Chapter 21. Stabilization policy with rational expectations ECON320 Prof Mike Kennedy The role of expectations • Activity today will depend importantly on what people expect to happen in the future • The convention is to assume that expectations are formed by looking at the past – for example, our assumption that πe = π-1 • Such an assumption is reasonable when things are normal, but there are lots of cases when it is not – A change in the monetary policy regime – Visible supply shocks that impinge on the structure of the economy – A change in government with a new policy agenda • The logical limit of forward looking expectations is the Rational Expectations Hypothesis or REH – Here it is assumed that expectations are based on all the information available today – That includes information on the structure of the economy and policy changes • The equation below is a formal way of saying that expectations for any variable X today (time t) are based on all the available information, I, at time t-1 Rational expectations and policy ineffectiveness • Suppose that the central bank makes its interest rate decisions on expected or forecast values of inflation and output, based on information at time t-1 • The monetary policy rule is now • Goods market equilibrium is still the same • The SRAS curve is now • We need to specify the stochastic properties of the exogenous variables, which are assumed to be white noise Policy ineffectiveness con’t • Assume the central bank cannot observe current πt and yt – Step 1: Express the endogenous variables yt and πt as functions of the exogenous variables and expectations of y and π Next substitute this expression into SRAS equation – Step 2: Use the above two equations to calculate the rationally expected values of yt and πt, remembering that E[st] = E[vt] = 0 The rationally expected values of y and π are their respective means h( t,e t1 *) b(yt,e t1 y) 0 If we use this final condition we get the following for the forecasts of y and π: and Policy ineffectiveness con’t – Step 3: If we go back to the first two equations in Step 1, we see that e e since h( t, t1 *) b(yt, t1 y) 0 then t * vt st yt y vt – Notice that the policy parameters π, h and b do not appear in the equation for yt leading to the conclusion that systematic monetary policy stabilisation is ineffective! – Systematic demand management cannot influence real output and employment when expectations are rational – To see how this works, rewrite SRAS curve in terms of yt yt y (1/ )( t t,e t 1 ) (1/ )st – Since potential output and the shock are exogenous, the only way to influence output is to create surprise inflation – create errors in the forecasts of the private sector! How robust is the Policy Ineffectiveness Proposition (PIP)? • A problem with PIP is that it assumes that the central bank cannot act on the basis of new information as it becomes available • While it may be true that the private sector cannot (due to fixed contracts or a desire to have infrequent price changes) the central can react and often does react to new information if it is important • When the central bank can act after prices and wages have been set then we get the familiar monetary policy rule rt r h( t *) b(yt y ) • While central bank may not know actual inflation, the above is a convenient way of noting that the central bank can react to new information • With this policy rule, we will again proceed in three steps to solve the model Policy effectiveness under rational expectations • Step 1: Solve the model for yt and πt in terms of exogenous variables – Inserting the new policy rule into the goods market equation (2nd equation slide 3) v 2 h( t *) yt y t 1 2 b – From the aggregate supply equation (3rd equation slide 3) we have t * t,e t1 * (yt y ) st – This can be re-inserted into the 1st equation above to get vt 2 hs t 2h( t,e t1 *) yt y 1 2 (b h) – Next we substitute in the 1st equation on this slide into the 2nd to get (1 2 b)( t,e t1 *) (1 2 b)s t vt t * 1 2 (b h) Policy effectiveness under rational expectations con’t • Step 2: Find πet, t-1 by taking the expected value of the final equation based on information available at t-1 and remembering that E[st] = E[vt] = 0 e (1 b)( 2 t, t1 *) t,e t1 * 1 2 (b h) t,e t1 * • Agents expect the central bank to hit its target • Step 3: Using this condition and the final two equations in Step 1 we get vt 2 hs t 1 2 (b h) (1 2 b)s t vt t * 1 2 (b h) • The key point here is that the parameters of the policy function now appear as determinants of yt and πt • The reason for the effectiveness of policy is that the central bank can react to vt and st after the private sector has been locked into contracts and prices yt y The Lucas Critique • An econometric macro model with backward looking expectations and which was estimated under a previous policy regime cannot be used to predict economic behaviour under a new policy regime • The parameters of the model are likely to change • An example is a lowering of the inflation target: – If expectations are modelled as π-1 then the model will not be able to predict • This critique applies to structural policies as well – If the level of unemployment benefits or the degree of competition in the economy changes then so will the natural unemployment rate • The solution is to build macro modes based on micro foundations Optimal stabilisation under rational expectations • Policy can influence real output and unemployment even when expectations are rational as long as nominal wages and prices are fixed or slow to adjust • The question becomes: What are the optimal values of h and b in the Taylor rule? • We start by assuming that the bank wants to minimize the following 6 4 4 4 7SL 4 4 4 8 E[SL] [(yt y ) 2 ( t *) 2 ] y2 2 , 0 • The parameter κ measures the social loss of inflation relative to output • We can find the two variances from the final two equations in slide 8 2 2 2 2 2h s y2 E[(yt y ) 2 ] v [1 2 (b h)] 2 2 2 2 2 (1 b) s v 2 2 E[( t *) 2 ] [1 2 (b h)] 2 Optimal stabilisation under rational expectations con’t • From the above we see that if the economy were hit by only demand shocks then the variance of both output and inflation would be lower, the higher are both b and h • The economy is however hit by both types of shocks which will present tradeoffs due to supply shocks – they go in the opposite directions • We can see this by taking the first order conditions of SL wrt h and b y2 E[SL] 2 0 0 h h h y2 E[SL] 2 0 0 b b b • To lower the computational burden we will assume that b = 0; the central bank focuses on just the inflation gap which changes the SL to: v2 22h 2 s2 ( 2 v2 s2 ) E[SL] (1 2h) 2 Optimal stabilisation under rational expectations con’t • Next we calculate the first order conditions to get 2h 22 s2 (1 2h) 2 2 2 (1 2 h)[ v2 h 2 22 s2 ( 2 v2 s2 )] E[SL] 0 0 4 (1 2 h) h h 2 s2 (1 2 h) [ v2 h 2 22 s2 ( 2 v2 s2 )] 0 h 2 s2 h 2 22 s2 [ v2 h 2 22 s2 ( 2 v2 s2 )] 2 2 v h (1 ) 2 2 s • The final expression says that the optimal value of h will depend importantly on the relative variances of the demand and supply shocks – When demand shocks are large, a strong interest rate response will serve to close both the inflation and output gaps – In the opposite case, the central bank should respond only moderately to an inflation shock – The coefficients α2 and γ as well as κ are also important Note: The 3rd equation simplifies to the 4th because the terms in ovals cancel Monetary policy in a liquidity trap • Can forward-looking expectations be manipulated to get out of a liquidity trap • Noting that the demand shock (vt) represents future expected levels of consumption and investment we can re-write the AD curve as: e vt yt1,t y at , E[at ] 0, E[at a j ] 0, t j, E[at s j ] 0, • The goods market equilibrium is still given by e yt y vt 2 (it t1,t r ) • It follows from the above that the rational expectation of next period’s output gap is given by e e e e e e e yt1,t y vt1,t 2 (it1,t t2,t r ) yt2,t y 2 (it1,t t2,t r ) • Substituting the first and third equation into the second we get e e e e yt y yt2,t y 2 (it1,t t2,t r ) 2 (it t1,t r ) at Monetary policy in a liquidity trap, con’t • The final equation on the previous slide may be written as t2,t y 6 4 4 4 44y7 4 4 4 4 48 e e e e e e yt y yt3,t y 2 (it2,t t3,t r ) 2 (it1,t t2,t r ) 2 (it t1,t r ) at e • Continuing to eliminate the output gap we get the following for the current output gap j1 t t 2 t t1,t t j,t t j1,t y y a i e r (i e e r ) • This expression shows that under rational expectations the current output gap depends not only on current real interest rates but also on the future path of monetary policy • When the nominal interest rate is stuck at zero then the above becomes yt y at 2 (r e t1,t ) 2 (ite j,t te j1,t r ) j1 • Now the central bank can influence the output gap by promising both lower interest rates but as well high inflation in the future Announcement effects • Under rational expectations, announcement effects can play an important role in affecting the economy • An announcement of a new policy can influence the economy even before it is implemented • To see how this works we return to our model of equity prices e e Dt,te Dt1,t Dt2,t Vt ... 1 r (1 r) 2 (1 r) 3 • Importantly here define D as after-tax dividends and before-tax dividends as d or (where ε is a stochastic ‘white noise’ variable) d tn d tn • If dividends are tax proportionally at a rate τ0, then e Dtn,t (1 0 )d Announcement effects con’t • As long as the tax rate, τ0, stays constant then (1 0 )d Vt r • We now assume that at time t = t1 the government will lower the tax rate to τ1 e Dtn,t (1 0 )d for t n t1 and t t0 • If we insert this into the first equation on the previous slide we get (1 0 )d (1 0 )d (1 0 )d (1 1 )d (1 1 )d Vt ... ... 1 r (1 r) 2 (1 r) t1 t (1 r) t1 1t (1 r) t1 2t d 1 1 for t0 t t1 Vt 1 t1 t (1 0 ) t1 t (1 1 ) r (1 r) (1 r) • The above shows the price of equity today and how it will be affected by policy changes in the future Announcement effects con’t • Between the time of the announcement and the actual tax cut, the value of equity is given by the final equation on the previous slide • Once the tax cuts occurs, we get Vt (1 1 )d r for t t1 • Note that the market value of equity jumps immediately when the policy is announced Vt0 Vt0 1 0 1 (d /r) (1 r) t1 t0 • Thereafter the price will rise and the speed will depend on how long it takes to implement the policy The effect of an announced dividend tax cut