Notes Chapters 12 Point of the class Math Growth rates Ratio scales Logs and exponents Algebraic manipulation Partial derivatives and maximization Model building Modifying the Solow model to include population growth and technological progress Economic concepts and intuition Capital/output ratio Definitions Rule of 70 Growth accounting Homework Problems On the webpage. Capital/output ratio Capital deepening Properties of Growth Rates Growth rates: how they work Year 𝑥𝑡+𝑛 = 𝑥𝑡 (1 + 𝑔)𝑛 o This allows us to calculate average growth rates over long period of time. 𝑥𝑡+𝑛 1/𝑛 𝑔=( ) −1 𝑥𝑡 1870 1929 1950 2004 US Average Income growth rate 2525 7,100 1.77% 11,720 36,880 2.15% Rule of 70 Property of logs 2𝑥𝑡 = 𝑥𝑡 (1 + 𝑔)𝑛 ln(𝑥 𝑛 ) = 𝑛 ln(𝑥) 2 = (1 + 𝑔)𝑛 ln(𝑎𝑏) = 𝑙𝑛(𝑎) + 𝑙𝑛(𝑏) 𝑙𝑛2 = 𝑙𝑛(1 + 𝑔)𝑛 𝑎 ln ( ) = 𝑙𝑛(𝑎) − 𝑙𝑛(𝑏) 𝑏 𝑙𝑛2 = 𝑛 × 𝑙𝑛(1 + 𝑔) 𝑙𝑛(1 + 𝑔) ≈ 𝑔 0.7 ≈ 𝑛 × 𝑔 𝑛≈ o o 70 𝑔 × 100 Suppose a quantity is growing at a constant rate. To figure out the number of years for it to double, divide 70 by the growth rate times 100. So if it’s growing at 2% per year, it will double every 35 years, regardless of the starting point (the xt cancelled out). Bank account balance of $100 At times 0, 1, 2, 12, 24, 48, 60, what is the bank balance Assuming interest rate of 1% Assuming interest rate of 6% Ratio (logarithmic) scales allow one to see data more easily if their rate of growth is constant. Plot both on a standard scale and on a ratio scale Rules of Growth Rates 𝑥 If 𝑧 = 𝑦, then 𝑔𝑧 = 𝑔𝑥 − 𝑔𝑦 If 𝑧 = 𝑥𝑦, then 𝑔𝑧 = 𝑔𝑥 + 𝑔𝑦 If 𝑧 = 𝑥 𝑎 , then 𝑔𝑧 = 𝑎𝑔𝑥 𝑌 = 𝐴𝐾 𝛼 𝑁1−𝛼 A is growing at a rate of g(A) K grows at g(K) 𝐾 𝛼 𝑦 = 𝐴 ( ) = 𝐴𝑘 𝛼 𝑁 Using the second rule 𝑔(𝑦) = 𝑔(𝐴) + 𝑔(𝑘 𝛼 ) N grows at g(N) Using the first rule Using the second rule 𝑔(𝑌) = 𝑔(𝐴) + 𝑔(𝐾 𝛼 ) + 𝑔(𝑁1−𝛼 ) 𝑔(𝑦) = 𝑔(𝐴) + 𝑔(𝐾 𝛼 ) − 𝑔(𝑁 𝛼 ) Using the third rule Using the third rule 𝑔(𝑦) = 𝑔(𝐴) + 𝛼[𝑔(𝐾) − 𝑔(𝑁)] 𝑔(𝑌) = 𝑔(𝐴) + 𝛼𝑔(𝐾) + (1 − 𝛼)𝑔(𝑁) Suppose xt=(1.05)t and yt=(1.02)t Calculate the growth rate of z if z=xy, z=x/y, z=x1/3y2/3 0 5000 10000 Real GDP per capita 15000 20000 Why does GDP per worker increase? 1950 1960 1970 1980 year 1990 2000 Real GDP per capita, Korea Real GDP per capita, Nicaragua 𝑦 = 𝐴𝑘 1/3 Increases in capital per worker. o But this is limited by diminishing returns: Saving rates determine the level but not the growth rate of output Empirical Test o o Suppose A=1, so only the level of capital-per-worker determined output-per-worker Get data for capital-per-worker and output-per-worker. Divide all the values by the corresponding values for the US, to see if it yields commonsensical predictions. Take the cubic root of capital-per-worker, and plot it. Why the exponent of 1/3? Because empirically, most countries are pretty close to 1/3 contribution of capital to production. Why do most countries underperform? SWITZERLAND 2.097544 Predicted Real GDP per worker, 1985 US=1 𝒚 = 𝒌𝟏/𝟑 1.28008 NORWAY 1.499282 1.144531 0.85099 LUXEMBOURG 1.419515 1.123863 0.911168 FINLAND 1.289591 1.088472 0.701536 GERMANY, WEST 1.192749 1.060514 0.806678 CANADA 1.154052 1.048919 0.921973 AUSTRALIA 1.131997 1.042194 0.857236 BELGIUM 1.108104 1.034809 0.808839 FRANCE 1.062523 1.020421 0.801113 SWEDEN 1.046817 1.015368 0.784537 NEW ZEALAND 1.019582 1.006485 0.770772 Country Capital Stock per worker, 1985 US=1 Actual Real GDP per worker, 1985 US=1 0.883521 U.S.A. 1 1 1 AUSTRIA 0.992749 0.997577 0.705592 NETHERLANDS 0.97995 0.993272 0.845484 DENMARK 0.978647 0.992831 0.706302 ITALY 0.939582 0.979441 0.804813 JAPAN 0.939215 0.979313 0.557085 ISRAEL 0.74543 0.906711 0.649824 GREECE 0.740217 0.904593 0.481603 SPAIN 0.729524 0.900216 0.626617 IRELAND 0.691729 0.884393 0.568244 VENEZUELA 0.682339 0.880373 0.543528 TAIWAN 0.641404 0.862403 0.375958 U.K. 0.58934 0.838408 0.680253 PANAMA 0.548605 0.818628 0.297161 ICELAND 0.534369 0.811485 0.688394 SYRIA 0.52401 0.806207 0.508125 ECUADOR 0.519165 0.803714 0.284611 MEXICO 0.468371 0.776599 0.504277 COLOMBIA 0.427402 0.753261 0.274576 ARGENTINA 0.40381 0.739138 0.442678 KOREA, REP. 0.402206 0.738158 0.306693 POLAND 0.375439 0.721406 0.239144 HONG KONG 0.374937 0.721085 0.486843 IRAN 0.357093 0.709459 0.409881 PORTUGAL 0.317561 0.682248 0.335761 PERU 0.316792 0.681697 0.240979 SRI LANKA 0.275288 0.650523 0.165675 YUGOSLAVIA 0.257109 0.635876 0.337951 CHILE 0.235923 Predicted Real GDP per worker, 1985 US=1 𝒚 = 𝒌𝟏/𝟑 0.617908 TURKEY 0.233551 0.615829 0.209899 Country Capital Stock per worker, 1985 US=1 Actual Real GDP per worker, 1985 US=1 0.28914 BOLIVIA 0.233484 0.615771 0.166445 ZIMBABWE 0.192147 0.577047 0.096528 DOMINICAN REP. 0.176508 0.560947 0.209632 BOTSWANA 0.15462 0.536729 0.201048 HONDURAS 0.15061 0.532048 0.137702 SWAZILAND 0.150409 0.531812 0.154664 PHILIPPINES 0.136575 0.51498 0.125181 THAILAND 0.135372 0.513463 0.140633 GUATEMALA 0.133166 0.51066 0.217802 JAMAICA 0.124478 0.499303 0.139893 MOROCCO 0.093668 0.454147 0.190244 MAURITIUS 0.079967 0.430827 0.221236 ZAMBIA 0.059649 0.390722 0.071012 MADAGASCAR 0.057277 0.385472 0.050528 INDIA 0.05721 0.385322 0.080484 KENYA 0.039666 0.34104 0.059616 IVORY COAST 0.039131 0.339501 0.110707 NIGERIA 0.036859 0.332798 0.085072 PARAGUAY 0.028371 0.304994 0.184738 NEPAL 0.02533 0.293683 0.066424 MALAWI 0.015673 0.250253 0.034662 SIERRA LEONE 0.007185 0.19296 0.071367 1.2 SWITZERLAND 1 NORWAY LUXEMBOURG FINLAND GERMANY, WEST CANADA AUSTRALIA BELGIUM FRANCE SWEDEN NEW ZEALAND U.S.A. AUSTRIA NETHERLANDS DENMARK JAPAN ITALY .2 .4 .6 .8 ISRAEL GREECE SPAIN IRELAND VENEZUELA TAIWAN U.K. PANAMA ICELAND SYRIA ECUADOR MEXICO COLOMBIA ARGENTINA KOREA, REP. HONG POLAND KONG IRAN PORTUGAL PERU SRI LANKA YUGOSLAVIA CHILE TURKEY BOLIVIA ZIMBABWE DOMINICAN REP. BOTSWANA HONDURAS SWAZILAND PHILIPPINES THAILAND GUATEMALA JAMAICA MOROCCO MAURITIUS ZAMBIA MADAGASCAR INDIA KENYA IVORY COAST NIGERIA PARAGUAY NEPAL MALAWI SIERRA LEONE 0 .5 1 1.5 Capital per worker (US=1) Penn World Table 5.6. 1985 data 2 The red line is what the model would predict if countries only differed on capital stock levels. 1 1.5 Penn World Tables 5.6, in KAPW-RGDPW.dta SWITZERLAND 0 .5 U.S.A. CANADALUXEMBOURG AUSTRALIA NORWAY NETHERLANDS BELGIUM WEST GERMANY, ITALY FRANCE NEWSWEDEN ZEALAND AUSTRIA FINLAND ICELAND U.K. ISRAEL DENMARK SPAIN IRELAND JAPAN VENEZUELA SYRIA GREECE HONGMEXICO KONG ARGENTINA IRAN TAIWAN YUGOSLAVIA PORTUGAL KOREA, REP. PANAMA CHILE ECUADOR COLOMBIA PERU POLAND MAURITIUS GUATEMALA DOMINICAN TURKEY REP. BOTSWANA MOROCCO PARAGUAY BOLIVIA SRI LANKA SWAZILAND THAILAND JAMAICA HONDURAS PHILIPPINES IVORY COAST ZIMBABWE NIGERIA INDIA SIERRA LEONE ZAMBIA NEPAL KENYA MADAGASCAR MALAWI 0 .5 1 1.5 Capital per worker (US=1) Real GDP per worker, actual 2 RGDP, predicted Penn World Table 5.6. 1985 data o Improvements in technology make a difference 𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝐹𝑎𝑐𝑡𝑜𝑟 𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑑𝑢𝑐𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑖𝑡𝑦 = 𝐴 = 𝑦 𝑘 1/3 Capital Stock per worker, 1985 US=1 Predicted Real GDP per worker, 1985 US=1 𝒚 = 𝒌𝟏/𝟑 Actual Real GDP per worker, 1985 US=1 𝒚 = 𝑨𝒌𝟏/𝟑 U.S.A. 1 1 1 Implied TFP (A) The Residual 𝒚 𝑨 = 𝟏/𝟑 𝒌 1 ITALY 0.939582 0.979441 0.804813 0.821707 U.K. 0.58934 0.838408 0.680253 0.811363 Country SPAIN 0.729524 0.900216 0.626617 0.696074 SWITZERLAND 2.097544 1.28008 0.883521 0.690208 MEXICO 0.468371 0.776599 0.504277 0.649341 JAPAN 0.939215 0.979313 0.557085 0.568853 SIERRA LEONE 0.007185 0.19296 0.071367 0.369855 ECUADOR 0.519165 0.803714 0.284611 0.354119 INDIA 0.05721 0.385322 0.080484 0.208876 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 𝑦 = 2(𝑘)1/3 U.S.A. CANADA ICELANDNETHERLANDS AUSTRALIA ITALY U.K. LUXEMBOURG FRANCE BELGIUM SWEDEN NEW ZEALAND GERMANY, WEST NORWAY ISRAEL DENMARK AUSTRIA SPAIN SWITZERLAND HONG KONG MEXICO IRELAND FINLAND SYRIA VENEZUELA PARAGUAY ARGENTINA IRAN JAPAN YUGOSLAVIAGREECE MAURITIUS PORTUGAL CHILE TAIWAN GUATEMALA MOROCCO KOREA, REP. BOTSWANA DOMINICAN REP. SIERRA LEONE COLOMBIA PANAMA ECUADOR PERU TURKEY POLAND IVORY COAST SWAZILAND JAMAICA THAILAND BOLIVIA HONDURAS NIGERIA SRI LANKA PHILIPPINES NEPAL INDIA ZAMBIA KENYA ZIMBABWE MALAWI MADAGASCAR 0 .5 Real GDP per worker, 1985 1 What determines TFP? (denoted by A) o Human capital Average years of schooling in US is 13; 4 in poorest countries In US, an extra year of education raises lifetime income by 7% In poorest countries, because the skills are so much more basic, the rate of return can be 10-13% If, then, every one of those extra 9 years of education that the average US person receives is worth an extra 10% of income, the income difference would be about 1.9: double. So the residual goes from a factor of 10 to a factor of 5. o Technology Ideas o Institutions Rule of law, Corruption, Property rights, Expropriation, Contract enforcement, Separation of powers The Steady State with Population Growth and Technological Progress The Steady State with Population Growth The model in chapter 11 said that capital accumulation was given by 𝐾𝑡+1 𝐾𝑡 𝑌𝑡 𝐾𝑡 − =𝑠 −𝛿 𝑁 𝑁 𝑁 𝑁 Divide both sides by 𝐾𝑡 ⁄𝑁 𝐾𝑡+1 𝐾𝑡 𝑁 − 𝑁 = 𝑔 = 𝑠 𝑌𝑡 ⁄𝑁 − 𝛿 𝐾 𝐾𝑡 𝐾𝑡 ⁄𝑁 𝑁 Since we assumed that population was stationary, we could cancel out all the “N”s and find that capital 𝑌 𝑌 grew at a rate equal to 𝑠 𝐾𝑡 − 𝛿. But population is growing, so if capital grows 𝑠 𝐾𝑡 − 𝛿, capital per 𝑡 worker will grow by 𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑁 = 𝑡 𝑌 𝑠 𝐾𝑡 𝑡 − 𝛿 − 𝑔𝑁 . We need to include a factor that we neglected in chapter 11: the price of capital!! Capital has to be bought at a price, evidently. So it would make sense that if people save $100, and if capital costs $2 unit, firms can only buy $100/$2= 50 units. In general, if saving is a quantity of funds “X”, that quantity of funds can only by “X/pK” units of capital. So far we’ve been (implicitly) assuming that pK=1. So we modify the equation to take this into account. 𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑁 = 𝑌 𝑠 𝑡 𝐾𝑡 𝑝𝐾 − 𝛿 − 𝑔𝑁 Growth of capital-per-worker The Steady State with Technological Progress Suppose technology progresses over time (a reasonable assumption in the last two hundred years or so). We found that every improvement in technology makes the curves in the Solow diagram shift up, so that steady-state capital-per-worker and steady-state output-per-worker grow. The steady-state level of capital-per-worker must depend also on the rate of growth of Total Factor Productivity, A. Since productivity grows constantly, it deserves its own separate growth rate, which we can denote by gA. I=sAk1/3 Well, this is fine, but it’s very unsatisfactory to talk about a “steady state” that changes all the time due to perfectly well-known factors. We should reformulate our definition of the steady state to incorporate the fact that productivity growth causes changes in capital-per-worker. Imagine the world before padded horse collars. Farmers lived in a steady state with their horses, their plows, and their houses. Then the padded horse collar is invented. Capital (the horses) become more productive as people invest in padding. The same amount of capital produces more output out of their soil. More can be saved and people repair their houses. But because this was a one-time increase in productivity, eventually we come to another steady state with horses, padded collars, plows, and better houses. People end up with more capital per unit of output produced. So an improvement in technology changes the amount of capital-per-unit-of GDP. This suggests a new definition. In the steady state, the capital-output ratio is constant. In the steady state, the growth rate of capital is equal to the growth rate of output. In the steady state, 𝐾𝑡∗ 𝑖𝑠 𝑐𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑡 𝑌𝑡∗ ∗ 𝐾𝑡+1 𝐾𝑡∗ ∗ − ∗ 𝑌𝑡+1 𝑌𝑡 =0 𝐾𝑡∗ 𝑌𝑡∗ 𝑔𝐾∗ = 𝑔𝑌∗ = 0 𝑔𝐾∗ = 𝑔𝑌∗ Definition of the steady state This definition is new, but it is consistent with the definition in Chapter 11. There, capital accumulation stopped in the steady state (which, remember, doesn’t make sense if population is growing and technology is improving). If 𝑔𝐾 = 0, then we found that 𝑔𝑌 = 0. So it was also true there that 𝑔𝐾 = 𝑔𝑌 . Output-per-worker, Total Factor Productivity, and the Capital/Output Ratio We can use the capital/output ratio to figure out what determines normal output growth at any point and in the steady state. To do that, modify the “growth rate” version of the Cobb-Douglas production function (𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 = 𝑔𝐴 + 𝛼(𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑁 )) to have the capital/output ratio on the right-hand side. If we just plug −(𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 ) into the parenthesis, that’s like subtracting “𝛼(𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 )” from both sides of the equation. 𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 − 𝛼(𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 ) = 𝑔𝐴 + 𝛼(𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑁 − (𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 )) Now we simplify (1 − 𝛼)(𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 ) = 𝑔𝐴 + 𝛼(𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑌 ) And solve for the growth of output-per-worker (𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 ) = 1 𝑔 (1−𝛼) 𝐴 𝛼 + (1−𝛼) (𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑌 ) output per worker and capital deepening 𝑔𝐴 ⁄(1 − 𝛼) is productivity growth divided by the contribution of labor to output, so we can think of it as “growth in labor productivity.” Then this tells us that at any point in time, normal outputper-worker grows due to two factors: productivity growth and “capital deepening,” that is, increases in the amount of capital-per-unit-of-GDP. This is the extent to which the economy becomes “more industrial” in the sense that each unit of output made requires an increasing amount of capital behind it. The factor Since above we defined the steady state as the point where 𝑔𝐾∗ = 𝑔𝑌∗ , it follows that in the steady state (𝑔𝑌∗ − 𝑔𝑁 ) = 1 𝛼 (0) 𝑔𝐴 + (1 − 𝛼) (1 − 𝛼) (𝑔𝑌∗ − 𝑔𝑁 ) = 1 𝑔 (1 − 𝛼) 𝐴 (𝑔𝐾∗ − 𝑔𝑁 ) = 1 𝑔 (1 − 𝛼) 𝐴 So also In the steady state, the growth rate of GDP-per-worker is given by the growth rate of labor productivity. 𝑔𝑌∗ = 𝑔𝐴 + 𝑔𝑁 (1 − 𝛼) In the steady state, the growth rate of GDP is given by the sum of the growth rate of labor plus the growth rate of labor productivity. Variable Steady-State Growth Rate 𝑔𝐴 + 𝑔𝑁 (1 − 𝛼) 𝑔𝐴 𝑔𝑌 = + 𝑔𝑁 (1 − 𝛼) 𝑔𝐾 = Capital Output 𝑔𝑁 Labor 𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑌 = 0 Capital/output ratio 𝑔𝐴 (1 − 𝛼) 𝑔𝐴 𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑁 = Output-per-worker (1 − 𝛼) And output-per-worker and capital-per-worker grow by the rate of labor productivity growth. So making workers more productive makes living standards grow. 𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑁 = Capital-per-worker Determinants of the capital/output ratio What determines the capital/output ratio? Above we found that capital-per worker grows by 𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑁 = 𝐾 If we solve this for 𝑌𝑡 𝑡 𝑌 𝑠 𝐾𝑡 𝑡 𝑝𝐾 − 𝛿 − 𝑔𝑁 (𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑁 ) + 𝛿 + 𝑔𝑁 = 𝑌 𝑠 𝐾𝑡 𝑡 𝑝𝐾 (𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑁 ) + 𝛿 + 𝑔𝑁 𝑌𝑡 = 𝑠 𝐾𝑡 𝑝𝐾 We get 𝑠⁄ 𝐾𝑡 𝑝𝐾 = 𝑌𝑡 (𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑁 ) + 𝛿 + 𝑔𝑁 Capital output ratio Notice that if we set 𝑝𝐾 back to 1, and 𝑔𝑁 back to zero (and we assume no productivity growth), we get 𝑠⁄ 𝐾𝑡 1 = 𝑌𝑡 (𝑔𝐾 − 0) + 𝛿 + 0 In the steady state, 𝑔𝐾 = 0, so ratio is 𝐾𝑡∗ 𝑌𝑡∗ 𝐾𝑡 𝑌𝑡 s = 0+𝛿 and the capital-output 𝑠 𝛿 = , which is exactly what we got in chapter 11. The Capital/Output Ratio in the Steady State Above we found that in the steady state, (𝑔𝐾∗ − 𝑔𝑁 ) = 1 𝑔 (1 − 𝛼) 𝐴 Plugging that result into the output/capital ratio equation,1 𝐾𝑡∗ = 𝑌𝑡∗ 𝑠⁄ 𝑝𝐾 1 𝑔 + 𝛿 + 𝑔𝑁 (1 − 𝛼) 𝐴 Capital output ratio in the steady-state Phew! What’s nice about this is that historians actually have numbers for all of these variables. Output per worker, 1865-19292 In 1865 the United States had 35 million people in it, at an average measured economic standard of living of some $1,600 year-2008 dollars per year, at least two-thirds farmers or other small-town rural dwellers. By 1929 farming and other small-town rural dwellers were down to one-eighth of the population, the United States had 122 million people in it, and the average measured economic standard of living was some $6,000 year-2008 dollars per year. 1 2 Notice that the K and the Y now have an asterisk, indicating their steady-state levels. http://delong.typepad.com/american_economic_history/2008/09/20080927-growth.html Using the formula for long-run growth we had earlier, 𝑥𝑡+𝑛 1/𝑛 𝑔=( ) −1 𝑥𝑡 Population grew at a rate equal to 122 1/(1929−1865) 𝑔𝑁 = ( ) − 1 = 1.9% 35 An output per worker grew at a rate equal to3 𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 = ( 6000 1/(1929−1865) ) − 1 = 2.1% 1600 The comparable figure for pre-Civil war years is 1.4% annual output-per-worker growth. The continuation—nay, the acceleration—of growth (compared to the Pre-Civil War period) in output per worker alongside continued population growth is especially remarkable given that the frontier had closed in the immediate aftermath of the Civil War: the natural resources the United States had then conquered were all that there were. Yet growth continued: the focus shifted from expansion and resources to industrialization. America became an industrial economy. Even farming became an industrial occupation: much less muscle, ox, and horsepower; many more automatic reapers, harvesters, pumps, stationary gasoline engines, tractors. The Civil War itself brought about some of those transformations (principally in the North). As more farmhands were off fighting the war, McCormick found a ready market for its combine harvester, which could do the work of many farmhands. As the United States grew and transformed itself during those years, two things happened. First, it accumulated capital: it depended more “deeply” on capital accumulation for its production. Each unit of output relied more on capital and less on labor. Each bushel of wheat required less sweat and more steel. Secondly, it acquired new technologies, so the factors became more productive. In 1865 annual rate of population growth 𝑔𝑁 annual growth rate of total factor productivity 𝑔𝐴 3% 0.6% 1/3 annual growth rate of labor productivity 𝑔𝐴 (1 − 𝛼) 0.9% annual rate of depreciation 𝛿 rate of national savings s 4% 20% price of capital goods pK 1 Thus our equation for the capital/output ratio in the steady state becomes: 3 Which means that output (not output per worker, but just output) must have growth at a rate of 4.33% every year. 𝐾𝑡 = 𝑌𝑡 𝑠⁄ 𝑝𝐾 𝑔𝐴 + 𝛿 + 𝑔𝑁 (1 − 𝛼) = 0.20/1 = 2.53 0.006 + .04 + .03 1 − 1/3 So there were about 2.5 units of capital per each unit of GDP produced. By 1929 annual rate of population growth 𝑔𝑁 annual growth rate of total factor productivity 𝑔𝐴 2% 1.1% 1/3 annual growth rate of labor productivity 𝑔𝐴 (1 − 𝛼) 16.5% annual rate of depreciation 𝛿 rate of national savings s 4% 25% price of capital goods pK 0.67 So our equation becomes: 𝐾𝑡 = 𝑌𝑡 𝑠⁄ 𝑝𝐾 0.25/(2/3) = = 4.90 𝑔𝐴 0.011 + 𝛿 + 𝑔𝑁 + .04 + .02 (1 − 𝛼) 1 − 1/3 The jump from 2.5 to 4.90 in the capital-output ratio (measured at 1865 prices) gives us an annual rate of 4.90 1/(1929−1865) 1865−1929 𝑔𝐾/𝑌 =( ) − 1 = 1.0% 2.5 The average growth rate of TFP between 1865 and 1929 was about 1.0%. Plug all this into our “outputper-worker-and-capital-deepening” equation for the growth rate of output per worker: (𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 ) = 1 𝛼 (𝑔 − 𝑔𝑌 ) 𝑔𝐴 + (1 − 𝛼) (1 − 𝛼) 𝐾 (𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 ) = 1 1 (1 − 3) 1.1% + 1 3 1 (1 − 3) 1.0% 3 1 (𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 ) = 1.1% + 1.0% 2 2 (𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 ) = 2.1% 1 which fits our calculations for output-per-worker growth. Between 1865 and 1929 some 1/4 (= 2 1.1%) of American economic growth in measured economic output per capita came from capital deepening— more capital, more produced means of production, more machines backing up each worker. And 3/4 (= 3 1.1%) 2 of American economic growth in measured economic output per capita came from improvements in the efficiency of labor—working smarter made possible by more education, organizational improvements, and other improvements in technology not directly related to those that made capital goods cheaper. Growth Accounting4 We found above that Output-per-worker In Levels 𝑌⁄ = 𝐴(𝐾⁄ )𝛼 𝑁 𝑁 In Rates 𝑔𝑌 − 𝑔𝑁 = 𝑔𝐴 + 𝛼(𝑔𝐾 − 𝑔𝑁 ) Output 𝑌 = 𝐴(𝐾)𝛼 (𝑁)1−𝛼 𝑔𝑌 = 𝑔𝐴 + 𝛼𝑔𝐾 + (1 − 𝛼)𝑔𝑁 Changes in the Solow residual or (the same thing) total factor productivity can come about for many reasons. Economists often refer to total factor productivity as “technology,” but if it is technology it is technology in the widest possible sense. Not just new ways of constructing buildings, newly-invented machines, and new sources of power affect total factor productivity, but changes in work organization, in the efficiency of government regulation, in the degree of monopoly in the economy, in the literacy and skills of the workforce, and in many other factors affect total factor productivity as well. One at-a-time changes to output growth For the following, assume 𝛼 = 1/3. 1. Suppose the capital stock grows by 1%, while everything else remains constant. Then output will change by ∆𝑌 𝑌 =𝛼 ∆𝐾 𝐾 = ______________ 2. Suppose amount of hours worked (N) grows by 1%, while everything else remains constant. ∆𝑌 ∆𝑁 Then output will change by = (1 − 𝛼) = ______________ 𝑌 𝑁 3. Suppose total factor productivity (A) changes by 1%, while everything else remains constant. Then output will change by ∆𝑌 𝑌 = ∆𝐴 𝐴 = ______________ This part is based on Bradford DeLong’s handout, available at http://www.j-bradforddelong.net/macro_online/growth_accounting.pdf 4 Calculating the Solow Residual In 1980-2000, the growth-accounting parameters for the United States were estimated to be5 gY gN6 gK gA 1980-1990 3.3% 1.7% 4.9% 0.29 1990-1995 2.5% 1.3% 3.5% 0.30 0.5% 1995-2000 4.2% 1.9% 5.8% 0.30 Using the growth accounting equation gY g N g A g K g N , calculate the growth in total factor productivity, gA, for 1980-1990 and 1995-2000. What caused the productivity speedup after 1995? The natural candidate is the coming of the information age—the shifts in business organization and competition caused by the technological revolutions in data processing and data communications. Indeed, they did play a substantial role both in accelerating the rate of capital deepening and in boosting total factor productivity growth in hightechnology sectors. However, there is more to the story. A McKinsey Global Institute study concluded that the jump in productivity growth was overwhelmingly driven by six sectors—computer and other durable manufacturing, electronics, telecommunications, retail trade, wholesale trade, and securities brokerage,. The information technology revolution was the key to the boom in the first three sectors, and was a key but not the only key in the last three sectors. “Product, service, and process innovations… were important causes” as well. Increased competition to spur businesses to improve productivity, organizational changes to take advantage of the information technology revolution (like warehouse automation and information technology-based supply chain management), and smarter government regulation of industry played important roles as well in the acceleration of productivity growth in the second half of the 1990s. Calculating components of growth Fill in the blanks in this table. Assume 𝛼 = 1/3. Notice the big estimated productivity slowdown between 1973 and 1995. What short-run, business-cycle factors (of the kind we studied in other chapters) do you think affected US productivity during those years? 1948-2002 1948-1973 1973-1995 1995-2002 Output per hour (Y/L) 2.5 3.3 1.5 Contribution of KL 0.9 0.9 1.3 Contribution of Labor 0.2 0.2 0.4 Contribution of TFP (A) 3.1 1.3 2.7 5 Data derived from Marcel P. Timmer, Gerard Ypma and Bart van Ark (2003), IT in the European Union: Driving Productivity Divergence?, GGDC Research Memorandum GD-67 (October 2003), University of Groningen, Appendix Tables, updated June 2005, http://www.ggdc.net/dseries/growth-accounting.shtml 6 Note that gN is not population growth but the growth in worker-hours. There were more people in the US between 2000-2004, and the number of workers increased by 0.4, but the recession reduced the number of hours worked per worker by an average yearly rate of - 0.8%. Forecasting growth On the basis of the tools that you have and your own educated guesses, let’s make a guess for what will happen to gY, the normal growth rate of natural output in the US, in the next generation or so. First, we need to come up with estimates for gN, gK, , and gA in the next generation? Growth in worker-hours If gN is the growth in worker-hours, it must be determined by the growth in the number of people (population growth, which is probably different for different groups). But that’s not enough. How many people will work? (how will the labor-force participation rate change?) How will the average number of hours worked by each worker change? So if hours worked = hours per worker x labor-force participation rate x population, then 𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝐻𝑜𝑢𝑟𝑠 𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑊𝑜𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑟𝑠 𝐻𝑜𝑢𝑟𝑠 𝑤𝑜𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑑 = × × 𝑃𝑜𝑝𝑢𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑊𝑜𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑟𝑠 𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑃𝑜𝑝𝑢𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 Using the same tools that we developed earlier, we can take logs and derivatives to find how “Hours worked” will change: g N g hours/ wkr glfp rate g Pop 1. What do you think determines the number of hours each worker works? What changes it, and is it likely to change? 2. In the next few years, will the proportion of people who are in the labor force increase or decrease? 3. In the next few years, will population grow faster or more slowly? Growth in capital stock gK is the growth in capital (also known as fixed capital accumulation). But it’s not that simple. How much capital actually gets utilized? (this might change as firms change their engineering set ups, etc.) Capital accumulation is financed by the financial system, in one way or another. But not all the loans that the financial system makes are for investment (some are for consumption). And the total quantity of loans is really determined by three things: a) the efficiency with which the financial sector turns saving into investment, b) proportion of domestic saving that is lent domestically (and by the amount of foreign saving that is lent to domestic residents), and c) the rate at which people save their income. 1. What do you think determines the capacity utilization? What changes it, and is it likely to change? 2. In the next few years, will consumer credit grow faster than total credit or will it slow down? 3. In the next few years, will banks become more efficient at making loans out of deposits? Will financial disruptions cause fewer loans to be made, or lower-quality loans? 4. Will the US saving rate increase (personal saving, corporate saving, government saving)? Will foreigners continue to place their own saving into the US? Changes in capital intensity depends on the kind of products and industries in which a country specializes. Below is the evolution of the capital/labor ratio since 1980 (distinguishing between IT and non-IT capital). Do you think the US will continue present trends of specialization, or can you imagine reasons for change? Growth in total factor productivity A is technology in the broadest sense of the word. Can you imagine changes the rate of change of the way of constructing buildings, of the invention of Growth for IT for Nonmachines, and the development of new sources of in A capital IT Capital Total power, of changes in work organization, in the 1980 0.04 0.24 0.28 -0.022 efficiency of government regulation, in the degree of 1981 0.04 0.24 0.28 0.008 1982 0.04 0.24 0.28 -0.025 monopoly in the economy, in the literacy and skills of 1983 0.05 0.23 0.28 0.022 the workforce, etc.? 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.24 0.24 0.24 0.24 0.24 0.24 0.24 0.24 0.24 0.24 0.24 0.24 0.24 0.25 0.24 0.24 0.23 0.23 0.23 0.24 0.25 0.29 0.30 0.29 0.29 0.29 0.29 0.29 0.29 0.29 0.30 0.30 0.30 0.31 0.31 0.30 0.30 0.29 0.29 0.29 0.30 0.31 0.020 0.005 0.010 0.002 0.010 0.005 0.004 -0.005 0.025 0.002 0.009 -0.004 0.015 0.010 0.009 0.012 0.011 0.000 0.018 0.027 0.024