Production Technology • The physical laws of nature and limits of material availability and human understanding that govern what is possible in converting inputs into output. Inputs, Factors of Production • Land (incl. raw materials) • Labor (including human capital) • Capital (physical capital, like machinery and buildings) Production Function • A firm’s production function for a particular good (q) shows the maximum amount of the good that can be produced using alternative combinations of capital (K) and labor (L). q = f(K, L) • Producing less than the maximum is always possible and all levels of output below the maximum are feasible and define the “production set.” Production Function q q = f(K, L) K L Production set q = f(K, L) q K All points “under” the production function L Production Function and Isoquants q = f(K, L) q In the long run, all combinations of inputs are possible K L Isoquants are horizontal cross sections of the production function projected on the base plane. Short Run, Long Run • Long Run, quantities of ALL inputs used in production can be varied. • Short Run, the quantity of at least one input used in production is fixed. • ALL production takes place in a short run environment. • You can think of the long run as the ability to move from one short run environment to another. • Actual time it takes to make this move depends on many factors, technical, economic and regulatory. The model • Standard basic model to think of production as a function of K and L. • L variable in the short run while K is fixed. Short run, hold K fixed. q = f(K, L) q In the short run, K is fixed and only L can vary K L The cross section of the production function at a fixed K is the short run production function More, fixed K q = f(K, L) q In the short run, K is fixed and only L can vary K L The cross section of the production function at a fixed K is the short run production function Three levels of K q = f(K=K3, L) q In the short run, we assume, the quantity of at least one input used -but not all -is fixed. q = f(K=K2, L) q = f(K=K1, L) L L constant q = f(K,L=L3) q L and K are just names for inputs. Either one could be fixed in the short run. Just intuitive that K is fixed and L variable in the SR. q = f(K,L=L2) q = f(K,L=L1) K SR and then LR • First we’ll think about the short run, and then turn to the long run. Marginal Physical Product • Marginal Product is the additional output that can be produced by employing one more unit of that input – holding other inputs constant, so a short run concept q marginal product of labor: MPL fL L q marginal product of capital: MPK fK K Marginal Productivity Assumptions • We assume managers are not going to allow employees in the building if they bring total output down. q MPL fL 0 L q MPK fK 0 K • However, over the range where profit is maximized, marginal products are positive. Increasing and Diminishing Marginal Product (assumes something is fixed) • Empirically, economists find that most production processes exhibit (as L increases from zero): – Increasing Marginal Returns – each worker added causes output to increase by more than the previous worker (workers are not able to gain from specialization, K is fixed) – And then… – Decreasing Marginal Returns –workers added to production add less to output than the previous worker (workers crowd each other as they try to share a fixed amount of capital) Marginal Productivity Assumptions • Because of IMR and DMR, these are possible: MPL 2 f 2 fLL , , 0 L L MPK 2 f 2 fKK , , 0 K K • Whether MP is always diminishing or whether it first increases and then diminishes depends on the context of the economic discussion. • In economics classes, we think of increasing marginal returns and then diminishing marginal returns (need this for a U-shaped MC curve). MP Assumptions • As revenue or profit max means producing where MC is rising (MPL is falling), theoretically, we tend to ignore IMR and assume DMR MPL 2 f 2 fLL 0 L L MPK 2 f 2 fKK 0 K K Malthus and Diminishing Marginal Productivity • He argued that population growth meant declining marginal labor productivity – His mistake was holding all else (except labor, i.e. population) constant. – Ignored technological growth. – Productivity was actually growing exponentially, but at such a slow rate that he did not see it. Per Capita Output Watts’s Steam Engine Essay on the Principle of Population, 1st ed (1798) Economic growth of IR first noticed in the 1830s Malthus Dies, 1834 1800 1840 1880 Year Effect of Technology • If we think of higher technology as being like having MORE capital, then you can think of the industrial revolution the result of fLK > 0 and a rapid expansion of K. Average Physical Product • Labor productivity is often measured by average productivity. output q f(K,L) APL = labor input L L Specific Function • Suppose the production function for tennis balls can be represented by 3 3 KL 2 2 q f K,L 12K L 100 • To construct MPL and APL, we must assume a value for K – let K = 10 • The production function becomes q f K,L 1,200L2 10L3 SR Production Function (K = 10) q 1,200L 10L 2 q 3000000 3 2500000 2000000 q(K=10) 1500000 1000000 500000 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 L Marginal Product • The marginal product function is MPL 2,400L 30L 2 MPL 2,400L 30L2 0 30L2 2,400L 30L 2,400 L=80 • When MPL = 0, total product is maximized at L = 80. SR Production Function (K = 10) q q 1,200L2 10L3 3000000 2500000 2000000 q(K=10) 1500000 1000000 500000 0 0 20 40 60 Slope of function is MPL at that level of L 80 100 120 L Inflection Point • Output where MPL goes from increasing to decreasing (inflection point) fL MPL 2,400L 30L2 dMPL fLL 2,400 60L dL 2,400 60L 0 LI =40 SR Production Function (K = 10) At inflection point, MPL is at its highest q q 1,200L2 10L3 MPL 1,280,000 at L = 40 3000000 2500000 2000000 q(K=10) 1500000 1000000 500000 0 0 20 40 LI 60 80 100 120 L Average Product • To find average productivity, we hold K=10 and solve f K,L APL 1,200L 10L2 L dAPL Maximized where =0 dL dAPL 1,200 20L dL 1,200 20L 0 20L 1,200 L A 60 SR Production Function (K = 10) q Slope of ray from origin to curve at any L is = APL 3000000 Slope of this ray =36,000 So APL =36,000 when L= 60 2500000 2000000 q(K=10) 1500000 q 1,200L2 10L3 1000000 APL 1200L 10L2 500000 0 0 20 40 60 LA 80 100 120 L MPL and APL • In fact, when L = 60, both APL and MPL are equal to 36,000 • Thus, when APL is at its maximum, APL and MPL are equal • So long as a worker hired has a MPL higher than the overall APL, the APL will continue to rise. • If the MPL = APL, • But if a worker hired has a MPL below the overall APL, the APL will fall. MPL and APL 60000 40000 20000 0 0 -20000 -40000 -60000 -80000 20 40 60 LI LA 80 100 120 MPL APL MPL and APL q(K=10) 3000000 Where the ray is also tangent, MPL = APL 2500000 2000000 1500000 q(K=10) 1000000 500000 0 0 60000 50000 40000 30000 20000 10000 0 -10000 0 -20000 20 40 60 80 100 MPL APL 20 40 60 80 100 Long Run • All mixes of K and L are possible. • Daily decisions about production always have some fixed inputs, so the long run is a planning time horizon. Isoquant Map • Each isoquant represents a different level of output, q0 = f(K0,L0), q1 = f(K1,L1) K dK 0 dL q1 = 30 q0 = 20 L Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (TRS, RTS, MRTS) • The slope of an isoquant shows the rate at which L can be substituted for K, or how much capital must be hired to replace one Laborer. dK TRS dL qq0 K KA A B KB q0 = 20 LA LB L TRS and Marginal Productivities • Take the total differential of the production function: f f dq dL dK L K dq MPL dL MPK dK • Along an isoquant dq = 0, so MPL dL MPK dK MPL dK TRS defined as, TRS= dL qq0 MPK Alternatively: Implicit Function Rule Take an implicit function: f(K,L)-q=0 If the conditions of the implict function therorem hold, then there exists an equation K=g(L; q) and f dK L f dL K or fL dK fK dL or MPL dK MPK dL MPL dK Again,TRS defined as, TRS= dL qq0 MPK Diminishing TRS • Again, for demand (this time of inputs) to be well behaved, we need production technology (akin to preferences) to be convex. K MPL dK dL MPK Which means, the slope rises, gets closer to zero as L increases. And means the TRS falls as L increases. dK TRS dL L Diminishing TRS • To show that isoquants are convex (that dK/dL increases – gets closer to zero) along all isoquants) • That is, either: • The level sets (isoquants) are strictly convex • The production function is strictly quasi-concave Convexity (level curves) • dK/dL increases along all indifference curves • We can use the explicit equation for an isoquant, K=K(L, q0) and find d2K 0 2 dL qq 0 to demonstrate convexity. • That is, while negative, the slope is getting larger as L increases (closer to zero). • But we cannot always get a well defined equation for an isoquant. Alternatively (level curves) • As above, starting with q0 =f(K,L), fL (K,L) dK dL fK (K,L) fL (K,L) TRS fK (K,L) • So convexity if fL K,L d 2 fK K,L dK 0 or 2 dL dL fK (K,L) d fL (K,L) dTRS 0 dL dL Convexity (level curves) • And, that is fL (K,L) d 2 2 2 f (K,L) 2f f f f f f dK K LK L K K LL L fKK 0 dL2 dL fK3 fL (K,L) d 2 2 f (K,L) 2f f f f f f dTRS K LK L K K LL L fKK 0 3 dL dL fK *Note that fK3 > 0 • What of: – – – – – fL > 0, monotonacity fK > 0, monotonacity fLL < 0, diminishing marginal returns fKK < 0, diminishing marginal returns fLK = ? Strict Quasi-Convexity (production function) • Also, convexity of technology will hold if the production function is strictly quasi-concave – A function is strictly quasi-concave if its bordered Hessian 0 H fL fL fLL fK fLK fK fKL fKK – is negative definite H 0 fL 0 fL fK 0 and H fL fLL fK fLL fKL fLK 0 fKK fL Negative Definite (production function) • So the production function is strictly quasi-concave if – 1. –fLfL < 0 – 2. 2fLfKfLK-fK2fLL -fL2fKK > 0 • Related to the level curve result: – Remembering that a convex level set comes from this d2K (2fL fK fLK fK2 fLL fL 2 fKK ) 0 2 3 dL fK – We can see that strict convexity of the level set and strict quasi-concavity of the function are related, and each is sufficient to demonstrate that both are true. TRS and Marginal Productivities • Intuitively, it seems reasonable that fLK should be positive – if workers have more capital, they will be more productive • But some production functions have fKL < 0 over some input ranges – assuming diminishing TRS means that MPL and MPK diminish quickly enough to compensate for any possible negative cross-productivity effects TRS and MPL and MPK • Back to our sample production function: 3 3 K L 2 2 q f K,L 12K L 100 • For this production function 3 2 3K L 2 MPL 24K L 100 2 3 3K L 2 MPK 24KL 100 IMR and DMR vs. NMR • Pull out a few terms 3 2 3K L MPL 24K L 100 3 2 3K L 2 MPL 0, 24K L 100 fL 0 if (2,400 3KL) 0 fL 0 if KL 800 fL 0 if KL 800 2 2 3 3K L 2 MPK 24KL 100 2 3 3K L 2 MPK 0, 24KL 100 fK 0 if (2,400 3KL) 0 fK 0 if KL 800 fK 0 if KL 800 • If K = 10, then MPL = 0 at L=80 IMR vs. DMR • Because 3 6K L fLL 24K 100 3 6K L 2 fLL 0, 24K 100 2 3 6KL fKK 24L2 100 3 6KL 2 fKK 0, 24L 100 • fLL> 0 and fKK > 0 if K*L < 400 • fLL< 0 and fKK < 0 if K*L > 400 • If K = 10, then inflection point at L=40 Cross Effect •Cross differentiation of either of the marginal productivity functions yields 9K2L2 fLK fKL 48KL 100 9K2L2 fLK 0, 48KL 100 • fLK > 0 if KL < 533 • fLK < 0 if KL > 533 •If K = 10 • fLK> 0 when L < 53.3 • fLK< 0 when L > 53.3 A Diminishing TRS? • Strictly Quasi-Concave if + ? ? ? ? + ? f f 2fK fL fKL f f 0 2 K LL 2 L KK • Lots of parts that have different signs depending on K and L. Returns to Scale • How does output respond to increases in all inputs together? – suppose that all inputs are doubled, would output double? • Returns to scale have been of interest to economists since Adam Smith’s pin factory Returns to Scale • Two forces that occur as inputs are scaled upwards – greater division of labor and specialization of function – loss in efficiency (bureaucratic inertia) • management may become more difficult • fall of the Roman Empire? • General Motors? Returns to Scale • Starting at very small scale and then expanding, firms tend to exhibit increasing returns to scale at small scale, which changes to constant returns over a range, and then when they get larger, face decreasing returns to scale. • Obviously, the scale at each transition can vary. – – – – Vacuum Cleaner Repair Shops Steel Mills Doughnut Shops Automobile manufacture • Empirical analysis reveals that established firms tend to operate at a CRS scale. Returns to Scale • If the production function is given by q = f(K,L) and all inputs are multiplied by the same positive constant (t >1), then Effect on Output Returns to Scale f(tK1,tL1) = tf(K1,L1) Constant f(tK1,tL1) < tf(K1,L1) Decreasing f(tK1,tL1) > tf(K1,L1) Increasing Returns to Scale • Constant Returns to Scale q = K.5L.5 What if we increase all inputs by a factor of t? (tK).5(tL).5 = ? t(K).5(L).5 = tq • For t > 1, increase all inputs by a factor of t and output increases by a factor of t • I.e. increase all inputs by x% and output increases by x% Returns to Scale • Decreasing Returns to Scale q = K.25L.25 What if we increase all inputs by a factor of t? (tK).25(tL).25 = ? t.5(K).25(L).25 = t.5q, which is < tq • For t > 1, increase all inputs by a factor of t and output increases by a factor < t • I.e. increase all inputs by x% and output increases by less than x% Returns to Scale • Increasing Returns to Scale q = K1L1 What if we increase all inputs by a factor of t? (tK)1(tL)1 = ? tq < t2(K)1(L)1 = t2q, which is > tq • For t>1, increase all inputs by a factor of t and output increases by a factor > t • I.e. increase all inputs by x% and output increases by more than x% Returns to Scale • Using the usual homogeneity notation, alternatively, it is notated, for t > 0. • That is, production is homogeneous of degree k. Effect on Output Returns to Scale k = 1, Constant k f(tK1,tL1) = t f(K1,L1) k < 1, Decreasing k > 1, Increasing Returns to Scale, Example • Solve for k • • • • • • • • • q = K.4L.4 tkq = (tK).4(tL).4 = t.8(K).4(L).4 k ln(t) + ln(Q) = .8ln(t)+.4ln(K)+.4ln(L) k ln(t) = .8ln(t)+.4ln(K)+.4ln(L) - ln(Q) k ln(t) = .8ln(t)+.4ln(K)+.4ln(L)-.4ln(K)-.4ln(L) k ln(t) = .8ln(t) k ln(t) = .8ln(t)/ln(t) k = .8, production is Homogeneous of degree .8 k < 1 so DRS Returns to Scale by Elasticity • What is the % change in output for a t% increase in all inputs? • Generally evaluated at t = 1 eq,t f(tK,tL) t , and evaluated at t=1 t f(tK,tL) CRS: q,t =1 DRS: q,t < 1 IRS: q,t > 1 Returns to Scale by Elasticity • What is the % change in output for a t% increase in all inputs? Evaluated at t = 1. q K.4 L.2 L f (tK, tL) t eq,t t f (tK, tL) eq,t tK .4 t .6 K .4 eq,t tL .2 tL L .2 L t .4 .6t K t tK .4 tL .2 tL t t .6 K .4 L .2 tL L tL eq,t .4 .2 t K L t1.4 L .4 .2 .6 K L L at t 1, eq,t .4 .2 K L L .4 .2 • In this example, RTS varies by K and L. Constant Returns to Scale is Special • Empirically, firms operate at a CRS scale. • If a function is HD1, then the first partials will be HD0. • If f(tK,tL) t f(K,L) • Then f(K,L) f(tK,tL) MPK K K f(K,L) f(tK,tL) MPL L L Constant Returns to Scale is Special • Obviously, if CRS, we can scale by any t > 0 • But let’s pick a specific scale factor, 1/L: • If • Then 1 1 K f K, L f ,1 L L L K f ,1 L MPK , K K f ,1 L MPL L • Which tells us that if production is CRS, then it is also homothetic. Isoquants are radial expansions with the RTS the same along all linear expansion paths. Constant Returns to Scale • The marginal productivity of any input depends on the ratio of capital and labor – not on the absolute levels of these inputs • Therefore the TRS between K and L depends only on the ratio of K to L, not the scale of operation • That is, increasing all inputs by x% does not affect the TRS • The production function will be homothetic (TRS constant along ray from origin) • Geometrically, this means all of the isoquants are radial expansions of one another Constant Returns to Scale • Along a ray from the origin (constant K/L), the TRS will be the same on all isoquants K The isoquants are equally spaced as output expands q=3 q=2 q=1 L Economies of Scale (not Returns to Scale) • In the real world, firms rarely scale up or down all inputs (e.g. management does not typically scale up with production). • Economies of scale: %ΔLRAC/%ΔQ – Economies of scale if < 0 – Diseconomies of scale if > 0 Elasticity of Substitution • The elasticity of substitution () measures the proportionate change in K/L relative to the proportionate change in the TRS along an isoquant % K d K TRS L L %TRS dTRS K L • And as was demonstrated earlier, elasticity is the effect of a change in one log on another. dln K dln K L L dlnTRS dln fL f K • The value of will always be positive because K/L and TRS move in the same direction Elasticity of Substitution • Both RTS and K/L will change as we move from point A to point B is the ratio of these K proportional changes measures the TRSA A (K/L)A (K/L)B curvature of the isoquant TRSB B q = q0 L Elasticity of Substitution • If is low, the K/L will not change much relative to TRS – the isoquant will be relatively flat • If is high, the K/L will change by a substantial amount as TRS changes – the isoquant will be sharply curved • More interesting when you remember that to minimize cost, TRS = pL/pK so TRS changes with input prices. Elasticity of Substitution K q=g(K,L) g > f q=f(K,L) L • It is possible for to change along an isoquant or as the scale of production changes Elasticity of Substitution • Solving for σ can be tricky, but, we can employ this calculus trick (especially useful for homothetic production functions): y 1 x x y • This allows us to turn this problem • Into the (sometimes) easier L dln K f dln L fK 1 f dln L fK dln K L Elasticity of Substitution CRS is Special Again • For CRS production functions only we have this option too • Let q = f(K,L) fK fL q fK,L Common Production Functions • Linear (inputs are perfect substitutes) • Fixed Proportions (inputs are perfect compliments) • Cobb-Douglas • CES • Generalized Leontief The Linear Production Function (inputs are perfect substitutes) • Suppose that the production function is q = f(K,L) = aK + bL • This production function exhibits constant returns to scale f(tK,tL) = atK + btL = t(aK + bL) = tf(K,L) • All isoquants are straight lines Linear Production Function q aK bL fL b TRS fK a K K ln ln 1 1 L L ln TRS b b 0 ln ln a a K ln L The Linear Production Function Capital and labor are perfect substitutes TRS is constant as K/L changes K slope = -b/a q1 q2 = q3 L Fixed Proportions • Suppose that the production function is q = min (aK,bL) a,b > 0 • Capital and labor must always be used in a fixed ratio – the firm will always operate along a ray where K/L is constant • Because K/L is constant, = 0 Fixed Proportions No substitution between labor and capital is possible K/L is fixed at b/a K =0 q3 q3/a q2 q1 q3/b L Cobb-Douglas Production Function • Suppose that the production function is q = f(K,L) = AKaLb A, a, b > 0 • This production function can exhibit any returns to scale f(tK,tL) = A(tK)a(tL)b = Ata+b KaLb = ta+bf(K,L) – if a + b = 1 constant returns to scale – if a + b > 1 increasing returns to scale – if a + b < 1 decreasing returns to scale Cobb-Douglas Production Function q AKaLb fL bAKaLb1 bK TRS a1 b fK aAK L aL K K ln ln 1 1 L L 1 bK b b K K 1 ln ln ln ln ln aL L L a a K ln L Cobb-Douglas Production Function •The Cobb-Douglas production function is linear in logarithms ln q = ln A + a ln K + b ln L • a is the elasticity of output with respect to K • b is the elasticity of output with respect to L • Statistically, this is how we estimate production functions via regression analysis. CES Production Function • Suppose that the production function is q K L , 1, 0, 0 • > 1 increasing returns to scale • = 1 constant returns to scale • < 1 decreasing returns to scale CES Production Function • TRS q K L 1 1 fL K L L 1 fK K L K1 fL L TRS fK K 1 1 L K 1 1 L K 1 K L • Note, not a function of scale, γ 1 CES Production Function • σ K ln L TRS K ln L K 1 ln L 1 K 1 ln L K ln L 1 1 1 K 1 ln L K L 1 1 K L K L CES Production Function • For CES q K L , 1, 0, 0 1 1 • At limit as → 1, σ → ∞, linear production function • At limit as → -, σ → ∞, fixed proportions production function • When = 0, Cobb-Douglas production function A Generalized Leontief Production Function • Suppose that the production function is q K L 2 KL • TRS 0.5 0.5 0.5 K K L 1 0.5 0.5 fL K L L TRS 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 L K fK L L 1 0.5 K K .5 K TRS L A Generalized Leontief Production Function • σ K ln L 0.5 K ln L 2 1 1 1 0.5 K .5 ln K .5 ln L L K ln K L ln L Technical Progress • Methods of production change over time • Following the development of superior production techniques, the same level of output can be produced with fewer inputs – the isoquant shifts inward Technical Progress • Suppose that the production function is q = A(t)f(K(t),L(t)) where A(t) represents all influences that go into determining q other than K and L – changes in A over time represent technical progress • A is shown as a function of time (t) • dA/dt > 0 Technical Progress • Differentiating the production function q A t f K t ,L t with respect to time we get dq dA(t) df dK df dL f(K(t),L(t)) A(t) dt dt dK dt dL dt Which simplifies to dq dA df dK df dL f(K,L) A dt dt dK dt dL dt Technical Progress dq dA df dK df dL f(K,L) A dt dt dK dt dL dt • Since q A f K,L , then A q q , and f K,L f K,L A • And so dq dA q q dK dL fK fL dt dt A f(K,L) dt dt Technical Progress dq dA q q dK dL fK fL dt dt A f(K,L) dt dt • Dividing by q gives us dq dt dA 1 fK dK fL dL q dt A f(K,L) dt f(K,L) dt Technical Progress dq dt dA 1 fK dK fL dL q dt A f(K,L) dt f(K,L) dt • Expand by strategically adding in K/K and L/L dq / dt dA / dt K dK / dt L dL / dt fK fL q A f(K,L) K f(K,L) L Technical Progress dq / dt dA / dt K dK / dt L dL / dt fK fL q A f(K,L) K f(K,L) L • For any variable x, [(dx/dt)/x] is the proportional growth rate in x – denote this by Gx • Then, we can write the equation in terms of growth rates K L Gq GA fK GK fL GL f(K,L) f(K,L) Technical Progress • Note the elasticities K L Gq GA fK GK fL GL f(K,L) f(K,L) f(K,L) K f(K,L) L eq,K , eq,L K f(K,L) L f(K,L) • Yielding Gq GA eq,KGK eq,L GL • Growth is a function of technical change and growth in the use of inputs. Solow, US Growth 1909-1949 • Solow estimated the following • • • • • Gq = 2.75% GL = 1.00% GK = 1.75% eq,L = .65 eq,K = .35 • Plug these in Gq GA eq,KGK eq,LGL GA Gq eq,KGK eq,LGL • And GA = 1.5% • Conclusion, technology grew at a 1.5% rate from 19091949. 55% of GDP growth in the period. Appendix • Full derivations of TRS and convexity in production. RTS and Marginal Productivities: Implicit Function Rule Generalize the implicit function: f(K,L)-q=0 to F(K,L,q) 0 F F F dK dL dq 0 q L K If the conditions of the implict function therorem hold, then there exists an equation K=g(L,q) and g g dK dL dq q L Substitute g g Subsitute dK dL dq into L q F F F dK dL dq 0 to get K L q F g g F F dL dq dL dq 0 K L q L q F g F F g F dL dL dq dq 0 K L L K q q F g F F g F dL dq 0 K L L K q q And get to… F g F F g F dL dq 0 K L L K q q Since the dL and dq are independent, the bracketed expressions must = 0 for the equation to hold. That is: F g F 0 and K L L We are interested in: F g F K q q 0 F g F 0 K L L F g L 0 and K=g(L,q) and F(K,L,q) f(K,L)-q=0 L F K And get to… F g L F g F Solve this 0 to get 0 L F K L L K g dK And since K=g(L,q) with q held constant, and L dL F f F f F(K,L,q) f(K,L)-q=0, so and L L K K f(K,L) dK L f(K,L) dL K MP dK L dL MPK Convexity, Increasing dK/dL fL L,K dL dK dK dL d f f f f f f LL dL LK dL K L KL dL KK dL fK L,K fL d2K dK , Note: dL2 dL fK2 dL fK f L,K f f d L fLL fLK L fK fL fLK fKK L fK fK fK L,K dL UK2 2 fL L,K f L d fLL fK fLK fL fKL fL fKK f L,K fK K dL fK2 f Multiply by: K fK f L,K d L 2 2 f L,K K fLL fK fLK fL fK fKL fL fK fKK fL dL fK3 f L,K d L 2 2 fK L,K 2fLK fL fK fLL fK fKK fL 0 dL fK3 Diminishing TRS • TRS diminishing if this < 0 fL L,K d 2 2 f L,K d TRS f f 2f f f f K K LL K L KL L fKK 0 3 dL dL fK • Which is the same thing. Alternatively, the Bordered Hessian Strictly Quasi-Concave if and 0 det fL fL 2 f L 0 f LL 0 fL fK det f L fK f LL f KL f LK 2f LK f L f K f L 2f KK f K 2f LL 0 f KK which looks a lot like the negative of this: 2f K f L f KL f L2f KK f K2 f LL dRTS 0 if 0 3 dL fK