The Economics of Baseball

advertisement
Eco 383: PPT lecture slides,
Oct.–mid-Nov. 2007
(last updated 11/13/2007)
• Third debate (Thurs., Nov. 8):
– Topic: Resolved: MLB should have a payroll cap for the sake of
competitive balance.
• Fourth debate (Thurs., Nov. 29):
– Topic: Resolved: Most free agents are overpaid, so teams should
make lower bids for them.
• Topics:
– I. Franchise finances
– II. Competitive balance and market size
– III. Player salaries, MRPL, and monopsonistic exploitation
Franchise Finances
Franchise finances: An introduction
• Why we care:
– (1) To draw a conclusion about the health of the
industry (MLB), we need to know about the
health of individual firms (teams).
– (2) Issue of whether the small-market teams can
afford to field competitive teams.
• If too many teams cannot compete, then demand for
MLB will tend to fall.
MLB’s 2000 report concluded that...
• (1) 27 of the 30 MLB teams had cumulative
operating losses in 1995-99.
• (2) Small- and mid-market teams can’t compete,
because they can’t afford to field very good teams.
• Caveat: That was seven years ago. MLB officials
say the picture is much brighter now.
Computing team profits
• OPERATING PROFIT
• = total revenues total costs
• same as “operating
income”
• what’s usually focused
on
• reported in Forbes
(1997-), Financial
World (1990-96)
• PRE-TAX PROFIT
• = operating profit interest costs* “player depreciation”
• ≤ operating profit
• declared to IRS
• (* interest costs could
be from purchase of
team, stadium debt…)
Ways to hide a team’s profits
• Claim “depreciation” of your players as a loss (over 5
years, up to 50% of what you paid for the team; legal
under U.S. tax law).
• Deduct the interest paid on team-related loans.
• Related-party transactions: If you own another
company that does business with the team, overcharge
your team (or pay it too little) in those deals.
• Featherbedding: Pay yourself (and friends and
relatives) an excessive salary and claim it as a cost.
Breakdown of team revenues
(Forbes, 1998)
• 40% tickets & suites
• 34% broadcasting
• 12% food,
merchandise
• 7% ads, sponsorship
• 6% other
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
Tix B'cast Food Ads Other
Breakdown of team costs
In descending order of importance
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
Player salaries (~55% in 1992-2001)
Scouting & player development (farm teams…)
“General and administrative”
Team operations (front office, manager, coaches…)
Marketing, publicity, ticket operations
Stadium operations
(MLB revenue-sharing and general fund
– Net cost for richer teams, net revenue for poorer teams
What is the return on owning a
baseball team?
• Operating profits are almost irrelevant…
• As with a stock, most of the return comes
from the long-term increase in the value of
your asset (team).
Desirable properties of investments
• (1) High return, including
– Short-term interest, dividends, or earnings
– Long-term capital gain (can resell at profit)
– Favorable tax treatment
• (2) Low risk of loss
• (3) Liquidity (ease of resale)
• (4) Cash flow
Desirable properties of investments, as
applied to MLB teams
• (1) High return – excellent
– But, over 1998-2006, NFL franchise values grew much
faster, and NBA franchise values grew a little faster.
• (2) Low risk of loss – excellent
– Teams typically earn very high overall returns, with
very few exceptions.
• (3) Liquidity – poor
– Costly and time-consuming to resell a team
• (4) Cash flow – poor
– Yearly return on assets (operating profit as % of assets)
is tiny, less than interest on Treasury bonds
Calculating a team’s (one-year)
return on investment (ROI)
ROI =
% increase in estimated team value
+ (operating profit as % of previous year’s team
value)
Note well: Because operating profit is usually a very small
fraction of team value, ROI will usually be very close to
the one-year percent change in team value.
To calculate ROI from the Forbes table
The example below uses the data from the May 2006 Forbes ($1026 M value,
a one-year change of 8%, operating income of -$50 M in 2005) to compute
the 2005-2006 ROI for the Yankees
-- Note: The denominator under operating income needs to be the previous
year’s team value, which Forbes does not provide. You can get it by
working backwards from the current year’s estimated value and the “1-year
change in value” (percent change from previous year’s value).
-- Ex.: Forbes says the Yankees were worth $1026 M in 2006, an increase
of 8% (or .08) from 2005.  The Yankees’ 2005 valuation was then
($1026 M)/(1+.08) = $950 M
ROI  .08  $$1 0502 6M
M

1 .0 8
 .08 
 $50 M
$950 M
 .08  .053
 .027 ( *100%)  2.7%
Estimated one-year return on MLB teams
(source: Forbes)
Year
Operating profit % increase in team value
(return on assets) (return on investment)
1999 $1.0 million
(0.5% of team
value)
2000 $4.3 million
(1.8% of t.v.)
6%
(6.5%)
2001 $2.5 million
(1.0% of t.v.)
10%
(11.0%)
2002 -$1.3 million
(-0.5% of t.v.)
3%
(2.5%)
12%
(13.8%)
Estimated one-year returns, cont’d
Year
Operating profit % increase in team value
(return on assets) (return on investment)
2003 -$1.9 million
(-0.7% of t.v.)
3%
(2.3%)
2004 $4.4 million
(1.5% of t.v.)
15%
(16.5%)
2005 $12.1 million
(3.7% of t.v.)
2006 $16.5 million
(4.4% of t.v.)
15%
(18.7%)
14.8%
(19.2%)
Is the sky falling on MLB financially?
• YES, said owners and
commissioner (until
very recently)
• Selig: for 2001, a
$232 M operating loss
& $519 M book loss
• several MLB teams
were for sale in 200102, few buyers
• NO, say most
independent researchers
• Forbes: for 2001, a $75
M operating profit
• sluggish economy
explains poor resale
market in 2001-02
• franchises normally sell
at big profits; high rates
of asset appreciation
Media ownership of teams
• Ownership of teams by media companies, esp. TV
stations, complicates the profit picture.
– Media companies often buy teams as programming
content, not as separate investments; synergy strategy.
– Large operating losses may be OK if media company’s
own profits go up.
• Possible danger sign: Two media companies
recently sold their teams.
– (Fox) News Corp. sold Dodgers, Disney sold Angels
– Time Warner looking to sell Braves?
What a difference a year makes:
Baseball finances improved dramatically
from 2003 to 2004 (and still more in 2005 & 2006)
2003
2004
2005
2006
average operating -0.7% +1.5%
profit (as % of
assets)
3.7%
4.4%
# of teams with 15
positive operating
profit
# of teams whose 17
estimated value
rose
25
29
28
30
(only 1
fell)
30
20
What is competitive balance?
• Blue Ribbon Panel report (2000):
competitive balance exists when
– “there are no chronically weak clubs because of
MLB’s financial structural features”
– a well-managed club has a reasonable hope of
reaching postseason play and winning
Why is competitive balance an
economic issue?
• The demand for MLB will tend to fall if-– too many teams cannot compete
– fans perceive that the richest teams have an
unfair advantage
Simple measures of competitive
balance
• Standard deviation of team winning percentages
• Number of WS or pennant winners, in comparison
with-– number of teams in league
– previous years or intervals
• Average number of games out of first place?
MLB’s competitive balance, then & now
•
•
•
•
1903-1950s: not much, but gradually improving
1965-1976: improved more; amateur draft helped
1977-early 1990s: peak of competitive balance
1995-2001: competitive imbalance?
– strong correlation between payroll and W-L % and
postseason
• no teams outside top 25% of payrolls won WS
• only 4 teams from bottom half of payrolls made postseason
(and they won just 5 of 224 games)
• 2002-2007 WS winners and payroll rank: Angels (15thhighest), Marlins (26th), Red Sox (2nd), White Sox (13th),
Cardinals (11th), Red Sox (2nd) or Rockies (25th)
Does a higher payroll mean more wins?
(2002-2007)
• Regressions of regular-season win. % on Opening
Day payroll for all 30 teams find –
– About 25% of the variation in wins is explained by
variation in payroll
• Actual variation in wins is much larger than payroll-predicted
variation in wins
– Payroll has a positive effect on wins
• $7-8 M in payroll = 1 more win
• Marginal benefit of Yankees’ last $50 M in payroll = 0 wins?
– This effect is small but statistically significant
What is “market size”?
• Market size is based on REVENUES (both
actual and potential).
• Revenues are very dependent on the quality
of the team’s product (wins, players,
stadium, etc.), but also on local factors like
– area population
– area per-capita income
– area level of interest in baseball (hard to
measure)
• Hard to separate team factors from local
factors, actual from potential market size
Two crude measures of market size
• TOTAL REVENUES, as compared with the other
MLB teams
• ESTIMATED TEAM VALUE, as compared with
the other MLB teams
– more forward-looking, e.g., higher if team is about to
move into new stadium
• Top third = “large market,” middle third = “midmarket,” bottom third = “small market”?
• Market size perhaps cannot be measured precisely
Can the small-market teams compete?
MAYBE
• First 15 years of free
agency (1977-91) saw
unprecedented parity,
several successful smallmarket teams
• Insignificant correlation
between payroll and W-L %
through mid-1990s
• Recent success of some
small-market teams
• Market size is not static
MAYBE NOT
• Yankees: 4 WS titles in 5
years (1996-2000)
• 1997-2007: statistically
significant correlation
between payroll, W-L %
• Only one small-market,
low-payroll team has won
WS since 1991
• Collapse of Montreal
Expos (well-run smallmarket team)
Competitive balance in recent decades
• Recall:
– 1977-early 1990s: peak of competitive balance
– 1995-2001: some pattern of competitive imbalance
• Explanations:
– Free agency (post-1976) helped comp. balance
• Easier for also-rans to improve themselves with new talent
• Rising salaries --> harder to keep championship teams intact
– Growing revenue and wealth imbalance in 1990s
• Growing importance of local media and stadium revenues
– Value of MLB’s national TV deal fell 60% in 1994
• Increasing corporate (esp. media) ownership of teams
Competitive balance in other pro sports
• (NFL) National Football League: highest comp. balance
– lowest concentration of championships
– policies: ~70% of revenues are shared; hard salary cap;
“unbalanced” schedule
– lowest correlation between payroll and performance
• (NHL) National Hockey League: ????
– Pre-2004: in the middle:
• low concentration of championships (1991-2002: 8 different teams)
• little revenue sharing, no luxury tax, no salary cap
• lower payroll-performance correlation than MLB or NBA
– 2004-05: season-long lockout by owners, who got a salary cap
• (NBA) National Basketball Association: least balanced
– high concentration of championships (1991-2002: just 4 teams)
– increasing standard deviation of win percentages since 1980
The English Premier League (PL; soccer)
• League membership not fixed (non-monopolistic)
– no territorial rights
• London: 9 PL teams since 1990
• Within the league, a hierarchy of divisions
– bad high-division teams are relegated (demoted)
– good low-division teams are promoted to higher ones
• Comp. balance is mixed
– good in terms of standard deviation of win percentages,
upward mobility of teams
– high championship concentration (Manchester United)
How can be MLB’s competitive balance
be increased?
• Payroll cap / luxury tax?
– Payroll cap might work, but is not feasible -- players’
union willing to strike to prevent one
– MLB has a luxury tax on large payrolls, but threshold is
too high to be binding for most teams
• Increased revenue sharing?
– Could work, but details are key:
• What if teams use accounting tricks to hide revenues?
• Incentive for low-revenue teams to improve themselves?
– Part of 2002 Collective Bargaining Agreement (CBA)
• 2006 CBA keeps revenue sharing high, while supposedly
providing better incentives for teams to improve themselves
Player salaries, MRPL, and
exploitation
News flash:
MLB players are highly paid
• Average MLB salary = $2.9 M (April 2007)
– 2 times as high as in 1998
– 10 times as high as in 1983
– less than NBA ($5.4 M in 2007)
– more than NHL (~$2 M in 2007) and NFL ($1.4 M in
2006)
• Median MLB salary = $1 M in 2006 and 2007
– Highest ever; previous peak was $975,000 in 2000
– 66 players made $10 M or more
marginal revenue product of labor
(MRPL)
• = the amount of revenue that an employee
generates for his employer
• standard economic answer to “How much is
that employee worth?”
• can be measured in yearly terms (salary), or in
hourly terms (hourly wage)
• marginal product of labor (MPL) = how much
OUTPUT an employee produces
MRP theory & player pay
• First, note that athletes are not the only very highlypaid people in U.S. society
• Also, free-agent contracts are examples of
VOLUNTARY EXCHANGE (market transactions
agreed upon by buyer and seller)
– Nobody forces the owners to pay such high salaries.
• Rodney Fort: “talent is hired to produce [wins] in
the long run.”
– perhaps more than just wins...
– Mark McGwire, 1998: extra MRPL of $15M?
A labor market under perfect competition:
Assumptions
• Many buyers, many sellers
– > nobody has market power
• No restrictions on pay or employment
• No cartels among employers or workers
• Diminishing returns
--> downward-sloping demand curve for labor
• Upward-sloping supply curve for labor
Notation (for diagram drawn on board):
•
•
•
•
•
L = # of workers ( = QL = quantity of labor)
w = wage ( = PL = price of labor)
SL = supply of labor
DL = demand for labor
MRPL = marginal revenue product of labor
– MRPL = the amount of revenue that an
additional worker generates for the firm
Economic exploitation
• MONOPSONY: a labor market with just one buyer
• ECONOMIC EXPLOITATION
• = difference between a worker’s marginal
revenue product and his wage
• = MRPL - w
• In a monopsonistic labor market:
• w < MRPL
• w < w* (competitive wage)
When the baseball players’
labor market was a monopsony
• Until 1976, when all players were under the
reserve clause.
• RESERVE CLAUSE: a provision in baseball’s
rules that allowed owners to renew a player’s
contract automatically for one year.
– Players either re-signed with their teams after each
season or retired (or were traded or released).
– No free agency; no competitive bidding for players.
– Held salaries down; average salary = $25,000 in 1969.
Independence Day
• July 1976: new Basic Agreement gives all players
free agency after 6 years of service.
– Salaries surged after 1976; up 42% in 1976-77
– Can use monopsony diagram to illustrate
Baseball’s current system
Year of ML
service
Eligible for…
1st - 2nd
Rookie minimum (Team can pay
($380,000 in 2007) more if it wants.)
3rd - 6th
Salary arbitration
After 6th
Free agency
Baseball’s salary explosion,
1976-present
• “Freedom and prosperity”
• Shift from monopsony to competitive bidding was
less sudden than it seems
– Over time, more and more teams played the FA market
– Collusion against FA’s held salaries down in mid-1980s
• Salary arbitration (1973-) allowed 3rd-to-6th-year
players to piggyback on FA salary scale
• MLB revenues surged -- attendance rose, TV
revenues soared, stadium revenues soared, ...
Comparison of performance
(MRPL) and salaries
• First, how to measure MRPL?
For hitters, the one statistic that has
the highest correlation with team
winning percentages is...
“OPS”
• =
On-base percentage (OBP)
+ Slugging percentage (SLG)
• OPS * (player’s plate appearances as % of team’s)
= what Zimbalist and Bradbury use to measure
hitters’ productivity, in computing MRPL’s
For pitchers
• Earned run average (ERA) is the standard
measure
– Bradbury prefers “Defense-Independent
Pitching Statistics” (DIPS), which is like ERA
minus the contributions of the team’s fielders
• Includes walks, strikeouts, and home runs allowed
– Then compare a pitcher’s DIPS with the league
average, and multiply by his innings pitched as
a % of his team’s total.
Next steps toward estimating MRPL
• Estimate the player’s contribution to
team winning percentage, based on
wins as a function of OPS
• Estimate contribution of additional
wins to team revenues
Comparison of performance
(MRPL) and salaries:
• Exploitation = MRPL – salary
• Zimbalist (1992):
– Younger players tend to be exploited (pay<MRPL)
– Veteran players (6+ years in majors) tend to be
“overpaid” (pay>MRPL)
• MRPL calculations by Bill Felber (The Book on the
Book, 2005) echo Zimbalist’s conclusion
• MRPL calculations by Bradbury (p. 195) find
pay<MRPL but a much smaller gap for veterans
– But, “I don’t think this is exploitive,” if you take
development costs into account.
MRPL - salary, by service category
MRPL – pay, on average
(Bradbury,
(Zimbalist; 2005; hitters,
1986-89)
pitchers)
Year of
service
Category
1st - 2nd
reserved
75 – 84%
(highly
exploited)
89%, 90%
3rd - 6th
arbitrationeligible
36 – 50%
(exploited)
77%, 78%
After
6th
free-agenteligible
-40%
(overpaid)
8%, 36%
How do we explain those systematically
“overpaid”* veterans?
•
(* overpaid by Zimbalist’s and Felber’s estimates)
• Supply and demand: limited supply of free agent players,
high demand for players who can help a team
• Most free agents are past their prime (age 30+), which
reduces their MRPL, but as free agents they’re in a
position to earn the most money
• Statistical MRPL measure may be too narrow -- doesn’t
count leadership, consistency, marquee value
• Many free-agent contracts are long term
– --> reduced incentive to work hard?
Download