It also allows sufficient flexibility to adapt to an improved understanding of the benefits from peak savings and modify the value attributed to peak savings within the scheme accordingly. A stand-alone peak savings target suffers from placing additional compliance burdens on network businesses compared to the inclusion of an incentive within an ESI scheme. The incremental benefits of this approach compared against the first design option are minimal. A single peak savings buyer scheme benefits from creating a market for peak savings with greater revenue certainty for market participants compared with a national ESI and standalone peak savings scheme options. This is because it relies on direct contracts to purchase peak savings rather than predictions of the likely value of certificates that might be created by peak savings activities. That said the establishment and ongoing costs of such an approach would be substantial compared against the earlier design options. Finally, we believe that an important consideration for the design of an ESI scheme or for any approach to provide an explicit peak savings incentive is the likely impact on load factor for the system. Load factor measures the ratio of peak to average electricity demand and so any deterioration in load factor (ie, if average demand decreases at a higher rate than peak demand decreases) will result in unit network electricity prices increasing. As a consequence any energy savings scheme should consider the merits of explicitly recognising and accounting for this possible outcome in order to avoid the introduction of an energy savings scheme potentially causing negative outcomes. Modelling the benefits of peak savings In addition to considering design options, we were also asked to provide advice on the methodologies that can be used to model the wholesale and network benefits of peak savings. In general, there are two approaches that can be used to estimate the wholesale market benefits of peak savings, namely; a static approach that multiplies the typical values for peak demand and energy consumption reductions (that is, the avoided cost associated with generation investments that do not have to be made, and the cost of fuel that does not need to be used in generation) by the anticipated savings in peak demand and energy consumption; and a dynamic approach that estimates the change in cost by simulating the change in plant mix and fuel usage using an electricity market model. Overall the dynamic approach is likely to provide a more realistic estimate of the generation benefits compared with a static approach. While the static approach is significantly easier to NERA Economic Consulting iv Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options apply, the data and computing resources needed for the dynamic approach are generally readily available. There are two principal approaches to calculating network benefits, these are: the deferral approach, which uses a bottom-up approach to estimate network benefits by examining actual projects and considering which projects could be deferred if peak demand savings were to be achieved; and the area-wide demand reduction approach, which is a top-down approach that assumes that peak demand reductions made anywhere in the network will result in reduced need for capital expenditure in the long run. Applying the deferral approach is particularly complex given the detailed network data required, as savings only occur in locations where additional capacity is required in the foreseeable future. A detailed understanding of these opportunities is required and so this approach can only be practically done for time periods where distribution companies have forecasts of additional network capacity needs, which is typically for five years. To estimate network benefits over a longer time horizon, an area-wide approach is more likely to be appropriate. An area-wide approach can be used to account for some network areas experiencing very slow (or even negative) growth, and other areas experiencing peak demands at different times of the day or seasons. NERA Economic Consulting v Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options 1. Introduction Introduction Electricity use during peak periods has been growing at around 1.7 times the rate of total electricity use over the past ten years. Growing peak demand has a disproportionate impact on household bills because it results in: increased use of peaking generators, which have a higher cost per unit of electricity produced; and the need for network capacity that is used for a small fraction of the year, and remains idle for the remainder. If electricity use was not so variable over a year, the total cost of supplying electricity would be lower because less physical infrastructure would be needed, lower cost generation could be used to supply electricity and the average cost of providing network capacity would also be lower. Given concerns about the network and generation cost implications of growing peak demand, NERA Economic Consulting (NERA) and Oakley Greenwood (OGW) have been asked to investigate design options for a scheme to reduce peak electricity demand. This investigation has been undertaken within the context of a wider review of the merits of implementing a national Energy Savings Initiative scheme to provide direct incentives to promote overall energy efficiency. To assist with the investigation of peak energy savings scheme design options, a Peak Technical Group (PTG) and Network Modelling Group (NMG) were formed to provide an advisory and review role for the project. The groups were made up of representatives of electricity retailers, networks and generation, energy savings companies, and regulators. The groups met on a number of occasions between November 2011 and February 2012 and provided input on the design options presented in this paper. We have benefited considerably from these discussions, but the remainder of this paper reflects our opinions on the relative merits of the design options considered. In this report we outline three broad design options for a peak energy savings scheme, and examine the relative merits of each scheme. We also examine the methodologies for estimating the benefits of such a scheme, and the associated data requirements. The remainder of this report explains these scheme options in greater detail, and is structured as follows: chapter 2 sets out the rationale for a peak energy efficiency scheme; chapter 3 describes each of the design options that have been investigated in detail, namely: a specific peak energy saving incentive within a broader energy savings scheme, a stand-alone peak energy savings scheme, and a peak energy savings buyer scheme; chapter 4 discusses methodologies for estimating the benefits of a peak energy savings scheme, with a particular focus on estimating network deferral benefits, and the associated data requirements; NERA Economic Consulting 1 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Introduction chapter 5 provides an evaluation of the scheme options against a number of identified criteria for assessment; and chapter 6 sets out some further considerations for the design of an ESI Scheme. Appendix A provides a list of the organisations that were represented in the PTG and NMG meetings. NERA Economic Consulting 2 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options 2. The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme This chapter explains some of the key electricity supply chain concepts relevant for a consideration of peak energy savings, and also provides the rationale for a peak energy saving scheme. 2.1. Concepts relevant to a peak energy savings scheme Before considering peak energy savings design options, it is important to have a common understanding about what is the ‘peak’. In this section we explain how ‘peak’ can be defined, while also explaining the concept of ‘load factor’ and the distinction between demand management and energy efficiency. These concepts are relevant for any scheme design. 2.1.1. What is the ‘peak’? The starting point for a consideration of a peak energy savings scheme is to consider what is meant by a ‘peak’. The peak can relate to either: the half hourly period within an electricity supply system within a year where demand is at its maximum; the half hourly period within an electricity supply system within a year where the half hourly wholesale market settlement price2 is at its maximum;3 the period of half hours that represent the top say 10 per cent4 of total load or wholesale prices within an electricity supply system within a year; the period of highest demand or wholesale price within an electricity supply region within a day; or a localised network maximum demand, either over a year or day. These different definitions of what a ‘peak’ is highlights that the peak can be defined for either electricity demand or wholesale price, with reference to: the period of time over which the demand or price is considered to be at its peak (eg, a year, a quarter, or a day); the length of the period that is considered to be ‘peak’ (eg, 10 per cent of total periods); and the geographic area over which the demand or price is considered to be at its peak (eg, a NEM region, subregion or a defined distribution network or sub-network). 2 The half hourly wholesale market settlement price (ie, the half hourly spot price) is calculated as the average of the six dispatch prices within the half hour period. The dispatch prices are determined every 5 minutes by actual demand and dispatch price submitted by the generators. 3 Peak price and peak demand may not occur within the same half hour period within a year. 4 10 per cent has been chosen here as an illustrative example only. NERA Economic Consulting 3 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme For the purpose of this paper there is no need to decide on a single definition of ‘peak’ as this choice is immaterial to a consideration of design options. Any of the designs considered can be tailored to any definition of ‘peak’ that is preferred. That said, the choice of definition for the peak requires consideration to be given to: the benefits of targeting different peaks during particular times of the year or geographic locations; compared against the administrative costs and ease of implementation of the scheme. As part of our consideration of scheme design options, we examine how each scheme varies in terms of the scope to target benefits versus the administrative costs and ease of implementation. 2.1.2. The cost of supplying electricity differs throughout the day and year A key characteristic of the electricity sector is the variation between the costs of the different generation technologies available, ie: base load plants (such as coal) and renewable electricity generation technologies (such as solar and wind), have relatively low operating costs, but this intrinsic, short run cost advantage is offset by relatively high capital fixed costs (ie, the cost per unit of potential output) and reduced ability to vary output in the short term (ie, ‘stopping’ and ‘starting’ such plants is not straightforward); mid-merit plants, typically in the form of combined cycle gas turbines (CCGT), have higher running costs, but mid-range capital (fixed) costs; and peaking plants, typically in the form of open cycle gas turbines (OCGT) have relatively low capital costs, a high degree of short-term controllability (ie, ‘stopping’ and ‘starting’ such plants is easy) but relatively high running costs. The variability of demand for electricity during the day and over a year means that the least cost combination of generation involves a mixture of these plants. Given the different fuel and operating costs of each plant type the wholesale price of electricity generation also varies throughout the day and year. In addition, the variability of demand when combined with system reliability and security obligations means that networks are built so as to ensure that maximum demand can be satisfied most of the time at all geographic locations across the network. By implication this means that the network cost of supplying an additional unit of electricity (ie, the marginal cost) can vary considerably according to the specific location, and the localised demand and network characteristics. These characteristics of electricity generation and networks mean that the cost of supplying a unit of electricity varies according to both the time it is used in a day and year, and the location within the network. In other words, the marginal cost of supplying electricity varies considerably across the network. NERA Economic Consulting 4 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme It follows that the potential benefits of saving a unit of electricity also vary depending on the time profile of the saving and its location within the network. In general terms this means that: energy savings have a higher value in locations where the network is nearing its capacity and only during peak periods when demand is highest and thereby driving the need for additional capacity in that location5; energy savings have higher value when wholesale energy prices are higher, and particularly when they are at or near the market price cap; where the local network peak period coincides with the peak period of the wholesale market and the local network peak demand is approaching local network capacity limits, peak period energy savings will be of high value from both perspectives; and energy savings have a significantly lower value when neither of the conditions described in the first two dot points above are met; in such cases, the value of energy savings are most accurately represented by the avoided fuel cost. 2.2. What is load factor? Load factor is simply a measure of the ratio of average demand to peak demand, and so measures the ‘peakiness’ of electricity consumption. Given the variation in costs of the different technologies, the average cost of supplying electricity decreases as load factor improves (ie, as electricity load becomes ‘flatter’) and vice versa. Activities that reduce energy consumption during peak periods or shift energy use from peak periods to off-peak periods will therefore result in a flatter load curve. This means that the average cost of supplying electricity will decrease, all other things being equal. Figure 2.1 provides a stylised example of an activity that improves load factor. The figure is based on data for New South Wales on 2 February 2011 and shows the potential effect of direct load control systems for air conditioners, which are activated during the peak to reduce total demand. In this example, this has the effect of reducing the amount of electricity generated from open cycle gas turbines. 5 To be of most value in a network application demand reductions must achieve the level of megavolt ampere needed to defer the need for a planned expenditure of capital to augment the capacity of the local distribution network, and that level must be achieved prior to the time commitment to the augmentation would need to be made (or at very least, the achievement of that amount of demand response would need to be seen as certain to be achieved prior to the time the additional capacity itself would be needed). The deferral of that network investment has a financial value at the time the deferral is achieved, and this value flows into network charges no later than the subsequent regulatory period. However, even if demand reductions in these areas do not achieve the level needed to defer the planned augmentation, they will reduce the potential for peak demand in such areas to exceed network supply capacity, thereby increasing supply security, until the augmentation has been implemented. However the benefit of increased security of supply does not have a financial impact on network charges. More broadly, any demand reduction anywhere on the distribution network can be seen to have an economic value in that, as long as that demand reduction remains available, it will potentially delay the time at which augmentation of capacity in that part of the distribution network will be needed. Clearly, the financial impact of this is much less certain and will have a lower present value the farther into the future that deferral might be. While the value of any such demand reduction will vary based on where it occurs and when it is likely to affect capacity augmentation, its value can be thought of as being equal to the average cost of capacity augmentation over time, which is referred to as the long run average incremental cost (LRAIC). NERA Economic Consulting 5 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme Figure 2.1 Stylised Example of an Activity that Improves Load Factor: Direct Load Control for Air Conditioners 16000 14000 14000 12000 12000 10000 8000 8000 6000 $/MWh MW 10000 6000 4000 4000 2000 2000 0 0:30 2:00 3:30 5:00 6:30 8:00 0 9:30 11:00 12:30 14:00 15:30 17:00 18:30 20:00 21:30 23:00 Time of Day Gas - CC Hydro - intermediate Black coal Other Gas - OC Hydro - peaking DLC AC $/MWh However, if activities that reduce peak energy use also decrease non-peak energy use, then this could have the effect of increasing unit costs as the load curve becomes peakier. This is because the fixed network and generation costs need to be recovered from a lower through put of electricity. Similarly, any activities that only reduce electricity use during non-peak periods without affecting energy use during peak periods will also increase the average cost of supplying electricity. Figure 2.2 provides a stylised example of the impact of installing high efficiency street lights on the system load profile. The reduction in electricity demanded during off-peak periods has the effect of reducing the need to use both hydro and combined cycle gas turbines, and also marginally decreases black coal generation. However, because over time network costs are sunk, the reduced overall demand without any offsetting decrease in the network capacity leads to a higher network cost per unit of electricity supplied. NERA Economic Consulting 6 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme Figure 2.2 Stylised Example of an Activity that Worsens Load Factor: High Efficiency Street Lighting 16000 14000 14000 12000 12000 10000 8000 8000 6000 6000 4000 4000 2000 2000 0 0 0:30 2:00 3:30 5:00 Black coal Hydro - intermediate High efficiency streetlighting 2.2.1. 6:30 8:00 9:30 11:00 12:30 14:00 15:30 17:00 18:30 20:00 21:30 23:00 Time of Day Other Gas - CC Gas - OC Hydro - peaking $/MWh What is energy efficiency and demand management? Energy efficiency can have a number of different meanings. Importantly, a distinction can be drawn between the terms ‘energy saving’ and ‘energy efficiency’. Energy saving is any absolute reduction in energy use, and it follows that peak energy saving is an absolute reduction in energy use during a defined peak period. However, energy efficiency is a change in the ratio of productive output per unit of energy used. This means that an improvement in energy efficiency can occur when: for a given level of energy input, productive output (or benefits) increases; or for a given level of productive output (or benefits), energy input decreases. This means that an improvement in energy efficiency does not necessarily imply that total energy use falls. Examples of activities that improve energy efficiency include (amongst other things): replacing older appliances with newer, and more efficient appliances; programmes that replace light globes with more efficient light globes; and improvements in home insulation, which lowers the need for energy for heating or cooling. Demand management in contrast is any activity that seeks to actively manage customer demand in response to either electricity price signals (whether at the wholesale, network or NERA Economic Consulting 7 $/MWh MW 10000 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme retail level) or electricity marginal costs.6 As a consequence, the net effect of demand management activities is to shift the proportion of energy consumed from peak to non-peak periods. Examples of demand management activities include (amongst other things): direct load control programmes, where load is ‘switched off’ or ‘cycled’ during peak periods; investments in customer-side local power storage to shift demand from the network during peak periods; and power factor correction improvements at the site or facility level. 2.3. Context and rationale Growing peak energy demand over recent years has been identified as a significant contributor to the planned growth in network and generation expenditure to ensure that system reliability requirements are satisfied. Peak demand has been growing across Australia at a compound growth rate of 1.2 to 4.2 per cent, with the highest growth occurring in Queensland – see Figure 2.3. MW Figure 2.3 Maximum System Demand by National Regions, 1996-07 to 2010-117 16000 14000 12000 10000 8000 6000 4000 2000 0 NSW VIC QLD 1996-97 SA WA TAS NT SNOWY 2010-11 The core of the network peak problem is that: 6 Where electricity pricing reflects electricity supply costs in both the magnitude of the price and how the price is structured, it is more likely to engender demand management activities on the part of end-use customers without further intervention. The less cost-reflective electricity prices are, the more likely it is that programmatic interventions will be required to motivate end-use customers to undertake those actions. 7 Some of the growth in peak demand for New South Wales and Victoria between 1996-97 and 2010-11 is as a consequence of the abolishment of the Snowy region in 2008. 2009-10 maximum demand figures were used for NT. Source: AEMO (2011), Statement of Opportunities, ESAA, (1998), Electricity Australia, IMO (2011), Statement of Opportunities, and Utilities Commission (2011), Power System Review 2009-10. NERA Economic Consulting 8 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme the network costs of supplying electricity to customers for the top 10 per cent of the load duration curve can be significant; current network charges mean that customers using electricity during these periods pay a fraction of the costs incurred by the network to supply the infrastructure necessary to satisfy demand (that is, a lack of cost-reflective pricing); demand is therefore higher than would be the case if customers faced the true cost of meeting system peak demands; and the benefits (from avoided network costs) of lowering demand during peak periods are likely to be greater than the costs involved. The problem from a generation perspective is more complex. Specifically: the wholesale costs of supplying electricity vary for each period according to the lowest marginal cost of generation to satisfy demand in the period; most consumers do not pay the marginal wholesale market prices, as retailers manage these wholesale price volatility risks on behalf of their customers principally through wholesale market hedging; while this might suggest that wholesale investment is efficient because customers are managing wholesale costs either directly or via a retailer, it does not take into account the observation that: – sufficient and persistent reductions in wholesale peak energy use could result in the avoidance or deferral of new peak generation capacity, thereby reducing the long run wholesale costs of electricity generation by an amount greater than the current observed wholesale price; and – no individual would be likely to invest at the level required to reduce peak demand because the benefits received by other electricity users through lower wholesale charges for all would not be factored into the decision to reduce demand. In other words, the benefit to a customer of reducing demand during peak periods is equal to: the avoided wholesale cost (as typically represented by the electricity price faced by the customer); plus the deferral of investment in additional peak generation capacity in the future to satisfy growing peak demand if sufficient demand can be reduced.8 However, the customer would only receive at most the avoided wholesale cost benefit and so will underinvest in demand reducing activities. The current market pricing arrangements mean that the true supply chain cost (ie, the combined cost of electricity generation, network provision and retailing services) of 8 This benefit arises because of the lumpy nature of generation capacity investments, which is not adequately represented in wholesale prices. The benefit is therefore contingent on the achievement of sufficient demand reduction to defer the generation investment and so lower the wholesale price. NERA Economic Consulting 9 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme supplying electricity during system peak periods is considerably higher than faced by electricity consumers. As a consequence electricity demand is higher than would be the case if the true benefits of reducing demand were reflected in prices. It follows that there is less investment in demand management and energy saving activities than is ideal, given the costs of these activities as compared to the benefits they would produce in avoided network and generation costs. The impracticality of pricing to most customers the true cost of generation and network supply during peak periods means that alternative mechanisms are needed to ensure that cost effective demand management and energy saving activities are undertaken. Under current arrangements retailers operating in New South Wales, Victoria, and South Australia are required to satisfy energy reduction obligations. While these schemes do not explicitly target peak reductions, many of the activities that are undertaken have an impact on peak energy use. In addition, the National Electricity Rules require transmission network providers to consider the system costs and benefits of both network augmentation and non-network alternatives (eg, peak demand reducing activities) when considering an expansion to network capacity. In principal this should ensure that where non-network alternatives are more cost effective they are undertaken instead of network augmentations. The challenges with ensuring appropriate incentives for peak demand reductions by consumers in the absence of providing direct price signals are: the benefits of reducing network peak demand arise from various sources, such as deferring network augmentation, improving reliability and where network and wholesale peaks coincide, from deferring generation investments; the generation benefits arise from avoiding the cost of new generation investments, and over time changes to the generation plant mix, which is a non-monetised benefit captured by consumers; uncertainty as to the reliability of non-network alternatives to network investments; and the lack of depth in the market for provision of demand management and energy efficiency services. The first two challenges arise because of the split in benefits between generation and networks. This means that for efficient network investments to be made the entire supply chain benefits of both network and non-network investments to satisfy reliability obligations should be considered. Fortunately, the requirements in the NER directly address the split benefits disincentive by allowing transmission network businesses to recover the cost of nonnetwork alternatives where they deliver greater net benefits to a planned network augmentation. A similar approach is anticipated to be included in revisions to the regulatory investment test applied to distribution networks. This can be expected to result in efficient investment in non-network alternatives. The uncertainties of demand management compared to network alternatives are likely to act as a barrier, and are related to the lack of depth in the market and experience with these activities so as to allow them to be relied upon. As network businesses are charged with NERA Economic Consulting 10 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme managing these risks, so their appetite for risk given the incentives faced for cost efficiency is a relevant consideration. Finally, the uncertainty surrounding demand management arises in part because of a lack of depth in third party demand management provision. This has likely arisen because of the lack of a transparent market for the provision of these services, in part because there is no clear purchaser with the requisite incentives to purchase these services. 2.4. Potential benefits from a peak savings scheme The benefits from peak demand reductions arise from: changes in the mix of plant needed to satisfy load requirements; avoiding network augmentation investments and fuel over time; and reductions in unserved energy. The relative size of these benefits is difficult to determine in total, but will likely arise in the medium to long term given the planning time horizons for both generation and network augmentation investments. A significant amount of investment in network and generation capacity is needed over the next few years. The total regulatory allowance for electricity network capital expenditure is around $38 billion ($7.7 and $30 billion for transmission and distribution businesses respectively in the NEM) in the current five year cycle9, of which $3.7 billion for transmission10 and between $10 to $16 billion for distribution,11 are related to augmentation expenditure. Augmentation related expenditure is therefore expected to account for somewhere between 35 and 50 per cent of all electricity network capital expenditure forecast to take place within the next five years. That said, not all of this will be related simply to growth in peak demand. In many cases, the growth will come from the construction of new residential developments and other sources of growth in the customer numbers. Peak energy savings can be valuable in both cases. However, where augmentation is needed to meet growing peak demand in established areas, peak energy savings can, in some cases, defer the need for that augmentation. In this regard it is useful to note that 25 per cent of network capacity in the Victorian region in 2008-09 was used for only 10 days.12 Where network augmentation is needed to meet the demand of new customer facilities – as is the case in areas experiencing significant population growth – peak energy savings can reduce the amount of infrastructure needed to meet that demand. However, the specific amount of the 9 Page 15, Investment Reference Group, (2011), ‘Investment Reference Group Report - A Report to the Commonwealth Minister for Resources and Energy’, April. 10 48 per cent of the $7.7 billion transmission capital expenditure is related to system augmentations. 11 Estimated using augmentation expenditure information (excluding reliability and quality improvements) from various state AER distribution determinations. The proportion of DNSP expenditure related to augmentation and demand expenditure is around 33 to 54 per cent ( 33 and 54 per cent for Ergon and Energex from 2010-11 to 2014-15, 34, 36 and 40 per cent for Country Energy, EnergyAustralia and Integral Energy from 2009-10 to 2013-14, and 48 per cent for Victorian DNSPs as a whole). 12 Page 172, (2011), ‘Draft Energy White Paper 2011: Strengthening the Foundations for Australia’s Energy Future’, A Report to the Commonwealth Minister for Resources and Energy, December. NERA Economic Consulting 11 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme forecast network augmentation that can be reduced or deferred by demand management is very difficult to estimate without a great deal of research and analysis. In addition expenditure on new generation capacity required by 2020 in the NEM and the Western Australia South West Interconnected System (SWIS) is estimated to be between $33.4 billion and $36.5 billion, assuming a moderate emission reduction target. This figure includes plant that will be required to meet the Renewable Energy Target and to replace old generation units that are likely to be retired. Reductions in peak demand could help significantly offset the need for some of this expenditure. Energy savings in peak periods can reduce the amount of plant required to meet peak demand, and change the proportion of peak, intermediate and baseload generation (and associated fuels) that are needed to meet customers’ aggregate electricity needs. A number of studies have been conducted to estimate the effect on system costs of growing peak demand: ENERGEX estimates that the cost of supplying an additional MW of electricity during peak periods is approximately $3.5 million (comprising $2 million of distribution network costs, $0.7 million of transmission network costs, and $0.8 million of generation costs);13 Ausgrid’s estimates of benefits of between $2.6 and $4.5 million for avoiding each MW of peak demand;14 Institute for Sustainable Futures and Energetics estimate that the possible savings in infrastructure costs of $16.7 billion (undiscounted) by 2020 as a result of improving building energy efficiency, which results in reductions in summer peak demand of between 5,000 and 7,000 MW and 26,000 GWh less electricity consumption annually over the period. The network benefits, which are likely to be caused by a reduction in peak demand, are around $11 billion;15 Ernst & Young estimated ‘the possible value of reducing peak in the NEM at between $3.3 billion and $15 billion from 2011 to 2030 in present value terms’ and that “the majority of precedent supports a value of between $90 and $300/kVA per annum to defer network load”;16 EnergyAustralia reduced its forecast capital expenditure by $234 million from 2009-10 to 2013-14 when it updated its average peak demand growth from 2.8 per cent to 2.7 per cent from 2009 to 2014, which represents a reduction in peak demand of around 33 MW. This is a savings of around $7 million per MW of peak demand avoided, and represents a 6 per cent reduction in its revised area plan expenditure during this period17; and 13 Page 4, Department of Employment, Economic Development and Innovation, (2011), ‘Queensland Energy Management Plan’, May. 14 Page 5, Ausgrid, (2011), ‘submission responding to the Australian Energy Market Commission’s Discussion Paper on Strategic priorities for Energy Market Development’, May 15 Page 98, Institute for Sustainable Futures, (2010), ‘Building Our Savings: Reduced Infrastructure Costs from Improving Building Energy Efficiency’, Final Report, May. 16 Page 72 and 73, Ernst and Young, (2011), ‘Rationale and Drivers for DSP in the Electricity Market – Demand and Supply of Electricity’, December. 17 Page 26, EnergyAustralia, (2009), ‘Revised Regulatory Proposal and Interim Submission’, January. NERA Economic Consulting 12 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options The Rationale for a Peak Energy Savings Scheme on the generation side, CRA estimated that demand management programmes that reduce summer peak demand by 2770MW and winter peak demand by 1770MW, would create generation benefits of $949 million in present value terms over a 20 year time period.18 While the exact figures vary, these reports highlight that the potential benefits of a peak demand scheme over the next 20 years are likely to be material. 2.5. Objective for a peak savings scheme Within this context, the two potential objectives for introducing a specific peak energy savings scheme include: improving the efficiency of wholesale generation and network investment by reducing inefficient use of and investment in infrastructure to satisfy periods of high demand; or lowering the total cost of electricity supply, by changing the electricity load shape over time. In addition, the objective can have a temporal dimension, ie, for the achievement of the stated objective in the short, medium or long term. This depends on the relative preference for near term efficiency achievements, as compared to the achievement of benefits over a longer time horizon. The scheme design options have been developed with these potential objectives in mind. We consider how each option compares against these objectives and different timeframes in chapter 5. 18 Page 4, CRA International, (2006), ‘Assessing the Value of Demand Response in the NEM’, Final Report prepared for IEA Task XIII Team, December. NERA Economic Consulting 13 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options 3. Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options The peak savings scheme options that we have considered can be grouped into three broad approaches, namely: schemes that provide incentives to promote peak demand reductions as part of a general energy savings scheme – ie, a general peak savings incentive within a general energy savings scheme; schemes that create a separate obligation on a party to achieve specified reductions in peak demand – ie, a stand-alone peak savings scheme; and schemes that directly purchase peak demand reductions within a specified budget – ie, a peak savings buyer scheme. The remainder of this chapter describes how these schemes might operate, and their associated benefits, costs, risks and uncertainties. We start with a brief description of current arrangements to provide a basis against which the scheme design options can be evaluated. 3.1. Status Quo Arrangements The National Electricity Rules (NER) provide the framework within which network businesses (both transmission and distribution businesses) undertake planning and investment decision making. The incentives created by the NER for undertaking non-network alternatives to planned network augmentations are therefore relevant for peak savings scheme design. Box 3.1 provides an overview of the rules relating to the requirements on network businesses to consider non-network alternative investments. In summary, the rules: require transmission and distribution businesses to explicitly consider non-network alternatives to planned network augmentations, as part of annual planning processes; provide information to the market about planned network augmentations and the network and non-network alternative options that had been considered in its project evaluation; require transmission businesses to explicitly calculate a value for benefits of both network and non-network investments along the entire supply chain, including any benefits received by generators or consumers; and provide dispute resolution procedures if any party believes that the analysis has been undertaken inappropriately. NERA Economic Consulting 14 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options Box 3.1: Summary of the Principal National Electricity Rules related to Network Planning and Investment Rule 5.6.2(b) requires each Transmission Network Service Provider (TNSP) to conduct an annual planning review with each Distribution Network Service Provider (DNSP) taking into account a number of factors. Relevant to a consideration of peak demand is the obligation to consider the potential for network and non-network alternatives to augmentations that are likely to provide a net economic benefit to all those who produce, consume and transport electricity in the market. 19 Rule 5.6.2(g) requires DNSPs to carry out an economic cost effectiveness analysis of possible options to identify options that satisfy the regulatory test. Rule 5.6.2A obliges TNSPs to publish an annual planning report that provides information arising from the planning review. As part of this report, information must be provided (Rule 5.6.2A(4)(vi)) on what other reasonable network and non-network options were considered as an alternative to a planned network augmentation. Rule 5.6.5A requires the Australian Energy Regulator to publish the regulatory test, the purpose of which is to identify new network investments or non-network alternative options that: maximise the net economic benefit to all those who produce, consume and transport electricity in the market; or in the event the option is necessitated to meet the service standards… minimise the present value of the costs of meeting those requirements. Rule 5.6.5B outlines the requirements for the regulatory investment test for transmission (RIT-T). Rule 5.6.5B(4) lists all of the benefits that must be taken into account by the TNSP, which explicitly includes wholesale market benefits in additional to network benefits. Rule 5.6.5D requires a TNSP to explicitly consider non-network options as being credible for a network solution. The Australian Energy Regulator is obliged to develop guidelines for the application of the regulatory investment test as it is applied to transmission (RIT-T) and distribution network investments (RIT-D). The most recent guidelines for the RIT-T were finalised in July 2011. The effect of these arrangements is that: TNSPs must consider non-network alternatives to network investments and also consider benefits along the entire electricity supply chain in its evaluation; if a non-network solution costs more than a network solution, but it has high net benefits, then the non-network solution must be undertaken; and any additional costs incurred will be recovered through network charges to customers. 19 See in particular Rule 5.6.2(b)(4), NER. NERA Economic Consulting 15 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options In short, these arrangements address the split benefits problem and are also intended to go some way to addressing possible network business aversions to non-network investments by at least requiring a proper analysis of alternative non-network investments to be undertaken. While most likely not perfect, these arrangements go a long way towards promoting peak savings when and where it is cost effective for peak saving activities to defer planned transmission network investments. That said, the changes to the regulatory investment test as applied by distribution businesses have not been implemented as yet. As a consequence, there is a need to ensure that these changes are made so that distribution businesses also take adequate account of up and downstream benefits when evaluating network and non-network alternative investments to maintain network reliability. In addition, AER’s demand management incentive scheme (DMIS) is aimed at providing distributors with incentives to implement non-network alternatives to reduce or shift peak demand. At a high level, there are two key components to the DMIS, namely: an allowance to fund innovation in demand management (the demand management innovation allowance (DMIA)); and a methodology for recovering any revenue that might be foregone as a consequence of engaging in demand management activities. The DMIA provides distributors with an additional allowance each year to implement demand management projects or programs that meet the DMIA criteria. To remove any financial disincentive that distributors have to implement demand management programs, the AER allows distributors to recover forgone revenue from implementing DMIS programs and projects for non-tariff demand management programs20. Figure 3.1 provides a representation of the incentives and likely effects of the RIT-T and anticipated revisions to the RIT applicable to distribution network investments. Importantly, under these arrangements there are incentives on network businesses to engage with third party energy savings businesses (ESCOs) to deliver targeted peak demand savings to achieve network deferrals. 20 Tariff based demand programs allow distributors to charge cost reflective prices by charging a higher price during peak periods. The AER argues that distributors that implement tariff based demand management will receive more revenue due to higher prices and therefore do not need to recover forgone revenue. NERA Economic Consulting 16 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options Figure 3.1 Incentives for Peak Demand Reductions under Current Arrangements21 The effect of these incentives is to lower network charges and so overall charges to customers in the near term compared to the alternative where these rule changes had not been made. To the extent that network peaks correspond with wholesale peaks there is also potential to influence the shape of the overall generation system load profile over time, and so deliver generation deferral and fuel savings benefits as well. That said, because the incentives do not explicitly target the load profile these benefits are likely to be less than might be the case if wholesale peak demand was explicitly targeted. Finally, the incentives under the rules to achieve network deferral savings where cost effective are limited by the requirement that they are implemented on a project-by-project basis. The rules require market benefits to be considered for each project evaluated, so long as the analysis is commensurate with the size of the project. This means that while market benefits might be small for a project when considered in isolation, there is the potential that demand side opportunities that might be viable on a larger scale are ignored. 3.2. Option 1: Peak Energy Saving Incentives This section provides a detailed explanation of Option 1, which involves providing a direct incentive to promote peak energy savings as part of a wider energy savings scheme. 3.2.1. Description of the option The first option presumes that a peak demand savings scheme has been implemented as part of a national ESI. From this starting assumption, Option 1 examines how incentives to promote peak savings might be incorporated as part of a general energy savings scheme. 21 We have characterised anticipated changes to the RIT as applied to distribution as part of the current arrangements but acknowledge that these changes have not been implemented at this time. NERA Economic Consulting 17 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options Given that the details of how a general energy savings scheme might operate are currently being explored, we have had to assume how such a scheme might operate to allow for a consideration of how a peak savings incentive might be included. We have therefore assumed that a national energy savings scheme would: place an energy savings obligation on electricity retailers,22 requiring energy savings certificates to be surrendered annually to fulfil the obligation; require a retailer to pay a penalty price if it does not have sufficient certificates to satisfy its obligations; allow approved activities to generate energy efficiency certificates based on the total kilowatt hours (kWh) saved (or deemed to be saved); be based on energy efficiency certificates that represent 1 kWh of energy saved; allow energy efficiency certificates to be traded and capable of being carried over into future years; and allow the energy efficiency attributable to identified actions to be deemed for administrative simplicity, with a certificate creator having the option to use actual energy savings measurement as an alternative to deeming. Such a scheme would value energy savings equally irrespective of the time of day or day of the year those savings are achieved. This means that the value of a certificate represents the average value of reducing energy demand by 1 kWh and so will: be an underestimate of the value of reducing demand – in locations that might need network augmentation as a consequence of peak demand expectations within the near term; and – at times when the wholesale market price is above the annual average price be an overestimate of the net value of reducing demand – in locations where there is sufficient spare capacity to supply all of the energy demanded including during peak periods; and – at times when the wholesale market price is below the annual average price; and ignore the impacts of that energy saving on the load factor of both the generation and network systems, and the consequent impact on infrastructure use and the average cost per unit of electricity produced, and so impact on average electricity price. Incorporating an additional incentive for peak energy savings would allow for reduced energy consumption at times of peak demand to be valued more accurately (ie, higher than they would be based on the average value of reducing energy demand), and would increase the benefits received by those energy saving activities that have a greater impact on peak demand. 22 We understand that no decision has been made on the obligated party for a wider energy efficiency scheme. We have chosen retailers given that this has been the approach used in the state-based energy savings schemes. NERA Economic Consulting 18 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options An explicit incentive to achieve peak energy savings could be incorporated in a wider energy savings scheme by: Option 1A – assuming that a 1 kWh reduction in peak energy generates more than one energy savings certificate (eg, say 3 certificates23); or Option 1B – requiring electricity retailers to achieve a specified minimum percentage of energy savings within a defined peak period, or a specific peak energy savings target. Option 1A provides an additional incentive for energy saving activities that target peak savings by multiplying the value of these reductions by a fixed amount, compared against the value of a kWh saved during non-peak periods. This approach presumes that any energy saving during a peak period is valued equally irrespective of the location of the saving, as represented by the multiple applied to energy savings during the peak period. So long as the multiple represents the relative difference in the average benefits of peak versus non-peak energy savings then this approach will provide a better signal to energy saving creators of the value of peak energy savings along the supply chain, and so can be expected to lead to greater uptake of peak saving activities than if no direct peak incentive was created. Option 1B differs from Option 1A by providing energy retailers with a specific peak energy savings target. The target could take the form of a minimum of energy savings being achieved during peak periods, or by establishing a separate peak savings target. Either approach provides a specific target that must be satisfied, and so ensures that a predetermined level of peak energy savings is achieved. Figure 3.2 provides a representation of the incentives and likely impacts of the inclusion of a peak savings incentive as part of a national energy savings scheme. The key features are: an incentive is created to achieve peak energy savings through an obligation on retailers; the creation of a market for energy savings certificates, which provides certificate creators with a market for the sale of activities that lower energy use and provides additional incentive for activities that reduce energy use in periods that are characterised by peak demand; retailers will recover the costs of the energy savings obligation through retail charges, with the competitive retail market and retail price regulation creating the incentives to lower the cost of compliance with the obligation; network businesses retain an incentive to undertake cost effective targeted demand savings where this results in network deferral from existing arrangements; while network businesses can also create certificates, the incentive to do so is limited because the cost of network deferral activities can be recovered through network charges and so any revenue from the sale of certificates would most likely simply reduce the amount of revenue needing to be recovered in network charges; and 23 Ideally the number would be determined with reference to the temporal and locational value of the energy saving, including avoided capacity. However, the interaction between these two factors means that understanding these values in practice is difficult. This issue is discussed further in Section 6. NERA Economic Consulting 19 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options a direct incentive can be created for wholesale peak savings, separate from network peak savings. Figure 3.2 Option 1: Peak Energy Savings Incentive Scheme 3.2.2. Benefits By providing a direct incentive for peak savings, Option 1 is expected to result in peak savings over time compared against the status quo arrangements. That said, because the incentives for network deferral arises from the status quo arrangements, the incremental benefit of this option results from the scope to provide incentives for targeted wholesale peak savings to change the load shape over time. This would be expected to incrementally increase the generation deferral and fuel savings benefits compared to the status quo case because: under the status quo the wholesale benefits arise only where network peak savings are coincident with wholesale peaks and so influence the wholesale market over time; the current wholesale market arrangements do not compare the cost of changes to the load shape compared with the associated cost of new generation investments; and even if customers faced the cost of wholesale and networks at each point in time and location, energy savings would not be optimal because of the need to aggregate sufficient demand savings to defer lumpy network and wholesale investments (in other words, no single customer acting alone will likely face a price signal that reflects the full potential value for each unit of demand saved). The last two points are particularly important as they go to the heart of the benefit case for providing an incentive for peak savings over time. In the absence of pricing that reflects the true cost of supplying electricity at each location and point in time, and given the lumpiness of wholesale and network investments, demand savings need to be coordinated to achieve optimal investment in electricity supply chain infrastructure. The market alone, without NERA Economic Consulting 20 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options appropriate pricing, cannot provide this coordination and so there is a case for a market intervention to facilitate optimal peak energy savings. The benefits of Option 1 therefore arise from the placement of a value on the wholesale benefits resulting from the achievement of wholesale peak energy savings over time, where these are independent of network peaks. This option provides a means for transferring a portion of the benefit that is ultimately received by customers to the party that can engage in activities to promote large-scale wholesale peak savings. Importantly, this scheme is unlikely to result in more targeting of network benefits compared against the incentives created through the rule requirements. This is because the RIT-T and the likely amendments to the RIT for distribution investments provides a means of ensuring that any wholesale benefits created are taken into account when choosing between network and non-network investment alternatives. As a consequence the introduction of a specific peak savings incentive is unlikely to further enhance these network deferral incentives. That said, creating a peak savings incentive as part of an energy savings certificate scheme does create the means of transferring possible wholesale benefits from customers separate from the network regulatory arrangements and so third party aggregators might be prepared to offer networks a lower price for demand savings activities in localised areas. This is because the value of peak savings to the third party aggregator is equal to: the revenue received by the creation of certificates, plus the revenue that can be earned from networks for network investment deferral. If third party aggregators do not target peak savings in areas that create value for network businesses then those aggregators are potentially losing additional revenue that could be earned from network businesses. So far in our analysis we have assumed that the incentives created through the scheme to achieve peak energy savings translates into both wholesale and network benefits, which are captured in part through the value of the certificates created. This assumption relies on there being strong incentives within the wholesale market to minimise the cost of generation given changes to the load profile over time. In our opinion the current wholesale market arrangements do provide strong incentives to minimise the cost of generation to satisfy a given electricity demand load profile.24 However, the current arrangements do not provide an incentive to optimise investment in peak load generation investments compared with investments in peak savings activities. In addition it requires strong incentives within the network regulatory arrangements to ensure that incidental changes in peak energy demand are translated into network deferral savings and passed back onto customers. A further benefit from this option is that by creating a market for demand savings separate from network businesses it provides a platform for innovation in the development of programmes and activities to achieve demand savings. Businesses that are capable of 24 As we have explained earlier, this does not imply that the current wholesale market arrangements optimise the mix of demand management and generation activities to balance electricity demand and supply. NERA Economic Consulting 21 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options delivering demand savings for a cost less than market certificate prices will have an incentive to invest in those activities. Over time these incentives might be expected to lower the overall cost of reducing peak demand and improve the acceptability of these activities as a means of deferring network investments. In terms of the likely timing of benefits, Option 1A will likely result in changes to the load profile over the medium to long term and so will likely only deliver network or wholesale cost savings in the future. In contrast because Option 1B specifies a peak savings target, the peak demand reductions can be expected to arise in the near term and so there is a greater chance that this will result in near term benefits. However, for this to occur there is a need to ensure that the regulatory framework provides sufficient incentive to ensure that peak savings do in practice translate into network augmentation deferrals given the reliability risks created for network businesses. 3.2.3. Costs While this option is expected to result in lower wholesale costs over time, this will be partly offset by higher retail charges as retailers recover the cost of meeting energy savings obligations. For Option 1 to be net beneficial the incremental costs of the scheme should be less than these incremental benefits, taking into account all of the uncertainties involved. The incremental costs of including peak energy savings incentives within a wider scheme are likely to be minimal once a wider scheme is established. This is because much of the cost of the scheme is likely to involve developing appropriate assumptions about the energy savings values associated with particular activities, and the development of a scheme register. That said there are likely to be additional costs associated with determining the time profile of demand savings for defined energy saving activities, to allow the peak savings to be separately identified. This information is not needed for a general energy efficiency scheme. 3.2.4. Risks and uncertainties The core risk associated with creating a peak incentive relates to the size of the incentives created. If the value of certificates for peak savings, or a peak savings target is larger than the anticipated benefits then there is a risk that there will be over investment in peak savings programmes and activities. This creates a risk that costs will be imposed on electricity customers without the resultant benefits outweighing those costs. Alternatively, if the value of certificates or a peak savings target is smaller than the anticipated benefits from the scheme then there is a risk that there will be under investment in peak savings programmes and activities. There is also an issue related to additionality. In both Option 1A and 1B25 there is the risk that some activities that would have been undertaken even without additional certificates for peak energy savings or a peak savings target would now receive additional compensation through the creation and sale of peak certificates. This ‘free-rider’ cost means that the true 25 This risk would be reduced under a peak energy savings target to the extent that such a scheme expanded the list of eligible measures and tended to incentivise measures whose energy savings primarily take place at times of peak (eg, interruptible load). NERA Economic Consulting 22 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options benefit of such a peak savings incentive would need to be calculated as the value of additional take-up engendered by the peak savings initiative (in terms of avoided capacity and energy costs) less the additional compensation provided to those activities that would have occurred regardless of the peak savings scheme. Given these uncertainties, there is merit in ensuring that the scheme is sufficiently flexible to adapt to an improved understanding of the benefits over time. This suggests that incorporating an initial peak savings incentive based on the best available information and with a penalty price that is appropriate to manage the cost of the scheme to electricity consumers would be appropriate. However, the scheme administrators should be capable of updating this value or altering the penalty price as improved information becomes available. To ensure that scheme participants have certainty for their programme investments, this flexibility might involve periodic reviews of the target and penalty price after say two to three years. This would help ensure that a balance between scheme certainty and flexibility is achieved. In addition, Option 1B also risks pre-empting the outcomes of certain review processes currently underway in the NEM. Both the AER’s RIT-D and the AEMC’s Power of Choice review are exploring potential barriers to demand-side participation (DSP) and identifying mechanisms for overcoming those barriers. There is at least some potential for a mechanism that sets an explicit target for peak energy savings to (a) pre-empt the approaches to be developed by those processes (or require the peak energy saving mechanism to be discontinued, thereby potentially stranding investments made by ESCOs in responding to it), or (b) set a target level that turns out to have been inefficient as revealed subsequently by those processes. 3.2.5. Summary In summary, incorporating a specific incentive for peak energy savings within a wider energy savings scheme benefits from being administratively simple to implement, and will likely improve incentives to achieve incremental wholesale cost savings, particularly in the medium to long term. It would also complement incentives to consider non-network investments to planned network augmentations as provided through the NER. 3.3. Option 2: A Stand-Alone Peak Energy Saving Scheme This section examines the development of a stand-alone peak energy saving scheme that is separate from any general energy savings scheme that might be implemented. 3.3.1. Description of the option Option 2 creates a separate dedicated peak energy savings scheme that is not directly linked to a national energy savings scheme. This provides the flexibility to tailor the scheme’s design to ensure that the best peak energy savings outcomes are achieved. The key features of a stand-alone peak energy savings scheme include: NERA Economic Consulting 23 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options placing an energy savings target obligation on either electricity retailers or electricity network businesses, requiring energy savings certificates to be surrendered annually to fulfil the obligation; requiring the obligated entity to pay a penalty price if it does not have sufficient certificates to satisfy its obligations; allowing approved activities to generate energy savings certificates based on the total kilowatt hours (KWh) saved within a defined peak period (or deemed to be saved); being based on peak energy savings certificates that represent 1 kWh of energy saved during peak periods; allowing energy savings certificates to be traded and capable of being carried over into future years; and allowing the energy savings attributable to identified actions to be deemed for administrative simplicity, with a certificate creator having the option to use actual energy savings measurement as an alternative to deeming. The key differences of a stand-alone scheme compared to having an incentive for peak savings within a national energy savings scheme are: the flexibility to place the obligation on a different entity to the entity that might be responsible for the obligation under a national energy savings scheme (eg, allowing the obligation to be placed on network businesses rather than retailers); and the transparency of the cost of peak savings, as represented by the market price of peak savings certificates. In addition, there is the potential with a stand-alone scheme to place different target obligations for each state, network business or subregions within a network business’ area of operations, and/or apply a network deferral obligation rather than a peak energy savings obligation on network businesses. This would allow for potentially more refined targeting of the incentive for peak savings reductions.26 Figure 3.3 provides an illustrative representation of the incentives and outcomes anticipated from the implementation of a stand-alone peak energy savings target scheme on network businesses. For the purposes of this figure and the subsequent discussion we have assumed that the peak savings target is placed on distribution network businesses. 26 That said, we are sceptical about whether such an approach would enhance the incentives already faced by network businesses through the requirements of the NER to achieve peak savings where this is a cost effective alternative to a network investment. NERA Economic Consulting 24 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options Figure 3.3 Option 2: Stand-Alone Peak Energy Savings Target Scheme Under this option certificates would be generated for activities that lead to peak energy savings regardless of the location of those savings within the network. Network businesses would be required to surrender certificates up to the value of its obligation, or pay a penalty price. The penalty price ensures that the cost of achieving peak savings does not exceed the anticipated benefits from these savings. As a matter of principle, whether a peak energy savings obligation is placed on network businesses or retailers should not have any implications for the outcomes achieved from the scheme. So long as there are no limitations on the creation of certificates, the least cost options for achieving peak savings should be preferred as certificate creators seek to maximise profits from the creation of certificates. This means that network businesses will have an incentive to seek out network peak reductions, particularly where the network benefits, through avoided network costs, and additional revenue via the creation and sale of peak energy efficiency certificates is less than the cost of achieving the peak energy reductions. That said, a stand-alone peak energy savings scheme is unlikely to create additional incentives for a network business to seek out peak savings to defer planned network investments, because the cost of purchasing peak savings certificates in the market would be recoverable through network charges, which is equivalent to the purchase of peak savings directly from ESCOs, where this is a cost effective alternative to a planned network investment. It follows that the obligation and creation of a peak savings certificate market should not result in any ‘additional’ network deferment to the extent that the current incentives are sufficient to drive efficient investment in network deferral. That said, placing a direct obligation on network businesses means that these businesses would most likely actively participate in any peak energy savings scheme as it seeks to manage its obligation. In other words it enhances the incentives that network businesses would already have through the NER. In contrast, if the obligation is placed on retailers the incentives for network businesses arise only from the NER requirements and so if the reliability risks are considered substantial relative to the network deferral benefits then this NERA Economic Consulting 25 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options might result in less non-network investment activity than is desirable given the underlying cost and benefit comparisons. As with Option 1, while placing an obligation on peak energy savings will ensure that peak savings are achieved this does not mean that there will be greater deferral of near term planned network augmentation investments. This is because: there might be insufficient peak demand savings in locations where network augmentations are required; or the network business is not confident that planned non-network approaches will in practice avoid anticipated growth in peak demand and so undertakes the network augmentation so as to not breach system security requirements; and the network will already have a strong incentive to defer network investments where this is cost effective, through the NER requirements. This highlights the importance of the incentives placed on network businesses through the application of the NER to ensure that cost effective peak demand savings and associated network augmentation deferrals are achieved. 3.3.2. Benefits As with Option 1B, a stand-alone peak energy savings target scheme where the target is a peak savings obligation ensures that the peak savings are achieved where the cost of doing so does not exceed the penalty price. The scheme ensures that a market is created particularly for wholesale peak savings and so addresses the problem that there is no mechanism in the current arrangements to transfer the value of wholesale peak savings, where these savings are not coincident with network peaks, from customers to those parties that engage in activities to achieve peak savings. The benefits therefore most likely arise from placing a direct incentive on peak demand savings and influencing the load shape over time. This in turn allows for generation investment deferrals that over time lead to cost savings for consumers. Such a scheme is expected to create wholesale market benefits over the medium to long term because it provides a value for activities and programmes that target wholesale peak savings where these cost effectively result in generation investment deferrals over time. Importantly it provides the means for transferring the external benefits from an individual reducing peak demand to the third party undertaking the peak savings activity thereby ensuring that peak savings reductions are efficient. 3.3.3. Costs The cost of Option 2 is likely to be incrementally higher than for Option 1 because of: the additional administration costs associated with a separate scheme; and the need for a separate peak energy certificate register, certificate creation accreditation, and system for trading. NERA Economic Consulting 26 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options That said a stand-alone scheme would most likely make use of the systems and processes that would be developed for a national energy savings scheme and so these additional costs would most likely be marginal, so long as a national energy savings scheme was also introduced. As with Option 1B, the additional costs of the scheme therefore relate mostly to the establishment costs of determining the time profile for energy savings for activities that target peak demand reductions. We understand that there is some information available on this, which would likely form the base for developing further evidence on these savings. In addition, we would expect that the agency responsible for the scheme would develop its understanding of these savings over time, and so could improve upon any initial estimates made thereby improving the incentives for peak savings. 3.3.4. Risks and uncertainties The risk with any target based scheme is ensuring that incentives are not created to overinvest in peak savings relative to the anticipated benefits from the peak savings. This creates a risk that costs will be imposed on electricity customers without the resultant benefits outweighing those costs. This highlights the importance of ensuring that any penalty price associated with a scheme is set in line with an estimate of the anticipated benefits from each kilowatt hour of peak savings achieved. If the penalty price is set too high, then more activity will be undertaken than is justified relative to the underlying benefits and costs. Similarly if the penalty price is set too low then less activity will be undertaken compared to the underlying benefits and costs. In addition, Option 2, like Option1B, increases the risk that some activities which would have been undertaken absent a peak savings target will now receive additional compensation through the creation and sale of peak certificates. This ‘free-rider’ cost means that the true benefit of such a peak savings incentive would need to be calculated as the value of additional take-up engendered by the peak savings initiative (in terms of avoided capacity and energy costs) less the additional compensation provided to those activities that would have occurred regardless of the peak savings scheme. Given the uncertainty of benefits, there would be merit in having a modest penalty price commensurate with the costs of existing programmes that achieve peak energy savings. This will ensure that the scheme results in some activities being undertaken while limiting the possible costs of the scheme. It should also be noted that several current and past reviews have been undertaken with the explicit purpose of exploring the potential barriers to demand-side participation (DSP) and identifying mechanisms for overcoming those barriers and so promoting an efficient level of DSP. Two reviews of significance that are currently underway are the AER’s RIT-D and the AEMC’s Power of Choice review. There is at least some potential for a mechanism that sets an explicit target for peak energy savings to (a) pre-empt the approaches to be developed by those processes (or require the peak energy saving mechanism to be discontinued, thereby potentially stranding investments made by ESCOs to respond to it), or (b) set a target level that turns out to have been inefficient as revealed subsequently by those processes. NERA Economic Consulting 27 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options 3.3.5. Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options Summary In summary, Option 2 provides flexibility to design a peak energy savings scheme that places an obligation on network businesses directly (as compared to retailers) and also potentially allows those obligations to be more directly targeted. This will ensure that the value of peak savings is separately identifiable to general energy savings. 3.4. Option 3: A Single Buyer of Peak Energy Savings This chapter examines the creation of a single buyer for peak energy savings, as an alternative to the market based approaches for providing incentives for peak savings embodied in Options 1 and 2. 3.4.1. Description of the option The final option involves the creation of a new energy market role to manage peak energy demand. As a consequence, this option does not place any direct obligations on energy market participants to reduce peak demand. It also does not create a tradable certificate scheme. The aim of the single peak buyer would be to cost effectively flatten the load profile by purchasing activities from third parties that seek to reduce peak demand. Such an entity could: stand in the market offering to purchase all peak energy reductions at a predetermined price (linked to the estimated benefits of peak demand reduction); and/or conduct periodic requests for bids to achieve peak demand outcomes for each year over a forward time horizon, say every six or twelve months; and/or work closely with network businesses and/or demand management operators to fund identified peak demand activities and achieve voluntary targets; and/or activate/control purchased demand management actions during wholesale or network peak periods to directly achieve peak demand reductions. This function and the associated activities could be funded either through a levy on all electricity customers or from consolidated revenue. The middle two approaches would allow for specific targeting of peak demand reductions to achieve network deferral benefits. It would create an opportunity for each network business to determine its price for undertaking a demand management option as compared to a network augmentation given both the direct costs and risks involved. Figure 3.4 provides an illustrative representation of the incentives and outcomes anticipated from the implementation of a single peak savings buyer scheme. NERA Economic Consulting 28 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options Figure 3.4 Option 3: Single Peak Savings Buyer Scheme The key feature of the single peak savings buyer scheme is that it creates a market distinct from networks or retailers, for the provision of peak savings whereby third parties can have certainty about the revenue associated with providing actual or deemed peak savings. In contrast to the previous two options, energy savings businesses would be paid an agreed amount (either through an agreed purchase contract or fixed price arrangement) and so could undertake activities with certainty about the revenue that will be received. The certificate based schemes require ESCOs to forecast likely revenue from the sale of peak savings certificates which would be more uncertain. 3.4.2. Benefits The benefits of this option include: it creates a transparent market for demand management initiatives with financial certainty provided to demand management providers about the value of peak demand reductions into the future; the cost of the scheme can be directly managed through the size of the levy; where the entity purchases demand reductions directly and guarantees the achievement of these reductions, it removes the risk of non-achievement of peak demand reductions from network businesses,27 as a third party becomes responsible for managing the load profile; and to the extent that the single buyer controls load it can actively manage load during wholesale peak demand events. 27 This arrangement would require distributors to gauge the likely effectiveness of peak savings programmes given obligations to satisfy reliability and security standards. NERA Economic Consulting 29 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options This approach allows generators, network businesses and retailers to focus on their own activities and respond to changes in forecast load shape as a consequence of the scheme over time. It also does not alter the incentives for network businesses to seek out peak savings to defer network investments, as created through the NER regulatory investment test requirements. 3.4.3. Costs Establishing a dedicated peak energy savings buyer is the highest cost option across each of the options that have been developed. These costs relate to: the cost of establishing a new entity or creating a new responsibility within an existing entity, to undertake the single buyer functions; and the ongoing cost of operating the entity, which will vary according to the extent of involvement of the entity in developing and identifying peak savings options. This option is likely to have considerably higher costs for administration compared to the other scheme design options. This is because of the need for the buyer to be actively involved with managing peak energy use, and potentially working directly with network businesses and/or ESCOs to identify the opportunities for peak savings. The cost of operating the entity would also need to be borne by either governments (ie, taxpayers) or electricity customers more directly perhaps through the implementation of a levy. The latter arrangement would mean that the cost of the scheme would be transparent, while the benefits arising from the scheme will be less clear as they will be shared across electricity users in the form of lower prices. This is in comparison to a scheme that places an obligation on retailers to achieve peak energy savings, where the costs of this obligation will likely be incorporated into the retail prices (though likely not in a transparent way). 3.4.4. Risks and uncertainties While the single buyer has higher establishment and ongoing operational costs, it also provides greater flexibility to manage peak savings over time as improved information and understanding of the opportunities arise. This means that the single buyer: will likely learn from its experience in purchasing peak savings and so improve its understanding of the reliability of particular activities and programmes; can choose to increase or decrease the amount of peak savings purchased as its understanding of the benefits increases; and can directly manage the cost of peak savings through its budgetary processes. In addition, it means that any changes in the anticipated load profile that are achieved by the actions of the single buyer can be taken by network businesses in their network planning processes. This means that network businesses need not separately evaluate the potential for peak savings activities to be achieved. As in the case of Options 1B and 2, Option 3 runs the risk of pre-empting the various reviews that have been put in train to explore the potential barriers to demand-side participation NERA Economic Consulting 30 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Peak Energy Savings Scheme Options (DSP) and to identify mechanisms for overcoming those barriers and thereby assist in achieving an efficient level of DSP. The two most significant of these are the AER’s RIT-D and the AEMC’s Power of Choice review. As was also the case in Options 1B and 2, there is at least some potential for Option 3 to (a) pre-empt the approaches to be developed by those processes (or require the peak energy saving mechanism to be discontinued, thereby potentially stranding investments made by ESCOs to respond to it), or (b) set a target level that turns out not to have been an efficient level as revealed subsequently by those processes. 3.4.5. Summary The single peak energy buyer option has the advantage of creating a clear and transparent market for third party providers of peak energy savings activities to develop, which over time would be expected to enhance the market’s capacity to deliver these activities. Similarly the single buyer would have the flexibility to adapt to changes over time and learn from its experience in delivering peak energy savings. In practice this means that the load duration curve for the market would be actively managed by an independent third party entity with clear rules governing its activities, and within an overarching operational objective. This means that network businesses can focus on satisfying network reliability obligations given expectations about future load requirements, taking into account the activities of the single buyer. While a single buyer creates flexibility in the achievement of peak demand savings, and allows for greater targeting of activities, it also involves the largest administrative costs compared to scheme design Options 1 and 2. This is because of the costs involved with actively planning and participating in the market for peak demand savings. Relevantly, this option is least consistent with a market-based approach to reducing peak demand. NERA Economic Consulting 31 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options 4. Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings There are two principle benefit categories resulting from peak energy savings, namely: generation benefits; and network benefits. This chapter examines the methodologies that can be employed to model these benefits. In addition, we outline some of the data considerations. 4.1. Modelling generation benefits Lowering wholesale peak demand over the medium to long term is expected to result in three key wholesale market outcomes, specifically: a reduced need for new peaking generation capacity and fuel costs (as greater use is made of lower fuel cost generation capacity) as a consequence of a flatter system load profile and load duration curve; reduced fuel requirements as a direct result of reduced total electricity consumption; and a reduction in unserved energy. The effect of these outcomes is lower average wholesale market prices over time and reduced unserved energy. The remainder of this section describes the methodological approaches that can be used to estimate these benefits. 4.1.1. Methodological approaches There are two basic approaches that can be used to assess the impact of peak demand (and energy consumption) reductions on the generation sector, namely: a static approach, and a dynamic approach. The static approach uses a representative economic value for each unit of demand saved and simply multiplies this unit value by the peak demand and energy consumption impacts expected to be achieved by an ESI scheme (or other scheme of interest). The unit value of peak demand reduction is usually estimated with reference to the installed cost of peaking generation (though in some analyses fixed operating and maintenance costs are added). The unit value of reduced electricity consumption is generally estimated with reference to the fuel and other variable operating and maintenance costs of a peaking plant. In both cases, the costs used are generally those of an open-cycle gas turbine (OCGT), which is the type of plant most commonly used to meet peak energy and demand requirements.28 28 That said, this is not always the case. In practice OCGT plants are not always the marginal generation type. Often other plants are called upon specifically to meet peak demand. These can include hydro or wind generation depending on the particular characteristics of the NEM region or generation system. NERA Economic Consulting 32 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings Energy reductions are generally estimated on an annual basis over a future time horizon and the resulting avoided costs discounted to a present value. The installed cost of the plant is therefore converted into an annualised cost that includes the initial capital and labour cost to construct the plant, the financing charges that would be incurred, and the annual fixed operating and maintenance costs. Future fuel costs are estimated based on expected real price increases. By contrast, the dynamic approach uses a market model to simulate the change in the overall plant mix and fuel usage that could be expected to result from the peak demand and electricity consumption reductions achieved by a peak energy savings scheme. Such models are set up to represent the generation system being examined29 and the businessas-usual forecast30 of peak demand and electricity consumption (ie, the peak demand and electricity consumption that is expected to occur in the absence of the scheme being analysed). These models also generally have databases of the cost and operating characteristics of a wide range of types of electricity generation plant. An optimisation model is used to identify the amount of generation capacity of each different plant type that will meet forecast peak and total electricity demand at least cost.31 The impact of the scheme is assessed by altering the load forecast to reflect the changes that the scheme is forecast to produce in peak demand and electricity consumption on an annual basis over the life of the scheme and the expected useful life of the changes in end-use technology it engenders.32 4.1.2. Data considerations The data requirements for the two approaches differ considerably, as shown in Table 4.1 below. 29 Wholesale electricity market models will also generally ensure that “committed plant” (generating plants that have already at least commenced the siting and licencing process) are included as planned in the future generation plant mix. Plants beyond the existing and committed plants are brought into the generation system based on their ability to meet forecast peak and total electricity demand at least cost. To do so, these models rely on ‘perfect foresight’; that is, they take the future demand forecast as certain and bring specific new plant into the generation system in the order and sizes that will produce the lowest cost for meeting all demand over the entire timeframe being analysed. While generation plant investment in real-world competitive electricity markets are not made by such a central decision-making process, the NEM has been shown to provide very close to least-cost generation investment outcomes. 30 Although these analyses generally use an ‘expected’ forecast of peak and total electricity demand, in practice, a number of alternative forecasts are generally investigated. 31 Many of these models will also have a mechanism for simulating generation bidding behaviour as a means of better forecasting prices. The realism of the prices is also often checked against the commercial adequacy of the total revenue they provide for individual generators and generation companies, the logic being that prices that fail to provide commercial returns for individual plants are likely to result in retirements and prices that fail to provide commercial returns for a number of plants are likely to be unsustainable in the longer term. 32 A less frequently used approach is to view demand-side actions as alternative generation options in the generation plant database. In this approach, the load forecast is simply re-run with the demand-side options included in the generation plant database. The optimisation routine will then simply see the various demand-side options as additional means for meeting forecast peak and total electricity demand at least cost. NERA Economic Consulting 33 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings Table 4.1 Data Requirements of the Static and Dynamic Approaches to Estimate Wholesale Market Benefits Static approach Supply-side data requirements Annualised cost of marginal generation plant Current and expected price of fuel for marginal generation plant (real dollars) Dynamic approach Operating costs and technical performance of existing and committed generation plants Bidding behaviour of current generation plants Capital costs for construction and operating costs and technical performance of the range of generation plant that could be constructed in the future (including any limits on how much or how quickly such plants can be constructed) Forecast annual electricity demand Demand-side data requirements peak and total Annual reduction in peak demand Either: Annual reduction in energy consumption reduction in demand on an hourly basis for each year of the period of interest, or reduction in peak demand and energy consumption in peak, shoulder and off-peak period for weekdays and weekends in each season While the data required in the dynamic approach on the supply side is considerable and complex, it is generally available in market simulation and generation system expansion models that are used by electricity market participants and regulatory and planning bodies concerned with the electricity market. Importantly, the information required in both the static and dynamic approaches to estimating wholesale benefits of peak and total electricity demand reductions requires consideration of a number of important and complex inputs, including: the number of existing facilities for which any particular demand-side technology is applicable (technical potential); the number of facilities in which any particular demand-side technology is likely to achieve a level of cost-effectiveness that could be assumed to be of interest to the owner of that facility (economic potential); the number of those facilities that will actually purchase and use the demand-side technology, and the timeframe over which they do so (achievable potential and take-up rate); the number of existing facilities (and end-use equipment) that will be taken out of service and the number of new facilities that will be built over the period of interest and the rate at which this will happen, as this will determine the number of facilities for which each demand-side technology is eligible; NERA Economic Consulting 34 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings the degree to which new facilities differ from existing facilities and the consequent change in the amount of savings that each demand-side technology will provide and therefore its likely economic and achievable potential; the degree to which the actual technical performance of each demand-side technology differs from the expected performance; the degree to which end users may increase their use of electricity (in the affected end use or other end uses) due to the savings provided by the demand-side technology (rebound effect); the degree to which participants in the scheme would have adopted the demand-side technology even in the absence of the programme (free-rider impact); and the degree to which the scheme encourages end users to undertake additional peak demand or energy consumption reduction technologies or behaviours (free-driver impact). Relatively little ‘real-world’ information on these variables is available in Australia, and as a result these variables are generally estimated in the analyses. While actual in-field data for these variables would be useful (and an increasing amount of data is becoming available from the various trials and pilot programs that have been undertaken by electricity companies and governments) the impact of changes in these variables on the overall performance of a demand-side scheme can be investigated via sensitivity and break-even analysis.33 Data availability is particularly poor for the hourly demand impacts of demand-side technologies that are required in the dynamic approach, and this variable is much more difficult to address through sensitivity analysis as it is actually a series of values (8,760 hourly values, though in practice many fewer can be used to adequately characterise the relevant load shape impact for the purpose of the dynamic analysis). While a number of programs have been undertaken in which interval metering has been installed along with demand-side technologies, very little data on the load shape of the affected end use both before and after installation of the demand-side technologies has become widely available. Establishment of a database of such information would provide an important resource for and significantly add to the credibility of demand-side analysis to support policy decision-making. Finally, the above discussion concerns the information that is required to assess the benefits of the demand-side activities that could be expected to result if a national peak energy savings initiative scheme were to be implemented. To evaluate the merits of such a scheme would also require consideration of the cost – and therefore the cost-effectiveness – of those activities and the scheme as a whole. Relevant costs include: the cost to the end-use consumer for purchase, installation and maintenance of the demand-side measures (note that these costs are those that will serve as the key inputs to the economic attractiveness and take-up of the demand-side activity); 33 Sensitivity analysis assesses the change in the dependent variable (in this case, the scheme’s impact on peak and total electricity demand) as changes are made to the value assumed for the independent variable (in this case, the variable discussed in the series of dot points above). The analyst can then ascertain whether the outcome of the dependent variable is particularly sensitive to assumptions about the independent variable, as well as the likelihood of the outcome of the dependent variable based on the likelihood of the specific values required for the independent variable to produce that outcome. Break-even analysis identifies the value of the independent variable that produces a given outcome in the dependent variable. NERA Economic Consulting 35 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings the cost to obligated parties in complying with the scheme obligation, which will include the amount these parties have to pay to purchase their required number of certificates (including penalty payments), and any administrative or marketing costs they incur in meeting their obligation; the cost incurred by certificate-creating organisations for accreditation or other compliance requirements; and the costs incurred by relevant government agencies in designing or administering the scheme, including any costs incurred by governments in decommissioning existing programs in favour of a national scheme. 4.2. Modelling network benefits There is the potential for network peak demand savings to result in lower network costs by: reducing the need for additional network infrastructure to satisfy reliability requirements under conditions of growing peak demand and so lower the costs of network infrastructure; and improving system security and reliability due to the scope for: – (a) ‘passive’ demand-side measures34 to reduce demand on system elements that could be overburdened at times of peak demand; and – (b) ‘callable’ and ‘dispatchable’ demand response35 to change the level of demand on system elements in response to peak demands or forced outage of a system element. Importantly, a reduction in the total amount of electricity consumed does not provide a benefit to networks (and therefore a benefit that could flow on in whole or in part to end-use consumers). This is primarily because the most significant driver of network costs is capital expenditure for network infrastructure. The costs of that infrastructure is recovered through tariffs which are largely based on throughput (ie, charges for electricity consumed). It follows that any scheme that reduces total electricity consumption will also reduce network revenue without any commensurate reduction in network costs, except where that consumption reduction is coincidental with peak demand. As a result, where the combination of peak and total electricity demand reduction reduces system load factor, it will exert upward pressure on network prices. Where demand-side activities increase system load factor, they will put downward pressure on network tariffs. 34 ‘Passive’ demand-side measures are those whose impact on peak and total electricity demand are a function of the technology itself, rather than how the end user operates the technology. High efficiency lighting, high efficiency refrigerators and high efficiency air conditioning are examples of passive demand side measures. 35 Both ‘callable’ and ‘dispatchable’ demand response differ from passive demand side measures in that they only come into play when the network (or generation) systems need them. In ‘dispatchable’ demand response, the network (or network agent) has control over the end-use load that is to be reduced or interrupted, though the exercise of that control is generally governed by explicit conditions mutually agreed by the network and the end-use customer. In ‘callable’ demand response, the network (or its agent) has the right to request that the end user reduce his/her consumption, but does not have control of that consumption. The number of such calls, the amount of load to be reduced, the timing and duration of the reduction, and the extent to which the end-use consumer can deviate from those conditions are generally agreed to between the network and the end-use customer. NERA Economic Consulting 36 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings Finally, as explained earlier many of the network benefits associated with network peak demand savings are likely to be attributable to the new and proposed arrangements for network investment decision making required by the NER. That said, the methodological approaches to estimating these benefits are common irrespective of the mechanisms by which the incentives for efficient investment in peak savings are achieved. 4.2.1. Methodological approaches Estimating network benefits of an energy savings scheme are complicated by the need to understand the peak demand and load factor implications of any energy saving activates undertaken. It is further complicated by the need to understand the locations in the network where demand is saved, as the benefits can vary considerably by location. Those areas within a distribution network can be as small as a feeder or a zone substation. In practice, this makes modelling the benefits of network peak demand savings for electricity networks significantly more difficult than in the case of the generation system. Specifically: the network costs that can be reduced by demand-side activities – namely reduction in peak demand – arise at the local level within the network asset base, and most networks (particularly distribution networks) have a very large number of such areas – not infrequently in the hundreds of specific areas; the need for additional capacity to meet peak demand within each local area can be foreseen by network planners, but the exact timing of each project can vary substantially; and the key parameters for each capacity augmentation project are unique in terms of: – the amount of demand reduction needed to defer augmentation; – the timeframe by which that amount of demand reduction must be achieved; – the exact timing, duration and frequency that demand response will need to be available in order to achieve the deferral; and – the nature of the customer base within the constrained area (and so the demand-side potential for providing the demand response needed within the timeframe available). Two basic modelling approaches can be used to estimate potential network benefits from network peak savings, namely: the deferral approach, which is a bottom-up approach that seeks to determine the actual capacity augmentation projects that can be deferred by demand-side activities (or other non-network solutions) and the aggregate value of those deferrals over time; and the area-wide demand reduction approach, which is a top-down approach that makes the assumption that any permanent reduction in peak demand that occurs anywhere in the network will reduce capital costs at some point in time, and applies judgemental (or at least semi-judgemental) adjustment factors to account for the fact that (a) some portions of the service territory may be experiencing very slow (or even negative growth) and (b) different parts of the service territory will experience peak demands at different times of the day or even different seasons from each other, and from the generation sector. NERA Economic Consulting 37 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings Table 4.2 below summarises the key advantages and disadvantages of each of these approaches. Table 4.2 Principal Advantages and Disadvantages of the Deferral and Area-Wide Approaches to Assessing the Network Benefits of Peak Savings Advantages Disadvantages Deferral approach Closely reflects the real financial cost of peak demand on the network and the benefits to be realised from deferral of specific augmentation projects Requires a significant amount of data on specific demand growth-related augmentation projects, including: the current capacity limitation and level of peak demand in the local area how quickly peak demand is growing in the local area the estimated cost and latest construction start date of the supply-side solution a list of major customers within the area and their peakday load profiles the number of other customers within the local area broken down into at least major customer sectors, including their contribution to peak demand or at least their aggregate electricity consumption on a peak day Networks generally project likely augmentation requirements on a rolling 5-year horizon, and the need for augmentation is not constant over time in volume or cost terms. This makes it difficult to accurately project potential deferral benefits over a longer time frame which also makes it more appropriate for guiding programme targeting rather than for assessing long-term scheme benefits. Area-wide approach Very simple to use Establishing the ‘average value’ for reducing network peak demand is difficult --the cost of network augmentation differs significantly across and within distribution service territories Requires only minimal network-specific information An average value – even a distribution business-specific average – will tend to be ‘wrong’ more often than right. some areas experience extremely slow growth not all local areas peak in the same season or time of day Adjustment factors are generally needed to account for this but rely significantly on the judgement of the analyst Can be made more granular by applying the approach to regions within the distribution service territory that have different cost characteristics or peak demands in different seasons 4.2.2. Each increase in granularity requires that all of the required information be gathered regarding the new level of granularity, and adds complexity to the task of forecasting outcomes Data considerations The main difficulties with obtaining the data required to assess the area-specific network benefits of network peak demand savings are that: NERA Economic Consulting 38 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings there are a large number of areas within each network (especially the distribution networks) that may require augmentation at any particular point in time; virtually all of the inputs to the valuation of area-specific augmentation deferral are specific to the particular situation, adding significantly to the amount of analysis required; the timing of the need for each specific augmentation can change not only due to external circumstances (such as deviations from forecast load growth and non-normal weather) but also due to changes in other parts of the network asset base (eg, new circuits that allow different areas to share capacity); and the network only publicly predicts the need for area-specific augmentation about five years into the future. Assembling and maintaining this data requires a significant amount of effort. The amount of data required for the area-wide assessment of the network benefits of network peak savings, by contrast, is much smaller – generally only consisting of: the season and time of day that best characterises peak demand across the network;36 the amount of peak demand reduction that can be provided by the scheme;37 and the average cost of augmenting network capacity.38 While these data requirements make area-wide analyses much less taxing from the perspective of data assembly and maintenance, the fact that several key bits of information are likely to be represented by highly uncertain values is of concern. The two items of most concern in this regard are: the appropriate value to use for the average cost of additional capacity that is required due to increases in peak demand – the value most frequently used is the long-run average incremental cost (LRAIC) of network capacity, which is easy to define but values can vary significantly; and the judgemental factors to be used to discount the expected value of the peak demand reductions available within the area due to peak demand that occur at different times or in areas within the network that are experiencing very slow (or negative) load growth. The area-wide approach can be applied at areas within a given distribution service territory that have different demand profiles and/or cost structures. This can allow a greater level of 36 In the case of larger network service areas that span different areas, different climate characteristics can produce peak demands that occur at different times of the day or even seasons of the year. Similar differences can occur in different local areas with different mixes of customers across the major customer sectors. In such cases, the network can be broken up into smaller, more homogeneous sub-areas and a different area-wide analysis conducted in each. 37 The amount of peak demand reduction that can be provided by the scheme is a function of the customer mix and enduse characteristics of those customers. Where different parts of the network can be classified as having different customer and end-use mixes, these groupings can be used to identify the amount and type of peak demand reduction that is likely to be available in various areas, based on customer counts. 38 In the case of networks that have different portions of their infrastructure with very different cost characteristics, separate area-wide analyses can be undertaken for each part of the system, with each area being expected to have its own average cost of incremental capacity. NERA Economic Consulting 39 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings granularity to the analysis, but requires a corresponding increase in data and would add to the complexity of scheme implementation. 4.2.3. Recommendations on modelling the network benefits of a national ESI Modelling the network benefits of the introduction of a national ESI requires consideration to be given to: the likely impact of the scheme on network peak savings; and the likely size of the network deferral benefits that can be achieved by the associated network peak savings. As we discuss in this report, we believe that the incremental impact on network peak savings of a peak energy savings incentive as part of an ESI is likely to be relatively small compared to the efficient peak savings which will potentially be achieved through incentives created through the NER. Regardless, there remains merit in considering the likely size of the network benefits of peak energy savings irrespective of how the incentives to achieve these savings are created. We have been asked as part of this project to provide any insights on the methodology for estimating the network benefits of an ESI, based in part on our discussions with both network businesses and the consultants that have been engaged to undertake this modelling. In summary, we believe that: To the extent possible, the analysis should try to assess the impact of a national ESI on network tariffs. This will require consideration of the changes wrought by the scheme in terms of both peak and total demand (ie, the change in load factor) as this will determine whether the scheme will tend to have an upward or downward impact on average network tariffs, and the relative magnitude of that pressure. This analysis will need to be undertaken on a jurisdictional or individual company basis, and will be unlikely to be undertaken with any real degree of accuracy for more than a single regulatory determination period (or two such periods at most), due to the large number of factors that are relevant to the setting of the tariffs, and the degree to which they could change over that timeframe. Both the system and end-use load profiles to be used in the analysis should be based on 10% Probability of Exceedance conditions as these will provide a more realistic assessment of the impact of the demand-side measures being considered. The load profiles (and more specifically the change in load profile) attributed to each energy efficiency or peak savings measure should be re-assessed for their impact at the time of network (or area-specific) peak demand, as illustrated in Figure 4.1 below. This is an important step to ensure that the demand-side impacts anticipated to be available are as realistic as possible. NERA Economic Consulting 40 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings Figure 4.1 Illustrative Alignment of Peak Savings Measure with Network Peaks (Impact of High Efficient Street Lighting) 14000 160 12000 140 MW (System wide) 100 8000 80 6000 60 4000 MW (Local network) 120 10000 40 2000 20 0 0 0:30 2:00 3:30 System peak demand 5:00 6:30 8:00 9:30 Reduced system peak 11:00 12:30 14:00 15:30 Local network peak 17:00 18:30 20:00 21:30 reduced network peak 23:00 Figure 4.1 illustrates the point by overlaying the summer peak day profile of the generation system (characterised by a broad, midday peak that persists through to early evening), on the peak day profile of a network area whose loads are predominantly residential (and characterised by a load profile of heavy demand in the morning and a slightly higher peak that builds in the afternoon and persists through the mid-evening hours). Overlaid on both of these is a representation of how an increase in the efficiency of street lighting would affect these load profiles. Note that the profiles are illustrative and so are not drawn to scale. Rather, it is the shape of these demands that is of interest. Specifically, in the middle of the day the street lights are turned off so the increase of efficiency in street lighting will not produce any reduction in the generation peak demand, which occurs at about 16:00. By contrast, by the time the network experiences its peak demand – at about 19:30 or 20:00 – the street lights will have come on and the increase in efficiency will reduce network peak demand. In addition, the following recommendations are offered with regard to modelling network benefits related to each of the peak scheme design options presented in chapter 3 above, regardless of which of the three design options discussed above is taken forward into the analysis: The peak demand impacts of the energy efficiency and peak demand reduction measures to be assessed should be calculated at the specific season and time of day of the relevant network or network area peaks to provide as accurate an estimate as possible of the value of the measure in each network application. This should be done whether the analysis is undertaken on an area-specific or area-wide basis. Any peak demand benefit of the NERA Economic Consulting 41 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings measure to the network will then need to be considered in addition to any generation system benefit that is taken into account in valuing the measure.39 Forecast impacts of the measures on network tariffs, (and electricity prices more generally) where material, should be taken into account in assessing the economic attractiveness of the demand-side measures in subsequent year programme take-up estimates. The consumers’ share of forecast certificate values should be taken into account in estimating the take-up of the various measures eligible for certificates under the programme. Wholesale market modelling should be used to assess the impacts of the benefits in the generation sector based on retailer obligations. To the extent that there is seen to be merit in adding a value for the potential network benefits of a national ESI to the wholesale market benefit, this would seem to be most reasonably done by using the area-wide approach and using a value such as the long-run average incremental cost (LRAIC) of network capacity additions as the value to be ascribed to reductions in network peak demand. The LRAIC value will allow the network to provide additional targeting for area-specific augmentation deferral where the deferral value is higher than the LRAIC, and consideration should be given to developing LRAIC values specific to each distribution business (or to different regions within larger distribution service territories, which might be at the option of the distribution business). In any case, the LRAIC should probably also be subject to an adjustment factor (a decimal value less than 1.0) to reflect the fact that not all energy efficiency impacts will result in peak demand savings for the network, and that even where they do reduce peak demand they may not change network capital requirements for the foreseeable future. No additional credit should be attributed for short-term deferral network benefits as these will accrue primarily due to the regulatory framework as it is expected to be enhanced by the addition of the RIT-D.40 4.3. Summary There are two principal approaches for assessing the impact of demand-side measures (including energy efficiency activities) that might be implemented as a consequence of peak savings on the generation sector. While the static approach is significantly easier to apply, the data and computing resources needed for the dynamic approach are generally available, and it also provides a more realistic estimate of peak savings implications on the generation sector. 39 It is our understanding that market modelling is being used to assess the benefits to the generation sector of each of the options for adding a peak demand savings initiative to a retailer obligation based ESI. We strongly support the use of that approach. 40 Although, it should be noted that under Option 1, networks may have a significant incentive to use the existence of an ESI to focus area-specific demand-side augmentation deferral efforts in those areas where there is significant overlap in the timing and duration of generation and network peak demand. NERA Economic Consulting 42 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Modelling the Benefits of Peak Energy Savings Data is significantly more problematic to estimate the impact of peak savings on electricity networks. This is because the network peak demand impacts that drive network costs are those that occur in the various specific asset areas comprising the network, and even more importantly, in those areas in which additional capacity is forecast to be needed within the foreseeable future. The benefit of a scheme to reduce peak demand in such areas rests in the potential to encourage the take-up of a sufficient number of demand-side options to keep peak demand within the capacity of the current infrastructure and to do so before construction of assets required to meet additional demand would have to be commenced. Calculating the aggregate potential of such instances across any single network requires a significant amount of data, and can only be done over the time period for which the distribution company can project the need for additional capacity, which is typically five years or so. It follows that while such an approach may be helpful for identifying specific targets in the event that a national ESI with either Option 1 or Option 2 is implemented, it is less likely to be useful for projecting the potential benefits of peak savings over a longer time period. For that purpose, an area-wide approach (of a yet to be determined level of granularity) is likely to be more appropriate. In that approach, the assumption is made that any reduction in peak demand anywhere on the network will be of value at some point, as ultimately, the entire network is very likely to have to be expanded. The long run average expenditure for capital expansion of the network is then deemed to equate, on an annualised basis, as the value of reduced peak demand to the network. Judgemental factors are applied to the figure to account for the fact that some parts of the network may experience peak demand at a different time of day or season than the system as a whole, and that some parts of the network are experiencing very slow growth. This approach can be used in association with the market modelling recommended for use in assessing the generation sector benefits of peak energy savings in each of the three options described in this study. NERA Economic Consulting 43 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options 5. Evaluating Scheme Design Options Evaluating Scheme Design Options This chapter evaluates the scheme design options and highlights the relative merits and disadvantages of each approach. 5.1. Criteria for assessment Each of the scheme designs has merits and deficiencies. To assist with an evaluation of the options a number of design criteria have been developed, specifically: scheme design and implementation; – ease of implementation; – scheme establishment and administrative costs; scheme benefits; – likelihood of achieving peak savings; – likelihood of achieving near term wholesale/network benefits; – likelihood of achieving medium to long term wholesale/network benefits; promotion of innovation in peak demand reductions; consistency with other regulatory processes; and certainty of peak reduction. The following sections examine each of the schemes against these criteria. 5.2. Scheme design and implementation The first criteria relates to the ease of scheme design and implementation. Both Option 1 (ie, a peak savings incentive) and Option 2 (a stand-alone peak savings scheme) are likely to be relatively easy to implement and administer compared against Option 3 (ie, a single peak energy savings buyer scheme). This is principally because of the scope to make use of the systems and processes that will also need to be developed as part of a national energy savings scheme. The incremental cost of either creating an incentive for peak savings, or establishing a separate peak savings target obligation, is therefore relatively small. That said, if a separate peak savings target is created with either Option 1 or 2, additional compliance costs will be imposed on the obligated party (ie, retailers or networks). These arise from the need to separately surrender peak certificates (in the case of Option 2) or account for peak savings (in the case of Option 1). Establishing a single peak energy savings buyer scheme (Option 3) would require consideration of the administrative arrangements for the scheme. The options could include the scheme being administered by a government department, the entity responsible for the national energy savings scheme, or a new separate entity. The choice between approaches NERA Economic Consulting 44 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Evaluating Scheme Design Options would likely reflect the entity’s approach to managing peak demand. If it was to actively manage peak demand then ensuring the entity was independent would be important to minimise any uncertainties for participants in the wholesale electricity market. However, if it was managing medium to long term load profile via a bidding scheme, then this might be readily administered by a government department or the peak energy savings scheme administrator. 5.3. Scheme benefits An important consideration for the choice of scheme design is the certainty with which the scheme will achieve the anticipated benefits. As we have noted, most of the schemes will achieve either the level of peak savings specified by a target obligation or requirement or result in a penalty being paid. The differences between the schemes relate to the incentives created to target the achievement of benefits and the timeframe within which those benefits might be achieved. As we have explained in the report, these schemes are unlikely to enhance the achievement of short-term network benefits arising from the deferral of specific augmentation projects because the incentives to undertake peak savings to defer network investments are based mostly on the requirements in the NER. That said there might be some incremental network benefits over the medium to long term from: innovation in peak savings activities and programmes resulting from an expansion of activities by ESCOs seeking to create certificates or to respond to requests from a single peak savings buyer; and improved certainty of savings as more peak savings programmes and activities are developed and implemented over time. In regards to wholesale benefits, both a peak savings incentive and a target scheme have the potential to achieve benefits in the medium to long term. This is because the benefits arise mostly from the deferral of new peak generation investments in the medium to long term. That said, a peak energy savings buyer might be capable of achieving near term wholesale benefits if it engaged in activities that involved controlling load into the market to influence peak prices. This would have a near term effect of lowering wholesale costs that would influence future contract prices and so lower retail costs. In summary, a peak savings incentive or peak savings target scheme would be expected to deliver benefits in the medium to long term as load profiles changed and generation investments were deferred. A peak savings buyer has the potential to create nearer term wholesale benefits. 5.4. Other considerations The remaining criteria relate to the promotion of innovation in peak demand reductions; consistency with other regulatory processes; and certainty of peak reductions. NERA Economic Consulting 45 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Evaluating Scheme Design Options All of the schemes will have the effect of promoting innovation in peak demand reductions because they all create a market for these activities. This contrasts with the current environment where any innovation in programmes and activities for peak demand savings may not have a buyer, which inhibits the development of innovation in the first place. Of the three scheme designs, the single peak savings buyer is anticipated to have the best incentives for innovation because it creates certainty of revenue for peak savings programmes through either a contracting or defined payment system. In contrast the market based schemes still require third parties to forecast likely certificate prices to determine the expected revenue from peak saving activities. All of the schemes are likely to be consistent with the existing incentives for network peak savings embodied in the NER. The creation of a peak savings incentive or peak savings target as part of a national energy savings scheme is most consistent with the wider policy approach to managing energy savings. That said, a single peak savings buyer would minimise the regulatory burden for electricity businesses while a stand-alone peak savings scheme with an obligation on networks would likely increase the compliance burden across the electricity sector. Finally, most of the scheme designs provide certainty of achieving a peak reduction because they place a direct obligation on the achievement of a defined level of peak savings, or the payment of a penalty. The exception is where the incentive for peak savings is achieved by increasing the number of energy savings certificates associated with activities that result in peak savings. 5.5. Summary In summary, providing a peak savings incentive as part of a national savings scheme is a low cost option for achieving wholesale peak savings benefits in the medium to long term. It ensures that the value of peak savings as compared to savings that worsen load factor can be explicitly valued. In contrast a single peak savings buyer provides the most flexibility to adapt to changing circumstances and the opportunity to target and learn from activities and programmes over time. It will also, most likely, provide the best incentives for the development of innovation in peak savings activities and programmes because of the certainty of funding that would be created for third parties contracted to deliver defined peak savings. That said, it is the highest cost option and also involves the greatest deviation from a market-based approach that has been an important part of electricity industry reforms over the past two decades. A risk with this scheme is the uncertainties it creates on the likely wholesale market outcomes, which could therefore create distortions to the signals created in the market with negative consequences for wholesale market efficiency. A stand-alone peak savings scheme seems to have relatively few incremental benefits compared to an incentive being placed within a national energy savings scheme. Its possible incremental merits arising from the potential to target savings within particular networks are diminished by the incentives created through the NER for network businesses. Given this, it is likely to have a similar impact on wholesale benefits but with incrementally higher administrative costs. In addition it would place a compliance burden on network businesses NERA Economic Consulting 46 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Evaluating Scheme Design Options that would otherwise not be directly obligated to be involved in a national energy savings scheme. Finally, Table 5.1 provides a summary of our ranking of the scheme design options against each of the design criteria. It is important to note that the criteria shown in the table have not been weighted in importance, and therefore the ratings shown should not be seen as establishing a definitive preference ranking of the various options. Table 5.1: Assessment of Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Option 1: Option 2: Option 3: Peak savings included in national energy savings scheme Standalone peak savings scheme Peak savings buyer scheme Likelihood of achieving wholesale/network cost reductions in short term (< 3 years) Likelihood of achieving wholesale/network cost reductions in medium/long term (> 3years) Promotion of innovation in peak demand savings Consistency with other regulatory processes Certainty of peak reduction Design Criteria Scheme design and implementation Ease of implementation Scheme development and administrative costs Scheme benefits Likelihood of achieving peak efficiency outcomes Other considerations NERA Economic Consulting 47 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options 6. Further Considerations for the Design of a National ESI Further Considerations for the Design of a National ESI Peak demand growth is a significant driver of costs for both the generation and network components of the electricity supply chain. As a consequence ongoing growth in peak demand is one of the main contributors to the electricity price rises that have been experienced over the past several years and that are projected to continue into the medium future. Concerns about peak demand growth and its impact on electricity system costs and electricity prices is one of the main reasons that the Commonwealth Government decided that one part of its Clean Energy Future package would be to expedite the development of a national energy savings initiative (ESI) and will examine further how such a scheme may assist households and businesses to adjust to rising energy costs,41 and that an ESI itself would have broad coverage (that is residential, commercial and industrial sectors); and create an incentive or a requirement to create certificates in both low income homes and in ways that reduce peak electricity demand.42 This specific project was undertaken by NERA and Oakley Greenwood to consider how incentives might be created to reduce peak demand. However, while reductions in peak demand will put downward pressure on the costs incurred by the electricity supply chain – and therefore the price of electricity – other factors are also important determinants of electricity prices. As discussed in Section 2.2, considering changes in load factor – ie, the time distribution of energy demand – is the simplest approach to understanding the impact of both energy consumption and peak demand reductions on electricity system costs and prices. While each of the options developed in this report have been designed to provide an incentive for peak demand savings, ensuring that they have a positive (or at least neutral impact on load factor) will require additional consideration. Specifically: While Option 1A can be expected to promote peak demand savings it cannot ensure (without the inclusion of additional measures) that enough peak demand savings will occur to keep load factor from deteriorating.43 Options 1B, 2 and 3 could be implemented in a way so as to avoid deterioration of load factor. This would require that the separate peak demand target be set to counterbalance 41 Australian Government, Report of the Prime Minister’s Task Group on Energy Efficiency, Canberra, July 2010, p. 81. 42 Australian Government, Securing a Clean Energy Future – The Australian Government’s climate change plan, Canberra, July 2011, p. 126. 43 An example of a measure that could be added to accomplish this is discussed below. NERA Economic Consulting 48 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Further Considerations for the Design of a National ESI any negative consequences on load factor that could be expected to result from the specific level of overall energy efficiency that had been targeted. Setting such a peak demand reduction target with regard to the load factor of the generation system would be relatively straightforward. However, it will be difficult to do so in such a way that would also protect the load factor of individual distribution networks or specific areas within any distribution network. This is because it is extremely unlikely that the geographic distribution of peak demand and general energy consumption reductions produced by an ESI at a national level would match the load profile of – and thereby produce beneficial load factor impacts in – each distribution network. This means that the setting of a peak demand savings target would have to be adapted to each distribution network, or at least to a set of categories of electricity distribution network types based on the timing of their peak demand. In Options 2 and 3 these arrangements could become more difficult in the event that the peak demand target is not set by the same agency responsible for setting the overall energy saving target. Of equal or perhaps greater concern is the fact that the scope for load factor deterioration is currently present in the state-based ESIs.44 The general conception of white certificates is that they represent a certain quantity of kWh (or tonnes of CO2-e) saved. These certificates are then awarded to eligible energy efficient activities under a white certificate scheme. But each energy saving activity also has an impact on the peak demand of the generation system and the local network system in which the activity occurs. These impacts can generate positive or negative effects on the load factor of the generation sector and each distribution network, and therefore on the unit price of electricity. Where load factors deteriorate, there will be upward pressure on unit prices. This will result in bill increases for consumers that have not reduced their consumption, essentially constituting a dis-benefit for non-participants in the scheme. One approach for addressing this that could be applied to either (a) an ESI that did not take peak demand into explicit account, or (b) Option 1A would be to award certificates to the various energy efficiency measures on the basis of the measure’s impact on system load profile. Under this option, the predicted public benefit or dis-benefit arising from each energy efficiency measure would be incorporated into the certificate-based reward it receives under the scheme, thereby encouraging the uptake of activities that minimise the scheme’s potential negative outcomes (and maximise the positive public benefit outcomes). Put another way, the relative number of certificates per annual kWh saved to be awarded to any energy efficiency measure would be proportional to the measure’s marginal impact on system load factor. In sum, the relative number of certificates per annual kWh saved to be awarded to any energy efficiency measure would be proportional to the measure’s marginal impact on system load factor. 44 This is not to say that the state-based energy savings schemes have resulted in load factor deterioration, but only to say that such an outcome could happen. NERA Economic Consulting 49 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Further Considerations for the Design of a National ESI This adjustment could be undertaken at either or both the generation system and/or network levels. The generation system loadshape impact for any particular measure would be likely to be relatively constant across jurisdictions within any particular generation system (ie, the NEM, the SWIS, etc). This is because the generation load shape is unlikely to vary significantly within each generation system. The exception to this would be where the magnitude of the measure’s impact changes across the area served by the generation system. For example, high efficiency air conditioners deployed in Tasmania are unlikely to have as great an impact on the loadshape of the NEM as the same machine installed in South Australia. The load shape impact of any particular energy efficiency activity is more likely to vary between distribution networks within each of the larger generation systems, as well among different areas within each of the distribution areas. If these network impacts are sufficiently different, consideration will need to be given to whether the added incentive value of their inclusion within the scheme justifies the additional complexity their inclusion will entail. For example, the installation of high efficiency lighting in office buildings is likely to reduce system load factor and revenue in network areas dominated by residential loads because it reduces energy use at non-peak times. Under this approach, the energy efficiency activity would receive fewer certificates than under a conventional ESI scheme design. In contrast, high efficiency air conditioning would be likely to receive more certificates under this approach as compared to a conventional ESI design. This would likely be the case because in this example the high efficiency air conditioning system would reduce peak demand for both the generation system and the network. In summary, the approach proposed here – or some variant of it – would seem to be of significant value in ensuring that the pursuit of energy efficiency and greenhouse gas reductions (which have a mix of private and public benefits) do not come at the expense of deteriorating load factors, which place upward pressure on prices the impact of which may be unequal across various different groups of end-use consumers. If the impacts at the network level are sufficiently large, it may be important (in terms of protecting the net public benefit of the scheme) to incorporate the network load factor impact into the overall scheme certificate award mechanism. However, if the impacts at the network level are very different from one another consideration will need to be given to whether the added incentive value and net public benefit of their inclusion within the scheme justifies the additional complexity that inclusion would entail for the implementation and administration of the scheme. Finally, there is merit in giving further consideration to: the materiality of the network benefits, by collecting information on actual network peak profiles of distributors and consulting with distributors on the possible opportunities to adjust LRAIC values to represent area-wide benefits of an ESI scheme; using information on distribution system load profiles to assess the likelihood of possible negative network consequences from different ESI scheme design options; NERA Economic Consulting 50 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Further Considerations for the Design of a National ESI how an ESI might be designed so as to avoid any possible negative consequences from deteriorating system load profiles; enhancing the operation of an ESI scheme through the development of a mechanism to provide incentives for demand management activities that directly manage load factor; scoping the information requirements and the feasibility of possible institutional and governance arrangements for implementing a preferred approach to creating a peak savings incentive; and the establishment of an expert advisory group to guide the further development and analysis of an national ESI scheme design options and associated benefits and costs, given the complexities involved. NERA Economic Consulting 51 Peak Energy Savings Scheme Design Options Appendix A. Appendix A Peak Technical Group and Network Modelling Group Members The following organisations participated in Peak Technical Group and Network Modelling Group meetings. Table A.1: Organisations that Participated in the Peak Technical Group and Network Modelling Group Peak Technical Group Members Network Modelling Group Members Department of Resources, Energy and Tourism (DRET) Department of Resources, Energy and Tourism (DRET) Department of Climate Efficiency (DCCEE) Department of Climate Efficiency (DCCEE) Change and Energy Change and Energy Australian Energy Market Commission (AEMC) Australian Energy Market Commission (AEMC) Australian Energy Market Operator (AEMO) Australian Energy Market Operator (AEMO) Australian Energy Regulator (AER) Australian Energy Regulator (AER) Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research Organisation (CSIRO) Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research Organisation (CSIRO) Energy Networks Associations (ENA) Energex Energex AusGrid AusGrid Office of Environment and Heritage (NSW) Ergon Energy Energy Retailers Association of Australia (ERAA) ERM Power Origin Energy EnerNOC UTS Institute for Sustainable Futures Office of Environment and Heritage (NSW) NERA Economic Consulting 52 NERA Economic Consulting Darling Park Tower 3 201 Sussex Street Sydney NSW 2000 Tel: +61 2 8864 6500 Fax: +61 2 8864 6549 www.nera.com NERA Australia Pty Ltd, ABN 34 092 959 665 Oakley Greenwood GPO Box 4345 Melbourne VIC 3001 Tel: +61 3 9486 8097 Fax: +61 3 8080 0760 www.oakleygreenwood.com.au