Tobacco Control in Developing Countries and Curbing the Epidemic P Jha, FJ Chaloupka on behalf of the report team The World Bank WHO Why this book? Economic arguments around tobacco control are unclear and often debated In 1996, an Asian Health Minister stated “cigarette producers are making large contributions to our economy... we have to think about workers and tobacco farmers” In 1997, The Economist commented "most smokers (twothirds or more) do not die of smoking-related disease. They gamble and win. Moreover, the years lost to smoking come from the end of life, when people are most likely to die of something else anyway” Source: Tobacco Control 1996, The Economist 1997 Methodology Consultation workshops: Washington D.C. 1996, Beijing 1997, Cape Town 1998 Cape Town Proceedings published in 1998 19 Background papers 40 economists, epidemiologists, and control experts from 13 countries. Reviews of literature New analyses 2 rounds of peer review Synthesized in “Curbing the Epidemic”, Jha and Chaloupka, 1999 Outline of book Tobacco use and its consequences Analytics of tobacco use Demand for tobacco Supply of tobacco Policy directions Most smokers live in developing countries Current smokers in 1995 (in millions) Region Number Low/Middle income 933 High Income 209 World 1,142 Quit rates low in low income countries 5-10% in China and India 15-21% in Hungary and Poland 30-40% in UK Source: Jha et al, 2002, AJPH Large and growing number of deaths from smoking Past and future tobacco deaths (in billions) Time 1901-2000 Billions of deaths 0.1 (mostly in developed countries) 2001-2100 0.5 1.0 (mostly in developing countries) B among people alive today 1 in 2 of long-term smokers killed by their addiction 1/2 of deaths in middle age (35-69) Source: Peto and Lopez, 2001 Trends in smoking in Norwegian males by Income Group Male smoking prevalence 85% 75% High income 65% 55% 45% Low income 35% 25% 1955 1960 1965 Source: Lund et al., 1995 1970 1975 Year 1980 1985 1990 Smoking is more common among the less educated Smoking prevalence among men in Chennai, India, by education levels 64% 58% Smoking prevalence 60% 42% 40% 21% 20% 0% Illiterate <6 years 6-12 years Length of schooling Source: Gajalakshmi and Peto 1997 >12 years Nicotine addition and the poor: Plasma cotinine ( ng/ ml) Plasma cotinine in adult smokers by socioeconomic status 35 0 30 0 25 0 20 0 0 1 2 3 4 Socio-economic status Source: Health Survey, England, 1999; Bobak et al, 2000 Smoking accounts for much of the mortality gap between rich and poor Risk of death of a 35 year old male before age 70, by education levels in Poland, 1996 60% 50% Other causes 40% 28% 30% 22% 20% 5% 21% 10% 1% 1% 5% 9% Higher Secondary 19% 0% Source: Bobak et al., 2000 Primary Attributed to SMOKING but would have died anyway at ages 35-69 Attributed to SMOKING Why should governments intervene? Economic rationale or “market failures” Smokers do not know their risks Addiction and youth onset of smoking Lack of information and unwillingness to act on information Regret habit later, but many addicted Costs imposed on others Costs of environmental tobacco smoke and health costs Source: Jha et al., 2000 Underestimated risks of smoking 7 in 10 of Chinese smokers thought smoking does them “little or no harm” Risks not internalized: personal risks perceived lower than average risks Risks of addiction downplayed: only 2 in 5 of US adolescents intending to quit actually do in high-income countries, 7 in 10 smokers wish they had not started Source: Kenkel and Chen, 2000; Weinstein, 1998; SGR, 1989 and 1994 Tobacco addiction starts early in life US (bot h sexes, Cumulative uptake in percent 100 born 1952-61) C hi na (males,1996) US 80 (bot h sexes, born 1910-14) I ndi a (males, 1995) 60 40 20 0 15 20 25 Age Every day 80,000 to 100,000 youths become regular smokers Source: Chinese Academy of Preventive Medicine 1997, Gupta 1996, US Surgeon General Reports, 1989 Healthcare costs from smoking Annual (gross) healthcare costs: 0.1-1.1% of GDP, or 6 -15% of total health costs in highincome countries proportionally similar in lower-income countries Net (lifetime) healthcare costs: Differences in lifetime costs are smaller than annual costs Best studies do suggest there are net lifetime costs Pension or “smokers pay their way” arguments are complex Source: Lightwood et al., 2000 Government roles in intervening To deter children from smoking To protect non-smokers from others’ smoke To provide adults with necessary information to make an informed choice First-best instrument, such as youth restrictions, are usually ineffective. Thus, tax increases are justified, and are effective. Tax increases are blunt instruments. Source: Jha et al., 2000 Tobacco deaths (million) Unless current smokers quit, smoking deaths will rise dramatically over the next 50 years 520 500 500 Baseline 400 340 300 220 200 100 0 0 1950 190 70 2000 2025 Year Source: Peto and Lopez, 2001 2050 If proportion of young adults taking up smoking halves by 2020 If adult consumption halves by 2020 Which interventions are effective? Measures to reduce demand Higher cigarette taxes Non-price measures: consumer information, research, cigarette advertising and promotion bans, warning labels and restrictions on public smoking Increased access to nicotine replacement (NRT) and other cessation therapies Taxation is the most effective measure Higher taxes induce quitting, reduce consumption and prevent starting A 10% price increase reduces demand by: 4% in high-income countries 8% in low or middle-income countries About half of the effect is on amount and half on initiation Long-run effects may be greater Young people and the poor are the most price responsive Source: Chaloupka et al., 2000 Cigarette price and consumption show opposite trends (1) Real price of cigarettes and annual per adult cigarette consumption in South Africa 1970-1989 1.3 Consumption per adult 1.2 0.08 1.1 0.07 1 0.9 0.06 Real price 0.8 0.05 0.7 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 Year Source: Saloojee 1995 Real Price Cigarette consumption per adult (in packs) 0.09 Cigarette price and consumption show opposite trends (2) Real price and consumption of cigarettes in the UK 1971-1996 Real price of cigarettes and cigarette consumption in the UK, 1971-96 17000 £ 2.65 CONSUMPTION 16000 Cigarette Consumption 1994 prices (£m) 14000 £ 2.25 13000 £ 2.05 12000 £ 1.85 11000 £ 1.65 PRICE 10000 £ 1.45 9000 1971 £ 1.25 1974 1977 1980 1983 Year Source: Townsend 1998 1986 1989 1992 1995 Price (£) 1994 value £ 2.45 15000 There is still ample room, especially in lowerincome countries, to raise cigarette taxes Average price in US$ Average tax in US$ Tax as a percentage of price 3.00 80 70 60 2.50 50 2.00 40 1.50 30 1.00 20 0.50 10 0.00 0 High Income Upper Middle Income Lower Middle Income Countries by income Source: Chaloupka et al., 2000 Low Income Tax as a percentage of price Average price or tax per pack (US$) 3.50 Cigarette tax increases result in higher tax revenues (1) Real cigarette tax rate and real cigarette tax revenue in the US 1960-95 Cigarette tax rate and cigarette tax revenue in the US 1960-1995 80 70 0.5 60 0.4 50 0.3 40 30 0.2 real cigarette tax rate real cigarette tax revenue 20 0.1 10 0 19 60 19 62 19 64 19 66 19 68 19 70 19 72 19 74 19 76 19 78 19 80 19 82 19 84 19 86 19 88 19 90 19 92 19 94 0 Year Source: Sunley et al., 2000 Real cigarette tax revenue in millions of US$ Real cigarette tax rate per pack (aveage for all states) 0.6 Non-price measures to reduce demand Increase consumer information: dissemination of research findings, warning labels, counter-advertising Comprehensive ban on advertising and promotion Restrictions on smoking in public and work places Increase access to nicotine-replacement therapies (NRT) Health information reduces the demand for cigarettes Country Time Event The US 1964 Surgeon General Report UK 1962 1st report of the Royal College of Physicians 5% Switzerland 1966 An anti-smoking campaign 11% Turkey Implementation of health warning labels 8% 1982 Source: Kenkel and Chen, 2000 Immediate reduction in cigarette consumption 1-2% Comprehensive advertising bans reduce cigarette consumption Cigarette consumption per capita Consumption trends in countries with such bans vs. those with no bans (n=102 countries) 1750 1700 Ban 1650 1600 No Ban 1550 1500 1450 1981 1991 Year Source: Saffer, 2000 Effect of advertising bans and counter-advertising A comprehensive set of tobacco advertising bans can reduce consumption by 6.3% Counter-advertising messages (set at 15% of the total number of advertising messages) can reduce smoking by about 2% a year Source: Saffer, 2000 Clean indoor-air laws and youth access restrictions Clean indoor-air laws: can reduce cigarette consumption can be self-enforcing work best with social consensus against smoking Youth access restrictions: mixed evidence of effectiveness require aggressive reinforcement Effectiveness of cessation Intervention Brief advice to stop by clinician Increase in 6 month quit rates (%) 2 to 3 Adding NRT to brief advice 6 Intensive support plus NRT 8 Source: Raw et al., 1999; AHCPR, 1999 NRT and cessation therapies Adherence rates still low (<40%), and time dependent Role of anti depressants, intensive efforts, combination agents still not clear Price and access issues remain barriers Source: Novotny et al., 2000 NRT and cessation therapies NRTs double the effectiveness of cessation efforts and reduce individuals’ withdrawal costs Governments may widen access to NRT and other cessation therapies by: Reducing regulation (like cigarette markets today) Conducting more studies on cost-effectiveness (especially in low/middle income countries) Considering NRT subsidies for poorest smokers Source: Novotny et al., 2000 Impact of interventions on initiation and cessation Intervention Price increases Anti-smoking media Advertising and promotion bans Initiation 10% increase=3-10% decrease Weak evidence Reduces experimenting and initiation, higher effects on female Cessation 10% increase=11-13% shorter duration, 3% higher cessation Increased number of attempts and success Complete ban reduces consumption by about 6% Youth access Weak evidence No evidence Smoking restrictions Some evidence of lower initiation Work and household restrictions most effective NRT No evidence More decisions to quit and higher number of attempts Source: Ross et al, 2001 Potential reductions in deaths (millions) from a price and non-price measures Income group Price increases of 10% Non-price measures with effectiveness of 2 to 10% NRT (publicly provided) with effectiveness of 0.5 to 2.5% Low / middle 4 to 14 4 to 21 1 to 5 High 0.5 to 2 1 to 5 0.2 to 1 World 5 to 16 5 to 26 1 to 6 Source: Ranson et al., 2002 Documenting changes in response to control policies CALIFORNIA: 14% versus rest of the US vs. 3% decline in lung cancer rates MONICA analyses of 36 countries: control has been partially effective male never smokers rose female ex-smokers rose, but new smokers rose Source: CDC, 2000; Molirus et al., 2000 Cumulative deaths avoided (millions) before age 60 with interventions in low and middle-income countries, 1998-2020 Infectious and maternal conditions ($26-46 billion/year) 124 83 42 13 4 2005 11 20 32 2010 2015 2020 Year Source: CMH, 2001 Adult smoking cessation (selffinancing) Which interventions are ineffective at reducing consumption? Most measures to reduce supply Prohibition Youth access restrictions Crop substitution Trade restrictions Control of smuggling is the only exception and it is the key supply-side measure Source: Jacobs et al., 2000; Woolery et al., 2000; Taylor et al., 2000 What are the costs of tobacco control? Revenue loss: likely to have revenue gains a 10% tax increase would raise revenue by 7% Job loss: temporary, minimal, and gradual Possible smuggling: crack down on criminal activity, not lower taxes Cost to individuals, especially the poor: partially offset by lower consumption Studies on the employment effects of dramatically reduced or eliminated tobacco consumption Type of country Name and year Net Exporters US (1993) 0% UK (1990) +0.5% Zimbabwe (1980) -12.4% South Africa (1995) +0.4% Scotland (1989) +0.3% Bangladesh (1994) +18.7% Balanced Tobacco Economies Net Importers Net change as % of economy in base year given Source:Buck et al, 1995; Irvine and Sims, 1997; McNicoll and Boyle 1992, Jacobs et al, 2000; Warner et al , 1996 Smuggling of cigarettes Industry has economic incentive to smuggle Increase market share and decrease tax rates Best estimate: 6 to 8.5% of total consumption Non-price variables important Perceived level of corruption more important than cigarette prices Tax increase will lead to revenue increase, even in the event of increased smuggling Source: Merrriman et al. 2000; Joosens, 2000; BAT,1998 Estimated smuggling in 1995 in selected European countries Country Price per pack in US$ 1995 Estimate of smuggling as a percentage of 1995 domestic sales by expert sources Austria 2.96 15% Spain 1.38 15% Germany 3.38 10% Italy 2.19 12% Greece 1.90 8% Sweden 4.58 2% UK 4.16 2% Source: Merriman et al., 2000 Tobacco smuggling tends to rise in line with the degree of corruption Smuggling as a function of transparency index Smuggling as a share of consumption (%) 0.40 Cambodia 0.35 0.30 Pakistan 0.25 y = - 0.02x + 0.2174 R2 = 0.2723 0.20 0.15 Brazil Austria 0.10 0.05 Indonesia Sw eden 0.00 0 2 4 6 Transparency index for country Source: Merriman et al., 2000 8 10 Control of smuggling Countries need not make a choice between higher cigarette tax revenues and lower cigarette consumption Higher tax rates can achieve both Effective control measures of smuggling exist Focus on large container smuggling Prominent local language warnings and tax stamps Increase penalties Licensing and tracking of containers Increase export duties or bonds Multilateral tax increases help combat smuggling Source: Merrriman et al. 2000; Joosens, 2000; BAT, 1998 Lower tax rates in Canada in response to smuggling Real price of cigarettes and annual cigarette Tax reduc ed in an attempt to c ounter smuggling I Real price per pack (USD) 7 90 80 V 6 70 5 60 4 50 3 40 30 2 20 1 10 Real Price Consumption Source: Jha and Chaloupka, 1999 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 0 1989 0 Annual cigarette consumption per capita (in packs) consumption per capita, Canada, 1989-1995 Smuggling and tax revenue (1) SOUTH AFRICA, 1990s Increased excise tax from 38 to 50% of retail price Smuggling rose from 0 to 6% Sales fell 20% Revenue went up 2 fold CANADA, 1993-94 Lowered tax in response to organized smuggling Retail price fell by half Total consumption rose 30%, more so in young Average revenue per capita fell by 35% Source: Abedian, 1998; Sweanor, 1998 Distribution of control policies scores by income group Income group ETS Low (n=51) Middle (n=52) Upper middle (n=30) 3.9 3.2 2.0 1.3 9.1 6.0 3.7 1.3 2.6 13.7 6.3 3.7 1.7 3.2 15.3 Source: Chaloupka et al., 2001 A and P Product Tax Total score Regulation Summary Tobacco deaths worldwide are large and growing, and have higher burdens among the poor Specific market failures support government intervention Demand measures, chiefly tax increases, information, and regulation are most effective to reduce consumption, and are also cost-effective Helping adults quit is as important as preventing kids from starting Control of smuggling is the major supply-side intervention Poor coverage of known effective interventions in lower income countries An agenda for cessation in Europe Goal: raise ex-smoking rates to 50% by 2010 in Eastern and Central Europe European Tobacco Intervention Program (modelled after regional HIV/AIDS programming in Africa and Latin America or ASSIST program by CDC); Major EU/World Bank support of 1 billion Euro/year for 7-10 years (1E/capita); WHO as accountable nodal agency (with separate governance board) with tasks as: research networks on surveillance (inc. smoking on all death certificates), quit campaigns, cessation advice standards and warning label research, policy work on standardising EU entry, partnership with Big Pharma; Regional centres for local publicity and clinical research (MONICA or EPIC as models or as a base), including regional training network on tobacco policy at 5-10 universities; NGOs selected for advocacy and uncovering industry practices; Negotiated future price guarantees for better cessation products; and Only major supply-side focus is on smuggling, including industry involvement and impact on price (take little action on the tobacco subsidy); Source: Jha, Ross, Chaloupka www.tobaccoevidence.org International Tobacco Evidence Network (ITEN) internet-based information sharing enhancing research capacity in 5 regional technical centres; providing a peer review function and dissemination vehicle for primary research fostering interdisciplinary research using peerreviewed research protocols on priority topics www.tobaccoevidence.org