You are bidding for an object in an auction.
The object has a value to you of $20.
How much should you bid?
Depends on auction rules presumably
Suppose that the auction is a second-price auction
High bidder wins
Pays second highest bid
Sealed bids
We showed (using dominance) that the best strategy was to bid your value.
So bid $20 in this auction.
An English (or open outcry) auction is one where bidders shout bids publicly.
Auction ends when there are no higher bids.
Implemented as a “button auction” in Japan
Implemented on eBay through proxy bidding.
Again, suppose you value the object at $20.
Dominance says to drop out when bid = value.
The fact that bidding strategies are the same in the two auction forms means that they are strategically equivalent.
How much does the seller earn on the auction?
Depends on the distribution of values.
Suppose that there are 2 bidders and values are equally likely to be from $0 to $100.
The seller earns an amount equal to the expected losing bid.
The seller is interested in the expected value of the lower of two draws from 0-100.
This is called the second order statistic of the distribution.
We will sometimes write this as E[V k
(n)
] where the k denotes the order (highest, 2 nd highest, etc.) of the draw and (n) denotes the number of draws.
So we’re interested in E[V 2
(2)
]
There order statistics have simple regularity properties
The mean of a uniform draw from 0-100 is 50.
Note the mean could be written as E[V 1
(1)
].
100
0
50
Now suppose there are two draws.
What are the first and second order statistics?
0 33 66
100
With uniform distributions, the order statistics evenly divide the number line into n + 1 equal segments.
Let’s try 3 draws:
3rd
2nd
1st
50
0
25
75 100
So in general,
E[V k
(n)
] = 100* (n – k + 1)/(n + 1)
So revenues in a second price or English auction in this setting are:
E[V 2
(n)
] = 100 * (n – 1)/(n + 1)
As the number of bidders grows large, the seller’s revenues increase
As the number of bidders grows unbounded, the seller earns all the surplus, i.e. 100!
Now suppose you have a value of $20 and are competing with one other bidder in a firstprice auction
You don’t know the exact valuation of the other bidder.
But you do know that it is randomly drawn from 0 to 100.
How should you bid?
As usual, you want to bid to maximize your expected payoff
But now you need to make a projection about the strategy of the other bidder
Presumably this strategy depends on the particular valuation the bidder has.
Let b(v) be your projection for the bid of the other bidder when his valuation is v.
Choose a bid, B, to maximize expected profits.
E[Profit] = (20 – B) x Pr(B is the highest bid)
What is Pr(B is the highest bid)?
It is Pr(B > b(v))
b(v)
B
I win b -1 (B)
I lose v
Suppose that I believe that my rival’s strategy is to bid a constant fraction of his value
Then b(v) = av
Where a is some fraction
I win whenever
B >= av
Or, equivalently
v <= B/a
So Pr(B > b(v)) becomes:
Pr( v <= B/a) = B/100a
So now I need to choose B to maximize
E[Profit] = (20 – B)(B/100a)
Optimize in the usual way:
(1/100a) x (20 – 2B) = 0
Or B = 10
So I should bid 10 when my value is 20.
Suppose my value is V?
E[Profit] = (V – B)(B/100a)
Optimize in the usual way:
(1/100a) x (V – 2B) = 0
Or B = V/2
So I should always bid half my value.
My rival is doing the same calculation as me.
If he conjectures that I’m bidding ½ my value
He should bid ½ his value (for the same reasons)
Therefore, an equilibrium is where we each bid half our value.
This equilibrium we calculated is a slight variation on our usual equilibrium notion
Since I did not exactly know my rival’s payoffs in this game
I best responded to my expectation of his strategy
He did likewise
Mutual best responses in this setting are called Bayes-Nash Equilibrium.
The Bayes part comes from the fact that I’m using Bayes rule to figure out my expectation of his strategy.
In this setting, dominant strategies were not enough
What to bid in a first-price auction depends on conjectures about how many rivals I have and how much they bid.
Rationality requirements are correspondingly stronger.
How much does the seller make in this auction?
Since the high bidder wins, the relevant order statistic is E[V 1
(2)
] = 66.
But since each bidder only bids half his value, my revenues are
½ x E[V 1
(2)
] = 33
Notice that these revenues are exactly the same as in the second price or English auctions.
Two auction forms which yield the same expected revenues to the seller are said to be revenue equivalent
Operationally, this means that the seller’s choice of auction forms was irrelevant.
Suppose that I am bidding against n – 1 others, all of whom have valuations equally likely to be 0 to 100.
Now what should I bid?
Should I shade my bid more or less or the same?
In the case of second-price and English auctions, it didn’t matter how many rivals I had, I always bid my value
What about in the first-price auction?
Again, I conjecture that the others are bidding a fraction a of their value.
E[Profit] = (V – B) x Pr(B is the high bid)
To be the high bid means that I have to beat bidder 2.
Pr( B >= b(v
2
)) = B/100a
But I also have to now beat bidders 3 through n.
So now my chance of winning is
B/100a x B/100a x …B/100a
For n – 1 times.
Or equivalently
Pr(B is the highest) = [B/100a] n-1
Choose B to maximize expected profits
E[Profit] = (V – B) x Pr(B is highest)
E[Profit] = (V – B) x [B/100a] n-1
E[Profit] = (1/100a )n-1 x (V – B) x [B] n-1
Optimizing in the usual way:
(1/100a )n-1 x ((n-1)V – nB) [B] n-2 = 0
So the optimal bid is
B = V x (n-1)/n
I bid a proportion of my value
But that proportion is (n-1)/n
As I’m competing against more rivals, I shade my bid less.
Since all my rivals are making the same calculation, in equilibrium everyone bids a fraction (n-1)/n of their value.
How much does the seller make in this auction?
The relevant order statistic is E[V 1
(n)
] = 100* n/(n + 1)
But eveyone shades by (n-1)/n so
Revenues = (n-1)/n x E[V 1
(n)
]
Revenues = 100 x (n-1)/(n+1)
Revenues are increasing in the number of bidders
As that number grows arbitrarily large, the seller gets all the surplus, i.e. 100!
How does this compare to the English or
Second-Price auction?
First-price:
R = (n-1)/n x E[V 1
(n)
]
R = 100 x (n-1)/(n+1)
Second-price:
R = E[V 2
(n)
]
R = 100 x (n-1)/(n+1)
The auctions still yield the same expected revenues.
In fact, revenue equivalence holds quite generally
Consider any auction which:
Allocates the object to the highest bidder
Gives any bidder the option of paying zero
Then if bidders know their values
Values are uncorrelated
Values are drawn from the same distribution
Then all such auctions are revenue equivalent!
This means that we can determine the revenues quickly and easily for all sorts of auctions
Consider an all-pay auction
Bidders submit cash payments to the seller
(bribes)
The bidder submitting the highest bribe gets the object
The seller keeps all the bribe money
This auction auction yields the same revenues as an English auction.
Suppose that all bidders submit bribes to the auctioneer
The object is awarded to the person paying the highest bribe
And the seller gives back the bribe of the winner, but keeps all the others
This is also revenue equivalent.
Revenue equivalence says that the form of the auction does not affect how much money the seller makes.
But there are other tools the seller has to make money.
Suppose that the seller is running an auction that attracts only one bidder.
What should he do?
If he goes with the usual auction forms, he’ll make nothing since the second highest valuation for the object is zero.
Since the seller is a monopoly provider of the good, maybe some tricks from monopoly theory might help.
Suppose a monopolist faced a linear demand curve and could only charge a single price
What price should he charge?
P
Demand curve
Q
The monopolist should choose p to maximize profits
Profits = P x Q(P) – C(Q(P))
Or equivalently, the monopolist could choose
Q to maximize profits
Profits = P(Q) x Q – C(Q)
P(Q) is the inverse demand function
Optimizing in the usual way, we have:
MR = MC
P
Marginal Revenue
P*
MC
Q
Q*
What is the demand curve faced by a seller in a one bidder auction?
One can think of the “quantity” as the probability of making a sale at a given price.
So if the seller asks for $100, he will make no sales.
If he asks for $0, he will sell with probability = 1
If he asks $50, he will sell with probability .5
P
100
50
0
1 Q = Pr of sale
1/2
P
Q = 1 – F(p)
100
50
0
1 Q = Pr of sale
1/2
So the demand curve is just the probability of making a sale
Pr(V > P)
If we denote by F(p) the probability that V
<=p, then
Q = 1 – F(p)
But we need the inverse demand curve to do the monopoly problem the usual way.
P = F -1 (1 – Q)
Now we’re in a position to do the optimization.
The seller should choose a reserve price to maximize his expected profits
E[Profits] = p x (1 – F)
Equivalently, the auctioneer chooses a quantity to maximize
E[Profits] = F -1 (1 – Q) x Q
As usual the optimal quantity is where MR =
MC
But MC is zero in this case
So the optimal quantity is where MR = 0
P
Marginal Revenue
100
P*
0
1 Q = Pr of sale
Q*
Revenue = F -1 (1 – Q) x Q
Marginal Revenue = F -1 (1 – Q) – Q/f(F -1 (1 –
Q))
where f(p) is (approximately) the probability that v = p
Now substitute back:
P – (1 – F(p))/f(p) = 0
In the case where valuations are evenly distributed from 0 to 100
F(p) = p/100
f(p) = 1/100
So
P – (1 – P) = 0
Or
P = 50!
The seller maximizes his revenue in an auction by:
Step 1: Choosing any auction form satisfying the revenue equivalence principle
Step 2: Placing a reserve price equal to the optimal reserve in a one bidder auction
Key point 1: The optimal reserve price is independent of the number of bidders.
Key point 2: The optimal reserve price is
NEVER zero.
Optimal bidding depends on the rules of the auction
In English and second price auctions, bid your value
In first-price auctions, shade your bid below your value
The amount to shade depends on the competition
More competition = less shading
As an auctioneer, the rules of the auction do not affect revenues much
However reserve prices do matter
The optimal reserve solves the monopoly problem for a one bidder auction