International Trade The Trade Sector of the US Growth: - In 1975, exports and imports were each approximately 8% of the U.S. economy. - In 2000, exports accounted for 11.2% of GDP and imports made up 14.9%. Major Trading Partners: - Canada, Mexico, and Japan -China, Europe International Trade Is of Increasing Importance to the US U.S. International Trade in a World Context International Trade as a Percentage of GDP International trade is still less important to the United States than to most other countries. Year Exports Imports Difference 1970 59.7 55.8 ____ 1980 280.8 293.8 ____ 1990 552.4 629.7 ____ 1995 811.9 902.6 ____ 2000 1093.2 1475.3 ____ 2005 2010 2011 1035.1 1839.8 2087.6 2027.8 2356.7 2665.8 ____ ____ ____ Leading Trading Partners of the U.S. –––––––– Percent of Total U.S. Trade, 2002 –––––––– –––––––– Percent of Total U.S. Trade, 2006 ––––– ––– Canada 19.8% 18.5% Mexico China Japan Germany United Kingdom South Korea Taiwan France Malaysia All other countries 11.5% 11.9% 11.9% 9.1% 7.2% 8.6% 4.9% 4.5% 3.9% 3.4% 3.1% 2.7% 2.5% 2.1% 2.3% 2.1% 1.8% 1.7% 34.4% 32.2% • Today, Canada, Mexico, China, and Japan are the leading trading partners with the United States. • The impact of international trade varies across industries. -some compete effectively, some do not. Partner % Exports European Union 17.0 Canada 19.0 Japan 5.0 Mexico 14.0 China 7.0 % Imports 16.0 14.0 6.0 12.0 18.0 2013 Source: http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/ statistics/highlights/toppartners.html Gains from Specialization and Trade Law of Comparative Advantage • A group of individuals, regions, or nations can produce a larger joint output if each specializes in the production of goods in which it is a lowopportunity cost producer and trades for goods for which it is a high opportunity cost producer. Gains from Specialization and Trade • International trade allows each country to specialize according to the law of comparative advantage. • Each country can produce those goods that it can produce at a low opportunity cost. • Trading partners can consume a wider variety of goods than they could produce domestically. Absolute advantage: The ability to produce more of a good or service than competitors when using the same amount of resources. With one unit of resources: - Canada: 8 tons of wheat or 4 tons of soybeans -Brazil: 4 tons of wheat or 8 tons of soybeans Opportunity Costs: Canada 1 t wheat = ___ ton soy 1 t soy = ___ ton wheat Brazil 1 t wheat = ___ ton soy 1 t soy = ___ ton wheat Advantage in wheat? __________ Advantage in soybeans? ________ With one unit of resources: Canada 8 wheat or 4 soybeans Brazil: 4 wheat or 8 soybeans With two units of resources, 1 for wheat 1 for soybeans -Canada: __ wheat and __ soybeans -Brazil: __ wheat and __ soybeans Totals: __ wheat and __ soybeans With two units of resources, produce good with comparative advantage - Canada: __ wheat and __ soybeans -Brazil: __ wheat and __ soybeans Totals: __ wheat and __ soybeans Protectionism: With two units of resources, produce good other than comparative advantage - Canada: __ wheat and __ soybeans -Brazil: __ wheat and __ soybeans Totals: __ wheat and __ soybeans Bonsai Areca Guns 12 8 4 0 Butter 0 2 4 6 Guns 16 12 8 4 0 Butter 0 1 2 3 4 Production Possibilities - Mexico Product A B C D E Avocados 0 20 24 40 60 Soybeans 15 10 9 5 0 1 S = __ A 1 A = __ S Production Possibilities - US Product A B C D E 1 S = __ A Avocados 0 30 33 60 90 1 A = __ S Soybeans 30 20 19 10 0 US should produce? Mexico should produce? Terms of Trade? ___ A for ___ S • Columns (1) and (2) show the daily per worker output of the food & clothing industry in the U.S. and Japan. Output per worker day Food Clothing (1) (2) Country United States Japan Change in total output 2 3 1 9 Potential change in output* Food Clothing (3) (4) +6 -3 +5 -3 +9 +6 * Change in output if US shifts 3 workers from clothing to food industry and if Japan shifts one from food to the clothing. • If the U.S. moves 3 workers from clothing to food, it produces 6 more units of food and only 3 fewer of clothing. • If Japan moves 1 worker from food to clothing, it produces 9 more units of clothing and only 3 fewer of food. • With such a reallocation of labor, the U.S. and Japan are able to increase their aggregate output of both food and clothing. PPC Before Specialization and Trade • Output of the labor force of both the US (200 million) and Japan (50 million) given the production costs of food and clothing from the previous slide. • In the absence of trade, consumption possibilities will be restricted to points like US1 in the U.S. and J1 in Japan. • Each of these points lay along the production possibilities curve (PPC) of the respective nation. Clothing United States (million units) 450 400 350 Production possibilities, U.S. 300 250 M 200 150 US1 100 50 Clothing 450 R 375 Production possibilities, Japan 300 225 J1 150 75 S N 100 200 300 Food 400 (million units) Japan (million units) 75 150 Food (million units) Consumption Possibilities with Trade • Specialization and trade expand consumption possibilities. • If the U.S. trades food for clothing (1-for-1), it can specialize in the production of food and consume along the ON line (rather than its original production-possibilities constraint, MN). • Similarly, if Japan trades clothing for food (1-for-1), it can specialize in the production of clothing and consume any combination along the RT line (rather than its original, RS). Clothing United States (million units) 450 400 O 350 300 250 M 200 150 US1 100 50 100 Clothing 450 Consumption possibilities of U.S. with trade Japan (million units) R Consumption possibilities of Japan with trade 375 300 225 J1 150 75 S N 200 300 Food 400 (million units) 75 150 T Food 400 (million units) Consumption Possibilities with Trade • For example, with specialization and trade, the U.S. could increase its consumption from US1 to US2, gaining 50 million units of clothing and 100 million units of food. • Simultaneously, Japan could increase consumption from J1 to J2, a gain of 125 million units of food and 25 million units of clothing. Clothing United States (million units) 450 400 O 350 300 250 M 200 150 US1 100 50 100 Clothing Japan (million units) 450 R 375 300 250 225 US2 J1 J2 150 75 200 300 Food 400 (million units) T S N 75 150 Food 200 400 (million units) Consumption Possibilities with Trade • How exactly do the U.S. and Japan consume at US2 and J2? • The U.S. produces 400 million units of food, consumes 200 million, and exports 200 million to Japan. • Japan produces 450 million units of clothing, consumes 250 million, and exports 200 million to the U.S.. • They consume more together than they could individually. Clothing United States (million units) 450 375 300 250 225 US imports US2 Japan (million units) R Japan exports 450 400 O 350 300 250 M 200 150 100 50 Clothing J2 150 75 US exports 100 200 300 N Food 400 (million units) Japan imports S 150 200 T Food 400 (million units) Exports 1985% 2010% Foods, feeds, beverages 11.0 8.4 Industrial supplies 26.7 30.6 Capital goods 33.8 34.9 Automotive 10.5 8.8 5.8 13.0 Non-Food consumer goods Imports 1985% 2010% 6.5 4.8 Capital goods 33.8 31.5 19.3 23.5 Automotive 19.9 11.8 Non-Food consumer goods 20.3 25.3 Foods, feeds, beverages Industrial supplies Some U.S. Exports Quantity of Exports Quantity of Imports ($ billions) ($ billions) Autos Food and Beverage Capital Goods $146 $133 $537 $298 $110 $549 Consumer Goods Passenger Fare $182 $39 $516 $35 Other transportation $45 $55 Why do similar high-income economies engage in intra-industry trade? The division of labor leads to learning, innovation, and unique skills. Economies of scale Gains from Specialization and Learning In working on very specific and particular products, firms in certain countries develop unique and different skills The US may be exporting machinery for manufacturing with wood, but importing machinery for photographic processing. Splitting up the Value Chain? 1. The Value Chain is all of the stages in the production process. 2. Due to improvements in communication technology, sharing information, and transportation, it has become easier to split up the value chain. 3. All of these steps can be split up among different firms operating in different places and even different countries. Does Anyone Lose as a Result of International Trade? Some firms win, and some lose. The losers are likely to try to convince their governments to interfere by barring imports of the competing products from the other country or by imposing high tariffs on them. A Hard Lesson to Learn Exports and Imports are Linked • Exports provide the foreign exchange needed for the purchase of imports. • Imports provide trading partners with the currency needed to purchase exported goods and services. • Therefore, restrictions that limit one will also limit the other. U.S. Has a Comparative Advantage • The price of soybeans and other internationally traded commodities is determined by the forces of supply and demand in the world market. • If U.S. soybean producers were prohibited from selling to foreigners, the domestic price would be Pn. • Free trade permits U.S. soybean producers to sell Qp units at the higher world price of Pw. U.S. Market Sd Price Pw a b Sw World Market Price Sw Pw c Pn Dw Dd Qc Qn Qp Soybeans (bushels) Qw Soybeans (bushels) U.S. Has a Comparative Advantage • At the world price of Pw, the quantity (Qp – Qc) is exported. • Compared to the no-trade situation, the producers’ gain from the higher price (Pw b c Pn) exceeds the cost imposed on domestic consumers (Pw a c Pn) by the triangle (area) a b c. U.S. Market Sd Price Pw a b Sw World Market Price Sw Pw c Pn Dw Dd U.S. exports Qc Qn Qp Soybeans (bushels) Qw Soybeans (bushels) Foreigners Have a Comparative Advantage • Consider the international market for manufacturing shoes. • In the absence of trade, the domestic price would be Pn. • Since many foreign producers have a comparative advantage in the production of shoes, international trade leads to lower prices Pw. U.S. Market World Market Price Sd Price Sw Pn a Pw Dd Dw Qn Shoes Qw Shoes Foreigners Have a Comparative Advantage • At the price Pw, U.S. consumers demand Qc units of which (Qc – Qp) are imported. • Compared to no trade, consumers gain Pn a b Pw, while domestic producers lose Pn a c Pw. • A net gain of a b c results. U.S. Market World Market Price Sd Price Sw a Pn Pw b c Sw Pw Dd Dw U.S. imports Qp Qn Qc Shoes Qw Shoes 1. Measured as a share of the economy, the size of the trade sector (exports plus imports) of the United States has a. been increasing since 1980, but it declined during 1960– 1980. b.been relatively constant during the last four decades. c. increased by about 10 percent during the last four decades. d.approximately doubled since 1980 and tripled since 1960. 2. A U.S. trade policy that restricts the sale of foreign goods in the U.S. market will a. reduce the demand for U.S. export goods since foreigners will be less able to buy our goods if they cannot sell to us. b.benefit producers in industries that export goods. c. increase the nation’s income since it protects domestic jobs. d.enhance economic efficiency by allocating more resources to the areas of their greatest comparative advantage. True or False 1. The purchase of goods and services from abroad is called exporting. 2. The largest category of U.S. exports is foods and beverages. 3. The country with which the United States carries on the largest amount of international trade is Canada. 4. The scarcity problem can be eliminated by increasing production through specialization. 5. A country is said to have a comparative advantage over another country if it can produce a product at a lower opportunity cost than can the other country 6. The availability of appropriate markets and the ability to trade are necessary if countries are to specialize in their production 7. Trade restrictions must be imposed between countries if they are to gain the full benefits of production according to comparative advantage.