New Economic School (NES), Moscow Russia

advertisement
Doug Campbell, Assistant Professor
New Economic School (NES), Moscow Russia
Relative Prices, Hysteresis, and the Decline of American Manufacturing
The 2000s began with the Federal Reserve narrowly missing the zero lower bound on short-term interest
rates. Then the US needed a housing bubble to attain full-ish employment in the mid-2000s, a decade that
ended with the US and other major economies falling into liquidity traps, where they have been ever since.
The causes of this sustained shortfall in demand, termed secular stagnation, was the topic of a recent
VoxEU.org ebook. In this post, based in part on my job market paper, I argue that one of the main sources
of this economic “time of troubles” has to do with relative prices, trade, and the rise of China.
A Theory of Secular Stagnation: Trade and China
This thesis is not new. Ryan Avent, Acemoglu et al. (2013), Autor et al. (2013), Dean Baker, and Pierce
and Schott (2014) all tell stories in which trade and the rise of China have had left marks on the US
economy. In my preferred version, there were two factors, the rise of low-wage China and a sharp
appreciation of the US dollar in the late 1990s (Figure 1, the green line shows the Fed’s RER index;
WARP will be explained later) fueled in part by the Great Reserve Accumulation. These two events led to
a persistently large trade deficit (Figure 1, blue line) and a collapse in US manufacturing employment
(Figure 2). This collapse caused the Fed to keep interest rates very low in the 2000s just to attain
investment levels consistent with full employment, contributing to the housing bubble. The flip side of a
trade deficit is a capital inflow, which, via an accounting identity, implies that domestic savings is less
than investment. Less savings means more debt, and thus the trade deficit could itself have caused
Americans to become overleveraged, leading to a balance sheet recession once the housing bubble
collapsed. Finally, due to hysteresis and balance sheet effects, an overvalued dollar in 2002 can continue
to effect aggregate demand today. Historically, temporary appreciations of relative prices have lead to
persistent trade deficits and persistently smaller tradable sectors. In addition, households are still trying to
replenish their balance sheets by reducing spending. Fortunately, US relative prices no longer appear to
be much higher than our trading partners as a whole (not so for much of Europe). On the other hand, the
“Rise of China” is still far from complete.
.8
-.04
1
-.02
1.2
0
1.4
.02
Figure 1: Real Exchange Rate Measures vs. the Goods Trade Balance, Ex-Oil
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
Goods Trade Balance ex-Oil, GDP Share
Divisia using CPI (Fed's Method)
2000
2010
WARP
Figure 2: American Manufacturing Employment
American Manufacturing Employment
Millions
22
Share
12%
20
employment
(left axis)
10%
18
8%
16
6%
14
share of population
(right axis)
4%
12
10
1960
2%
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010
The Evidence
What is the evidence that a temporary appreciation of US relative prices led to the surprisingly sudden
collapse of US manufacturing employment? In my job market paper, “Relative Prices, Hysteresis, and the
Decline of American Manufacturing”, I try to get at this question by studying the impact of relative price
(or real exchange rate) movements on manufacturing. There are two key difficulties with answering this
question.
The first difficulty, surprisingly, was to design a theoretically appropriate measure of the real exchange
rate. Longtime readers of Econbrowser, of course, know from this post that commonly-used real
exchange rate measures produced by the Federal Reserve and the IMF suffer from an index numbers
problem. This problem is almost identical to “outlet substitution bias” in the CPI, the bias that arises when
new stores, such as Walmart, open and offer lower prices than existing stores. This effective price
reduction does not get reflected in the CPI. In the case of real exchange rate indices, China is essentially
the new giant low cost entrant, wreaking havoc on various government statistics including the Fed’s
widely used Broad Trade-Weighted RER index. In Figure 1 (green dashes), the Fed’s index is compared
to a simple Weighted-Average of Relative Prices (WARP), which adequately reflects the growing role of
trade with China, computed using price level data from version 8.0 of the PWT.1 In my research, I extend
WARP back to 1820 for the US, and find that the US price level in 2002 had not been that high relative to
trading partners since the worst year of the Great Depression. 2 WARP, however, does not take
productivity into account (Bangladesh may have low wages, but since it also has low productivity it may
not be a competitive threat), and so I introduce two new series, a Balassa-Samuelson adjustment to
WARP and Weighted Average Relative Unit Labor Costs (WARULC), both of which I use as my main
measures of relative prices in my dissertation.
The second problem is ubiquitous in economics – how to identify a causal relationship as opposed to
correlation. One strategy I use is to look at disaggregated, sectoral data. In the early 2000s, the
manufacturing sectors that did the worst were those who were the most exposed to trade (and not just to
China), and their worst years were when the dollar was the most overvalued (controlling for the most
likely potential other factors, such as recessions and interest rates). Secondly, I look at several natural
experiments, periods in which we can plausibly identify the cause of movements in relative prices.
Several of the episodes I study are the US experience in the 1980s, when the Reagan deficits led to a
1
It is worth mentioning that the PWT is being revised in a way in which WARP for the US could be more
comparable to the PWT v7.1, in which case the relative price shock in the early 2000s would have been about as
large as the appreciation in the 1980s. This likely would not change the basic story.
2
In addition, I found that Japan’s price level was on average nearly twice that of its trading partners during its two
decades spent in a liquidity trap.
sharp dollar bubble, and Canada’s experience since 2000, when a weak US dollar and rising oil prices led
to an appreciation of Canadian relative prices. In each case, I find that relative price appreciations have a
large adverse impact on trade, productivity, output, and employment concentrated in those sectors most
exposed to trade. (I also found that productivity growth has not resulted in more jobs lost since 2000 than
in previous decades when aggregate manufacturing employment was flat, a finding supported by others.)
That the results appear to hold up out of sample in different time periods and countries give reason to
believe that the relationship is causal.
The methodology in my study on manufacturing is readily apparent in Figure 3 below. In panel (a), I
compare the most open manufacturing sectors in 1972 (where openness is the trade share of output) with
the least open sectors. In the 1970s, when US relative unit labor costs were similar to our trading partners,
there was no difference in employment (or output) performance of the most open sectors relative to the
least open sectors. However, when US RULC’s appreciated sharply in the mid-1980s, the more open
sectors lost ground relative to the sectors which were less exposed, controlling for other factors.
Interestingly, once US RULCs returned close to fundamentals, the jobs lost in the most open sectors did
not return – a striking example of hysteresis. Panel (b) of Figure 3 shows that much the same thing
happened in the early 2000s. The finding of hysteresis is important, because the implicit model most
economists assume when they think about trade policy, particularly vis-à-vis China, does not incorporate
the potential for hysteresis.
1.4
120
WARULC
100
90
1.1
1.2
1.3
110
1.4
1.3
1.2
1.1
1972
1976
1980
Most Open: Top 25%
2 s.d. Error Bounds
1984
1988
1992
1996
Least Open: Bottom 50%
Rel. ULC Index
(a) The 1980s Dollar Bubble
1
80
1
85
90
95
100
Weighted-Avg. Rel. ULCs
105
1.5
110
Figure 3: Employment Growth by Initial Openness
1989
1992
1995
1998
Most Open: Top 25%
2 s.d. Error Bounds
2001
2004
2007
2010
Least Open: Bottom 50%
Rel. ULC Index
(b) The 2000s Manufacturing Collapse (NAICs)
The Trade Deficit and the Rise of China: Big Enough to Matter?
Was the collapse in manufacturing large enough to lead to secular stagnation? My panel estimates imply
that two million jobs were lost directly due to the appreciation of US relative prices through 2008.
However, the input-output tables tell us that every dollar of manufacturing output requires 60 cents of
input (a bit more than half of this is direct, the rest indirect) from other manufacturing sectors. This could
seemingly put the actual number of jobs lost in manufacturing due to trade closer to three million.
Additionally, manufacturing also consumes input from other sectors of the economy in a proportion
similar to which it consumes other manufactures, and affects local labor markets and local government
revenue. While we might not know what elasticity to apply, exactly, we do know that areas which lose
manufacturing jobs typically struggle to attract other industries. If these areas were totally unable to
attract other tradable sectors, then the long-run elasticity would simply be the inverse of the share of
tradable employment in the economy. Defining tradable sectors very generously, I get a number of
perhaps 3 or 4 to 1 for the US as a whole. Thus it isn’t hard to wind up with a total long-run shock to
employment, in the absence of a central bank response, of more than 10 million. This is easily large
enough to be the primary cause of secular stagnation, even if other factors, such as demography, are also
at play.
Policy Implications: A Return to Free Trade
Now that we know one of the chief causes of the poor growth since 2000, how does this change our
knowledge of what needs to be done? Certainly one implication is the necessity of encouraging China to
let the free market determine the value of its currency, particularly as manufacturing sectors which
compete with China continued to shed jobs through 2011 even as overall manufacturing employment
increased. And there are still millions more US manufacturing jobs which could eventually be relocated.
Unilateral attempts by the Fed and/or Treasury to weaken the dollar directly or via fiscal policy may have
been helpful in the early 2000s, but they wouldn’t work against China with its capital controls, and would
(rightfully) meet with international opposition. I favor an indirect approach: the Fed should aim for higher
inflation, which functions as a tax on China’s estimated 2.5 trillion in dollar-denominated foreign reserves.
This policy makes sense for other reasons given that US inflation has been extremely low for years and
prime aged employment has only just started to recover. Can the Fed achieve higher inflation? In short,
yes. All recent evidence points to the conclusion that, for better or worse, the limits of monetary policy in
a liquidity trap lie in the minds of FOMC members rather than in their policy tools. One strategy the Fed
and the ECB might want to consider is to stop tightening monetary policy when core inflation is well
below target and there is mass unemployment – something both central banks have done repeatedly since
2009 (in emulation of the Bank of Japan during its lost decades?). And, the lesson of hysteresis tells us
that the legacy of continued slow growth as the world waits for the Fed (and the ECB) to discover their
wits will be diminished economic possibilities for years to come.
Download